Top Banner
1 Yoram Barzel June 2012 he exchange of variable-quality commodities mmodity variability is the root of all evil
44

1 Yoram Barzel June 2012. Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

Dec 16, 2015

Download

Documents

Emma Harper
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

1

Yoram Barzel

June 2012

The exchange of variable-quality commodities

Commodity variability is the root of all evil

Page 2: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

2

Introduction

The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of many commodities is far from uniform. Moreover, buyers are seldom uniform either sellers’ perspective.

Two questions arise: 1. How to incorporate the non-uniformity in the analysis? Indeed,

what does “price” mean in this context?

2. What are the consequences of the non-uniformity?

Page 3: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

3

It might appear that to incorporate the non-uniformity in the D-S model we can simply add a quality dimension to it. But quality is multi-dimensional.The heart of the problem is the positive cost of information about non-uniform commodity specimens. This cost prevents the clear delineation of rights. The competition to capture these rights is dissipating.

Introduction, cont.

Page 4: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

4

Introduction, cont.

• A number of major organizational forms have been adopted to reduce these costs. These include guarantees, restrictions on buyers’ opportunities to pick and choose, securitizing and employment for wages.

• The rationale for the employment for wages underlies the theory of the firm.

Page 5: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

5

Introduction, cont.

• I have been thinking and writing about variability for a long time, especially in Barzel (1982).

• Akerlof (1970) is the first to introduce the variability problem.

• I proceed by first discussing the underlying problem. The rest of the time is given to two distinct issues. One is analyzing how equilibrium is attained in the face of buyers who pick and choose. The other regards arrangements to reduce the effects of variability.

Page 6: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

6

The role of information cost

• In the purely competitive Walrasian world information cost is zero and commodities are uniform and of known quality. There are no disputes as to what is being exchanged, or at what terms.

• When information is not free, resources are required to produce it.

• We expect information to be produced by whoever has comparative advantage in doing so. The possessors of the information, which is necessarily asymmetric, might exploit it at others’ expense.

Page 7: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

7

The role of information cost, cont.

• Two questions arise:

1. How is the information actually produced?

2. What are the consequences of it being asymmetric?

Akerlof (1970) pioneered the analysis of asymmetric information. His assumptions that sellers possess information about their commodities that buyers do not have preempts the analysis of the first and limits the range of its consequences. I attempt to answer the two questions.

Page 8: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

8

The role of information cost, cont.

• Sellers may realize the value of their non-uniform commodities by selling every specimen at a price commensurate with its quality. But for most commodities this is too costly.

• Making commodities more uniform alleviates the problem, but is costly too, so variability usually remains.

Page 9: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

9

Who chooses?

• Sellers may retain the right to select specimens for buyers, or let buyers pick and choose. To effect the former requires buyers to trust them.

• Sellers sometimes effect the selection.• In most cases, however, sellers allow buyers to pick and

choose, but prior to that they can sort their commodities or make other arrangements.

Page 10: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

10

Sorting

• Sorters who have comparative advantage in the activity, must decide how many attributes to sort by, and which attributes to leave unsorted.

• I assume that sorting takes place at a central location where commodities are sorted into “grades” to meet the specifications of customers such as supermarkets.

• Customers seek sorting levels such as to equate their sorting costs to the increase in net revenues that the better sorting generates.

Page 11: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

11

Sorting, cont.

• Buyers’ measurement skill is lower than sorters’; otherwise they would have performed the sorting in the first place. Moreover, sorters effect sorting when and where it is most advantageous.

• In spite of their higher sorting cost, buyers may still sort primarily because sorting is designated for the general buyer but not for particular ones.

Page 12: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

12

Sorting, cont.

• Buyers with taste for particular attributes not sorted by will find it worthwhile to pick and choose.

• Buyers make (implicit) measurements when choosing. Others duplicate the measurements of the specimens “rejected” by previous buyers.

Page 13: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

13

Pick and choose

• Under pick and choose sellers cannot capture the

difference between the price they charge and the value of specimens buyers select.

• To buyers the quality differential is a free attribute; they select only units valued more than the price and continue to choose until their marginal gain from the positively valued quality is zero.

Page 14: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

14

Pick and choose, cont.

• What buyers gain is not a pure transfer to them. As with catching fish in the ocean, part of it is dissipated because they compete with each other for the better units by rushing or waiting in line.

