Top Banner
Development Policy Review, 2001, 19 (4): 449-466 Overseas Development Institute, 2001. Published by Blackwell Publishers, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins How important is agricultural growth to poverty reduction? This article first sets out the theoretical reasons for expecting agricultural growth to reduce poverty. Several plausible and strong arguments apply – including the creation of jobs on the land, linkages from farming to the rest of the rural economy, and a decline in the real cost of food for the whole economy – but the degree of impact is in all cases qualified by particular circumstances. Hence, the article deploys a cross-country estimation of the links between agricultural yield per unit area and measures of poverty. This produces strong confirmation of the hypothesised linkages. It is unlikely that there are many other development interventions capable of reducing the numbers in poverty so effectively. How important is agricultural growth to alleviating poverty in a world in which farming’s share of total output is in decline? We can assess the impact of agricultural growth on poverty in general and rural poverty in particular, in two ways. One draws on theory, building plausible arguments about how changes in agricultural production may affect the numbers of poor and the depth of their poverty. The other takes an empirical approach, by observing directly changes in agricultural productivity and poverty, and then estimating the degree to which they are related. This article deploys both approaches. Theoretical expectations of the effects of agricultural growth on poverty The arguments are summarised in Table 1. They have been classified by the scale at which they are expected to apply: that of the agricultural economy at farm and village level, the (local, regional) rural economy as a whole, and the national economy. The arguments, and some of the evidence cited in support of them, are then reviewed. Xavier Irz and Steve Wiggins are in the Department of Agricultural and Food Economics, University of Reading; Lin Lin is in the Department of Environmental Science and Technology, Imperial College of Science, Technology and Medicine, London University; and Colin Thirtle is in the Department of Environmental Science and Technology, Imperial College of Science, Technology and Medicine, London University, and the University of Pretoria, South Africa.
18

Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

May 11, 2023

Download

Documents

Ismo Stranden
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

Development Policy Review, 2001, 19 (4): 449-466

Overseas Development Institute, 2001.

Published by Blackwell Publishers, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.

Agricultural Productivity Growth and PovertyAlleviation

Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins∗∗∗∗

How important is agricultural growth to poverty reduction? This articlefirst sets out the theoretical reasons for expecting agricultural growth toreduce poverty. Several plausible and strong arguments apply – includingthe creation of jobs on the land, linkages from farming to the rest of therural economy, and a decline in the real cost of food for the whole economy– but the degree of impact is in all cases qualified by particularcircumstances. Hence, the article deploys a cross-country estimation of thelinks between agricultural yield per unit area and measures of poverty. Thisproduces strong confirmation of the hypothesised linkages. It is unlikelythat there are many other development interventions capable of reducingthe numbers in poverty so effectively.

How important is agricultural growth to alleviating poverty in a world in whichfarming’s share of total output is in decline?

We can assess the impact of agricultural growth on poverty in general and ruralpoverty in particular, in two ways. One draws on theory, building plausible argumentsabout how changes in agricultural production may affect the numbers of poor and thedepth of their poverty. The other takes an empirical approach, by observing directlychanges in agricultural productivity and poverty, and then estimating the degree towhich they are related. This article deploys both approaches.

Theoretical expectations of the effects of agricultural growthon poverty

The arguments are summarised in Table 1. They have been classified by the scale atwhich they are expected to apply: that of the agricultural economy at farm and villagelevel, the (local, regional) rural economy as a whole, and the national economy. Thearguments, and some of the evidence cited in support of them, are then reviewed.

∗Xavier Irz and Steve Wiggins are in the Department of Agricultural and Food Economics, University ofReading; Lin Lin is in the Department of Environmental Science and Technology, Imperial College ofScience, Technology and Medicine, London University; and Colin Thirtle is in the Department ofEnvironmental Science and Technology, Imperial College of Science, Technology and Medicine, LondonUniversity, and the University of Pretoria, South Africa.

Page 2: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

450 Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins

Table 1: The consequences of agricultural growth

Effect of agricultural growth Qualifications and necessary conditions

Farm economyF1 Higher incomes for farmers, including

smallholdersExtent to which poor have access tofarm land & their production levels.

Extent to which output prices aresustained & do not fall as outputincreases.

Input prices may rise more thanproportionately to output.

Increased land rents may offset highergross earnings for tenant &sharecropping farmers. Distribution ofland ownership & abundance of landaffect ability of rich to capture rents.

Ability of poor to adopt improvedtechnology – scale biases intechniques, increased exposure torisks, access to inputs, complementaryservices & credit.

F2 More employment on-farm as labourdemand rises per hectare, the areacultivated expands, or frequency ofcropping increases. Rise in farm wagerates.

Degree to which rural poor depend onfarm labouring for their incomes.

Nature of technical change – labour-displacing technology (machinery,herbicides, etc.) may reduce labourdemand per hectare.

Changes in output mix. A move tocrops & livestock that use less labourper unit output might reduceemployment.

Changes in supply of rural labour –affected by population growth, out-migration, availability of non-farmjobs, etc.

Rural economy

R1 More jobs in agriculture & food chainupstream & downstream of farm

Strength of linkages – much affectedby technology of production & needfor processing.

Location of linked activities.

Page 3: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation 451

R2 More jobs or higher incomes in non-farm economy as farmers & farmlabourers spend additional incomes

Kinds of goods & services demanded.Local linkages are especially strongwhen demand is for non-tradables.

Supply elasticity of goods & servicesproduced by non-farm rural economy.

R3 Increased jobs & incomes in ruraleconomy allow better nutrition, betterhealth & increased investment ineducation amongst rural population.Lead directly to improved welfare, &indirectly to higher labourproductivity.

Distribution of incomes & marginalpropensities to spend on food, healthcare & schooling.

R4 Generates more local tax revenues &demand for better infrastructure –roads, power supplies,communications. Leads to second-round effects promoting ruraleconomy.

Local tax regime, quality of localgovernment & support from centralgovernment.

R5 Linkages in production chain generatetrust & information, build social capital& facilitate non-farm investment.

Nature of linkages & socialcharacteristics of actors.

R6 Reduced prices of food for ruralinhabitants who buy in food net.

