Top Banner
1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist
90

1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

Dec 19, 2015

Download

Documents

Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

1

Ka-fu WongUniversity of Hong Kong

Thinking Like An Economist

Page 2: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

2

“I’d like to introduce you to Marty Thorndecker. He’s an economist but he’s really very nice.”

Page 3: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

3

Hi, I am Marty….

Page 4: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

4

Hi, I am Marty….

Page 5: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

5

Can we express yourself?

Suppose you had the chance to meet the Chief Executive in a cocktail party. You were asked to express your opinion on minimum wage legislation in Hong Kong.

How do you express your views and convince him/her in five minutes?

Page 6: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

6

Can you express yourself?

Most students who take introductory economics leave the course without really having learned even the most important basic economic principles.

Their ability to answer simple economic questions several months after leaving the course is not measurably different from that of people who never took a principles course.*

*Hansen, W. L., M. K. Salemi, and J. J. Siegfried (2002) “Use it or lose it: teaching economic literacy,” American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), 92 (May): 463-72.

Page 7: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

7

How do we learn a new language

Start simple

Repetition and drill

Active learning

“How much is this?”

Page 8: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

8

Should there be 12 separate sections of Econ 101, with 25 students each?

Page 9: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

9

Or should there be only one section, with 300 students?

Page 10: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

10

What is the Optimal Class Size?

To maximize learning without consideration of cost?

How would considering costs change our answer?A personal tutorial course in economics might

cost $40,000A class of 300 students might cost $200/studentExtreme case: a class of infinite students might

cost less than $0.1/student

What trade-offs must university administrators and students consider when choosing class size?

Page 11: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

11

The Scarcity Principle (also called no-free-lunch principle)

Boundless wants cannot be satisfied with limited resources.

Therefore, having more of one thing usually means having less of another.

Because of scarcity we must make choices.

Page 12: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

12

Selling Seats Through An English Auction

In the classroom, the teacher owns the seats. As usual, the teacher can assign seats. Here, we do it in the economics way -- the teacher will sell seats through an English auction. In an English auction, bidders cry out their bid for a good item until no one is willing to submit a higher bid. The highest bidder will get the item. This kind of auction has been used in Hong Kong’s land auction. There is no restriction on how many seats a student can buy or resale activity. Non-bidders will be assign to an “homeless area” after the auction results.

Bidders suggest a seat for auction. A suggestion is also taken as minimum bid of HK$0.5. The minimum price of the seat is HK$0.5. Each cry should be at a HK$0.5 or higher. When submitting a bid, raise your “number plate” and cry out the bid. Students who do not get a seat will have to seat on the floor.

The teacher will collect the money/ IOU (I owe you) and put it in a jar. The money collected will be used to fund class refreshments as determined by the class later.

Page 13: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

13

Seat auction results in a class of 18 gifted students aged 12-15

30

$4.5(03)

29

$22(04)

1

$15(08)

2

$10.5(02)

3

$8.0(08)

4

$14(09)

5

$12(11)

21

$11(09)

22

$8.0(07)

32

$5.0(16)

31

$10(15)

6

$15(06)

7

$16(12)

8

$7.5(13)

9

$10.5(14)

10

$9.5(10)

23

$3.5(01)

24

$0.5(01)

34

$4.0(07)

33

$5.0(16)

11

$12(18)

12

$7.0(17)

13

$10(18)

14

$9.5(05)

15

$8.5(10)

25

$4.5(01)

26

$2.0(07)

36

$1.0(01)

35

$1.0(07)

16

$4.5(17)

17

$5.0(18)

18

$7.5(07)

19

$5.0(18)

20

$5.5(10)

27

$1.0(17)

28

$2.0(18)

Bidder No.Highest bid

Seat No.Although students did not immediately recognize that there was a problem of scarcity in a classroom with more chairs than students, seats in desirable locations were scarce. The shortage problem exacerbated as many students desired to purchase more than one seat.

Although students did not immediately recognize that there was a problem of scarcity in a classroom with more chairs than students, seats in desirable locations were scarce. The shortage problem exacerbated as many students desired to purchase more than one seat.

Page 14: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

14

What are the alternatives to English auction?

First come, first served; Teacher assigned; Class negotiation.

Page 15: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

15

Microeconomics

The study of how people make choices under conditions of scarcity and of the results of those choices for society.

