YOU ARE DOWNLOADING DOCUMENT

Please tick the box to continue:

Transcript
Page 1: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

1

Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How Different?

Robert C. M. Beyer and Frank Smets Goethe Universität Frankfurt; European Central Bank and KU Leuven

PAPER PRESENTED AT THE 60th PANEL MEETING OF ECONOMIC POLICY IN

OCTOBER 2014

1. INTRODUCTION

Since the outbreak of the financial crisis in 2008, high and diverging unemployment

rates across European countries and regions have become an increasingly important

concern for European policy makers. In 2013 the unemployment rate in Spain was above

25%, but only around 5% in Germany. Heterogeneity is large not only between countries

but also within countries. For example, in France, Belgium and Spain the highest

regional unemployment rates were twice as high as the lowest. In Italy, as an extreme

example, the unemployment rate in Veneto was just a third of the unemployment rates in

Campania or Sardinia. Moreover, this regional heterogeneity has increased since 2008

(Marelli, Patuelli, and Signorelli, 2012).

These persistent differences in unemployment rates across regions and countries have

put the role of migration in labour market adjustment back on the European policy

agenda. Migration can cushion the negative impact of adverse labour demand shocks on

unemployment and thereby smooth the adjustment to heterogeneous macroeconomic

developments. This is particularly important within a monetary union, in which relative

wage adjustments may be slow due to the absence of nominal exchange rate adjustments.

In 2013 the Commission adopted a proposal for a directive on new measures to facilitate

labour mobility and the European Council agreed on measures to fight youth

unemployment aiming, among other things, at increasing the mobility of young workers.

The views expressed in this paper are our own and not necessarily those of the European Central Bank or its

Governing Council. We are grateful to Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln, Michele Lenza, Giuseppe Bertola, Domenico Giannone, Ana Lamo, Jens Suedekum, four anonymous referees, to the participants of the 2013 ECB-CEPR

conference on ‘Heterogeneity in currency areas and macroeconomic policies’ at the European Central Bank,

and to seminar and workshop participants at Goethe Universität, DIW, and Deutsche Bundesbank for helpful comments.

Page 2: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

2

In this paper we contribute to this policy debate by empirically investigating how

labour markets adjust to asymmetric labour demand developments and whether

migration contributes substantially to this adjustment, using a modified version of the

methodology of Blanchard and Katz (1992). In particular, we compare regional and

country labour market adjustment in Europe with state adjustment in the US. The US is a

natural benchmark for such a comparison because it is a large monetary union of similar

size with a well-functioning, quite homogenous labour market. The US benchmark may

therefore give an idea of how much scope there is for increased labour mobility and

migration to play a role in labour market adjustment in Europe.

We are not the first ones to make this comparison. In particular, Decressin and Fatás

(1995) and Obstfeld and Peri (1998) also applied the methodology of Blanchard and

Katz (1992) to compare regional labour market adjustment in Europe and the United

States.1 Overall, they found that the regional adjustment process is faster in the United

States due to higher labour mobility. There are at least three reasons why it is important

to update and refine this analysis.

First, we have a much longer sample (38 years rather than 13 years in Decressin and

Fatás (1995)). This allows us to investigate the robustness of their findings and, more

importantly, whether the adjustment process has changed over time. Since the early

1990s European integration has continued to proceed in a number of areas which should

facilitate the regional adjustment process. There is, for example, evidence that migration

between European countries has increased due to the Schengen Agreement and the

introduction of the euro (Beine et al., 2013). Some of these changes have become quite

visible since the outbreak of the financial crisis. For example, net migration between

Germany and the crisis countries (Spain, Portugal, Italy and Greece) has risen from

minus 10.000 in 2009 to 70.000 in 2012. In contrast, interstate migration in the US has

been decreasing since the 1980s and has dropped during the crisis to the lowest values

since World War II (Frey, 2009). It is therefore interesting to see whether this has led to

a convergence of the regional labour market adjustment process in Europe and the

United States.

Secondly, when comparing Europe and the United States, Decressin and Fatás (1995)

did not make a distinction between regional labour market adjustment within countries

and between countries, while Obstfeld and Peri (1998) only focused on adjustment

within countries. In this paper, we use the common factor methodology of Greenaway-

McGrevy and Hood (2013) to filter out country factors and analyse the adjustment of

countries to national labour demand shocks, which is likely to be hampered by bigger

cultural, language and institutional differences. This allows us to investigate whether any

convergence with the US is due to a smoother working of the adjustment process within

or between countries.

Thirdly, a straightforward comparison of the European and US results was hampered

by the different data sources being used in those studies. We show that the differences

are less pronounced when similar data sources are used.

1 See Section 2 for a more detailed overview of the literature.

Page 3: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

3

The following findings are worth highlighting. First, looking at the full sample we find

that both in Europe and the US labour mobility accounts for about 50% of the long run

adjustment to region-specific labour demand shocks. The other 50% is accounted for by

a reallocation of jobs across regions. But, in Europe it takes longer (10 years) than in the

United States (5 years) for this adjustment process to be completed. And due to the

greater rigidity of labour markets, the temporary response of the unemployment rate is

more important and more persistent in European regional labour market adjustment.

Second, we show that in Europe labour mobility is a less important adjustment

mechanism in response to country-specific labour demand shocks. In this case, both the

unemployment rate and the participation rate play a larger and more persistent role in the

adjustment process. This underlines the remaining cultural, language and institutional

barriers to labour mobility across European countries and provides support to European

policy initiatives to further facilitate migration across countries.

Third, in line with Dao, Furceri and Loungani (2014), we find that the role of

migration in the regional adjustment process has decreased in the US. In contrast, in

Europe migration has become a more powerful adjustment factor in response to both

regional- and country-specific labour demand shocks in the second half of the sample

(1990-2013 versus 1977-1999). This suggests that the acceleration of the European

integration process after the early 1990s has led to more labour mobility across regions

and countries.

In the rest of the paper, we first briefly review in Section 2 how migration is typically

analysed in the literature. Section 3, presenting the Blanchard-Katz methodology and our

modifications, may be skipped by readers only interested in the results. The data is

presented and discussed in Section 4 and Section 5 contains the main empirical analysis.

Section 6 links our results to Blanchard and Katz (1992) and is not relevant for the main

message. Finally, Section 7 discusses some policy implications.

2. Studying Migration

The importance of labour migration in facilitating adjustment to asymmetric shocks in

a monetary union has been recognised at least since the seminal research on optimal

currency areas of Mundell (1961). The empirical analysis of migration has, however,

been hampered by the lack of reliable data. Recently an increasing number of papers

have started to analyse migration patterns directly. Molloy, Smith and Wozniak (2011)

analyse changes in the US over the last 30 years and detect a widespread decline in

movements across all distances and across all population sub-groups. Frey (2009) shows

that in 2007 migration rates in the US reached their lowest value since World War II and

Page 4: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

4

that the decline was strongest for interstate migration. Reasons for the decline in

mobility remain, however, unclear.2

Beine et al. (2013) with a new dataset containing 30 countries and covering the period

1980-2010 come to contrary conclusions regarding migration in Europe. They find that

both the Schengen Agreement and the introduction of the Euro have increased migration

between the member countries. However, migration between countries covers only a

small part of all movements. In Germany, for example, roughly twice as many people

move every year within Germany from one state to another than from Germany to

another country.