Rural economy sufficiently isolated bydistance from national & internationalmarkets.

National economy

N1 Reduced prices of food & rawmaterials raise real wages of urbanpoor, reduce wage costs of non-farmsectors.

Extent to which economy is closed tointernational markets. If economy isopen, increased farm production willnot affect price levels.

N2 Generation of savings & taxes fromfarming allows investment in non-farmsector, creating jobs & incomes inother sectors.

Institutions & conditions that mediatethese flows, & extent to which they arechannelled into productiveinvestments.

N3 Earning of foreign exchange allowsimport of capital goods & essentialinputs for non-farm production.

Degree to which farm production istradable, either as export crop orimport substitute.

N4 Release of farm labour allowsproduction in other sectors.

Willingness of labourers to migrate, &their skills and capabilities foremployment in other sectors.

Page 4: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

452 Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins

The farm economy

The most direct contribution of agricultural growth is through generating higherincomes for farmers (F1). Two conditions affect the influence of this on poverty. First,there is the degree to which the poor are engaged in farming. Even if the majority of theworld’s poor live in rural areas – estimates vary from around 60% (CGIAR, 2000) to75% or more (IFAD, 2001) – that does not mean they necessarily farm. Jazairy et al.(1992) found that, for a sample of 64 developing countries, 64% of the ‘functionallyvulnerable’ (that is, in this case, the rural poor) were smallholders who can gain directlyfrom on-farm production growth and 29% were landless. The extent of involvement infarming varies geographically, so that in sub-Saharan Africa smallholders typicallyaccount for 77% of the poor, whereas in Asia the comparable figure is less than half(reported by Cox et al., 1998). But even when the poor do typically farm, theirproduction is often small: indeed many smallholders, even those who grow food cropsmainly for their own consumption, may have to buy in food. In Madagascar in 1990, forexample, 63% of smallholders growing rice were net buyers of the grain (Barrett, 1998).Incomes from farming may thus make up only a small fraction of their total income.

The second condition is the extent to which output growth raises incomes. Shouldincreased output drive down product prices, or costs of production rise as the demandfor inputs increases, the rise in gross margins may be small. In particular, if land isscarce, increased returns to agriculture may be reflected in higher land rents. In caseswhere the poor till land belonging to others, the capitalisation of benefits into higherrents could seriously undermine the contribution to poverty reduction.

When output increase is due to technical innovation, benefits to the poor who farm,and for whom farming provides the majority of their income, may be limited for severalreasons. First, adoption by the poor can be limited (see Hazell and Haddad, 2001) by alack of access to inputs and to the knowledge necessary to use the technology, as well asby a scale bias in the new technology – as, for example, when inputs are indivisible,such as with some machinery. Secondly, it can also be explained by marketimperfections or policies that limit the access of small farmers to inputs, includingcredit. Poor farmers may be more risk-averse than wealthier ones and therefore unlikelyto adopt techniques that increase the variance of yields. Finally, new technology mightnot suit the agro-climatic conditions typical of many smallholdings. The adoption of thefirst wave of green revolution cereal varieties was largely confined to irrigated areaswith good soils, and even then required major inputs of pesticides and fertiliser (Barkerand Herdt, 1985). In contrast, many of the rural poor live in rainfed areas and arid andsemi-arid zones (Lipton, 2001).

When technology and policies are biased against smallholders, agricultural growthcan even have perverse effects on poverty. For example, technical change can result inan increase in landlessness as large farmers and landlords expand their cropped area bytaking in land previously rented out (Hazell and Haddad, 2001) or by appropriatingpreviously common land (Dasgupta, 1998).

The other contribution within the farm economy is through the labour market (F2).The effect of this on poverty reduction depends in part on the degree to which the ruralpoor depend on labouring. In South Asia, it is common to find one-third to one-half ofvillage households without access to land and depending very heavily on farm labouringfor their incomes. Even in rural Africa, where landlessness is uncommon, households

Page 5: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation 453

with only small plots or that lack working capital may still depend significantly onlabouring for their incomes.

Greater agricultural production is likely to boost the demand for farm labour as theamount of labour used per hectare rises, either as the area cultivated expands or as thefrequency of cropping increases. How much more labour is demanded depends largelyon the technology used to increase output or the changes in the composition of outputexperienced. A new crop technology may reduce input use, raise yields, raise labourproductivity, or, in the case of, say, a short-season maize variety, allow the cultivatedarea to be expanded. The first will increase profit but not output, and may reduceemployment; the second will increase output and probably employment, but notnecessarily profits; the third will raise the remuneration of labour, but possibly at theexpense of employment, and the output effect is indeterminate. The last may raiseoutput, employment and profits, but could well lower yields. A new technology mayalso induce a change in the composition of output towards more or less labour-intensivecrops.

If no general outcome can be predicted a priori, the evidence suggests thatagricultural growth driven by yield increases raises the demand for farm labour. Hayamiand Ruttan (1985) review the literature on the effect of modern varieties of rice andwheat in Asia to conclude that their introduction typically resulted in an increase inlabour requirements per unit of land, and, in some cases, in higher cropping intensity.Lipton and Longhurst (1989) suggest that, in its initial stage, the green revolutiontechnology boosted the demand for labour per unit of land by 20%, but that this gainslowly eroded owing to the subsequent adoption of labour-displacing inputs such asherbicides, mechanical threshers and tractors. In a similar vein, Binswanger and Quizon(1986) find a relatively low but positive output elasticity of agriculture with respect tolabour.

