Top Banner
What works” What works” among active labour market policies among active labour market policies David Grubb David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD Social Affairs, OECD February 2007 February 2007
23

What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

Mar 27, 2015

Download

Documents

Eric Oneal
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

““What works” What works” among active labour market policies among active labour market policies

David GrubbDavid Grubb

Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD OECD

February 2007February 2007

Page 2: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

2

OutlineOutline Benefits without active measures increase unemployment,

especially if replacement rates are high. Effective active measures reduce unemployment. Both types of impact can be large.

Classic active measures include labour market information and ALMPs (training, job creation and hiring subsidies).

“Activation” measures include:

(Traditional) direct referral/placement into job vacancies

Other PES “interventions in the unemployment spell”

Compulsory participation in ALMPs (“workfare/trainingfare”)

Focus on the limits encountered by high-benefit countries

A few slides consider employment rate outcomes

Page 3: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

3

The impact of benefitsThe impact of benefits

Simple hazard rate graphs show that limits on UI duration considerably affect behaviour (Chart).

When UI duration is 14 months the hazard rate increases throughout months 10-16 search frictions are significant. But employable people can usually find work within 6 months.

Similar “spikes” are found in studies from other countries.

Page 4: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

4

Monthly rate of entry to employment when the Monthly rate of entry to employment when the duration of UI benefit was 14 months, Franceduration of UI benefit was 14 months, France

Source: Dormont et al, as cited by OECD Employment Outlook 2005

For four levels of earnings prior to unemployment

Page 5: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

5

The impact of benefits (2)The impact of benefits (2)

Better-quality studies of the impact of replacement rates suggest a fairly large elasticity of job entry rates rates with respect to replacement rates, e.g. -0.7. But such a number is only part of the story:

Benefits influence rates of entry to unemployment, as well as rates of exit

Studies estimate short-run impacts, holding institutions and social attitudes to unemployment near-constant

Caseload growth for new (i.e. much more generous) assistance benefits has typically continued for 15 to 20 years (e.g. see OECD, 2003). The long-run impact is often around 3 times the short-run impact, as judged by caseloads after 20 years vs. the first few years.

Page 6: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

6

History of UI systems and active History of UI systems and active measuresmeasures

Finland (1971), Luxembourg (1976), Sweden (1974) and Switzerland (1976) introduced their current (much more generous) unemployment insurance (UI) benefits “late”. They suffered sharp increases in unemployment “late, in the 1990s i.e. again caseload growth took about 20 years. (Chart).

Finland and Sweden spent heavily on active labour market programmes (ALMPs) before the 1990s, but in itself that didn’t help.

The modern activation strategies were often adopted when other measures had been tried but unemployment was high or still rising.

Page 7: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

7

Unemployment in four countries which introduced Unemployment in four countries which introduced generous unemployment benefits after 1970generous unemployment benefits after 1970

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

%

Finland Luxembourg Sw eden Sw itzerland Other w estern Europe*

“other” Western Europe

Finland, Sweden

Switzerland, Luxembourg

Page 8: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

8

The direct impact of ALMPsThe direct impact of ALMPs

Evaluations have identified modest direct impacts (impacts on employment-related outcomes of participants) from ALMPs. Perhaps slightly positive for training programmes, none or even negative for job creation. Impacts tend to be more positive for adult women than for youth or adult men.

Training programmes sometimes do better when outcomes are tracked over a longer period but scope for large-scale implementation of specialised training remains limited

Hiring subsidies are often found effective by evaluations using non-experimental (matching) estimators but other studies continue to show deadweight effects (Boockmann et al., 2007).

Job-search assistance programmes are often found to be relatively effective in relation to their low cost.

Reference: Martin and Grubb (2001).

Page 9: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

9

Indirect effects of ALMPsIndirect effects of ALMPs

ALMPs can have a large impact through their interaction with the benefit system:

“Carousel” effects when ALMPs re-qualify participants for unemployment benefits.

“Motivation” effects when participation in ALMPs is compulsory for long-term benefit recipients.

Some channels of impact are rarely identified statistically:

A general change in expectations that affects most labour market groups and unemployment durations.

Impact on rates of (re)entry to unemployment

Social interaction effects, i.e. impacts on the behaviour of the non-participants in the programme.

Reference: OECD Employment Outlook 2005

Page 10: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

10

Activation through regular interventions in Activation through regular interventions in the unemployment spellthe unemployment spell

In Australia, the UK and the US (Welfare Reform) activation strategies rely on “regular interventions" in the unemployment spell: personal contact with jobseekers

intensive interviews and individual action plans

job-search requirements and monitoring

job-search training

direct referrals to job vacancies

sanctions

These strategies limit benefit caseloads, with only a small proportion of the unemployed being referred to expensive (full-time) programmes.

