Top Banner
1 Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition C.L. Mattoli (C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008
119

Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Jan 15, 2016

Download

Documents

kapono

Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition. C.L. Mattoli. Prologue. Businesses are stuck in the short run, although the length of the short run can vary depending on the business. The point is that, in most businesses it is not possible to change everything quickly. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

1

Econ 1000 Lecture 6:Perfect Competition

C.L. Mattoli

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 2: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Prologue Businesses are stuck in the short run,

although the length of the short run can vary depending on the business.

The point is that, in most businesses it is not possible to change everything quickly.

For example, if you own a store, it will not be easy to move the location. To move will require fitting out the new place, changing business cards, advertising the new location, etc.

2(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 3: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Prologue Other changes for other businesses might be

even longer. Thus, businesses will have some inputs that

are fixed and others that can be more easily varied, like man (woman) hours.

When we begin production and go from 0 units to the first, that will require adding some variable input, for example, labor, to the fixed.

Given that, we can calculate the output per unit of the variable input, e.g., labor.

3(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 4: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Prologue There is efficiency gained when you add,

for example, a second unit of labor. Suppose that the company consists of 2

machines, fixed inputs. The first machine does the roughing out of the products and the second machine is a finishing machine.

With one laborer she has to do the roughing out, then, move over to the other machine to finish the product. It is very inefficient.

4(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 5: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Prologue There is an efficiency gain, and the two can

produce more than 2 times the output of one laborer.

The marginal product is the change in output that occurs by adding one more unit of variable input. So it is a unit cost, specifically, for the next unit.

As more units of input are added, there will continue to be efficiency gains, up to a point, then, efficiency begins to be lost.

5(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 6: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Prologue As a result, the extra (marginal) output

(product) increases, peaks, then, decreases. There is also an average output per unit of

input. Using the average-marginal rule, the average

output per unit of input will increase, as marginal product increases.

Average variable cost per unit of output is inversely related to average output per unit variable input, i.e., 1/[output/variable input] = variable input/output.

6(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 7: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Prologue For example, 2 employees/2.2 tons of

grapes = 0.91 employees/ton of grapes. So, it costs 0.91 employees per unit of grapes.

Thus, as MP increases, average cost decreases, and vice versa.

As output increases, the fixed input is also spread over more units, so total cost per unit decreases, then increases.

7(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 8: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Prologue MC will be inverse to MP, as the

change in output per input increasing means the cost per new unit is decreasing.

Then, we can use the average-marginal rule to look at cost curves.

We give a diagrammatic summary of the basic concepts in the next few slides.

8(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 9: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

9

Marginal Product

Marginal Product

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

0 2 4 6 8

Employees

Mar

gina

l Pr

oduc

t

Marginal Product

Employees Marginal Product

0 0.0

1 1.0

2 1.2

3 1.1

4 0.9

5 0.6

6 0.2

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 10: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

10

MP vs. MC

MP vs. MC

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

0 2 4 6

Output

Co

st (

$)

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

1.2

1.4

MP

Labor MP Output TVC MC/unit

0 0.0 0 0

1 1.0 1 100 100.00

2 1.2 2.2 200 83.33

3 1.1 3.3 300 90.91

4 0.9 4.2 400 111.11

5 0.6 4.8 500 166.67

6 0.2 5 600 500.00

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 11: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

11

AC & MC Q TC MC AFC AVC AC

0 100 --- --- --- ---

1 150 50 100.00 50.00 150.00

2 184 34 50.00 42.00 92.00

3 208 24 33.33 36.00 69.33

4 227 19 25.00 31.75 56.75

5 250 23 20.00 30.00 50.00

6 280 30 16.67 30.00 46.67

7 318 38 14.29 31.14 45.43

8 366 48 12.50 33.25 45.75

9 425 59 11.11 36.11 47.22

10 500 75 10.00 40.00 50.00

11 595 95 9.09 45.00 54.09

12 712 117 8.33 51.00 59.33

Average and Marginal Costs vs. Output

0.00

20.00

40.00

60.00

80.00

100.00

120.00

140.00

160.00

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14

Quantity

Uni

t Cos

t($)

AVC

AFC

ATC

MC

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 12: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

12

This week

Chapter 7 Perfect Competition

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 13: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

13

Objectives

We will describe market structure. We will finally get to a bottom line: profits. We will look at what it means for a market

to be perfectly competitive. We will see why governments around the

world promote market competition. We will examine how the internet is

changing the structure of world markets

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 14: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

14

Where we are coming from We have studied the ideas of supply

and demand, on their own, and examined the underlying motivations that lead to the general shapes of supply and demand curves.