Agricultural growth, then, is likely to create some more jobs for farm labourers:whether this results in higher rural wages is another matter. The impact of agriculturalgrowth on labour earnings is more difficult to establish, since the agricultural wage rateis determined by factors both within and outside agriculture. In some cases, wage rateshave risen – for example, on central Luzon by 39% to 58% during the adoption of thegreen revolution rice technology from 1966 to 1986 (Estudillo and Otsuka, 1999), or inBihar where agricultural wage rates in 1990–91 in prosperous farming areas were morethan twice those in stagnating regions (Thakur et al., 1997) – whereas in other casessuch as West Bengal in the late 1980s (Beck, 1995), wages hardly increased asirrigation and the green revolution were adopted. Indeed, agricultural growth driven bymodern varieties resulted in a decrease in the factor share of labour in several countries(Jha, 1974; Mellor and Lele, 1973). Interpretations of this observation, however, vary.Hayami and Ruttan (1985) consider that this cannot be attributed to the factor-savingbias of the new technology; instead, it is explained by the growing supply of labourassociated with population growth and by the slow adjustment of the wage rate to itsnew equilibrium value. Lipton and Longhurst (1989) suggest that, without theagricultural growth of the green revolution, farm wage rates would have declinedfurther.

Page 6: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

454 Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins

The rural economy

Increased agricultural production should have effects on other sectors in the ruraleconomy through a series of linkages.

These include production links, both ‘upstream’ from the farm in demand for inputsand services for agriculture, as well as ‘downstream’ from the farm in the demand forprocessing, storage, and transport of produce (R1). There are also consumption links asfarmers and farm labourers spend their increased incomes on goods and services in thelocal rural economy (R2).

The precise degree and form of these linkages are likely to be affected by factorssuch as the amount of rural infrastructure, rural population density, the need forimmediate and local processing of farm produce, the nature of technical change infarming, and the tradability of both farm output and the goods and services demandedby farming communities.

Since the early 1980s models have been built to estimate the first two of thesemultipliers for specific regions.1 These studies show high multipliers (see Table 2).Most of these studies show that the bulk – 75% or more – of the effects arise throughconsumption linkages.

Some studies show greater effects in areas with more infrastructure and welldeveloped rural-urban links, and correspondingly lower multipliers for cases fromAfrica where these conditions do not usually apply. On the other hand, Delgado andcolleagues (1994) have produced equally high if not higher linkages for African cases,arguing that isolation in rural Africa means that any exogenous increase in farmearnings will be spent disproportionately on locally produced goods and services.

Table 2: Multipliers from increases in farm output to other sectors

Study location and time Multiplier estimated Source

Muda Valley, Malaysia, 1972 1.83

[1.71]

Haggblade et al., 1989

[Haggblade et al., 1991]

North Arcot District, TamilNadu, India, 1982–3

1.87 Hazell and Ramasamy 1991

Sierra Leone, Rural, 1974–5 1.35 Haggblade et al., 1991

Burkina, 1984–85

Niger, 1989–90

Senegal, 1989–90

Zambia, 1985–86

Ranging:

From 1.31 to 4.62

Delgado et al., 1994a

Delgado et al., 1994b

These findings have, however, been disputed. As with most models, theassumptions may be questioned. In particular, the strong multipliers for rural Africareported by Delgado and his colleagues have been criticised by de Janvry (1994) asbeing based on unlikely assumptions about the perfect elasticity of supply of non-tradables. 1. See Haggblade et al. (1991) for a discussion of these models. They favour using semi-input-output models.

Page 7: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation 455

Hart (1989) comments that the Muda Valley study underplayed the extent to whichincreased spending went on goods that were imported into the region. She also focuseson how capital has been exported from the Muda Valley. In similar fashion, Harriss-White’s detailed studies (1997) of a market town and its hinterland in North Arcotsuggest that capital is being siphoned out of the rural areas to the urban economy. Shealso casts doubt on the extent to which the farm economy stimulates the non-farmeconomy. Her work suggests that the growth of rural industries in the town of Arniowes more to links with the urban hierarchy of India as a whole, than to the fortunes ofthe surrounding rural areas.

But there are other possible links. For example, there may be gains both to welfareand to rural human capital (R3) as increased food production and farming incomesallow better nutrition of rural workers and investment in health and education (Timmer,1995). Increased agricultural output may generate more tax revenues, allowing morepublic investment in infrastructure, the demand for which may be stimulated by thegrowth of the farm sector (R4). A final linkage may run from a more dynamic farmsector to social capital formation, as increased interactions between farmers, inputsuppliers, processors and banks generate the confidence and trust needed to mount newnon-agricultural businesses (R5).

Little research has been done into the strengths of these three linkages. Almostcertainly, however, their applicability and importance will vary greatly betweendifferent contexts.

The last impact on the rural economy may be that of reducing food prices (R6).Since this usually applies when national food prices have been lowered, this issue willbe discussed together with effect N1 below.

The national economy

Nationally, it is argued that an increase in output tends to drive down the price of food,hence benefiting consumers and all net purchasers of food (N1). Since the poor, bothurban and rural, spend a greater proportion of their incomes on food than better-offhouseholds (see, for example Musgrove (1985) on the case of the Dominican Republic),they benefit relatively more (Pinstrup-Andersen and Hazell, 1985).

The strength of this effect depends a great deal on the degree to which farmproduction is tradable and the associated price elasticity of demand. Alston and hiscolleagues (1998) show that, following an increase in supply, the price decreasedetermining the distribution of benefits between producers and consumers depends onthe elasticity of demand of the commodity considered. The more inelastic the demand,the greater the fall in price and hence the share of the benefits accruing to consumers.On the other hand, if demand were perfectly elastic, only producers would gain. Theelasticity of demand that producers face depends largely on the size of the marketsupplied –and hence on tradability. Thus, recent liberalisation of trade probably meansthat producers are capturing an increasing share of the benefits from agriculturalgrowth, while any consumer gains become increasingly global. That said, wheremarkets are poorly integrated and infrastructure underdeveloped, farm produce becomeseffectively non-tradable so that increased output is likely to cause substantial falls inoutput prices with consequent gains to consumers. It is thus likely that the poor in sub-

Page 8: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

456 Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins

Saharan Africa and South Asia should benefit more from domestic agricultural growththan the poor in Latin America, West Asia and North Africa (Byerlee, 2000).

Evidence suggests that this mechanism has been quantitatively important over thelast few decades in the fight against poverty. At the most aggregated level, Grilli andYang (1988) establish that the world price index of cereals exhibited a downward trendbetween 1900 and 1987, a trend that has been maintained subsequently (Johnson, 1997)with only a short-lived interruption in 1996–7. Otsuka (2000) and Binswanger andQuizon (1989) conclude that much of the positive effect of green revolution technologyon inequality and poverty came from lower food prices because of output expansion.Schuh (2000) also suggests that the greatest achievement of world agriculture in thefight against poverty has been the supply of affordable food to the masses.