Page 16: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

16

Rationality assumption

People have goals and try to fulfill them as best as they can.

Page 17: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

17

The Cost-Benefit Principle

An individual (or a firm or a society) should take an action if, and only if, the extra benefits from taking the action are at least as great as the extra costs

Should I do activity x?

C(x) = the costs of doing x

B(x) = the benefits of doing x

If B(x) > C(x), do x; otherwise don't.

Page 18: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

18

Should we make the econ class larger?

Benefit of making the class size larger = the reduction in cost per student = B(x)

Cost of making the class size bigger = The amount people would be willing to pay to avoid the reduced quality of instruction = C(x)

Page 19: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

19

Some relevant costs:

Faculty salary: $90,000 per course

Per student faculty salary cost: 1 section: $90,000/300 = $30012 sections: $90,000/25 = $3600

Page 20: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

20

Benefits and costs

Benefit of increasing class size from 25 students to 300 students = ($3600 - $300) = $3300 = B(x)

If you were currently in a class with 25 students, how much would you be willing to pay to avoid switching to one with 300 students? C(x)

If C(x) < $3300, then it makes sense to offer the larger class.

Page 21: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

21

Optimal class size

ObservationsThe “best” class from an economic point of

view will generally not be the same as the “best” size from the point of view of an educational psychologist.

People will feel differently about the value of smaller classes.

Page 22: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

22

Optimal class size

Who will opt for smaller classes:Those who value smaller classes more.Those who are less financially constrained.

Observations: We have colleges of different class size.Colleges of smaller class size charge higher

tuition fees.

Page 23: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

23

Example 1.1 Should I turn down my stereo?

You have settled into a comfortable chair and are listening to your stereo when you realize that the next two tracks on the album are ones you dislike.

If you had a programmable disc player or a remote control, you would have programmed them not to play.

But you don't, and so you must decide whether to get up and turn the music down, or to stay put and wait it out.

Page 24: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

24

Example 1.1. Should I turn down my stereo?

Suppose C(x) = $1.00 = the minimum amount it would take to get you out of your chair.

B(x) = the maximum you would be willing to pay someone to turn down the volume.

If B(x) > $1, then turn your stereo down.

If B(x) < $1, then don't.

Page 25: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

25

The Cost-Benefit Principle

An individual (or a firm, or a society) should take an action if, and only if, the extra benefits from taking the action are at least as great as the extra costs.

Critics of the cost-benefit approach often object that people don’t really calculate costs and benefits when deciding what to do.

Page 26: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

26

People often behave as if they were comparing the relevant costs and benefits.

Page 27: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

27

People often make bad decisions because they fail to compare the relevant costs and benefits.

Page 28: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

28

Can cost-benefit analysis help you make better decisions?

Example 1.2You are about to buy a $20 alarm clock at the campus store when a friend tells you that Fortress has the same alarm clock on sale for $10.

Do you travel to Fortress?

Page 29: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

29

Can cost-benefit analysis help you make better decisions?

Example 1.3. You are about to buy a $6510 laptop computer from the campus store when a friend tells you that Fortress has the same computer on sale for $6500.

Do you travel to Fortress?

Page 30: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

30

Example 1.2 and 1.3 Should you travel to Fortress?

B(x) = benefit of traveling to Fortress = $10 in both cases.

C(x) = cost of traveling to Fortress = the same amount in both cases.

So your answer should be the same in both cases.

Page 31: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

31

Can cost-benefit analysis help you make better decisions?

Example 1.4. Choosing a public health program.

A rare disease will claim 600 lives if we do nothing. We must choose between the following two programs:

Which program would you choose? A or B?

Program A: save 200 lives with certainty

Program B: save 600 lives with probability 1/3, and save zero lives with probability 2/3

Page 32: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

32

Can cost-benefit analysis help you make better decisions?

Example 1.5. Choosing a public health program.

A rare disease will claim 600 lives if we do nothing. We must choose between the following two programs:

Which program would you choose? C or D?

Program C: 400 people will die with certainty

Program D: 1/3 chance that no one will die, and 2/3 chance that all 600 will die

Page 33: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

33

Example 1.4 vs. Example 1.5

In Example 1.4, most people choose to save 200 lives with certainty (Program A).

In Example 1.5, most people choose to save all 600 lives with prob. 1/3 (Program D).