Then, we looked at general interactions between supply and demand to get market equilibrium, and think about how changes in equilibrium might occur.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 15: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

15

Where we are coming from People are motivated by self-interest, but that

self-interest leads to competition on both sides, supply and demand, and, in the end, self-interest serves society and results in positive benefits.

On the demand side, self-interest is manifest in wants, desires, and needs, but it also tempers the price that they will pay for things.

That puts limits on the supply side: they cannot simply charge whatever they want.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 16: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

16

Where we are coming from What suppliers charge will affect not only

how much they sell but also the total revenue that they will be able to take in.

Last week we examined output, its motivations, and its limitations.

Suppliers want to make profits but they have to face certain constraints.

We saw that there is a short-run, in which only certain changes can be made to change the ability to supply, and a longer-run, in which more can be done to change supply.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 17: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

17

Where we are coming from We examined the cost side and found that

suppliers face diminishing returns to inputs. Diminishing returns means that suppliers will

face changing unit costs, which will affect their eventual profitability.

We also saw that they might face changing costs structures depending on their size, which are manifest in concepts of economies of scale: bigger, itself, might result in a longer-run way to reduce unit cost.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 18: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

18

Where we are coming from Suppliers, eventually, might also face

diseconomies of scale because of the organizational structure of business, in general.

In the end, that means that suppliers will, in most cases, always face a cost structure that will limit their ability to make profits.

This week, we examine profitability in the case of perfectly competitive markets.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 19: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

19

Market Structures

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 20: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

20

Market Structure Firms sell things under a number of different

sets of market conditions, which economists refer to as market structures.

Economists then go on to identify several basic forms of market structure characterized by certain key features.

The basic characteristics that shape market structure, include the number of firms in the industry, the differentiability of products, ease of entry and exit in the market, and availability and dissemination of information.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 21: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

21

Market Structure Those characteristics are indicative of the degree

of competition firms face in a market. If there are more firms, there are more places to

buy something. If the products of those firms are more or less

interchangeable, there is no reason to go to one firm than to another, except, perhaps for other reasons of convenience.

If entry into the industry is easy, firms already in the industry will face the threat of more competition. If it is difficult, they will face less of a threat.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 22: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

22

The Basic Market Structures Based on these simple parameters,

there will be a range of competitiveness by firms in markets, ranging from none to a lot.

In a monopoly, there is one seller who dominates the market.

Then, there might be only a few large firms that dominate a market in an oligopoly.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 23: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

23

The Basic Market Structures After that, there might be monopolistic

competition, in which products are differentiable, and there are many sellers, but monopolists compete to get people to like their product instead of the others.

Finally, there is perfect competition, which is the focus of this lecture.

We summarize features of the various market structures, in the next slide.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 24: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

24

Comparative Market StructuresStructure # of sellers Product Entry Examples

Perfect Competition

Large Homogeneous Very easy Small crops, commodities markets

Monopolistic competition

Large Differentiable Easy Restaurants, motels, clothing or other types of boutiques

Oligopoly Few Usually differentiable; can be homo

Difficult Airlines, Automobile manufacturing, oil production

Monopoly One Unique Extremely difficult

Public utilities

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 25: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

25

The Elements of Perfect Competition

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 26: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

26

Perfect Competition Perfect competition means,

basically, that no single firm can gain a competitive advantage over the others. That will be the case under a few rudimentary conditions.

1. If there are many small firms, none of which has a large enough share of total output (total supply) that it can affect market price.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 27: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

27

Perfect Competition In addition, it must be assumed that the

suppliers do not collude but act independently.

Example would be egg farmers. There are thousands of egg farmers. If one decides to raise his price, it will have no affect on the going market price for eggs.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 28: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

28

Perfect Competition2. Next, we assume the product is

fungible (homogeneous, indistinguishable, standardized, all the same).

That way, no single supplier is able to gain a competitive advantage through advertising, quality distinction, or even convenience of location.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 29: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

29

Perfect Competition Buyers are indifferent about which

supplier they go to. There are no famous brand names. No one knows Coke and Pepsi. They just know cola.

For example, fishmonger Ho’s lobster (long xia) is no better than fishmonger Chen’s lobster. They all come from the same sea.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 30: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

30

Perfect Competition3. Ease of both entry and exit are part of the

basis for perfect competition. That means, first, that there are no barriers

to entry, like, startup cost (financial), technical, licensing, patent, permit, or government-imposed barriers.