Agricultural growth can contribute to overall national growth and through this topoverty reduction. The dual-economy models of Lewis (1954) and followers (Fei andRanis, 1961) stress the importance of capital formation2 and wage costs fordevelopment. Furthermore, in spite of the recent liberalisation of capital markets,investment in developing countries still relies largely on domestic savings (Ventura,1997).

Agricultural growth can thus facilitate development by allowing a sustainedtransfer of resources from agriculture to the rest of the economy, including through thesupply of capital to other sectors (N2). Although this transfer of resources can rely onvoluntary savings by the agricultural population, given the right set of incentives(Griffin, 1979), many governments have accelerated the process by taxing agriculturedirectly or indirectly. Hence, early industrialisation in Japan in the last decades of thenineteenth century was largely financed by a land tax, representing over 80% of fiscalrevenues at the time (Ghatak and Ingersent, 1984). In many developing countries,agriculture still makes a substantial net contribution to government revenue (Schiff andValdés, 1992).

Similarly, scarcity of foreign exchange in low-income countries may restrict thepurchase of capital goods and other imports essential to investment. Here again, growthin output of tradable farm commodities can make a contribution by either substitutingfood imports or increasing exports (N3).3

Finally, growth of agricultural productivity per labour unit at a rate higher thanagricultural production can allow the release of labour to other sectors where there arehigher productivity jobs (N4). This transfer, central to Lewis’s theories of development,has been an important element in the very high rates of growth experienced in EastAsian economies since the 1980s.

2. More recent work suggests that capital should be understood in a broad sense to include human aspects

and knowledge, as argued by the endogenous growth literature (Romer, 1986; Lucas, 1988).3. In Taiwan during the 1950s and 1960s, exports of agricultural commodities, primarily rice and sugar,

provided the foreign exchange for at least half of the country’s imports and were essential in launching theindustrialisation process (Mao and Schive, 1995). Henson and Loader (2000) report that during the period1980¯97, agricultural and food products typically accounted for over 25% of total merchandise exportsfrom sub-Saharan Africa.

Page 9: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation 457

Theoretical effects summed up

The sixteen different effects identified here do not necessarily apply in all cases. Indeed,some are contradictory –for example, R6 and N1 depend on falling food prices thatwould offset any increased incomes to farmers (F1) and consequent effects such as N2,R3, and R4. Those benefits that might arise from absorbing labour (F2) conflict with thecontribution of releasing labour (N4). Which effect applies, and how strongly, dependson circumstances specific to particular cases. There is thus ample scope for increases inagricultural output to generate very different outcomes in different circumstances.

That said, the literature suggests that some of these effects apply more commonly,or tend to have greater strength, than others. For the poor, extra farm jobs and higherwages (F2) may be the single most obvious benefit; followed by the impact ofadditional spending in the rural economy (R2); and the value to the national economyand social welfare of reduced costs of food (N1, R6).

If net outcomes can be difficult to determine a priori, this justifies an empiricalinvestigation of the relationship between agricultural growth and poverty. This is whatwe examine in the next section.

Empirical estimates of the relationship between agriculturaloutput and poverty

Previous studies

Several country studies reported in the literature demonstrate convincingly the pro-poorbias of agricultural growth. Datt and Ravallion (1996) establish that the sectoralcomposition of economic growth is a key determinant of poverty alleviation in India.First rural growth reduces poverty in both rural and urban areas, but urban growth doesnot alleviate poverty in rural areas. Second, a decomposition of growth by sectorsdemonstrates that growth in agriculture benefits the poor in both urban and rural areas,while growth in manufacturing has no impact on poverty in either. In their 1998 paper,the same authors explain further the pro-poor character of agricultural growth byestimating a simultaneous equation model of poverty determination. The results showthat land yield is inversely related to a variety of poverty measures, with an elasticityranging from one to two. As expected, yield growth contributes to poverty alleviationboth directly and by inducing a rise in the wage rate as well as a decline in the price offood, although these price effects take several years to materialise.

Wodon (1999) also establishes the superiority of rural growth over urban growthfor poverty alleviation in Bangladesh. His simulations suggest that a pro-ruraldevelopment strategy would probably bring down the poverty headcount in the countryby 3 points by 2008, compared with a baseline scenario of no policy change. Moreover,analysing poverty in Indonesia, Thorbecke and Jung (1996) reach the conclusion thatthe bulk of poverty reduction is achieved by growth within agriculture.

Rangarajan (1982, reported in Hazell and Haddad, 2000) estimated that a 1%addition to the agricultural growth rate in India stimulated a 0.5% addition to the growthrate of industrial output, and a 0.7% addition to the growth rate of national income. ForKenya, Block and Timmer (Timmer, 1995) obtained a multiplier from an exogenous

Page 10: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

458 Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins

shift in farm output of 1.64 for the rest of the economya higher value than that arisingfrom industrial growth, where the multiplier was estimated at 1.23.

Coxhead and Warr (1991) used a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model,loosely styled on the case of the Philippines, to show how, in a small open economy,technical improvements in farming are likely to benefit labour, especially if thetechnical change is labour-using or land-saving. Taking the case of a 10% improvementin farm output, applicable to irrigated areas, with technology that saves land but useslabour, their work predicts almost an 8% increase in the incomes of landless labourers.

For Bolivia, de Franco and Godoy (1993) also built a CGE model to show thattechnical improvements to crops generate all-round benefits in the economy, stimulatinggrowth and employment. But improvements to the main non-tradable crop, potatoes,have greater effects than improvements to traded crops such as wheat or soybeansinlarge part because the price of potatoes falls, raising real incomes in a country where thepoor spend large fractions of their household budgets on foodstuffs.