Due to a lack of reliable data to analyse regional labour mobility directly, a large part

of the literature has pursued the indirect approach proposed by Blanchard and Katz

(1992). In their seminal paper on regional evolutions they develop a small model of

regional labour markets (in the following: BK model) and suggest estimating the joint

behaviour of the employment growth, the employment rate and the participations rate to

analyse regional labour market adjustments to regional labour demand shocks. The

respective reduced-form vector autoregression model (VAR) that they derive from their

theoretical model offers an indirect approach to study migration because all employment

changes unexplained by either the participation or the employment rate must originate

from a change in population, which is identified with migration.

Applying the methodology to US states, Blanchard and Katz (1992) find that as of the

first year migration plays a dominant role in the adjustment process following a shock to

regional labour demand. Decressin and Fatás (1995) analyse large Western European

regions and compare them to US states and find that in Europe the participation rate is

the major force driving adjustment. Obstfeld and Peri (1998) analyse how regions in the

US, Canada, the UK, Germany and Italy react to asymmetric labour demand shocks and

show, first, that regional real exchange rates play a minor role in the regional adjustment

process and, second, that the US adjustment process is the fastest due to higher labour

mobility.

The methodology of Blanchard and Katz (1992) has been applied in many other

studies and has become the standard model to analyse regional labour market adjustment

mechanisms and to approach migration patterns indirectly.3 Greenaway-McGrevy and

Hood (2013) apply the model to metropolitan areas in the US and find that the

adjustment to location-specific and aggregate shocks differ considerably. Our paper

shares their main modification, namely the use of a factor structure to separate region-

specific from common shocks. Dao, Furceri and Loungani (2014) reassess the

2 Demographics and an aging of the population, increasing home ownership rates and an increasing share of

women in the labour force may matter. Glaesser and Tobio (2007) discuss the role played by very long-term

adjustment processes over many centuries that may have been concluded. Dao, Furceri and Loungani (2014)

point to a decreasing dispersion of regional labour markets. Earlier papers detecting a decline include

Greenwood (1997) and Long (1988). The recent decline in migration in the US may be somewhat

overestimated (Kaplan and Schulhofer-Wohl, 2012). 3 Numerous other papers relied on the BK model: Jimeno and Bentotila (1998) adapt the methodology to study

Spanish regions; Fredriksson (1999) looks at Swedish regions; Fidrmuc (2004), Gács and Huber (2005),

Bornhorst and Commander (2006) focus on regions in Central and Eastern Europe, and Tani (2003) suggests that migration in Europe is higher than expected.

Page 5: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

5

adjustment of US states and find that the contribution of migration has decreased since

1980 and link it to a declining trend in the dispersion of unemployment rates across

states. In addition, they show that migration contributes more in aggregate downturns

and sketch some differences between the US and Europe.

For our purposes there is no alternative to inferring migration indirectly as in the

Blanchard and Katz (1992) methodology. But we acknowledge that the chosen approach

comes with drawbacks, including weak micro-foundations and a debatable identification

of the labour demand shocks. Due to the availability of more and better regional data

economic geography offers an increasingly feasible alternative. Counterfactual analyses

in spatial general equilibrium models – as in Redding (2012), Ahlfeld et al. (2013), or

Behrens et al. (2013) – could be used to understand how individuals relocate after a

shock and where they move. An alternative approach is to look at how mobility response

to well-identified shocks. Both in the US and Germany trade shocks, for example, have

been shown to induce relatively small mobility responses (Autor, Dorn, and Hanson

2013; Dauth, Findeisen, and Südekum 2014).

3. EMPIRICAL STRATEGY

3.1 Intuition of the BK Model

In this section, we provide some intuition behind the BK model. For a full model

description, we refer the interested reader to the original paper of Blanchard and Katz

(1992). Starting from the observation that region-specific labour demand shocks have

permanent effects on employment, but only temporary effects on the employment rate,

the participation rate and wages, Blanchard and Katz (1992) develop a simple model of

regional labour market dynamics that is based on two basic features. First, regions are

assumed to produce distinct bundles of goods that are sold in an aggregate goods market

and, second, labour and capital are assumed to be perfectly mobile in the long run. In

this model, state-specific shocks to labour demand result in short-lived mean deviations

of wages, but cause permanent changes of the employment level. An adverse shock to

labour demand, for example, increases unemployment and lowers wages, which induces

some workers to leave the region. Since workers move out of the region until wages are

back to equilibrium, lost jobs after an adverse demand shock are not fully recovered.

Similarly, when region-specific labour demand increases, relative wages tend to

increase. Thus leads some firms to relocate at least part of their production outside the

region and thus reduces employment compensating for some of the newly created jobs.

However, higher wages also cause inward migration of workers so that some of the

newly created jobs remain permanently in the region. The relative sensitivities of labour

demand and supply determine how large the permanent effect of the labour demand

shock is on regional employment. In the short run, changes in the unemployment and the

participation rate can also contribute to the change in employment.

Page 6: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

6

In order to implement this model empirically and in the absence of reliable regional

wage data, Blanchard and Katz (1992) propose to estimate the joint behaviour of

employment growth, the employment rate and the participation rate. The short and long

run adjustment of the regional labour market can then be analysed by tracing out the

impact of a shock to the employment growth equation.

3.2 Region-Specific Variables

Blanchard and Katz (1992) measure region-specific variables as simple differences

between the regional variables and their aggregate continental counterpart. Let stand

for the number of persons employed, for the labour force in persons and for the

population in persons, in region i, at time t; let

contain the regional employment growth, employment rate and participation rate;

and let stand for the respective continental data. Then the region-specific variables

– denoted by – are given by

(1)

This definition of a region-specific variable boils down to conditioning each of the

variables on one common factor (the continental aggregate variable) and to restricting

the loading on that factor to be equal to one.4 Such a transformation will identify the

adjustment to region-specific shocks, only if all regions respond identically to aggregate

fluctuations. But in a regression of regional variables on their aggregate counterparts

most coefficients are quite different from one, suggesting that regions react quite

heterogeneously to aggregate business cycles (see Hamilton and Owyang 2012).5 In this

case, the simple transformation like in equation (1) will estimate a mixture of the

adjustment to local and aggregate shocks. One advantage of the simple difference

transformation is that one does not need to identify local and aggregate shocks. This may

still be justified if the regional dynamics is independent of the local or aggregate origin

of the shock.

There may, however, be reasons why regions adjust differently following aggregate

versus idiosyncratic shocks. For example, using the BK methodology Dao, Furceri and

Loungani (2014) find that the regional adjustment differs depending on aggregate

conditions. One explanation may be that job-churnings are pro-cyclical, i.e. they

decrease during an economic bust and increase in good times (Fallick and Fleischman

4 For large cross-sections the idiosyncratic components average out so that the aggregate converges to the common factor (Forni and Reichlin 1998 and Pesaran 2006). For a large sample this is hence identical to

including a common time trend. The aggregate most often refers to national variables (as in Blanchard and

Katz 1992 or in Obstfeld and Peri 1998) but continental variables can also be used (as in Decressin and Fatás

1995). 5 Decressin and Fatás (1995) reject a unity reaction of regions to aggregate shocks for most regions as well.

They suggest using the estimated coefficients as weights when differencing, so that regions are allowed to react with a different sign and magnitude to aggregate movements. They thus condition on one common factor per

variable, but allow for different weights. These variables, so called β-differences, are uncorrelated with

aggregate variables and, if there were only one common factor per variable, would indeed enable a separation of regional and aggregate fluctuations.