Yet the two pairs of programs are identical: A=C and B=D

Page 34: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

34

Illusions

If the list of alternatives among which we choose are the same in two cases, then the particular alternative we choose should also be the same in both cases.

Yet people seem to prefer the safe alternative when the alternatives are framed as choices between different numbers of lives saved, and to prefer the risky alternative when the alternatives are framed as choices between different numbers of lives lost.

Page 35: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

35

Example 1.6. Losing a $100 bill

Do you buy a ticket and see the play anyway?

You have just arrived at the theater to buy your ticket and discover that you have lost a $100 bill from your wallet.

Page 36: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

36

Example 1.7. A lost theater ticket.

You have just arrived at the theater and discover that you have lost the $100 ticket you purchased earlier that day.

Do you buy another ticket and see the play anyway?

Page 37: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

37

Example 1.6 vs. Example 1.7

In both cases, you are $100 poorer than before.

In both cases, the benefit of seeing the play, as measured by what you are willing to pay, may therefore be slightly smaller, but this benefit is the same in both cases.

In both cases, the additional cost you must incur to see the play is exactly $100.

Since the relevant costs and benefits are the same in both cases, your decision should also be the same.

Page 38: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

38

Example 1.8. How much memory should your computer have?

Suppose that random access memory can be added to your computer at a cost of $0.50 per megabyte.

How many megabytes of memory should you purchase?

Page 39: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

39

Cost-benefit principle:

Buy an additional megabyte if the marginal benefit of RAM is at least as great as its marginal cost.

Marginal benefit = added benefit from having 1 more unit.

Marginal cost = added cost of having 1 more unit.

Page 40: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

40

Cost-benefit principle:

MB

MC

4000300020001000

Megabytesof memory

Value of an additionalmegabyte

Dollars permegabyte

2.00

0.500.25

Cost of anadditionalmegabyte

1.00

Optimal amount of memory

Page 41: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

41

Everyday Choices

"Should I do X?"

"How much X should I buy?"

"Should I buy an additional unit of X?"

Page 42: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

42

Some Common Pitfalls for Decision Makers

Pitfall 1: Measuring cost and benefits as proportions rather than absolute dollar amounts

Page 43: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

43

Example 1.9. Proportion vs. absolute

Your employer has a travel discount voucher that can be redeemed on one of your next two business trips.

You could use it to save $100 on a $2000 plane ticket to Tokyo; or you could save $90 on a $200 plane ticket to Chicago?

If your goal is to do what would be best for your company, for which trip should you use the coupon?

Page 44: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

44

Some Common Pitfalls for Decision Makers

Pitfall 2: Ignoring Opportunity Costs If doing activity x means not being able to do

activity y, then the value to you of doing y is an opportunity cost of doing x.

Many people make bad decisions because they tend to ignore the value of such foregone opportunities.

Page 45: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

45

Pitfall 2: Ignoring Opportunity Costs

It will almost always be instructive to translate questions like

"Should I do x?" into ones like

"Should I do x or y?"

In the latter question, y is simply the most highly valued alternative to doing x.

Page 46: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

46

Example 1.10. Should I go skiing today?

Page 47: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

47

Example 1.10. Should I go skiing today?

From experience you can confidently say that a day on the slopes is worth $50 to you.

The charge for the day is $30 (which includes bus fare, lift ticket, and equipment).

But this is not the only cost of going skiing. You must also take into account the value of the most attractive alternative you will forego by heading for the slopes.

Page 48: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

48

Example 1.10. Should I go skiing today?

Suppose that if you don't go skiing, you will work at your new job as a research assistant for one of your professors.

The job pays $40 dollars per day, and you like it just well enough to have been willing to do it for free.

"Should I go skiing or stay and work as a research assistant?"

Page 49: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

49

Example 1.10. Should I go skiing today?

C(x) = cost of skiing plus value of forgone earnings

= $30 + $40

= $70

B(x) = $50 < C(x),

So don't go skiing.

Page 50: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

50

Willing to do it for free

The fact that you liked your job just well enough to have been willing to do it for free is another way of saying that there are no psychic costs associated with doing it.

This is important because it means that by not doing the job you would not be escaping something unpleasant.

Page 51: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

51

Many jobs, of course, are not pleasant.

Page 52: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

52

Example 1.11 Unwilling to do the job for less than $25/day

Suppose instead that your job had been to scrape plates in the dining hall for the same pay, $40/day, and that the job was so unpleasant that you would be unwilling to do it for less than $25/day.