Cross-country examinations of the relationship between growth and povertyconfirm the previous results. Gallup et al. (1997) find that a 1% increase in agriculturalGDP leads to a 1.61% increase in the incomes of the poorest quintile, while thecorresponding values for the manufacturing and services sectors are only 1.16% and0.79%. Other cross-country studies, reviewed in Hanmer and Naschold (2000), providefurther evidence of the pro-poor bias of agricultural growth, with only the results ofWhite and Anderson contradicting this view.4

The estimates made here

In this section we examine the proposition that agricultural productivity has a directimpact on poverty headcounts and other poverty measures.5 This relationship, supportedby the work of Datt and Ravallion in India mentioned above, does not appear to havebeen investigated in a cross-section of countries. It is similar to the notion of estimatingpoverty elasticities for growth.

Agricultural output is measured by its value added, that is, gross output net of thecosts of intermediate inputs, hence removing the costs of intensification usingincreasing amounts of modern inputs. It is not clear whether labour or land productivityshould be included as the explanatory variable in the poverty regressions. Thereforeseveral models are estimated, using the following identity:

4. White and Anderson (2001) find a negative effect of agricultural growth on poverty. Their data are from

the same source as Timmer (1997) and Gallup et al. (1997), but they retain only ‘high quality’ data, thusdropping many developing countries, and all of SSA except Zambia. Thus their result seems to come fromthe fact that half the sample is developed countries, with agricultural sectors that are too small to affectpoverty. This is of little interest for the current study, where the emphasis is on the poorer developingcountries.

5. The poverty measures are not discussed here, but they can differ considerably. See Wodon (1997) forsome comparisons of poverty indicators in Bangladesh that give inconsistent results.

LABOURUNITPER

LAND

LAND

ADDEDVALUE

LABOURUNITPER

ADDEDVALUE×= (1)

Page 11: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation 459

Equation (1) decomposes labour productivity into the product of two components:land productivity, or yield, and the land labour ratio, which can be viewed as anindicator of a country’s resource endowment. Thus, the yield contribution to labourproductivity can be separated from the relative scarcity of land, which it is not possibleto change. This relationship is exploited to specify three simple models:

1 1 1: POVERTY INDEX a b VALUE ADDED/LANDn n= + +[ ] ε (2)

2 1: n 1n [POVERTY INDEX VALUE ADDED LABOUR= + +α β ε/ ] (3)

3 :1 1n 1n [ n [POVERTY INDEX VA LAND LAND LABOUR= + + +α β δ ε/ ] / ] (4)

Both double-log and non-log forms of the relationships presented in equations (2)–(4)were tested, leading to very similar results. The double-logarithmic form was thereforechosen since it makes interpretation of the regression results straightforward,coefficients β and δ representing the elasticities of poverty with respect to yields and theland-labour ratio. The data for the independent variables were obtained from the WorldDevelopment Indicators (2000) data set.

Several sets of regressions were run using alternative poverty indices and differentsample sizes. The analysis begins by fitting equations (2)–(4) with the available cross-section of US$1 per day poverty percentages as the dependent variable taken from theWorld Development Report 2000/2001. The results are reported in Table 3. Model 1 hasonly 40 observations because the yield data end at 1995 and many of the 72 povertyestimates are for later dates. However, the 40 countries constitute a reasonable sampleof the developing world.6

The adjusted R2 of 0.20, in model 1 of Table 3, means that yield explains only 20%of the variance in poverty, which is not satisfactory, since it suggests that other, omittedvariables explain the majority of the differences. The productivity measure, however, issignificantly different from zero at a high level of confidence. The poverty elasticity of-0.37 means that a 1% increase in yields reduces the percentage of the populationsliving on less than US$1 per day by 0.37%.

Model 2 explains just over 50% of the variance, which is far better, and the povertyelasticity, which is again highly significant, rises to -0.83, so a 1% improvement inlabour productivity reduces the poverty count by 0.83%. The sample increases to 66,but the problem with this model is that the effect could all be coming from the land-labour ratio component of the labour productivity index.Thus, following these preliminary tests, Model 3 separates the two terms. The modelexplains 62% of the variance in poverty, and the large increase in the F statisticindicates that it is statistically preferred to the two previous attempts. A 1% increase inthe land–labour ratio reduces poverty by 0.82%, which is surprisingly low relative to the

6. The countries are Algeria, Botswana, Bulgaria, Burkina Faso, Central African Republic, Chile, Côte

d'Ivoire, Ecuador, Egypt, Estonia, Guatemala, Kenya, Korea, Lesotho, Madagascar, Mali, Mauritania,Mexico, Mongolia, Morocco, Namibia, Nepal, Niger, Paraguay, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Rwanda,Senegal, Sierra Leone, Slovenia, South Africa, Sri Lanka, Tanzania, Tunisia, Turkey, Uganda, Uruguay,Uzbekistan and Zimbabwe. The greatest weakness is that the largest countries of Asia, such as China andIndia, are missing, so a huge proportion of the world’s poor people are not included. Also, some wouldomit the central and eastern European countries.

Page 12: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

460 Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins

effect of the land productivity term, which indicates that a 1% improvement in yieldsdecreases the percentage of the population living on less than US$1 per day by 0.91%.7

Again, the variables are highly significant and this is the preferred model.

Table 3: Regressing agricultural productivity on poverty count:cross sectiona

Explanatory variables Expected sign Estimated coefficients

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3VA/LAND Negative -0.37b -0.91b

VA/LABOUR Negative -0.83b

LAND/LABOUR Negative -0.819b

Constant 4.26b 8.06b 8.48b

R square 0.20 0.506 0.625F Test 13.35b 13.35b 53.42b

Sample Size 40 66 40a) dependent variable is % of population with less than $1 per day; b) significant at the 1% level,two-tailed test.

The implications of these results should be assessed in view of the yield increasesthat the world has experienced over the last few decades and the potential for futureyield growth. Mitchell et al. (1997) report that between 1950 and 1990 cereal yields indeveloping countries grew at an annual rate of 2.17%. Using the elasticity computedabove, such a growth rate reduces a poverty head count of 40% typical of a leastdeveloped country to 30% in only ten years. Further, the green revolution demonstratesthat much faster yield growth can be achieved, given investments in agricultural R&Dand rural infrastructure.8 The results therefore suggest that agricultural growth driven byyield gains can provide a particularly effective way of fighting poverty. This claimcould be tested further if an elasticity was calculated to link R&D expenditure to yieldgains. Then, the cost of generating a 1% decrease in poverty could be inferred. SinceR&D expenditures are quite modest, we expect that this could appear as a very cost-effective means of reducing poverty.