In that regard, anyone will be able to enter the market, on the one hand, and will not be discouraged by penalties, like investment, contractual, or legal reasons, to exit the business, on the other hand.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 31: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

31

Perfect Competition Resources are completely mobile to

freely enter and exit the market. That is especially important in an industry

in decline, in order for prices to adjust quickly.

Easy entry assures that excess profits will not persist. Others seeing juicy profits will quickly enter the industry, and prices will be competitive.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 32: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

32

Perfect Competition

For example, you go into the bicycle rental business. You buy a bicycle and a cell phone to start your business, and you can easily close the business any time.

A further assumption is that market participants are well-informed and well-educated about the product, including knowledge of the product, its production costs, and prices.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 33: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

33

Perfect World (No one’s Perfect)

The idea of perfect competition is a perfect world ideal. Models are not reality but only try to approximate it under simplified ideal conditions.

The world is not perfect and rational. There is no perfect information. There is convenience of going to a store one block from you instead of one mile. Self-interest can lead to bad behavior.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 34: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

34

Perfect World (No one’s Perfect) However, we expect markets, like farm

products, inter-city trucking, or housecleaning services, to be close to the competitive model. There are many sellers, and products are very similar.

Moreover, the model can provide a benchmark against which real-world market structure and performance can be judged.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 35: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

35

Competition and Policy In chapter 4, we saw that lack of competition

can lead to market failures that result in inefficient outcomes.

On the other hand, perfectly competitive markets will lead to maximum efficiency.

In that regard, governments around the world have devoted much regulation and legislation to promote efficiency by encouraging competition and to discourage anti-competitive behavior through legal and financial penalties.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 36: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

36

ACCC: Australia’s Competition Watchdog In Australia, for example, The Australian

Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) is the statutory authority charged with oversight and enforcement of the relevant Trade Practices Act that deal with competition.

The objective of The Act is to enhance the welfare of Australians by promoting competition and fair trading and providing for consumer protection.

The ACCC also administers the Price Surveillance Act.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 37: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

37

ACCC Objectives1. Improve competition and efficiency in

markets

2. Foster fair trade practices in well-informed markets.

3. Promote competitive pricing when possible and restrain prices in markets where competition is less than effective

4. Inform and educate the community about the Trade Practices Act

5. Use resources efficiently and effectively(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 38: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

38

New Zealand Commerce Commission (NZCC) Goals

1. Dynamic markets and all goods and services produced at competitive prices

2. Consumers confident of information they receive when making choices

3. Regulated industries constrained from making excess profits, face incentives to invest, and share efficiency gains with consumers.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 39: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

39

Policy Goals, Summarized Even if not all industries are naturally

competitive, government policies encourage efficiency by encouraging them to act as if they are competitive.

Even though not all people practice enlightened self-interest, policy seeks to ban unethical behavior.

Bad behaviors that governments seek to eliminate are: colluding to raise price/ profitability, exercising monopoly power at the expense of consumers, and misleading advertising.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 40: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

40

Policy Goals, Summarized The authorities can order breakups of

companies that have gained too much market power.

They can disallow mergers that would result in too much market power residing in one company.

They can disallow false advertising. They can impose price controls, like many

countries do with public utility companies. They can impose fines and compensatory

damages for bad behaviors, (C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 41: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Information

Information is one of the most important things in business.

Businesses need to keep some information secret, otherwise their competitors will gain advantage.

The importance of information is highlighted by the large role that disclosure of information and its accuracy play in competition and securities laws around the world.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008 41

Page 42: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

42

Consequences of Perfect Competition for Suppliers

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 43: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

43

Price Taker, not Price Maker

In a perfectly competitive market, market price is determined by aggregate supply and demand.

Moreover, consumers have perfect information about the actual market price.

The product is fungible, and the firm faces competition from inside the industry and the threat of others entering the industry.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 44: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

44

Price Taker, not Price Maker An individual firm is small and has no control

to affect price (no market power), and if it tried to charge a higher-than-market price, informed consumers would not purchase from that firm because they can switch to another supplier with no effort, at all (he is right next door with the proper price).

Thus, a firm is a price taker: it will necessarily have to sell at the going market price or sell nothing, at all.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 45: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

45

Price Taker, not Price Maker In that regard, we can think of the individual firm as facing a

completely horizontal, perfectly elastic demand curve. The firm must supply any amount that it can and wants to supply

at the going market price or consumers will simply turn to another of the many other suppliers.

Quantity of output(1000’s units/hour)

0 20 40 60 80 100 0 5 10

Market Aggregates Individual Firms

120

100

8070

60

40

20

Pri

ce p

er u

nit

(do

llar

s)

Quantity of output(units/hour)

The International Market for Electronic Components

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 46: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

46

Each Firm Faces Perfect Elastic Demand In the above, graphical example, the

individual firm’s output is several units per hour, while the industry output is an aggregate of 60,000 units/hr. at equilibrium with total demand.