Page 11: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

11

Activation through participation in labour Activation through participation in labour market programmesmarket programmes

In Denmark, Finland and Sweden activation often involves referral to a full-time ALMP. In Denmark’s “active period” (in the strategy as of about 2000) after a year the unemployed person had to participate in an ALMP 75% of the time.

Germany and the Netherlands also spend heavily on ALMPs.

Page 12: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

12

The limits of activation strategiesThe limits of activation strategies

Australia and the UK have moderate benefit replacement rates (net 50% to 65% over a five-year spell of unemployment) (Chart). They spend about 1% of GDP on LMPs (0.4% of GDP for active programmes).

Austria and Norway have intermediate replacement rates. So far they managed to avoid a major unemployment crisis and keep spending on LMPs at about 2% of GDP.

The seven OECD countries (Denmark, Finland, Germany, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland) with the highest replacement rates (75% or more over a five over a five-year spell of unemployment in 2002, 2004 data) find it relatively difficult and expensive to get good results.

Page 13: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

13

Average of net replacement rates over 60 months of Average of net replacement rates over 60 months of unemployment, including social assistanceunemployment, including social assistance

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

Italy

Unite

d Sta

tes

Gre

ece

Hunga

ry

Korea

Slova

k Rep

.

Canad

a

Austra

liaSpa

in

Czech

Rep

.

Japa

n

Polan

d

New Z

eala

nd

Norway

Unite

d Kin

gdom

Belgiu

m

Franc

eIrl

and

Icela

nd

Portu

gal

Austri

a

Finlan

de

Ger

man

y

Denm

ark

Luxe

mbo

urg

Sweden

Nethe

rland

s

Switzer

land

2004, for four family types and two earnings levels, in percentage

Page 14: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

14

In the high-benefit countriesIn the high-benefit countries High spending on ALMPs (e.g. Sweden, Finland before

1990 and Germany in the 1990s) did not prevent unemployment from rising further, to postwar peak levels.

Total LMP spending is very high in several cases (3.0-4.5% of GDP in Denmark, Finland, Germany and the Netherlands).

A large immigrant-native differential in unemployment and employment rates (Chart) is proving hard to tackle.

Strict “workfare/trainingfare" requirements seem to be needed for the management of social assistance (Kildal, 2000; Thoren, 2005, describes some Swedish schemes).

Experimentation continues, e.g. privatisation of employment services in Denmark, the “Activity Guarantee" in Sweden, and controversial benefit cuts.

Page 15: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

15

Unemployment rates of non-EU Unemployment rates of non-EU immigrants vs. nativesimmigrants vs. natives

AT

BE

CHCZ

DK

EL

ES

FIFR

HU

IE

LU

NL

NO

PT

SE

UK

05

1015

2025

Imm

igra

nts

from

ou

tsid

e E

U15

0 5 10 15 20Natives

PercentOverall unemployment rates 2003

Source: Jean (2006)

Page 16: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

16

Avoiding “programme dependency”Avoiding “programme dependency”

When referral to ALMPs is a key element in an activation strategy, one issue is how to avoid “programme dependency” - when some unemployed people prefer ALMPs (rather than passive benefits) to market work. Employer demand for subsidies should not be allowed to drive

growth in ALMPs.

Subsidised employment positions should pay less than market work.

Potential “programme careers” should be interrupted by short intervals in open unemployment with a focus on job search and renegotiation of the individual action plan, as in Denmark.

Page 17: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

17

Improve PES performanceImprove PES performance

The Public Employment Service (PES) implements “regular interventions”, so this type of activation strategy depends on PES performance.

The PES may tend to limit itself to bureaucratic routines and “intermediation” (matching willing workers with employers).

An ineffective PES may remain so for long periods, since clear evidence of poor performance is absent.

The biggest policy reforms have often involved not only legislation but also PES restructuring - new financing arrangements, new objectives, new management.

Page 18: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

18

Performance managementPerformance management Structure PES operations to:

Measure the performance of different employment offices in terms of entries to employment (of minimum duration, at least 3 months) achieved by their clients.

Compare employment outcomes across employment offices, and reform underperforming operations

A quasi-market or subcontracting approach, where “regular interventions” are implemented by provide providers works well in Australia and arguably also in the UK (Employment Zone providers are benchmarked against outcomes achieved by the PES with comparable client groups).