The sensitivity of the results to sample size was tested by applying the samemethodology to the data used by Hanmer and Naschold (2000)9 that have scatteredobservations from 1985 to 1995 for 58 countries, thus increasing the number ofobservations to 109. Table 4 is totally consistent with the previous analysis: thespecification decomposing labour productivity into yield and land-labour ratio (model3) is preferred; the poverty reduction from a 1% increase in yields still appears to beabout 0.7% and the relationship is again highly significant.

7. Interestingly, the equivalent figure for African countries alone is 0.96, an even stronger linkage (see

Thirtle et al., 2001)8. Hence, wheat yields in India doubled from 1967 to 1983 (FAO-STAT database), implying an annual rate

of growth of almost 4.5%. It should be noted, however, that some believe that yield growth is slowingdown (Pinstrup-Andersen et al., 1999) and that marginal yield gains are becoming increasingly difficultand costly to achieve (Ruttan, 2000).

9. We thank them for making these data available.

Page 13: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation 461

Table 4: Regressing agricultural productivity on poverty count:pooled samplea

Explanatory Variables Expected sign Estimated coefficients

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3VA/LAND Negative -0.299b -0.72 b

VA/LABOUR Negative -0.629 b

LAND/LABOUR Negative -0.605 b

YEAR DUMM -0.014 0.117 0.1066Constant 4.498c 7.177c 7.616c

R square 0.088 0.3095 0.328F Test 6.44 b 20.2 14.79b

Sample Size 109 113 109a) dependent variable is % of population with less than $1 per day; b) significant at the 1% level,two-tailed test; c) significant at the 5% level, two-tailed test.

The earliest observations for the US$1 per day poverty index are for 1985, whereasthe Human Development Index (HDI) from the UNDP dataset goes back to 1975, so theHDI was used in the place of the US$1 per day poverty measure in an attempt to coverthe effects of the green revolution period. Only the preferred model 3 is reported inTable 5. The two agricultural productivity variables alone explain 76% of the variancein the HDI and both are highly significant. Thus, this regression confirms the apparentlysolid link between agricultural productivity growth and poverty reduction. Raisingyields by 1% increases the HDI by 0.12%, which is the right direction, but an increasein the value of a composite index is more difficult to interpret than a reduction in thenumbers of poor falling below US$1 per day.

Table 5: Explaining the Human Development Index

Variables Expected sign Estimated coefficients

Model 3VA/LAND Positive 0.1226a

LAND/LABOUR Positive 0.1011 a

Constant -2.39 a

R square 0.759F-statistic 328.48 a

Sample Size 280a) significant at the 1% level, two-tailed test.

In summary, the regressions presented strongly suggest that agriculturalproductivity is an important determinant of poverty, and that increases in yields havethe potential to lift a large number of individuals out of poverty. However, althoughthese results appear to be robust, they should be analysed with caution. There areobviously other variables affecting poverty, such as the provision of public goods or thelevel of inequality, and they should ideally be included in the model. Otherwise,

Page 14: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

462 Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins

variable omission may bias the elasticities.10 To ensure that the elasticities presented didnot only reflect gross mis-specification of the model, a system of equations explainingsimultaneously inequality, poverty and income per capita was estimated. The resultsconfirmed the significance of the poverty elasticity with respect to land yield.11

Conclusion

Theoretically there are reasons to expect agricultural growth to relieve rural poverty, butthese depend on all manner of qualifications dependent on specific circumstances.Empirical work, however, tends to show strong poverty-alleviating effects ofagricultural growth. Indeed, the strength of these is potentially remarkable. It seems, forexample, that a yield increase of one-third might reduce the numbers in poverty by aquarter or more.

This implies that the hypothesised linkages from agricultural production to povertyprobably operate significantly and strongly in many circumstances. In particular, it islikely that the ability of agriculture to generate employment, to stimulate the ruraleconomy through linkages, and to reduce the real cost of food accounts for much of thepoverty-reducing effects observed.

The question then arises: how many other comparable development efforts arelikely to have greater impact on reducing poverty than those that help raise agriculturalproduction? This requires additional analysis, but if the linkages really are as strong asour estimates suggest, it is a fair guess that rather few alternatives will show a betterreturn.

References

Alston, Julian M., Norton, George W. and Pardey, Philip G. (1998) Science underScarcity. New York and Wallingford: NAR and CAB International.

Barker, R. and Herdt, R. (1985). ‘Who Benefits from the New Technology?’, in TheRice Economy in Asia. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.

Barrett, Christopher B. (1998) ‘Immiserized Growth in Liberalized Agriculture’, WorldDevelopment 26(5): 743-53.

Beck, Tony (1995) ‘The Green Revolution and Poverty in India. A Case Study of WestBengal’, Applied Geography 15 (2): 161-81.

Binswanger, H.P. and Quizon, J.B. (1986) What Can Agriculture Do for the PoorestRural Groups? Report No. 57. Washington, DC: Agricultural and Rural DevelopmentDepartment, World Bank.

Byerlee, Derek (2000) ‘Targeting Poverty Alleviation in Priority Setting forAgricultural Research’, Food Policy 25: 429-45.

Carney, D. (ed.) (1998) Sustainable Livelihoods: Lessons from Early Experience. London:DFID.

10. Specifically if a variable that is positively correlated with the explanatory variables is omitted, this will

tend to bias the elasticities upwards, since the contribution of the omitted variable will tend to be picked upby those that are included. The reverse will be true if the omitted variable is negatively correlated with theregressors

11. The results are reported in Lin et al. (2001), available from the authors on request.

Page 15: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation 463

CGIAR (2000) A Food Secure World for All: Toward a New Vision and Strategy for theCGIAR. Washington DC: CGIAR Secretariat.