Page 7: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

7

2004; Caballero and Hammour 2005; Molloy, Smith and Wozniak 2011; Davis et al.

2011). As a result, when a region is hit by an idiosyncratic negative labour demand

shock and the labour market in other regions is not affected, it may be easier to find a job

there and the incentive to migrate may be higher. In contrast, when the whole country is

negatively affected but one region worse than another, it may be more difficult to find a

job in the region that is hit less, dampening the incentives for migration.

Greenaway-McGrevy and Hood (2013) show how a factor model can be embedded

into the structural innovations of the original BK model in order to distinguish between

the adjustment to aggregate and local shocks. Region-specific variables are then defined

as residuals of a factor model:

(2)

),

where , , are the factors and

, , are constant but region-

specific loadings.

Intuitively, regions are allowed to respond to two different processes, namely a

local, idiosyncratic shock process and a set of common or aggregate shock processes,

with potentially different responses. The data is modelled as the sum of these two

processes. Strong-form dependence in the panel allows consistent identification of the

factors justifying their use in linear regressions (Bai and Ng 2006, Bai 2009,

Greenaway-McGrevy and Hood 2013). Greenaway-McGrevy and Hood (2013) show

that the adjustment processes of MSAs are different after location-specific and

aggregate shocks. In the former case migration is rapid but relatively weak. Conversely,

the adjustment after common shocks is driven by more prolonged and larger migration.

3.3 Estimation Procedure

Partly following Greenaway-McGrevy and Hood (2013), our estimation proceeds in

two steps.6 In the first step, we decompose the regional variables in three orthogonal

components: the contribution of a continent-wide factor, of a country factor and a

region-specific variable. This is done by estimating a multi-level factor model. In the

second step, we separately estimate a pooled VAR in the region-specific variables and

the country factors to investigate and compare the labour market response to region-

specific7 and country-specific shocks respectively.

3.3.1 The Factor Model

We estimate a separate multi-level factor model for Europe and the US. We include

one continental factor, one country factor in Europe and one area factor in the US. In

Europe, we include a German (G), French (F), Italian (I), Spanish (SP) and British (GB)

6 Because in this model also the data vector follows a factor structure the factor model can be estimated before

the VAR. For more details regarding the augmented BK model refer to Greenaway-McGrevy and Hood

(2013). 7 We use the terms region-specific, idiosyncratic and local shock interchangeably.

Page 8: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

8

factor, and in the US we include the four US areas Northeast (NE), Midwest (MW),

South (S), and West (W).8 We restrict the loadings so that only regions belonging to a

particular country (area) are able to load on the respective country (area) factor.9

Accordingly, the following factor model is estimated for Europe and the United States

separately:

(3)

Where i denotes the region, c the country in Europe the region belongs to or the area the

state in the US belongs to, and a is the continent (Europe or US). The idiosyncratic

component contains the region-specific variables. The loadings represent the

sensitivity of the regional series to the country, area or continental factors and since they

are region-specific, they allow for heterogeneous effects of those factors.

Since principal-components methods cannot account for a hierarchical factor structure,

we estimate the factors with the quasi-maximum likelihood approach of Doz, Giannone,

and Reichlin (2012). They show that maximum likelihood is suitable to estimate the

common factors in large cross-sections of time series. We implement the QML estimator

using the Kalman smoother and the EM algorithm.10

3.3.2 The Vector Autoregression Model

We then separately estimate the following panel VAR and pool over different

subsamples:

(4)

(5)

8 Different factor structures are, of course, possible. The results are not changing importantly for different

structures. 9 We impose a structure on the factors in order to capture the variables’ pervasive covariation for the different geographical entities. In Europe it is important to account for country factors. Using the ABC criterion of

Alessi, Barigozzi and Capasso (2010), we find indeed strong evidence for more than one common factor per

series. 10 Forni, Hallin, Lippi, and Reichlin (2000) and Stock and Watson (2002) propose to estimate common factors

using principal components. Principal components are indeed easy to compute and consistent for any path of

the cross-section and sample length (Bai and Ng 2002; Forni, Giannone, Lippi, and Reichlin, 2009). Yet, with principal components it is not possible to restrict the factor structure as we intend. Other authors working with

structural factors include: Forni and Reichlin (2001); Bernanke, Boivin, and Eliasz (2005); and Boivin and

Giannoni (2006). Also Kose, Otrok, and Whiteman (2003) apply a likelihood based estimator. The QML

approach of Doz, Giannone, and Reichlin (2012) assumes that all series are I(0). In our case, however, some

series are I(1). Principal components deliver consistent estimates also in this case (Bai and Ng 2004). We re-

estimate the three global factors using principal components and the structural factors of the remaining unexplained fluctuations – that all turn out to be I(0) – with the QML approach. The factors are very similar.

Doing the factor analysis in two steps underestimates the errors, because the QML estimation uses estimated

data. However, in the VAR we treat the factors in any case as observations (Bai 2003, Giannone and Lenza 2009).

Page 9: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

9

where the region- or country-specific constants represent regional or country fixed

effects that allow for different long-term averages.11

Given our large cross-section and

modest sample length the two-step procedure does not cause a generated regressor

problem (Pagan 1984, Bernanke and Boivin 2003, Bai and Ng 2006) so that we can

indeed treat the region- and country-specific variables as observations (Bai 2003,

Giannone and Lenza 2009).

The short and long run adjustment of the regional labour market can then be analysed

by tracing out the impact of a shock to the employment growth equation on the other

variables. The identifying assumption is that this shock captures unexpected changes in

regional labour demand meaning that contemporaneous employment growth is weakly

exogenous in the other equations of the VAR. The Choleski decomposition implies that

current changes in employment affect both employment and participation rates but not

vice versa. There are examples that violate this assumption, for example changing

fertility rates, but we assume these changes are small relative to the labour demand

shocks.12

A region-specific labour demand shock is a change in labour demand in a region that is

uncorrelated with national and continental labour demand. Think for example of a

change in local government spending, the bankruptcy of a big company with many

employees in one particular region, or a regional natural catastrophe like a storm tide.

Examples of shocks to country-specific labour demand could result from a change in

military spending, oil prices, a national banking crisis or changes in national policies.

Note that

(6)

.

Changes of the employment level thus stem either from changes of the employment

rate, the participation rate or the population. With the VAR we can distil the population

response, since any change that is not explained by the employment rate or the

participation rates is attributed to a change of the population. Following Blanchard and

Katz (1992), we will assume that these changes of the population are due to migration.

11 We could also estimate (4) using the original regional variables on the left-hand side and augmenting the

VAR with the continental and country (area) factors. Results are very similar. 12 Dao, Furceri and Loungani (2014) in a recent working paper test the assumption for the US and conclude that identification with an instrument reveals a lower contribution of migration. We are not fully convinced that

the only effect of the IV identification is a clearer demand shock, as it may also change the type of the

adjustment. Because the IV approach is very difficult to implement in Europe also Dao, Furceri and Loungani (2014) rely on our assumption for their European analysis.