Equilibrium occurs at a price of $70/unit.

Therefore, a firm must take that price, no matter what it’s output.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 47: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

47

Each Firm Faces Perfect Elastic Demand It, effectively, faces horizontal

demand, on its part, because no matter how much output it supplies, that is the price that people will be willing to pay for its product.

As we learned, when demand is horizontal, perfect elastic, a firm charging a higher price than that where supply intersects the demand curve will sell nothing.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 48: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

48

Each Firm Faces Perfect Elastic Demand On the other hand, selling at a price,

below the one price in demand, would be stupid because he can sell the same amount at a higher price.

Moreover, a downward change in price would, in that case, also lead to a decrease in revenues because the firm will not be able to increase sales by decreasing price ([ΔQ/Q]/[ΔP/P] = ED = 0).

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 49: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

49

Short-run Profit Maximization: Perfect Competition

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 50: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

50

The Framework At the beginning of module 3, we

discussed how elasticity of demand puts a constraint on the supplier because changing price can have different affects on total revenues.

In perfect competition, the constraint becomes one fixed price against which the supplier must judge his costs and ability to make a profit.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 51: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

51

The Framework In the last lecture, we analyzed the

elements of increasing and diminishing returns and cost constraints, which suppliers face.

Now, we can put it all together and analyze profit.

We saw how the unit cost curves were U-shaped with minimums due to a maximum in marginal product, which comes at the point of diminishing returns.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 52: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

52

The Framework Profits = revenues – costs. On supply and demand curves we show

price per units, and the average cost figures show cost per unit.

We shall look at two methods to determine maximum profits: the total revenue-total cost approach and the marginal revenue equals marginal cost method.

We are in the short-run. (C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 53: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

53

Industry: Output, Revenue, Cost & Profit We show possible

output, revenue, cost, and profits for a mythical company in our mythical electronic component industry, in tabular form, here.

The data, in graphical form, is shown on the next page.

It continues MAT ATM’s from the previous lecture.

units TR TC Profits MC MR

0 0 100 -100

1 70 150 -80 50 70

2 140 184 -44 34 70

3 210 208 2 24 70

4 280 227 53 19 70

5 350 250 100 23 70

6 420 280 140 30 70

7 490 318 172 38 70

8 560 366 194 48 70

9 630 425 205 59 70

10 700 500 200 75 70

11 770 595 175 95 70

12 840 712 128 117 70(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 54: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

54

Industry: Output, Revenue, Cost & Profit As you can see

from the table and the figures, maximum profit occurs at 9 unit.

It is also between 8 and 10 units that marginal cost equals marginal revenues.

Total Revenue & Cost

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

900

Units

$

Profits

-150

-100

-50

0

50

100

150

200

250

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

Profits

Loss

Break-evenProfit

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 55: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

55

Analysis of the data and discussion Given a market equilibrium price of

$70, we calculate TR = $70 x unit output.

Profits = TR – TC. Marginal revenues are always equal to

$70 because unit price never changes: MR = P.

Marginal cost is changing unit cost: ΔTC/ΔQ = MC.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 56: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

56

Analysis of the data and discussion The firm has fixed costs, so there

are losses until output reaches 3 units, which is an approximate break-even point (profit = $2 = almost zero).

After that, profitability comes, but maximum profits are at around 9 units/hour.

Maximum profit will be $205 per hour. Above 9 units/hour profit declines.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 57: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

57

Marginal Revenue = Marginal cost Marginal revenue is equal to the extra revenue from one more unit of output MR = ΔTR/ΔQ.

In a perfectly competitive industry, the MR will always equal market price per unit, and the TR will be on a straight line with constant slope = MR.

Max profits will occur at MC = MR, Profit = TR – TC.

ΔProfit/ΔQ = ΔTR/ΔQ – ΔTC/ΔQ = MR – MC.(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 58: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

58

Marginal Revenue = Marginal cost That equation tells us that profit will

increase (ΔProfit/ΔQ > 0; positive change in profit) if MR > MC.

That simply says that the extra revenue you get from selling that one extra unit, MR, is greater than the extra cost that you take on to produce that extra unit, MC.

Therefore, there will be an addition to profits.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 59: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

59

Marginal Revenue = Marginal cost Profit will stop increasing (ΔProfit/ΔQ =

0) when MR=MC. And profit will begin to decrease

(ΔProfit/ΔQ < 0; negative change in profit) after that point when MC > MR.