• I define dissipation as the difference between actual outcomes and the (unattainable) Pareto outcomes.

Page 15: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

15

The selection process

• The model. • I construct a pick and choose model for a commodity and

illustrate it using numerical values. • Suppose the quality of a commodity is uniformly

distributed with support $90-110. • The seller initially charges a price p1.

Page 16: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

16

p

commodity value0 90 110100

0.10

Chart 1

P

P1

P2

Page 17: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

17

The selection process, Cont.

Buyers proceed in four steps. • 1. Given their demand (specified in constant quality

units ), the price charged, and their rough estimate of the offering, until thy find one where thy wish to shop.

• 2. At a cost of $1 they estimate the distribution of quality. • 3. Each randomly picks units one at a time and spends $1

for inspecting each of them. • 4. Each buys when the first unit in his sample whose

value exceeds the amount he is willing to pay.

Page 18: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

18

The selection process, Cont.

• Whereas a buyer would pay, say, no more that $98 for a

unit of average quality of the commodity selling at $100, he will nevertheless choose to shop at this particular seller because the chance of getting a unit worth sufficiently more than average is high enough.

• Individuals who demand n units will simply repeat the selection process n times.

Page 19: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

19

The selection process, Cont.

• The composition of the seller’s offering deteriorates with each purchase since the units purchased come form the upper end of the distribution. As a result

• 1. Fewer individuals will proceed with the inspection process. • 2. The net gain of those who choose to buy declines, and • eventually nobody would be willing to buy from that seller’s

collection.

Page 20: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

20

The selection process, Cont.

• To simplify what comes I assume that the units selected are always the best available.

• As support of the distribution shifts up (down), price will increase (fall) but buyers’ decision will follow the same pattern.

• As the support widens, picking and choosing becomes more attractive.

• As it narrows, eventually it will cease to generate net gains to buyers. Buyers will treat all the units as equal and refrain from picking and choosing. Their net price will fall, and dissipation form that activity will become zero.

Page 21: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

21

The selection process, Cont.

• Buyers differ in their cost of selection, say due to different time costs. The main effect of this factor is that the low-cost buyers deprive high-cost ones from the best units. Some of the latter even may decide not to visit sellers serving diverse buyers.

• Similarly, low time-cost patrons take the best seats in a single price movie theaters, making the events less attractive to high time cost ones.

• Sellers may counter by offering time saving services such as shorter lines at the cashiers, and raise prices correspondingly. Such sellers become less attractive to low time cost individuals.

• The practice, then, results in separating equilibria.

Page 22: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

22

The selection process, Cont.

• I now turn to sellers’ behavior. As is obvious, a seller must lower his price when buyers no longer find his commodity worth buying.

• As the seller’s act of price change is costly, he will change his price in price changes in discrete steps.

• Each step reflects different quality range, and each entails some picking and choosing.

• Sellers whose high quality merchandise is depleted put the remaining items on “sale” or sell what remains to “outlets” or to others catering to individuals more willing to buy the low quality units.

Page 23: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

23

• Dissipation and vertical relations. In the numerical example for simplicity I focus on buyers who are quality-variability neutral. The value of the variable component of the seller’s offering is, on average, $10 per unit. Of the $10, the seller retains about $3, buyers capture about $2 and $5, which is about one half of the value of the variable component of the commodity, is dissipated. The dissipation consists of the seller’s cost of changing price of about $1, of buyers’ selection cost of about $2, and of $2 in buyers’ competition with each other.

• The numerical results give an idea of what one might expect in reality, and why the parties are eager to reduce the effects of variability.

Page 24: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

24

Dissipation and vertical relations, cont.

• A loss of $5 out of $100 may not appear large. But first these costs are over and above the cost of sorting and the cost of other preventive arrangements. More importantly, they are incurred at every one of the vertical stages where the upstream input suppliers and their downstream recipients carry out a market exchange.

• For instance, had the Smithian upstream pin producers sold their output to the downstream producers, the dissipation would have occurred between each pair of the 18 successive, and seemingly independent stages of the pin production.

Page 25: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

25

Methods of coping with variety

•I now turn to methods of coping with variebilty. Besides more

thorough sorting or separating buyers, sellers may indirectly reduce

the impact of commodity variability or altogether finesse it in a

number of ways.