Page 10: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

10

4 DATA, DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS, VARIANCE DECOMPOSITION

4.1 Regional Disaggregation and Data Sources

The regional disaggregation follows Blanchard and Katz (1992) for the US and is

similar to Decressin and Fatás (1995) for Europe. For the US, the disaggregation is

straightforward: we count each state plus the District of Columbia as a region so that

there is a total of 51 US regions. In Europe entities of comparable size refer less strictly

to administrative divisions. Yet, all regions in the sample can be understood as

consisting of one or more NUTS2-regions. We include eight French, seven German,

eleven Italian, seven Spanish, and eight British regions, as well as Belgium, Denmark,

Greece, Ireland, the Netherlands and Portugal. While Decressin and Fatás (1995) classify

the small countries as regions, they are treated as countries in our set-up. For a list of all

regions see Appendix A.

We use data on the population, labour force and employment, from which we compute

the employment growth, the (un)employment rate, as well as the participation rate. Our

time series starts in 1976 and ends in 2013 so that it covers 38 years. The primary

European data sources are the national Labour Force Surveys. We apply some data

modifications to fill in missing data points and replace data of obviously bad quality

using data from different international and national sources. The data from different

sources is linked using adjusted growth rates of the working-age population, the

unemployment and the participation rates. They are then used to extend the most recent

data backwards. We compared different ways to link the data and found that differences

are minor. For European regions we restrict the sample to the working-age population so

that all series cover only persons between 15 and 64 years old.

For the US we use the Current Population Survey (CPS) as our main data source

because it is comparable to the European Labour Force Surveys. In section 6 below, we

also use Local Area Unemployment Statistics (LAUS) from the Bureau of Labor

Statistics as an alternative data source for investigating the US adjustment mechanism

because these are establishment data that are closer to the data used by Blanchard and

Katz (1992). All US series include all persons older than 15 years.

For more details regarding the regional disaggregation as well as data sources and

modifications refer to the data appendix.

4.2 Descriptive Statistics

In 2013 the average regional population in the US was 4.8 million with a standard

deviation of 5.4 million leading to a coefficient of variation of 1.1. With 30 million

California was the biggest region in the US and with less than half a million Wyoming

was the smallest. The average regional working-age population in Europe is very similar

and equal to 4.6 million but the standard deviation is with 2.4 million smaller, resulting

in a smaller coefficient of variation, 0.5. Nordrhein-Westfalen in Germany is the largest

region with a working-age population of 12 million in 2013, whereas Abruzzi-Molise in

Page 11: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

11

Italy is the smallest with only 1 million inhabitants. The total working-age population in

2013 was 240 million in the US and 220 million in Europe.

The average unemployment rate in a US region in 2013 was 6.8% with a standard

deviation of 1.6%. In Europe the average unemployment rate was nearly twice as high,

namely 12.5%, and the regions were much more heterogeneous, as indicated by a

standard deviation of 7.9%. Over the whole sample the average unemployment rate was

6% in the US and 10% in Europe.

[Insert Figure1 here]

Figure 1 plots the continental means of employment growth, the unemployment rate

and the participation rate over the period 1977 till 2013 in the US and Europe.

Employment growth fluctuates strongly, in particular in the US. While employment

growth was on average higher in the US than in Europe in the earlier part of the sample,

growth rates have become more similar since then. The unemployment rate shown in the

middle panel is less volatile and returns to its mean roughly every ten years. During most

of the sample the unemployment rate is higher in Europe than in the United States.

Finally, the lower panel shows the participation rate, noting that for Europe this only

includes persons below the age of 64. The participation rate in Europe shows a clear

upward trend throughout the sample, whereas in the US the participation rate increased

until 2000, and started to decline afterwards.

[Insert Figure 2 here]

Figure 2 plots the standard deviation of regional unemployment rates over time. In

Europe regions diverged until 1998. Following the introduction of the euro in 1999 they

converged very fast.13

However, since 2008 regional unemployment rates are again

diverging strongly in Europe. As a result, in 2013 the dispersion reached its maximum

over the sample period. In contrast, regional unemployment dispersion is considerably

lower in the US than in Europe, confirming that US regions are more homogenous than

European ones. Also note that in the US regions diverge particularly in recessions: the

three steepest increases of the standard deviation – in the early eighties, the early

nineties, and between 2008 and 2010 – all coincide with recessions.14

13 In the same period the standard deviation of unemployment rates of other developed countries decreased as

well, but less than in Europe (Estrada, Galí and López-Salido, 2013). 14 The connection between increasing standard deviations and recessions is also discussed in Greenaway-McGrevy and Hood (2013) as well as in Dao, Furceri and Loungani (2014).

Page 12: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

12

4.3 Variance Decomposition

Next we estimate the multi-level factor model (3) to extract the common factors from

the data.

[Insert Table 1 here]

Table 1 reports the proportion of variance explained by each level for each variable.

The common European factor explains 28% of the employment growth fluctuations,

41% of fluctuations in the employment rate and 69% of fluctuations in the participation

rate. Country factors are nearly as important for the first two series, but matter less for

changes in the participation rate. The importance of the country factors in Europe

supports our strategy to estimate a multi-level factor model. Together the EU and

country factors capture between 57% of the variance in employment growth and 85% of

the variance in the participation rate. Idiosyncratic fluctuations are most important (43%)

for the employment growth rate.

The greater homogeneity of the US economy is reflected in the fact that the US factor

plays a more important role in accounting for both employment growth and employment

rate fluctuations. As expected, US states are thus more correlated and their business

cycles more aligned than regions in Europe. The area factors, on the other hand, explain

less than half of the variance that is captured by the country factors, clearly showing that

country factors are more important in Europe. The contributions of region-specific

shocks are similar to the ones in Europe with a slightly lower contribution for the

employment rate.

5 LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS

In this section, we compare the labour market adjustment of regions to region-specific

shocks in Europe and the US, and analyse as well the country adjustment in Europe.

Moreover, we analyse changes in the role of labour mobility over time.

In each case, the figures below report impulse responses of the employment level, the

employment rate and the participation rate to a positive one standard deviation shock to

labour demand. Note that deviations of the employment rate are approximately equal to

negative deviations of the unemployment rate. The responses show percentage

deviations from region-specific means. In addition, we include a table below the impulse

responses that shows the adjustment in the first five years and in the long run to a

normalised initial increase of 100 jobs. Each table reports in the first line the number of

newly created jobs and in the lines below it decomposes the new jobs. Some of the new

jobs are filled with formerly unemployed, others with people previously not forming part

of the labour force and the remaining jobs are filled with people moving into the region.

Page 13: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

13

5.1 Regional Adjustment to Region-Specific Shocks

First we discuss the adjustment of regions to region-specific changes in labour demand

and compare the adjustment in Europe and the US. We estimate (4) and allow for two

lags.15

We test for unit roots and confirm that all series are stationary so that the model

specification is appropriate.16

[Insert Figure 3 here]

Figure 3 shows the impulse responses for Europe in the left and for the US in the right

panel. Note, first, that following a positive labour demand shock the employment level

increases on impact, then falls back towards its initial level, but remains above it in the

long run. The fact that some but not all of the initial increase in employment remains in

the long run suggests that both labour migration and job destruction or migration play a

role in the adjustment process. If no jobs disappeared, the permanent effect would be the

size of the initial increase. If, on the contrary, no migrants were moving into the region,

the permanent effect on employment would be zero. Since in the long run the

unemployment and participation rates revert to their pre-shock baseline, the permanent

change in employment must stem from migration. The permanent change in employment

relative to the initial increase thus reveals the relative importance of job migration versus

migration of employees. Due to the normalization the number of workers migrating in

the long run reported in the tables can be interpreted as the long-run contribution of

migration as percentage of the initial increase in employment.