Performance measurement in the PES has some (perhaps more limited) impact even without subcontracting.

Reference: OECD Employment Outlook 2005

Page 19: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

19

Activation of "non-employment" benefitsActivation of "non-employment" benefits “Non-employment” benefits are those paid without an

availability-for-work condition. Activation may involve:

Specific measures, e.g. employer financial responsibility for their employees’ sickness pay, work rehabilitation measures for medical conditions, child care provision for lone parents…

Abolition (e.g. phasing out an early retirement benefit) or stricter gatekeeping (e.g. for disability benefits). Some potential beneficiaries then claim unemployment benefit instead.

Introduction of an availability-for-work condition (e.g. for lone parents with children above a certain age, partners in a couple receiving a minimum income benefit, some groups in receipt of a disability benefit).

Reference: Carcillo and Grubb (2006)

Page 20: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

20

Low unemployment as a preconditionLow unemployment as a precondition

The PES is effective when most benefit spells are kept shorter than 6 months.

If benefit spells become longer, job-search motivation is difficult to maintain and the potential disincentive effects of high benefits act more strongly.

Success in managing the pre-existing “unemployed” caseload is a precondition for activation of non-employment benefits by adding an availability-for-work condition.

If the PES is overwhelmed by a transfer of new hard-to-place clients, the net effect may be negative.

Page 21: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

21

Employment ratesEmployment rates

Small variations in unemployment rates are associated with larger variations in labour force participation rates (Chart). Policies which keep unemployment low also (a) attract potential workers into the labour force (b) facilitate restrictive management of non-employment benefits.

For certain “outliers” such as Belgium (with a 60% employment rate, far below 72% in Canada which has a similar unemployment rate), non-employment benefits (e.g. early retirement benefits) are a factor.

Evidence about other factors influencing employment rates is relatively uncertain. Two suspects are employment protection (EPL) ( low employment rate) and progressive taxation of individual incomes ( high employment rate).

Page 22: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

22

Employment and unemployment rates, 2000-5Employment and unemployment rates, 2000-5

AUSAUT

BEL

CAN

CZE

DNK

FIN

FRA

DEU

GRCHUN

ISL

IRL

ITA

JPN

KORLUX

MEX

NLDNZL

NOR

PRT

ESP

SWE

CHE

TUR

GBRUSA

45

50

55

60

65

70

75

80

85

90

2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

Unemployment rate, 2000-05 (%)

Em

ploy

men

t rat

e, 2

00-0

5 (%

)

Page 23: What works among active labour market policies David Grubb Directorate for Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, OECD February 2007.

23

ReferencesReferencesBoockmann, B., T. Zwick, A. Ammermüller and M. Maier (2007), “Do Hiring Subsidies Reduce

Unemployment Among the Elderly? Evidence From Two Natural Experiments”, ZEW Discussion Paper no. 07-001

Carcillo, S. and D. Grubb (2006), “From Inactivity to Work: The Role of Active Labour Market Policies”, SEM Working Paper no. 36 (www.oecd.org/els/workingpapers).

Dormont, B., D. Fougère and A. Prieto (2001), “L’effet de l’allocation unique dégressive sur la reprise d’emploi”, Économie et Statistique, No. 343, pp. 3-28

Graversen, B. and J. van Ours (2006), “How to Help Unemployed Find Jobs Quickly: Experimental Evidence from a Mandatory Activation Program”, IZA DP no. 2504.

Kildal, N. (2000), “Workfare Tendencies in Scandinavian Welfare Policies”, ILO.Grubb, D. (2005), “Trends in Unemployment Insurance, Related Benefits and Active Labour

Market Policies in Europe” 10th Anniversary of EI seminar (www.kli.re.kr)Jean, S. (2006), “The Labour Market Integration of Immigrants in OECD Countries”,

(www.oecd.org/document/47/0,2340,en_2649_37415_36721391_1_1_1_37415,00.html).Martin, J. and D. Grubb (2001), “What works and for whom: A review of OECD

countries’experiences with active labour market policies”, Swedish Economic Policy Review 8, pp.9-56.

OECD (2003), “Benefits and Employment, Friend or Foe? Interactions Between Passive and Active Social Programmes”, Employment Outlook, Paris.

OECD (2005), “Labour Market Programmes and Activation Strategies: Evaluating the Impacts” and “Public Employment Services: Managing Performance”, Employment Outlook, Paris

OECD (2006), Employment Outlook: Boosting Jobs and Incomes, Paris.Thoren, K. (2005), “Municipal activation policy: A case study of the practical work with

unemployed social assistance recipients”, IFAU working paper 2005:20.