Should you go skiing?

There are two equivalent ways to look at this decision.

Page 53: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

53

I. One of the benefits of going skiing is not having to scrape plates.

B(x) = $25 + $50 = $75

C(x) is the same as before, namely the $30 ski charge plus the $40 opportunity cost of the lost earnings, or $70.

So now B(x) > C(x), which means you should go skiing.

Page 54: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

54

II. Alternatively, we could have viewed the unpleasantness of the plate-scraping job as an offset against its salary.

By this approach, the opportunity cost of not working in the dining hall is only $40 - $25 = $15/day.

Then C(x) = $30 + $15 = $45 < B(x) = $50, and again the conclusion is that you should go skiing.

It makes no difference which of these two ways you handle the valuation of the unpleasantness of scraping plates.

It is critically important, however, that you do it either one way or the other.

Don't count it twice!

Page 55: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

55

Some Common Pitfalls for Decision Makers

Example 1.11 makes clear that there is a reciprocal relationship between costs and benefits.

Not incurring a cost is the same as getting a benefit.

By the same token, not getting a benefit is the same as incurring a cost. Economic Surplus is the benefit of taking any

action minus its cost

The goal of economic decision makers is to maximize their economic surplus.

Page 56: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

56

Example 1.12

An African graduate student who recently got his degree in the US was about to return to his home country.

The trade regulations of his nation permitted people returning from abroad to bring back a new automobile without having to pay the normal 50 percent tariff.

He had been planning to bring back a new US$10,000 Chevrolet and sell it.

Since new cars normally face a 50 percent import tax, the car would sell at a dealership there for US$15,000.

The student thought he could easily sell it privately for US$14,000, which would net him a US$4000 profit.

Page 57: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

57

Example 1.12

Then the student's father-in-law asked him to bring him back a new $10,000 Chevrolet, and sent him a check for exactly that amount.

What was the opportunity cost of agreeing to this request?

Page 58: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

58

Example 1.13. Is it fair to charge interest when lending a friend some money?

Suppose a friend lends you $10,000, and her primary concern in deciding whether to charge interest is to decide if it would be "fair" to do so.

She could have put that same money in the bank, where it would have earned, say, 5 percent interest, or $500 each year.

If she charges you $500 interest for each year the loan is out, she is merely recovering the opportunity cost of her money.

If she didn't charge you any interest, it would be the same as giving you a gift of $500/yr.

Page 59: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

59

Example 1.13. Is it fair to charge interest when lending a friend some money?

If someone chooses not to give you a gift, is that unfair?

If not, it makes no more sense to say that recovering the opportunity cost of lending someone money is unfair.

Page 60: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

60

Example 1.14. Why do banks pay interest in the first place?

Suppose you owned a bank and someone deposited $10,000 in it on January 1 without your having to pay him interest.

You could then take the money and buy a productive asset, such as a stand of trees.

Suppose that each year trees grow at the rate of 6 percent annually, and that the price of a tree is proportional to the amount of lumber in it.

At the end of the year you could then sell the trees for $10,600, and have $600 more than before.

But that same option was available to the person who put his money in your bank.

Why should he give you the $600 he could have earned?

Suppose you owned a bank and someone deposited $10,000 in it on January 1 without your having to pay him interest.

You could then take the money and buy a productive asset, such as a stand of trees.

Suppose that each year trees grow at the rate of 6 percent annually, and that the price of a tree is proportional to the amount of lumber in it.

At the end of the year you could then sell the trees for $10,600, and have $600 more than before.

But that same option was available to the person who put his money in your bank.

Why should he give you the $600 he could have earned?

Page 61: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

61

Example 1.14. Why do banks pay interest in the first place?

Why should he give you the $600 he could have earned?

He will be willing to let you use his money only if you compensate him for the opportunity cost of not using it himself.

If you pay him 5 percent interest, he will get $500, which will probably be acceptable to him because he won't have to go to the trouble of tending the trees himself (or of lending the money to someone who will tend them).

You get to keep the remaining $100 for taking care of that.

Page 62: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

62

Opportunity cost

As simple as the opportunity cost concept is, it is one of the most important in microeconomics.

The art in applying the concept correctly lies in being able to recognize the most valuable alternative that is sacrificed by the pursuit of a given activity.