A number of points are worth making. First, the adjustment towards the new steady

state is faster in the US than in Europe. Employment reaches its long run level after 10

years in Europe and after five years in the US. After three years both the employment

and participation rate continue to contribute substantially in Europe, but not in the US.

After four years they still contribute more than 20 per cent in Europe, but only five in the

US. The employment rate (or unemployment rate) reacts much stronger in Europe and

contributes a lot more to the adjustment than in the US. Migration, on the other hand,

contributes a bit less in Europe over the whole adjustment period. Overall, a shock

changing employment initially by 100 workers leads to 47 immigrants in Europe and 57

in the US. In other words, due to migration 48% of the initial increase of employment

becomes permanent in Europe and 57% remain in the US. While migration is higher in

the US, the differences are not large.

Summarizing, there are differences between the regional adjustment mechanisms in

Europe and the US – in Europe it is more persistent, employment rates contribute more,

and migration less – but the differences are smaller than previous work suggests.

Compared to Decressin and Fatás (1995), we find a faster adjustment mechanism, a

15 Two lags are usually used in the literature. We estimate the model also with only one and four lags and find

that the results are very similar. 16 We use the panel unit root test of Harris and Tzvalis (1999) and reject a unit root for all series at the 1% level.

Page 14: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

14

more important role for job creation (and consequently a less important role for

migration), and smaller differences between Europe and the US.

5.2 The National Adjustment Mechanisms in Europe

Next we investigate the role of migration in labour market adjustment across countries.

The costs of migrating across countries are likely to be higher than those of migrating

between regions due to the larger distance, greater language and other cultural barriers,

and other institutional obstacles like the limited portability of pension and other social

security rights. We should therefore expect a lower contribution of migration to the

adjustment process following country-specific labour demand shocks.

We use the five country factors from (3) and add our small countries so that we have a

cross-section of 11 countries. We estimate (5) and due to the smaller cross-section now

allow for only one lag. Again we confirm the empirical validity of the VAR

specification.17

[Insert Figure 4 Here]

The left panel in Figure 4 shows the impulses responses of a one standard error

positive labour demand shock as before. Note that the standard errors are now larger as

the cross-section is smaller. The employment and participation rate contribute nearly

equally in all years and need 15 years to return to their pre-shock level. As a result, the

adjustment process takes longer in response to country-specific shocks than in response

to region-specific shocks. The right panel compares the number of migrants in the first

five years after an initial employment change of 100 workers for the different adjustment

mechanisms. From before we know that the number of migrants is somewhat lower after

a region-specific shock in Europe compared to the US. Migration is much lower after a

country-specific shock, in particular in the first years after the shock. In the first year

only 18 workers migrate to a country experiencing an unexpected increase of the

employment level by 100 jobs, whereas around 40 workers migrate after a region-

specific shock of that size in Europe and the US. These differences become smaller over

time. Migration also contributes less to the change in employment relative to the

participation and employment rate. In the first three years it contributes on average 51%

to the regional employment change in Europe after a local shock but only 21% to the

national adjustment after a country shock.18

Summarizing, we find that migration plays a less important role in the adjustment to

country-specific shocks. Since in section 5.1 we found that the regional adjustment

processes in Europe and the US are not very different, it follows that it is mostly lower

17 Here we test for unit roots using the test developed by Levin, Lin and Chu (2002). A unit root is rejected at

the 1% level for the employment growth, the participation rate, and for the employment rate. 18 We have also estimated the national adjustment mechanism with the country series instead of the factors. Results are very similar.

Page 15: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

15

labour mobility between European countries that slows down adjustment in Europe and

may contribute to the large heterogeneity in labour market pointed out in the

introduction.

5.3 Changes over time

In the previous sections we reported the full-sample results. Given the evidence of

changes in labour mobility discussed in the introduction, in this section we analyse

whether the role of migration has changed over time.

To do so, we estimate the VARs of equations (4) and (5) for two subsamples

separately (1977-1999 and 1990-2013). While this obviously shortens the sample, we

still have 23 observations per subsample and thus nearly twice as many observations as

Blanchard and Katz (1992) and Decressin and Fatás (1995). Still, we reduce the lag

length to one and focus mainly on the first five years in order to minimize issues related

to sample length. Note that our samples overlap so that changes originate in differences

in the adjustment in the first and last 13 years.

[Insert Figure 5 here]

Figure 5 shows the changes of the regional migration response in Europe and the US,

as well as the national migration response in Europe. The left panel plots the total

number of migrants after a shock of 100 workers in the first five years. The dashed lines

show the numbers of migrants between 1977 and 1999 and the solid lines the numbers

between 1990 and 2013. In addition, we use pie charts to report the average percentage

contributions of the employment and participation rate and of migration to the

employment change in the first three years. This allows us to see whether migration has

become relatively more important or not.

The upper panel reports the changes in the regional adjustment in Europe. The total

number of migrants has risen in all years and also the percentage contribution of

migration has increased. Molloy, Smith and Wozniak (2011) analyse inter-NUTS2

mobility in Europe using a LFS question asking whether respondents moved in the

previous year. In line with our results, they find that mobility rates were either flat or

slightly increasing in the early 2000s.

The increase of migration in Europe detected by Beine et al. (2013) refers to migration

between countries and not regions. As discussed in the introduction, recent divergence in

unemployment rates across European countries has led to increased migration in Europe.

It is thus interesting to see whether we can also detect changes in the adjustment to

country shocks using our methodology. The middle panel of Figure 4 shows the changes

in the country adjustment mechanism. As expected, the total number of migrants in

response to an initial increase in employment of 100 has indeed increased. After three

years, for example, it decreased from 31 in the first subsample to 45 in the second

subsample. And also the permanent effect of a country shock on migration has become

more important. Although not directly comparable, our results therefore qualitatively

Page 16: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

16

confirm the findings of Beine et al. (2013). In sum, we find that in the most recent

subsample country-specific changes in labour demand set in motion more cross-country

movement in workers and that this migration contributes more relative to the

employment and participation rate. At the same time, the role of migration between

countries remains lower than its role between regions.

Finally, the lower panel shows changes in the role of migration in the US. The total

number of migrants after a region-specific shock has notably decreased in all years.

Three years after the shock the number of migrants has decreased from 56 to 44. As the

pie charts show, the percentage contribution has declined as well and is compensated by

a more flexible labour force. For the US our results are thus in line with Dao, Furceri and

Ploungani (2014) and relate nicely to the literature on declining labour mobility in the

US.

6 Relation to Blanchard and Katz (1992)

In this section, we apply the original methodology of Blanchard and Katz (1992) who

defined regional variables as simple differences from the continent-wide mean to our

data. This is useful for two reasons. First, our results differ quite importantly from those

of Blanchard and Katz (1992) and Decressin and Fatás (1995) who found a much slower

adjustment process and a greater role for migration. In this section, we want to

investigate whether these differences are mainly due to the change in methodology or

also due to use of different data sets. Second, one might argue that the policy maker is

interested in the regional adjustment to differences independent of the type of the shock.

This may be captured somewhat better by analysing simple mean differences.

6.1 The adjustment with simple differences

[Insert Figure 6 here]

Figure 6 plots the impulse response functions for Europe and the US using simple

differences computed as specified in (1). While this specification results in stationary

series in the US, in Europe we can reject a unit root neither in the employment rate nor

in the participation rate so that that this filtering strategy is not appropriate for European

regions.19

As discussed before, our factor-based methodology of identifying region-

specific variables results in stationary series.