Cox, A, Farrington, J and Gilling, J. (1998) Reaching the Poor? Developing a PovertyScreen for Agricultural Research Proposals. ODI Working Paper 112. London:Overseas Development Institute.

Coxhead, Ian A. and Warr, Peter G. (1991) ‘Technical Change, Land Quality andIncome Distribution: A General Equilibrium Analysis’, American Journal ofAgricultural Economics 73: 345–60.

Dasgupta, Partha (1998) ‘The Economics of Poverty in Poor Countries’, ScandinavianJournal of Economics 100 (1): 41-68.

Datt, Gaurav and Ravallion, Martin (1996) ‘How Important to India’s Poor is theSectoral Composition of Economic Growth?’, World Bank Economic Review 10(1): 1-25.

Datt, G. and Ravallion, M. (1998) ‘Farm Productivity and Rural Poverty in India’, Journalof Development Studies 34 (4): 62-85.

David, C. and Otsuka, K. (eds) (1994) Modern Rice Technology and IncomeDistribution in Asia. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.

De Franco, Mario and Godoy, Ricardo (1993) ‘Potato-led Growth: The MacroeconomicEffects of Technological Innovations in Bolivian Agriculture’, Journal ofDevelopment Studies 29 (3): 561–87.

de Janvry, Alain (1994) ‘Farm-nonfarm Synergies in Africa: Discussion’, AmericanJournal of Agricultural Economics 76: 1183-5.

Delgado, Christopher, Hazell, Peter, Hopkins, Jane and Kelly, Valerie (1994a)‘Promoting Intersectoral Growth Linkages in Rural Africa through AgriculturalTechnology and Policy Reform’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76:1166-71.

Delgado, Christopher L., Hopkins, Jane C. and Kelly, Valerie A. (with Peter B.R.Hazell, Anna Alfano, Peter Gruhn, Behjat Hojjati and Jayashree Sil) (1994b)Agricultural Growth Linkages in Sub-Saharan Africa. Washington, DC: IFPRI.

Estudillo, Jonna P. and Otsuka, Keijiro (1999) ‘Green Revolution, Human Capital, andOff-farm Employment: Changing Sources of Income Among Farm Households inCentral Luzon, 1966-1994’, Economic Development and Cultural Change 47: 497-523.

Fei, J.C. and Ranis, G. (1961) ‘A Theory of Economic Development’, AmericanEconomic Review 51 (4): 533-65.

Gallup, John, Radelet, Steven and Warner, Andrew (1997) Economic Growth and theIncome of the Poor. CAER II Discussion Paper No 36. Cambridge, MA: HarvardInstitute for International Development.

Ghatak, Subrata and Ingersent, Ken (1984) Agriculture and Economic Development.Brighton: Wheatsheaf Harvester Press.

Griffin, K. (1979) The Political Economy of Agrarian Change. London: Macmillan.Grilli, Enzo R. and Yang, Maw Cheng (1988) ‘Primary Commodity Prices,

Manufactured Goods Prices and the Terms of Trade of Developing Countries: Whatthe Long Run Shows’, World Bank Economic Review 2 (1): 1-48.

Haggblade, Steven, Hammer, Jeffrey and Hazell, Peter (1991) ‘Modeling AgriculturalGrowth Multipliers’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics (May): 361-74.

Page 16: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

464 Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins

Haggblade, Steven, Hazell, Peter and Brown, James (1989) ‘Farm-nonfarm Linkages inRural Sub-Saharan Africa’, World Development 17 (8): 1173-1201.

Hanmer, L and Nashchold, F. (2000) ‘Attaining the International Development Targets:Will Growth be Enough?’, Development Policy Review 18 (1):11-36.

Harriss-White, Barbara (1997) ‘Regional Growth Linkages from Agriculture andResource Flows in Non-farm Economy’, Economic and Political Weekly 22 (1–2):31–46.

Hart, Gill (1989) ‘The Growth Linkages Controversy: Some Lessons from the MudaCase’, Journal of Development Studies 25 (4): 571-75.

Hayami, Y and Ruttan, V. (1985) Agricultural Development: An InternationalPerspective. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Hazell, Peter and Ramasamy, C. et al. (1991) The Green Revolution Reconsidered: TheImpact of High-yielding Rice Varieties in South India. Baltimore, MD and London:Johns Hopkins University Press for IFPRI.

Hazell, Peter and Haddad, Lawrence (2000) ‘CGIAR Research and Poverty Reduction’.Draft paper prepared for the Technical Advisory Committee of the CGIAR.Washington, DC: IFPRI, September.

Hazell, Peter, B. R. and Hojjati, Behjat (1994) ‘Farm/Non-farm Linkages in Zambia’,Journal of African Economies 4 (3): 404-35.

Henson, Spencer and Loader, Rupert (2001) ‘Barriers to Agricultural Exports fromDeveloping Countries: The Role of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Requirements’,World Development 29 (1): 85-102.

IFAD (2001) Rural Poverty Report 2001. The Challenge of Ending Rural Poverty.Oxford: Oxford University Press for IFAD.

Jazairy, Idriss, Alamgir, Mohiuddin and Panuccio, Theresa (1992) State of World RuralPoverty. London: Intermediate Technology Publications for IFAD.

Jha, Dayanatha (1974) ‘Agricultural Growth, Technology and Equity’, Indian Journal ofAgricultural Economics 29: 207-16.

Johnson, D. Gale (1997) ‘On the Resurgent Population and Food Debate’, AustralianJournal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 41 (1): 1-17.

Johnston, B. F. and Mellor, J. W. (1961) ‘The Role of Agriculture in EconomicDevelopment’, The American Economic Review 51 (4): 566-93.

Kuznets, S. (1964) ‘Economic Growth and the Contribution of Agriculture’, in C.K.Eicher and L.W. Witt (eds), Agriculture in Economic Development. New York:McGraw-Hill.

Lewis, W.A. (1954) ‘Development with Unlimited Supply of Labour’, Manchester School22:139-91.

Lin, Lin, McKenzie, Victoria, Piesse, Jenifer and Thirtle, Colin (2001) ‘AgriculturalProductivity and Poverty in Developing Countries’. Extensions to DFID Report No.7946.