Page 63: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

63

Class activity 1.1:Auction of a hundred-dollar bill

Students who are not interested can choose not to auction. In this case, we will ask you to help keep the records.

Each time a player bids, his or her bid is recorded by my assistant. If a player bids more than once, the higher bid replaces the lower bid, so that a player always has only one outstanding bid. The auction is conducted as an English auction, with the highest bidder taking the dollar bill. When submitting a bid, raise your hand and cry out the bid.

Initial bid should be at least $10. Each bid increment should be at least $5.

As opposed to a standard English auction however, the winning bidder is not the only bidder who pays for the dollar bill. When the auction ends, all bidders who entered a bid during the auction must pay an amount equal to their highest bid. Only the highest bidder, however, gets the dollar bill.

Page 64: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

64

Marginal cost versus sunk cost

Sunk costs are costs that have already been incurred and which cannot be recovered to any significant degree.

Marginal cost is the additional cost required to make a successful bid.

In a class of 18 students aged 12-15, only three students submitted bids for a twenty-dollar bill. I allowed students to chat during class and found that they had the intention to collude as soon as the auction began. Due to the lack of collusion, the highest bid was 65.5. After a 10-minute break (giving them some time to collude), a collusion was formed successfully. The highest bid was 0.5, the lowest possible bid.

Page 65: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

65

Some Common Pitfalls for Decision Makers

Pitfall 3: Failure To Ignore Sunk Costs An opportunity cost will often not seem like a

relevant cost when in reality it is. Another pitfall in decision making is that

sometimes an expenditure will seem like a relevant cost when in reality it is not.

The only costs that should influence a decision about whether to take an action are those that we can avoid by not taking the action.

Sunk cost is a cost that is beyond recovery at the moment a decision must be made

Page 66: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

66

Example 1.15: The Pizza Experiment

How much should you eat at an all-you-can-eat restaurant?

A local pizza parlor offers an all-you-can-eat lunch for US$3.

You pay at the door, and then the waiter brings you as many slices of pizza as you like.

The "waiter" selects half of the tables at random and gave everyone at those tables a US$3 refund before taking orders.

If all diners are rational, will there be any difference in the average quantity of food consumed by these two groups?

Page 67: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

67

"Should I eat another slice of pizza?"

Page 68: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

68

"Should I eat another slice of pizza?"

For both groups, C(x) is exactly zero.

Because the refund group was chosen at random, B(x) should be the same for each group, on the average.

People from both groups should keep eating until B(x) falls to zero.

Page 69: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

69

"Should I eat another slice of pizza?"

So the two groups should eat the same amount of pizza, on the average.

The US$3 admission fee is a sunk cost, and should have no influence on the amount of pizza one eats.

In fact, however, the group that did not get the refund consumed substantially more pizza.

Page 70: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

70

Four Important Decision Pitfalls

Pitfall 4: Failure To Understand the Average-Marginal DistinctionMarginal Benefit: The increase in total benefit

that results from carrying out one additional unit of an activity.

Average Benefit: The total benefit of undertaking n units of an activity divided by n.

Marginal Cost: The increase in total cost that results from carrying out one additional unit of an activity.

Average Cost: The total cost of undertaking n units of an activity divided by n.

Page 71: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

71

Example 1.15. Should NASA expand the space shuttle program?

NASA currently makes four launches per year. Should NASA expand the space shuttle program

from four launches per year to five? Benefits

Total of $24 billion Average of $6 billion/launch

CostsTotal of $20 billionAverage of $5 billion/launch

Page 72: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

72

Example 1.15. Should NASA expand the space shuttle program?

# of Launches Total Cost Average Cost Marginal Cost ($ billion) ($ billion/launch) ($ billion/launch)

What is the optimal number of launches?

0 0 0

1 3 3

2 7 3.5

3 12 4

4 20 5

5 32 6.4

Assume: Average Benefit = Marginal Benefit = $6 billion

3

4

5

8

12

Page 73: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

73

Example 1.16. Fishing boat allocation

Suppose you own a fishing fleet consisting of a given number of boats, and can send your boats in whatever numbers you wish to either of two ends of an extremely wide lake, east or west.

Where should you send your boats?

Page 74: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

74

Example 1.16. Fishing boat allocation

Under your current allocation of boats, the ones fishing at the east end return daily with 100 pounds of fish each, while those in the west return daily with 120 pounds each.