In Europe, the employment level exhibits a hump-shaped response and migration is

initially lower than for region-specific shocks. The number of migrants in the first years

drops from 39 to 25, but is nearly identical in the long run (47 versus 46). The

19 With Harris-Tzvalis test we reject a unit root in the US for all series at the 1% level. In Europe only the

employment growth is stationary – we reject a unit root at the 1% level – but both for the employment and participation rate we cannot reject the unit root at any level.

Page 17: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

17

participation rate is now much more persistent and is considerably above the pre-shock

level even 20 years after the shock. The employment rate contributes stronger and is

more persistent as well.20

Overall, it looks like the original BK methodology mixes the adjustment to region-

specific shocks with the adjustment to country-specific shocks. This results in a more

persistent adjustment process with a larger role for unemployment and a significantly

smaller role for migration.

Accordingly, in the US the differences are smaller and the responses look generally

similar to the ones after region-specific shocks. But again the process now takes longer

to be completed and in particular the contribution of the participation rate is more

persistent. Using simple differences, migration is a little lower initially, in the first year

we see 37 instead of 43 migrants, and a little higher in the long run with 63 instead of 57

migrants. The general conclusions from Section 5.1 are thus confirmed.

Next, we repeat the estimation for the same subsamples as before with simple

differences. Figure 7 reports again the number of migrants after a shock of 100 workers

in the left panel and the average percentage contributions in the first three years in the

right panel.

[Insert Figure 7 here]

From 1977-1999 to 1990-2013 the total number of migrants has again gone up in

Europe, though only from the third year onwards. The average percentage contribution

in the first three years is nearly the same but would increase if we added more years.

As before, the number of migrants has clearly decreased in the US and also the

percentage contribution in the first three years has gone down. Our results from Section

5.3 are thus also confirmed.

6.2 Local-Area Unemployment Statistics

While using simple differences brings the US impulse responses closer to the ones in

Blanchard and Katz (1992), we still neither observe the strong hump-shaped response

that characterises their responses nor the related permanent effect on migration of around

100%. In this section, we analyse whether the different data source may be the reason for

this. We estimate the adjustment process (4) for the US using simple differences and the

LAUS data set, which is establishment data closer to the data used by Blanchard and

Katz (1992). Figure 8 shows the impulse responses to a positive one standard deviation

shock.21

[Insert Figure 8 here]

20 We also estimated the regional adjustment with β-differences (see footnote 5) and find very similar results. 21 The Harris-Tzvalis test rejects a unit root at 1% for employment growth and the employment rate and at 5%

for the participation rate.

Page 18: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

18

In this case, the impulse responses look very similar to the responses reported in

Blanchard and Katz (1992) and more recently in Dao, Furceri and Loungani (2014).

Above all, the impulse response now is strongly hump-shaped and migration is more

than twice as important in the long run and above 100%.

We can only speculate about the reasons for the large differences with our results and

the larger contribution of migration in the long run. Since migration is identified as the

residual of the VAR, i.e. migration is given by the change of the employment level that

cannot be explained by changes in either the employment or the participation rate, the

quality of the data series may be very important. Inconsistent data series may result in a

larger contribution of the residual and hence of migration. Employment data from LAUS

is based on establishment data and there are important differences between household

and establishment series resulting from different definitions, coverages, and estimation

procedures. For example, CPS employment includes self-employed persons, unpaid

workers in family-operated businesses, and agricultural workers; establishment-based

employment data from the Current Employment Statistics does not. Unpaid absences

from work are differently accounted for and persons working in more than one

establishment are counted more than once with establishment-based data. The latter

inconsistency clearly matters: Blanchard and Katz (1992) overestimate migration

because they rely on establishment-based employment data, but on CPS data for

unemployment and persons out of labour force so that some of the unexplained

employment changes may result from changes in dual job holding and not migration.

With LAUS data the same might happen.

7 CONCLUSION

7.1 Summary

In this paper we revisit the role of labour mobility in regional labour market

adjustments in Europe and the US. We study 41 European and 51 US regions over a

period of 38 years. In line with Greenway-McGrevy and Hood (2013), we use a factor

model to distinguish between the regional adjustment to region-specific idiosyncratic

shocks and the country adjustment to country-specific shocks. We show that

distinguishing between whether migration takes place between regions or between

countries matters for the relative importance of both migration and unemployment.

In particular, we find that, once we control for country factors, the regional adjustment

process in Europe is not that different from the one in the United States. In both areas,

migration plays a relatively important role in the long run, but in European countries the

adjustment process takes somewhat longer and is accompanied by larger changes in

unemployment reflecting more rigid labour markets.

What makes a difference is the cross-country adjustment process in Europe. Due to

remaining differences in language, cultural factors and institutional differences, the role

Page 19: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

19

of migration is much less important when a country is hit by a labour demand shock. At

the same time, changes in the employment rate are more important reflecting different

national labour market institutions. If one does not account for the country factors, the

differences in regional adjustment between Europe and the US become much larger.

Using a much longer data set, we also find that the adjustment processes in Europe and

the US have further converged over the past decades. This reflects both a fall in

interstate migration in the US and a rise in the role of migration in Europe as European

integration proceeds. The latter shows up most strikingly in an increased role of

migration in the cross-country adjustment.

Finally, we show that part of the difference between Europe and the US in previous

studies may in addition be due to the use of different data sources.

7.2 Policy Implications

Our findings can inform the policy debate in at least two dimensions. First, most of the

differences in the role of migration in the regional labour market adjustment process

between the US and Europe are due to remaining barriers connected with country

borders. It is therefore right for European policy makers to focus on how to facilitate

labour mobility across countries in Europe. Our empirical investigation shows that

measures taken in the past such as the Schengen agreement, initiatives to bring down

cultural barriers through exchange programmes such as the Erasmus programme or

efforts like the Bologna process to harmonize educational standards may already have

contributed to a greater role for labour mobility in labour market adjustment. And there

is scope for additional measures to further reduce the persistence of labour market

adjustment to country-specific shocks and alleviate the associated social costs. A

variety of measures can be considered including promoting more flexible housing

markets, increasing the compatibility of school systems, improving language education,

harmonizing pension systems and promoting the portability of pension and other social

security rights, and changing the general attitude towards migrants. The recent

initiatives of the European Commission and Council may hence help to foster

adjustment to country-specific shocks.

However, our analysis also reveals that the differences with the United States, a

monetary union with a quite homogenous culture and a well-functioning labour market,

are not that large. Given that cultural and language barriers are likely to persist in

Europe, it is therefore important to be realistic about what increased labour mobility can

achieve. The differences in the importance of migration in Europe and the US are

smaller than has previously been argued, so that labour mobility might not hamper the

functioning of the Euro Area as strongly as some argue.

To become more specific is difficult given the positive nature of our analysis. This

would require a more structural and normative approach. In this context, one should

also recall that there are also costs to migration, in particular when it involves high-

skilled migration that may tend to exacerbate rather than alleviate regional disparities.

Page 20: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

20

Moreover, large-scale migration in Europe could be socially disruptive (Emerson et al.,

1992; Obstfeld and Peri, 1998). Moreover, from a normative perspective it is not clear

whether adjustment through workers or jobs is preferable. An acceleration of the labour

market adjustment through job creation may in any case often be desirable. It may be

achieved by more flexible wages – also increasing workers’ mobility – and, equally

important, a higher wage elasticity of jobs. In this context, it is also worth mentioning

the role of regional policies and a banking union in Europe. Regional policies may be

used to encourage job-creation in depressed regions, for example by offering tax

deductions to firms moving in. In addition, the implementation of a banking union in

Europe will foster adjustment through job creation. Morgan et al. (2004) show that

increased interstate banking in the US stabilised fluctuations within states and reduced

divergence between them.