It is only logical that total profits should decline at that point since the extra revenue that you take in, MR, is less than the extra cost that you incur, MC.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 60: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

60

Marginal Revenue = Marginal cost So you will actually be subtracting the

difference, MC – MR, from profits that have already been booked.

Then, we have the MR=MC Rule which says that maximum profits or minimum loss will occur at the point where MR=MC.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 61: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

61

MR = MC We can take the cost

curves from last week’s lecture and spreadsheet files and combine it with MR, this week.

Max profit/min loss occurs at MR=MC

Then, profit is equal to the area contained in the yellow square.

Average and Marginal Costs vs. Output

0.00

20.00

40.00

60.00

80.00

100.00

120.00

140.00

160.00

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14

Quantity

Uni

t Cos

t($)

AVC

AFC

ATC MC

MRProfit

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 62: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

62

Loss Minimization Similarly, when a firm

faces a MR less than its unit cost at any output, again it should choose output when MC=MR.

Then, it will minimize its short-run losses.

At that point the spread (loss) between ATC and MR will be a minimum.

Losing Firm

-350

-300

-250

-200

-150

-100

-50

00 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11

Units

Lo

ss

Average and Marginal Costs vs. Output

0.00

20.00

40.00

60.00

80.00

100.00

120.00

140.00

160.00

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14

Quantity

Un

it C

ost

($)

ATC

MC

MR

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 63: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

63

Average and Marginal Costs vs. Output

0.00

20.00

40.00

60.00

80.00

100.00

120.00

140.00

160.00

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14

Quantity

Un

it C

ost

($)

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 64: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

64

Shutting Down: MR < AVC When MR finally falls

below AVC, then, MR = MC < AVC at all possible outputs.

That means that revenues cannot even cover part of fixed cost per unit, which can happen when MR < AVC.

Thus, the firm should exit the business.

Average and Marginal Costs vs. Output

0.00

20.00

40.00

60.00

80.00

100.00

120.00

140.00

160.00

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14

Quantity

Unit

Cost

($)

MC

AVC

MR

Shut downpoint

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 65: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

65

Example: Motel at the beach During the summer season, Mom’s Motel

offers rooms for $100 per night. Fixed cost/room, including insurance,

depreciation, and taxes is $50/room (AFC). AVC, including electricity, water, and room

cleaning is $25/room. In the off-season, would it be ok to charge

$40/night for a room, or would it be better to just close the motel and let mom take a vacation?

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 66: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

66

Example Analysis Since AVC = $25, if the motel charges

$40/night for a room, it will have $15 left over after pay for AFC/room.

That leftover $15 of revenues, while not enough to actually recover all AFC per room, will at least go towards paying some of it.

Since the AFC has to be paid whether or not the motel is open, it is better business sense to at least pay for some by charging only $40/night than to close down and not recover any at all.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 67: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

67

Break Time

Please take a 10 minute break

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 68: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

68

Short-run Supply Curves:Perfect Competition

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 69: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

69

Individual Firm’s Possible Supply We looked at costs interacting with

revenues and discovered some general rules for a firm to remain in business.

For it to make sense for a firm to remain in business, MR must be equal to or above the minimum variable cost, the point at which MC = AVC.

Otherwise the firm cannot cover any FC, and it will go deeper and deeper into debt.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 70: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

70

Individual Firm’s Possible Supply After that condition is met, the firm should

supply the quantity that corresponds to MR = MC. Then, it will maximize its profits.

Thus, the supply curve for a firm is represented by its MC curve above the AVC curve, as shown in the next slide.

The MC curve represents the best possibilities for profit that the firm can face, in terms of what it should supply.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 71: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

71

Firm Supply Curve MC ≥ AVC As long as MC equal to or greater than AVC, it is

beneficial for a firm to offer supply

0.00

20.00

40.00

60.00

80.00

100.00

120.00

140.00

160.00

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14Quantity

DemandPossibilities

= MR

SupplyPossibilities = MC ≥ AVC

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 72: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

72

Industry Short-run supply Then, we do the same for each individual firm

in the industry: their supply curves will be their MC curves above the minimum AVC curves.

If their minimum AVC curves are above MR, the only price in the market, they should be or will be out of business.

Short-run industry supply curve is, then, the sum of all of the individual supply curves constructed as above and in the last slide.

We illustrate the construction in the next slide.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 73: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

73

Industry Short-run supply The short-run supply curve is the sum of all individual

MC supply curves. For 2 firms, for example, we have the situation depicted,

below. We have put in two possible horizontal demand curves,

also, to expand description and detail. We assume that input prices remain the same as output

expands.