Page 26: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

26

1. Guaranteeing output

• Guarantees, from buyers’ perspective, make commodities

essentially uniform. They dispenses with picking and choosing as

buyers are entitled to one good unit. To buyers guarantees

transform the variable commodity into a fixed one.

• By guaranteeing, sellers retain ownership over commodities’

variable components. They will lose when providing low quality as

they face a high level of guarantee claims and they are induced to

produce the optimal quality mix.

• Akerlof (1970) was the first to point out the use of guarantees to

avoid lemons. See also Barzel (1982).

Page 27: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

27

2. Restricting buyers’ opportunity to pick and choose.

• 2a. Bundling.

Bundling sits half way between sellers’ selection and

buyers’ picking and choosing. I hypothesize that bundling

serves to discourage buyers from picking and choosing.

But then buyers must trust sellers not to load the bundles

with low quality specimens.

An implications of the bundling hypothesis is that in areas

with significant wage dispersion, and thus wide dispersion

in the cost of picking and choosing, the fraction of bundled

commodities is larger than in areas with more uniform

incomes.

Page 28: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

28

2. Restricting buyers’ opportunity to pick and choose.cont.

• 2b. Restricting buyers. Barzel, Habib and Johnsen (2006) show that the

attempt to dissuade speculators from picking and choosing explains many of

the restrictions associated with IPO’s such as the number of shares one may

buy.

Two other cases where sellers restrict buyers’ ability to pick and choose are:

•First in some wholesale used cars auctions.

•Second is De Beers sightings where buyers’ picking and choosing is

severely restricted. In Barzel 1977 (preceding Kenny and Klein) I argue that

the purpose of the practice is to prevent dealers from picking and choosing.

Page 29: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

29

3. Sorting individuals into homogeneous groups to finance commodity purchases

• The variability of the individuals engaged in

exchange is another source of exchange problems.

Consider financing assets posted as collateral.

Securitizing the loans reduces the financing cost, but

variability in borrowers’ default rate facilitates adverse

selection. Lenders impose restrictions both in terms of

the assets and of the borrowers such that borrowers

become largely uniform, needing only modest scrutiny.

Page 30: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

30

3. Sorting individuals into homogeneous groups to finance commodity purchases cont.

• Consider new car buyers. New cars become less uniform as they age. The down

payment and a repayment schedule lenders require as well as minimal borrowers’

income-level requirement makes the latter’s default rate more uniform, reducing the

need to thoroughly scrutinize them. The standardized lenders’ assets is what

accommodates the securitization of the loans.

• Borrowers become the owners of the cars’ variable component, giving them a

strong incentive to protect the equity in their cars and avoid default.

• To prevent lenders from using excessively lax selection criteria, we expect

securitizers to require lenders to hold the “toxic” tranches of the loans they initiate.

• Similarly, securitizers are expected to require the mortgages’ originators to hold the

equity, i. e., the most junior, (“toxic”) tranche.

Page 31: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

31

4. Wage contracting and its rationale for the firm.

•The wage contract radically alters the form of exchange as it

altogether eschews the commodity exchange problem. Two major

reasons for exchanging labor services for wages are: 1. Bypassing the need to measure workers’ product. 2. Have workers cooperate with capitalists who guaranteeing their

output in exchange for employing and controlling them.

These reasons for the use of wage-labor contribute to the theory of the

firm.

Page 32: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

32

1. Bypassing the need to measure workers’ products.

•Owners of labor services may operate as independent contractors producing

and selling their output in the market, or sell their services for wages. In the

latter case upstream wageworkers transfer their output to downstream ones.

Employing workers for wages serves as a substitute for exchanging

commodities in the market.

Page 33: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

33

Employment for wages, including employment in vertically integrated firms,

requires less measurement of the commodities being transferred than where

workers sell their output in the market. Within firms employers instruct employees

what and how to produce and to whom to transfer their output, reducing

employees’ gain from picking and choosing, thus reducing the need to measure

the commodities (Barzel, 1982). The employment for wages, then, finesses the

problem of exchanging non-uniform commodities in the market.

Wage-employees’, however, have to be induced to produce, and this

requires costly supervision. Alchian and Demsetz (1972) explicitly point to

entrepreneurs’ need to employ workers for wages and supervise their effort when

measuring workers’ output is (prohibitively) expensive.