Page 21: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

21

I. Figures

Employment Growth

Unemployment Rate

Participation Rate

Figure 1. Means of original variables

Note: We plot the means of all European and the means of all US

regions over time.

Source: Labour Force Surveys with modification by authors for Europe

and CPS for the US.

-4

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

19

77

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

20

13

Europe US

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

19

77

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

20

13

56

59

62

65

68

71

74

19

77

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

20

13

Page 22: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

22

Figure 2. Standard deviation of

regional unemployment rates

Note: Standard deviations of unemployment rates

shown in the middle panel of Figure 1.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

19

77

19

80

19

83

19

86

19

89

19

92

19

95

19

98

20

01

20

04

20

07

20

10

20

13

Europe US

Europe

US

Years 1 2 3 4 5 10

1 2 3 4 5 10

Employment 100 83 73 64 59 50

100 92 72 62 59 57

Employment rate 20 18 16 11 7 1

13 9 5 1 0 0

Participation rate 41 18 15 11 8 2

44 30 12 4 2 0

Migration 39 47 42 43 44 47

43 54 56 57 57 57

Figure 3. Adjustment to region-specific shocks

Note: We plot the impulse responses to a one standard deviation shock to labour demand. The y-axis shows the effect of the shock

in percentage deviations from steady-state and the x-axis shows years. We allow for two lags and estimate the model with least-

squares. The grey area shows confidence bands of 95% bootstrapped with 250 replications. The table normalizes the size of the

employment change to 100 and decomposes the employment response into contributions of the employment rate, the participation

rate and migration, which is the unexplained part of the employment change. Source: Authors’ calculations.

Page 23: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

23

Years 1 2 3 4 5 20

Employment 100 115 109 99 89 40

Employment rate 42 52 45 35 26 -2

Participation rate 40 41 37 33 28 0

Migration 18 22 27 31 34 43

Figure 4. National adjustment to country-specific shock

Note: As Figure 3 but here we use the country factors and the small countries and allow for only one lag. Source: Authors’ calculations.

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

1 2 3 4 5

National Adjustment in Europe

Regional Adjustment in Europe

Regional Adjustment in US

Page 24: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

24

34

38

28

Employment Rate

Participation Rate

Migration

Regional Adjustment in Europe

National Adjustment in Europe

Regional Adjustment in the US

Figure 5. Changes of migration

Note: The left panel plots the number of migrants after a positive shock of 100 new jobs in the first

five years. The right panel shows the average percentage contributions of the employment rate, the

participation rate and migration to the employment change in the first three years. Note that these

three variables together explain the total employment change.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

20

40

60

1 2 3 4 5

1977-1999

1990-2013

21

28

51

1977-1999

15

24 60

1990-2013

0

20

40

60

1 2 3 4 5

30

39

30 41

24

35

20

40

60

1 2 3 4 5

9

31 59

11

38 51

Page 25: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

25

Europe

US

Years 1 2 3 4 5 20

1 2 3 4 5 20

Employment 100 120 127 124 116 56

100 108 99 93 88 63

Employment rate 34 47 50 46 39 -5

16 16 11 7 4 0

Participation rate 41 38 41 39 36 15

47 45 32 27 22 0

Migration 25 35 36 39 41 46

37 48 56 59 61 63

Figure 6. Regional adjustment with simple differences

Note: As Figure 3 but here we estimate the VAR in simple differences as in Blanchard and Katz (1992).

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Europe with simple differences

US with simple differences

Figure 7. Changes of migration with simple differences

Note: As Figure 5.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

20

40

60

1 2 3 4 5

1977-1999

1990-2013 27

40

33

1977-1999

37

33

30

1990-2013

34

38

28

Employment Rate

Participation Rate

Migration

20

40

60

1 2 3 4 5

15

38

47

14

45

41

Page 26: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

26

II. Tables

Figure 8. US regional adjustment with simple

differences and LAUS data

Note: As Figure 3 but with simple differences and LAUS data.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Table 1. Variance Decomposition

EU Country Region

Employment Growth 28 29 43

Employment Rate 41 36 23

Participation Rate 69 16 16

US Area State

Employment Growth 41 15 44

Employment Rate 71 17 12

Participation Rate 60 19 21

Note: The squared loading of a variable on a factor measures the

explained variance by that factor. We report the explained variance

for each variable in Europe and the US by aggregating over the area

and country factors.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Page 27: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

27

Appendix A Regions

Germany

Baden-Württemb.

Bayern Hessen

Nieders. & Bremen

Nord.-Westfalen R.-Pfalz & Saarl.

S.Holst. & Hamb.

France

Bassin Parisien

Centre-Est Est

Ile de France

Mediterrane Nord-Pas-de-Cal.

Ouest

Sud-Ouest

Italy

Abruzzi-Molise

Campania Centro

Emilia-Romagna

Lazio Lombardia

Nord-Est

Nord-Ovest Sardegna

Sicilia

Sud

Spain

Canarias

Centro Este

Madrid

Noreste Noroeste

Sur

United Kingdom

East Midlands

East of England Northern Ireland

Scotland

South-West Wales

West Midlands

York and Humb.

US Northeast

Connecticut

Maine

Massachusetts New Hampshire

New Jersey

New York Pennsylvania

Rhode Island

Vermont

US Midwest

Illinois

Indiana

Iowa Kansas

Michigan

Minnesota Missouri

Nebraska

North Dakota Ohio

South Dakota

Wisconsin

US South

Alabama

Arkansas

DC Delaware

Florida

Georgia Kentucky

Louisiana

Maryland Mississippi

North Carolina

Oklahoma South Carolina

Tennessee

Texas Virginia

West Virginia

US West

Alaska

Arizona

California Colorado

Hawaii

Idaho Montana

Nevada

New Mexico Oregon

Utah

Washington Wyoming

Page 28: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

28

References

Alessi L., Barigozzi M., and Capasso, M. (2010). Improved penalization for determining the

number of factors in approximate factor models. Statistics & Probability Letters,

80(23), 1806-1813.

Ahlfeldt, G. M., Redding, S. J., Sturm, D. M., and Wolf, N. (2012). The economics of

density: evidence from the Berlin Wall. CEP Discussion Paper, 1154.

Arellano, M., and Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo

evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic

Studies, 58(2), 277-297. Arellano, M., and Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of

error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29-51.

Autor, D. H., Dorn, D., and Hanson, G. H. Forthcoming. The China syndrome: Local labor

market effects of import competition in the United States. American Economic

Review.

Bai, J. and Ng, S. (2002). Determining the number of factors in approximate factor models.

Econometrica, 70(1):191-221.

Bai, J. (2003). Inferential theory for factor models of large dimensions. Econometrica,

71(1), 135-171.

Bai, J., and Ng, S. (2004). A PANIC attack on unit roots and cointegration. Econometrica,

72(4), 1127-1177.

Bai, J. (2009). Panel data models with interactive fixed effects. Econometrica, 77(4), 1229-

1279.

Bai, J., and Ng, S. (2006). Confidence Intervals for Diffusion Index Forecasts and Inference

for Factor Augmented Regressions. Econometrica, 74(4), 1133-1150.