7 10 11 15 18 25

$90

$45

Firm A Firm B Industry

MCAMCB MCB + MCA

+ =

=+

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 74: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

74

Short-run Equilibrium Adding in the an aggregate demand

schedule gives an interaction to find market price and quantity in equilibrium.

Firms will earn a profit, as long as the MR = an equilibrium price is above, not only the AVC, but also the ATC.

Profit = QP(=MR) – Q[AFC + AVC]

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 75: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

75

Short-run Equilibrium They will minimize loss by supplying

on MC=MR, below ATC but above AVC.

Short-run equilibrium will retain until something happens that changes it.

We show the situation for an individual firm and the industry in the next slide.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 76: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

76

Short-run Equilibrium For a firm and the industry. Equilibrium is at $90/unit

with quantity demanded and supplied = 10,000 units. At that price the hypothetical firm produces 10 units.

Profit = [Price/unit – ATC] x Q

PAggregate MarketHypothetical Individual Firm

10

MCATCMR

S = ΣMC

D

10,000

90

Q = units

75

50

25

0

Profits

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 77: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

77

Long-run Supply Curves:Perfect Competition

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 78: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

78

The long-run In the long-run, all inputs become variable. Existing firms can react to opportunities for

profits by expanding or down-sizing, buying or selling PP&E or other inputs that remain fixed in the short-run.

Opportunities for profit will attract new firms, while losses will cause firms to exit the business.

Free entry and exit are a crucial part of perfectly competitive markets.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 79: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

79

Long-run Equilibrium Variability of all inputs means that a

firm can decide to completely shut down, if it is earning less than normal profits (negative economic profits).

New firms will enter, if they see that existing firms are earning above normal profits.

Entry/exit of firms is the key factor in long-run market equilibrium.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 80: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

80

Long-run Equilibrium If new firms enter, supply is increased,

price decreases for the interaction of the old demand curve with the new supply curve.

The process will continue until there are no more above normal profits to be had.

If firms exit, supply will shift left, price will increase, and a new equilibrium will come when economic profits get up to the zero level, above loss levels.

In the next slide, we show a firm in long-run equilibrium.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 81: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

81

A Typical Firm in Long-run Equilibrium P = MR = SRMC = SRATC = LRAC. In LR equilibrium, firms will operate at the

minimum of LRAC.

SRMCSRATC

LRAC

MR

Entry/ExitOf Firms

Zero LREconomic Profits

Long-RunEquilibrium

Causal Chain

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 82: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

82

Typical Firm in LR Equilibrium Relating it back to the LR graph from last

lecture:

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

SRMC

SRATC LRAC

MR

Page 83: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

83

P = MR = SRMC = SRATC = LRAC We have established the P = MR =SRMC

concept, already. Also, SRMC = SRATC is the short run

minimum level for profits to cover all costs. In the long-run, a firm will also want to be

at the minimum in the LRAC curve, also, because larger or smaller operations will be on either side of that minimum will have higher average total costs.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 84: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

84

P = MR = SRMC = SRATC = LRAC Thus, LR equilibrium can occur only

after all firms have adjusted to that perfect minimal cost point.

As long as no variables change, there is no reason for a firm to produce a new level of output. Everything is the best that it can be.

There is no reason to change size of plant or anything else.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 85: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

85

P = MR = SRMC = SRATC = LRAC Since all firms are happy where they

are, the industry will be in equilibrium. There is no extra profit to cause new

entries and enough profit to keep all existing producers.

The price in the LR equilibrium is the best price that can be achieved.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 86: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

86

P = MR = SRMC = SRATC = LRAC The market is acting perfectly efficiently

and consumer welfare is maximized. Since things are constantly changing

(even world population, for example), LR equilibrium will not often be achieved, and

Most of the time markets will just be moving in the direction of an apparent LR equilibrium state.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 87: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

87

3 Types of Long-run Supply Curves

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 88: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

88

LR supply A perfect competitive industry’s LR supply

curve shows the quantities that the industry will supply at various equilibrium prices after all entry and exit has been completed.

The shape of the LR supply curve depends on the response of prices of inputs as new firms enter an industry.

There are three possibilities, increasing, flat and decreasing costs.

We look at each, in turn.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 89: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

89

Constant Cost Industry A constant cost industry is one in which

the expansion of output by entry of new firms into the industry has no affect on the firm’s cost curves.

Consider an upward shift in demand (see next slide).