These considerations apply to every vertical production stage except when

commodities are sold to final consumers

Page 34: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

34

2. Guaranteeing output

• The expected value of workers’ output may be positive yet in some cases the specimens they produce or their activities may have a large negative value (exploding products; damaging fellow workers). Buyers or fellow workers require guarantees to protect themselves from abuse. But when losses are large, workers are unlikely to possess the means to cover them.

• Capitalists may provide the guarantees accompanied with the wage contract along with the supervision that goes with it.

• Thus solutions to the problem that product variability create lead to the wage contract.

Page 35: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

35

3. The firm.

• Employer-employee relationships are conducted within firms.

The explanations given here for these relationships contribute

two major ingredients to the theory of the firm. One

contribution regards the scope of vertically integrated firms

that emerge in response to measuring variable-quality

products (Barzel,1982). Alchian and Demsetz (1972) is a

special case here,

• The other contribution regards firms guaranteeing workers’

output; a force that is enhanced by scale economies to

assembling guaranteeing capital. This force may lead to large,

integrated firms with clear boundaries (Barzel 1997).

Page 36: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

36

5. Exchanging services

•Like commodities, services may be

exchanged directly under explicit or implicit

guarantee or via the wage contract. Whereas

some services are sold by output, selling others

indirectly via the wage-employment is a

substitute for the more costly exchange by

output.

Page 37: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

37

5a. Services produced by wage workers.

•There must always be some connection between

input and output. But then service-workers’ output is

measurable, even if imperfectly. One may rather

conclude then that services differ from commodities

in that their output is more costly to measure directly

than that of commodities so they are often measured

indirectly via the input intensity. (Services can’t be

returned.)

Page 38: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

38

5b. Guaranteed services.

• Some services are readily measurable and given the variability in their output, they are often guaranteed. One such services is advice.

• One type of advice is how to minimize the net losses from fire, this service has measurable financial effects. Advice seekers are obviously ignorant of the quality of the advice they seek. The exchange of advice implies asymmetric information, and the advisor could overcharge for the quality he or she provides. To reduce that we expect the advisor to become the residual claimant to the effect of the advice, which . implies here guaranteeing it (Barzel 1997).

Page 39: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

39

Guaranteeing advice cont.

•Here too guarantors means may be insufficient for

guaranteeing. The advisers may abet clients’ fear of not

receiving the benefits they are entitled to by joining fire

insurance firms that back the advice of these specialized

employees.

Page 40: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

40

Summary

• This paper explores the effects of commodity (and service) quality-variability. The costliness of measuring commodities results in not well-delineated rights, and dissipation occurs in the competition for them.

• Pricing each of the specimens and selling them individually is too expensive for most commodities

• Sellers then must sell most of their commodities at uniform prices. They may select specimens for their buyers, but the cost of creating the trust needed for that purpose is usually too high.

• So sellers usually let buyers pick and choose from uniformly priced but non-uniform commodities.

• Sellers, however, first sort commodities and adopt arrangements to reduce their losses from buyers’ picking and choosing.

• How the market equilibrates in the face of picking and choosing is analyzed, and Chart 2 summarizes the results.

Page 41: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

41

• In Chart 2 D1 is the conventional demand curve and D2 is the demand curve net of buyers cost of picking and choosing and of competing with each other. S1 is the conventional supply curve and S2 reflects the added costs of sorting and changing prices. The actual market quantity is Q2 and Price is P2.

• While not shown, it is easy to see the associated dissipation consisting of the triangle between Q1 and Q2 and the areas between the two pairs of curves to quantity Q2.

Page 42: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

42

Chart 2

Quantity

Pri

ce

--------------------------------------------

S

1

1

D2

2

1Q 2

P1

P2

D

S

Q

Page 43: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

43

• Several methods are used to lower the cost of dealing with variability, each presumably chosen when it reduces the dissipation more than any of the others.

Of these methods one is making borrowers more uniform from sellers’ perspective, thus reducing lenders’ cost of selecting them when their loans are securitized, and one is measuring wage employees’ effort which is a substitute for measuring goods and services. Organizing the exchange via the use of the wage contracts means that workers are placed in firms.

The factors that explain the use of wage-workers also explain vertical as well as horizontal integration, and thus contribute to the theory of the firm.

Page 44: 1 Yoram Barzel June 2012.  Introduction The assumption that commodity quality is uniform is entrenched in economics. But in real life the quality of.

44

Thank you!