Behrens, K., Mion, G., Murata, Y., and Südekum, J. (2013). Spatial frictions (No. 7175).

Discussion Paper Series, Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit.

Beine, M., Bourgeon, P., and Bricongne, J. C. (2013). Aggregate Fluctuations and

International Migration (No. 4379). CESifo Working Paper.

Bernanke, B. S., and Boivin, J. (2003). Monetary policy in a data-rich environment. Journal

of Monetary Economics, 50(3), 525-546.

Bernanke, B. S., Boivin, J., and Eliasz, P. (2005). Measuring the effects of monetary policy:

a factor-augmented vector autoregressive (FAVAR) approach. The Quarterly

Journal of Economics, 120(1), 387-422.

Blanchard, O. J., and Katz, L. F. (1992). Regional evolutions. Brookings Papers on

Economic Activity, 1992(1):1–75.

Boivin, J., and Giannoni, M. P. (2006). Has monetary policy become more effective?. The

Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(3), 445-462.

Bornhorst, F. and Commander, S. (2006). Regional unemployment and its persistence in

transition countries. Economics of Transition, 14(2):269–288.

Caballero, R. J., and Hammour, M. L. (2005). The cost of recessions revisited: A reverse-

liquidationist view. The Review of Economic Studies, 72(2), 313-341.

Dao, M., Furceri, D., and Loungani P. (2014). Regional Labor Market Adjustments in the

United States and Europe (No. 14/27). IMF Working Paper.

Dauth, W., Findeisen, S., and Suedekum, J. (2013). The rise of the East and the Far East:

German labor markets and trade integration (No. 127). DICE Discussion Paper.

Davis, S. J., Faberman, J., and Haltiwanger, J. C. (2011). Labor Market Flows in the Cross

Section and Over Time (No. w17294). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Decressin, J. and Fatás, A. (1995). Regional labour market dynamics in Europe. European

Economic Review, 39(9):1627–1655.

Page 29: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

29

Doz, C., Giannone, D., and Reichlin, L. (2012). A Quasi–Maximum Likelihood Approach

for Large, Approximate Dynamic Factor Models. Review of Economics and

Statistics, 94(4): 1014-1024.

Emerson, M. (Ed.). (1992). One Market One Money: An Evaluation of the Potential

Benefits and Costs of Forming an Economic and Monetary Union. Oxford

University Press.

Estrada, Á., Galí, J., and López-Salido, D. (2013). Patterns of convergence and divergence

in the Euro Area. IMF Economic Review, 61(4), 601-630.

Fallick, B., and Fleischman, C. (2001). The importance of employer-to-employer flows in

the US labor market. Federal Reserve Board.

Fidrmuc, J. (2004). Migration and regional adjustment to asymmetric shocks in transition

economies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 32(2):230–247.

Forni, M., and Reichlin, L. (1998). Let's get real: a factor analytical approach to

disaggregated business cycle dynamics. The Review of Economic Studies,65(3),

453-473.

Forni, M., and Reichlin, L. (2001). Federal policies and local economies: Europe and the

US. European Economic Review, 45(1): 109-134.

Forni, M., Giannone, D., Lippi, M., & Reichlin, L. (2009). Opening the black box:

Structural factor models with large cross sections. Econometric Theory, 25(05):

1319-1347.

Forni, M., Hallin, M., Lippi, M., and Reichlin, L. (2000). The generalized dynamic-factor

model: Identification and estimation. Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(4),

540-554.

Fredriksson, P. (1999). The dynamics of regional labour markets and active labour market

policy: Swedish evidence. Oxford Economic Papers, 51(4):623–648.

Frey, W. (2009). The great American migration slowdown. Brookings Institution,

Washington, DC.

Gács, V. and Huber, P. (2005). Quantity adjustments in the regional labour markets of EU

candidate countries. Papers in Regional Science, 84(4):553–574.

Giannone, D., and Lenza, M. (2009). The feldstein-horioka fact (No. w15519). National

Bureau of Economic Research.

Greenaway-McGrevy, R. and Hood K. (2013). How mobile is labor in the United States?.

Manuscript

Greenwood, M. J. (1997). Internal migration in developed countries. Handbook of

Population and Family Economics, 1, 647-720.

Hamilton, J. D., and Owyang, M. T. (2012). The propagation of regional recessions. Review

of Economics and Statistics, 94(4), 935-947.

Harris, R. D., and Tzavalis, E. (1999). Inference for unit roots in dynamic panels where the

time dimension is fixed. Journal of Econometrics, 91(2), 201-226.

Houseman, S. N., and Abraham, K. G. (1993). Labor adjustment under different institutional

structures: A case study of Germany and the United States (No. w4548). National

Bureau of Economic Research.

Jimeno, J. F. and Bentolila, S. (1998). Regional unemployment persistence (Spain, 1976–

1994). Labour Economics, 5(1):25–51.

Kaplan, G. and Schulhofer-Wohl, S. (2012). Interstate migration has fallen less than you

think: Consequences of hot deck imputation in the Current Population Survey.

Demography, 49(3), 1061-1074.

Kose, M. A., Otrok, C., and Whiteman, C. H. (2003). International business cycles: World,

region, and country-specific factors. American Economic Review, 1216-1239.

Levin, A., Lin, C. F., and James Chu, C. S. (2002). Unit root tests in panel data: asymptotic

and finite-sample properties. Journal of Econometrics, 108(1), 1-24.

Page 30: Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and … · LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION 1 Labour Market Adjustments and Migration in Europe and the United States: How

LABOUR MARKET ADJUSTMENTS AND MIGRATION

30

Long, L. (1988). Migration and residential mobility in the United States (pp. 137-88). New

York: Russell Sage Foundation.

Marelli, E., Patuelli, R., and Signorelli, M. (2012). Regional unemployment in the EU

before and after the global crisis. Post-communist Economies, 24(2):155–175.

Molloy, R., Smith, C. L., and Wozniak, A. K. (2011). Internal migration in the United

States. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Morgan, D. P., Rime, B., and Strahan, P. E. (2004). Bank integration and state business

cycles. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(4), 1555-1584.

Mundell, R. A. (1961). A theory of optimum currency areas. The American Economic

Review, 51(4), 657-665.

Obstfeld, M., Peri, G., Blanchard, O. J., and Fatás, A. (1998). Regional non-adjustment and

fiscal policy. Economic Policy, pages 207–259.

Overman, H. G., and Puga, D. (2002). Unemployment clusters across Europe's regions and

countries. Economic Policy, 17(34), 115-148.

Pagan, A. (1984). Econometric issues in the analysis of regressions with generated

regressors. International Economic Review, 25(1), 221-247.

Pesaran, M. H. (2006). Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a

multifactor error structure. Econometrica, 74(4), 967-1012.

Redding, S. J. (2012). Goods trade, factor mobility and welfare (No. w18008). National

Bureau of Economic Research.

Saks, R. E., and Wozniak, A. (2011). Labor reallocation over the business cycle: new

evidence from internal migration. Journal of Labor Economics, 29(4), 697-739

Stock, J. H., and Watson, M. W. (2002). Forecasting using principal components from a

large number of predictors. Journal of the American Statistical Association,

97(460), 1167-1179.

Tani, M. (2003). Have Europeans become more mobile? A note on regional evolutions in

the EU: 1988–1997. Economics Letters, 80(1), 23-30.


Related Documents