The fish populations at each end of the lake are completely independent, and your current yields can be sustained indefinitely.

Average Catch:West End: 120 lbs/boatEast End: 100 lbs/boat

True or False: If you shift some of your boats from the east end to the west end, you will catch more fish.

Page 75: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

75

Example 1.17. Should you move one of your boats from the east end to the west end?

Currently two boats are sent to the east end and two to the west end.

Average output per boat

Number of boats

East end West end

1 100 lbs/boat 130 lbs/boat

2 100 lbs/boat 120 lbs/boat

3 100 lbs/boat 110 lbs/boat

4 100 lbs/boat 100 lbs/boat

Page 76: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

76

Example 1.17. Should you move one of your boats from the east end to the west end?

Average output per boat

Number of boats

East end West end

1 100 lbs/boat 130 lbs/boat

2 100 lbs/boat 120 lbs/boat

3 100 lbs/boat 110 lbs/boat

4 100 lbs/boat 100 lbs/boatNumber of boats

East end West end Total output

2 2 440 lbs

3 1 430 lbs

1 3 430 lbs

4 0 400 lbs

0 4 400 lbs

Page 77: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

77

Example 1.17. Should you move one of your boats from the east end to the west end?

Average output per boat

Number of boats East end West end

1 100 lbs/boat 130 lbs/boat

2 100 lbs/boat 120 lbs/boat

3 100 lbs/boat 110 lbs/boat

4 100 lbs/boat 100 lbs/boat

Marginal output per boat

The n-th boat East end West end

1 100 lbs 130 lbs

2 100 lbs 110 lbs (= 240-130)

3 100 lbs 90 lbs (=330-240)

4 100 lbs 70 lbs (400-330)

Page 78: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

78

Rules for allocating resources

The general rule for allocating a resource efficiently across different production activities is: Allocate each unit of the resource to the

production activity where its marginal benefit is highest.

For a resource that is perfectly divisible, and for activities for which the marginal product of the resource is not always higher in one than in the others, the rule is:Allocate the resource so that its marginal

benefit is the same in every activity.

Page 79: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

79

Normative Economicsvs. Positive Economics

Normative Economic PrincipleOne that says how people should behave

Example: Cost-benefit principle

Positive Economic PrincipleOne that predicts how people will behave

Example: The incentives matter principleA person (or a firm or society) is more

likely to take an action if its benefit rises and less likely if its cost rises

Page 80: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

80

Economics: Micro and Macro

MicroeconomicsThe study of individual choice under scarcity

and its implications for the behavior of prices and quantities in individual markets.

MacroeconomicsThe study of the performance of national

economies, and of the policies that governments use to try to improve that performance.

Page 81: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

81

Economic Naturalism

ApplicationsUse cost-benefit analysis to explain some

pattern of events or behavior you have observed in your own environment

Start simple

Repetition and drill

Active learning – apply to real life phenomena

Page 82: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

82

Economic Naturalism

Ask interesting questions

Provide plausible answers

Observe things happening around us

Page 83: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

83

Ask an interesting question

Why do so many computer hardware manufacturers include more than $1,000 worth of “free” software with a computer selling for only slightly more than that?

Page 84: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

84

Ask an interesting question

Why don’t automobile manufacturers make cars without heaters?

Page 85: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

85

Ask an interesting question

Why do the keypad buttons on drive-up automatic teller machines have Braille dots?

Page 86: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

86

Ask an interesting question ….

Why are round-trip fares from Hawaii to the mainland US higher than the corresponding fares from the mainland US to Hawaii?

Page 87: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

87

Ask an interesting question ….

Why is airline food so bad?

Page 88: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

88

Ask an interesting question ….

Why does a telecommunications equipment manufacturer offer “free” BMW sedans to employees with more than one year of service?

BMW lease price was $9000/year.

Why not give employees $9000/year in extra salary instead?

Page 89: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

89

Ask an interesting question ….

Criteria for choosing a film to see:

Is it by a well-known director?

Does it feature a favorite actor or actress?

Has it gotten rave reviews in the media?

Word of mouth?

The only foreign films with a chance to make it in the HK market are really good ones—those able to generate strong reviews and word of mouth.

Why are foreign films so good?

Page 90: 1 Ka-fu Wong University of Hong Kong Thinking Like An Economist.

90

End