In response to the demand shift, in the short run, price will rise along the supply curve to a new short-run equilibrium.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 90: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

90

Constant Cost Industry At that new equilibrium, existing firms

will adjust output along their supply curves, and they will increase profits to above normal.

As a result of excess profits, new firms will be induced to enter the industry.

Then, supply will increase until there are no abnormal profits.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 91: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

91

Constant Cost Industry Old firms will adjust down their SRMC supply

curves to the point that they were at before the change with the new equilibrium price of new demand met by new supply at an expanded quantity.

Since we have no increases in costs at the expanded output, the new equilibrium price should be the same as the original equilibrium price before demand increased.

In that regard, the change in equilibrium price traces out a straight line (see figure in next slide), and that is the long-term supply curve.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 92: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

92

Constant Cost Industry Causal Chain

SRMCSRATC

LRAC

MR1

S1S2

D2

LRSupplyCurve

D1MR2

IncreaseIn demand sets higher equilibrium

Entry of New firmsIncreases

supply

InitialEquilibrium

Price isrestored

PerfectlyElastic

Long-runSupply curve

Firm Industry

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 93: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

93

Constant Cost Industry If you imagine that the reverse situation

happens and demand decreases: New SR equilibrium will be at a lower

price. That means that firms are making less

than normal profits. Thus, firms will exit the business, supply

will decrease, and price will eventually be restored at the original equilibrium price with a lower quantity supplied.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 94: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

94

Decreasing Cost Industry

As new firms enter a decreasing cost industry, input prices fall as total output expands.

A decreasing-cost industry is one in which expansion of industry output by the entry of new firms decreases firm’s costs.

Consider, for example, the computer market.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 95: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

95

Decreasing Cost Industry As output of computers increase, suppliers

of computer chips might experience economies-of-scale cost decreases, themselves, and be able to supply a larger computer industry with cheaper chips.

Thus, computer makers will be able to decrease their costs as a direct result of their industry expansion.

Then (see slide below), an increase in demand will cause a temporary increase in price, resulting in expanded profits.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 96: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

96

Decreasing Cost Industry As new entrants into the market a new

supply curve will develop at which all suppliers have a new cost curve, below the original one.

Tracing out the straight line between equilibrium prices is a downward sloping curve.

Thus, the LR supply curve, in this case, is downward sloping.

See the next slide for a graphical illustration for this case.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 97: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

97

Decreasing Cost Industry Causal Chain

SRATC1

SRATC2

MR3

S1S2

D2

LRSupplyCurve

D1

MR1

MR2

IncreaseIn demand sets higher

Equilibrium price

Entry of newFirms

Increasessupply

EquilibriumPrice and

ATCdecrease

DownwardSloping

LR supplycurve

Firm Industry

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 98: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

98

Increasing Cost Industry As an increasing cost industry

expands its output with the entry of new firms, prices of inputs rise.

As the industry uses more labor, land, machinery, and raw materials, the demand for greater quantities drives up some or all of their prices.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 99: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

99

Increasing Cost Industry For example, suppose that the

home electronics industry uses a significant percentage of electrical engineers, in the country, and it decides to expand.

Then, salaries of electrical engineers, who are in limited supply, will increase, and the cost of home electronics might increase.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 100: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

100

Increasing Cost Industry It is believed that most industries, in

practice, are increasing-cost industries. As a result, the long-run supply curve of such

industries is the usual upward-sloping supply curve that we are familiar with.

We show what happens in such an increasing cost industry in the slide, below.

Demand increases, causing a temporary increase in equilibrium price, up the old supply curve, and a chance to earn abnormal profits.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 101: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

101

Increasing Cost Industry In response to this excess profit

potential, new firms enter the industry, and supply expands.

As a result, price begins to decrease. However, because of increasing costs

for everyone in the industry, there is a new ATC cost structure curve which is shifted upward from the initial one.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 102: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

102

Increasing Cost Industry

Then, the equilibrium price declines to a level, which is above the initial equilibrium price.

Thus, the LR supply curve traced out by the overall movement between initial and final market equilibriums is upward sloping.

See the figures for details..(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 103: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

103

Increasing Cost Industry Causal Chain

SRATC2

SRATC1

MR1

S1S2

D2

LRSupplyCurve

D1

MR3

MR2

IncreaseIn demand sets higher

Equilibrium price

Entry of newFirms

Increasessupply

EquilibriumPrice and

ATCincrease

UpwardSloping

LR supplycurve

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 104: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

104

The Internet & Global Markets

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 105: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

105

The Internet and the Global Marketplace The development of the internet has

increased competition on a global basis.