Lipton, M. (1977) Why Poor People Stay Poor: Urban Bias in World Development.London: Temple Smith.

Lipton, M. (2001) ‘The Changing Face of Rural Poverty, International DevelopmentAssistance and IFAD’s Role: The Issues’, in IFAD.

Lipton, M. and Longhurst, R. (1989) New Seeds and Poor People. London: UnwinHyman.

Page 17: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation 465

Lucas, R. (1988) ‘On the Mechanics of Economic Development’, Journal of MonetaryEconomics 22: 3-42.

Mao, Yu-Kang and Schive, Chi (1995) ‘Agricultural and Industrial Development inTaiwan’, in J.W. Mellor (ed.), Agriculture on the Road to Industrialization.Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Mellor, John W. and Adams Jr, Richard H. (1986) ‘The New Political Economy ofFood and Agricultural Development’, Food Policy 11: 289–97.

Mellor, J.W. and Lele, Uma (1973) ‘Growth Linkages with the New FoodgrainTechnologies’, Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics 28: 35-55.

Mitchell, D.O., Ingco, M.D. and Duncan, R.C. (1997) The World Food Outlook.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Musgrove, Philip (1985). ‘Household Food Consumption in the Dominican Republic:Effects of Income, Price and Family Size’, Economic Development and CulturalChange 34 (June): 83-101.

Otsuka, Keijiro (2000) ‘Role of Agricultural Research in Poverty Reduction: Lessonsfrom the Asian Experience’, Food Policy 25: 447-62.

Otsuka, Keijiro and Reardon, Thomas (1998) ‘Lessons from Rural Industrialization inEast Asia: Are They Applicable to Africa?’ Paper for IFPRI Conference on‘Strategies for Stimulating Growth of the Rural Nonfarm Economy in DevelopingCountries’, Airlie Ho, VA, May.

Pinstrup-Andersen, Per and Hazell, P.B.R. (1985) ‘The Impact of Green Revolution andProspects for the Future’, Food Review International 1 (1).

Pinstrup-Andersen, Per, Pandya-Lorch, Rajul and Rosegrant, Mark W. (1999) WorldFood Prospects: Critical Issues for the Early Twenty-first Century. Food PolicyReport. Washington, DC: IFPRI.

Ranis, G. (1979) ‘Appropriate Technology in the Dual Economy: Reflections onPhilippine and Taiwanese Experience’, in A. Robinson (ed.), AppropriateTechnologies for Third World Development. New York: Macmillan.

Ravallion, M. (1995) ‘Growth and Poverty: Evidence for Developing Countries in the1980s’, Economics Letters 48: 411-7.

Reardon, Thomas (1997) ‘Using Evidence of Household Income Diversification toInform Study of the Rural Nonfarm Labor Market in Africa’, World Development25 (5): 735-47.

Reardon, Thomas, Crawford, Eric and Kelly, Valerie (1994) ‘Links between NonfarmIncome and Farm Investment in African Households: Adding the Capital MarketPerspective’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76: 1172-6.

Reardon, Thomas, Taylor, J. Edward, Stamoulis, Kostas, Lanjouw, Peter and Balisacan,Arsenio (1998) ‘Effects of Nonfarm Employment on Rural Income Inequality inDeveloping Countries: An Investment Perspective’. Paper for the symposium onRural Diversification in the Developing World, Agricultural Economics SocietyAnnual Conference. University of Reading, 25-28 March.

Romer, Paul M. (1986) ‘Increasing Returns and Long-run Growth’, Journal of PoliticalEconomy 94 (5): 1002-37.

Ruttan, V. (2000). Technology, Growth and Development – An Induced InnovationPerspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Schiff, Maurice and Valdés, Alberto (1992) The Plundering of Agriculture inDeveloping Countries. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Page 18: Agricultural Productivity Growth and Poverty Alleviation

466 Xavier Irz, Lin Lin, Colin Thirtle and Steve Wiggins

Schuh, Edward G. (2000) ‘The Household: The Neglected Link in Research andPrograms for Poverty Alleviation’, Food Policy 25: 233-41.

Schultz, T.W. (1964) Transforming Traditional Agriculture. New Haven, CT: YaleUniversity Press.

Scobie, Grant M. and Rafael, Posada T. (1978) ‘The Impact of Technical Change onIncome Distribution: The Case of Rice in Colombia’, American Journal ofAgricultural Economics 60 (1): 85-92.

Stewart, F. (1978) Technology and Underdevelopment. London: Macmillan.Thakur, S. C. P., Mishra, R. R. and Choudhury, J. N. (1997) ‘Migration of Agricultural

Labourers in Bihar in the Perspective of Underdeveloped and DevelopedAgriculture’, Economic Affairs 42 (1): 28-37.

Thirtle, Colin, Irz, Xavier, Lin, Lin, McKenzie-Hill, Victoria and Wiggins, Steve (2001)‘Relationship between Changes in Agricultural Productivity and the Incidence ofPoverty in Developing Countries’. Report to DFID Natural Resources PolicyResearch Programme, Project R7946.

Thorbecke, E. and Jung, H. S. (1996) ‘A Multiplier Decomposition Method to AnalysePoverty Alleviation’, Journal of Development Economics 48 (2): 279-300.

Timmer, C. Peter (1995) ‘Getting Agriculture Moving: Do Markets Provide the RightSignals?’, Food Policy 20 (5): 455-72.

Timmer, C. P. (1997) How Well Do the Poor Connect to the Growth Process? CAER IIDiscussion Paper No.17. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Institute for InternationalDevelopment.

Ventura, Jaume (1997) ‘Growth and Interdependence’, Quarterly Journal of EconomicsCXII (1): 57-84.

White, H. and Anderson, E (2001) ‘Growth versus Distribution: Does the Pattern ofGrowth Matter?’, Development Policy Review 19 (3): 267-89.

Wodon, Q. (1999) Growth, Poverty and Inequality: A Regional Panel for Bangladesh.Policy Research Working Paper 2072. Washington, DC: World Bank.

World Bank (2000) World Development Report 2000/01: Attacking Poverty. New York:Oxford University Press for World Bank.