With the existence of the internet, information is more readily available, and it is as easy to order a book or a new coat, on-line, as it is to make a phone call to your local book or clothing boutique.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 106: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

106

The Internet and the Global Marketplace Now, a girl with a bedroom full of books

can market her books to people as easily as someone who has a book store. Both offer their own convenience.

The store has books on display that you can page through, the girl has excerpts of books on her website and you don’t even need to take a walk to the store.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 107: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

107

The Internet and the Global Marketplace It also has done away with the monopolies

that people have locally or geographically. Previously, one would have to invest in

opening a local store. Now, a bookseller from a small town in Guangdong province can offer books to a person in New York City.

In that regard, barriers to entry to many markets have been lowered by the internet and the ability to do browsing, buying and selling, on-line.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 108: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

108

The Internet and the Global Marketplace It has also allowed communication

among buyers and sellers in fragmented markets, like collectibles and art.

Now a local dealer in 19th century pottery can find current prices, on-line, at auction markets, like E-bay, and can adjust her prices according to a larger market with more information.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 109: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

109

The Internet and the Global Marketplace Securities markets and commodities futures

markets have also become more efficient because of the internet. Previously, a person could call his broker on the phone and place an order. Now, with the internet, a person can open his computer and enter orders to trade securities on-line or be directly connected to major exchanges, like the New York Stock Exchange or the Sydney Futures Exchange, even if they live in a small village in western China.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 110: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

110

The Internet and the Global Marketplace Smaller businesses, even with no actual

storefront in their house but only a dinghy storeroom in the back, can now compete directly with larger players who have large beautiful stores in elegant cites around the world and they can increase their reach in markets, from a local market that they would be stuck in, selling dresses in a small town, to selling their dresses around the world, competing with other sellers in a globalized marketplace.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 111: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

111

The Internet and the Global Marketplace Consumers, too, can look around the

whole world for competitive price, quality, and information.

Thus, the internet revolution has the potential to close the gap between idealized economic models of perfect competition and the reality that exists because of previous barriers to entry that have been battered down by electronic commerce.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 112: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Ask Yourself1. A horizontal demand curve is perfectly elastic.

Can you explain what it means, in terms of perfect elasticity, its definition and consequences, when we say that a firm in a perfectly competitive industry faces a horizontal demand curve?

2. You are a seller of a good in a perfectly competitive industry. You decide to make a famous brand name for your product and hire a marketing firm to develop the brand name and engage in an extensive advertising campaign. What will be the result in terms of your sales, costs, and profits?

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008 112

Page 113: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Ask Yourself3. Why is it important to assume that there are no

entry or exit costs in building a model of perfect competition?

4. At the point P=MR=SRATC=SRMC, what are profits? Why can a firm operate at zero profit: does it mean that the owners of the business are benefactors, not entrepreneurs, and earn no money for themselves but just run the business for the benefit of others?

5. Can you explain, in words and pictures, why MC will have a minimum when MP has its peak?

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008 113

Page 114: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Ask Yourself6. Can you explain why we allow monopolies

in businesses, like electricity and water suppliers? After we do allow that, what else do we do to such industries?

7. As it turns out, many people do not have enlightened self-interest but, instead, are greedy? How do modern societies deal with that?

8. Can you explain in words why maximum profits will happen when P=MC=MR?

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008 114

Page 115: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

Ask Yourself9. Can you explain why we refer to

businesses, like expensive exclusive restaurants or small expensive clothing boutiques, as monopolistic competition?

10. In the past, we have argued that supply curves are upward sloping. What does the LR supply curve look like for a decreasing cost industry? Can you give some examples of industries that might be decreasing-cost industries, and can you explain why they are, when prices of most things go up, not down?

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008 115

Page 116: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

116

Fill in the table

1. Fill in the table.2. Graph the TR, MR,

MC, and TC curves, and discuss the intersection points of the various curves.

units TR TC MR MC Profits

0 0 50

1 50 90

2 100 120

3 150 130

4 200 140

5 250 160

6 300 190

7 350 230

8 400 280

9 450 335

10 500 395

11 550 470

12 600 550(C) Red Hill Capital Corp.,

Delaware, USA 2008

Page 117: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

117

Homework

Chapter 7: Questions/Problems 1-13 Multiple Choice 1-17

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 118: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

118

Next Week We begin a new module: We leave microeconomic studies and move on to

macroeconomics. Covers chapters 11 and 12 (part) introducing

some macroeconomic concepts and the business cycle.

Also, don’t forget, your on-line exam is coming up.

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008

Page 119: Econ 1000 Lecture 6: Perfect Competition

119

END

(C) Red Hill Capital Corp., Delaware, USA 2008