Top Banner

of 16

Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

Feb 21, 2018

Download

Documents

nataliacn
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    1/16

    Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    Tanika Chakraborty a,b, Bakhrom Mirkasimov c,d, Susan Steiner b,e,

    a Indian Institute of Technology Kanpur, Kanpur, 208016 UP, Indiab IZA Bonn, Schaumburg-Lippe-Strae 5-9, 53113 Bonn, Germanyc Humboldt University of Berlin, Unter den Linden 6, 10099 Berlin, Germanyd Westminster International University in Tashkent (WIUT), 12 Istiqbol street, 100047 Tashkent, Uzbekistane Leibniz Universitt Hannover, Knigsworther Platz 1, 30167 Hannover, Germany

    a r t i c l e i n f o

    Article history:

    Received 12 September 2013

    Revised 8 September 2014

    Available online 22 September 2014

    JEL classification:

    F22

    I30

    O12

    Keywords:

    Private transfers

    Cash and labor exchange

    MigrationKyrgyzstan

    a b s t r a c t

    Chakraborty, Tanika, Mirkasimov, Bakhrom, and Steiner, SusanTransfer behavior in

    migrant sending communities

    We study how international migration changes the private transfers made between house-

    holds in the migrant sending communities of developing countries. A priori, it is indeter-

    minate whether migration and remittances strengthen or weaken the degree of private

    transfers in these communities. From a policy perspective, public income redistribution

    programs would have an important role to play if migration reduced the extent of private

    transfers. Using household survey data from rural Kyrgyzstan, we find that households

    with migrant members (as well as households receiving remittances) are more likely than

    households without migrants (without remittances) to provide monetary transfers to oth-

    ers and to receive non-monetary (i.e. unpaid labor) transfers from others. This suggests

    that migrant households, through their access to remittance income, insure their social

    networks against shocks or redistribute income to poorer households in the community

    and receive labor transfers in return. This implies that migration is unlikely to lead to a

    weakening of private transfers. Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (3) (2015) 690705.

    Indian Institute of Technology Kanpur, Kanpur, 208016 UP, India; IZA Bonn, Schaum-

    burg-Lippe-Strae 5-9, 53113 Bonn, Germany; Humboldt University of Berlin, Unter den

    Linden 6, 10099 Berlin, Germany; Westminster International University in Tashkent

    (WIUT), 12 Istiqbol street, 100047 Tashkent, Uzbekistan; Leibniz Universitt Hannover,

    Knigsworther Platz 1, 30167 Hannover, Germany.

    2014 Association for Comparative Economic Studies. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights

    reserved.

    1. Introduction

    Rural households in developing countries employ a wide range of strategies to deal with the harsh living conditions that

    many of them face. Two of these strategies are migration to economically more advantaged places and exchanging informal

    private transfers with the households in their social networks.1 In this paper, we study the implications of international migra-

    tion for private transfer behavior in the migrant sending communities.

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2014.09.004

    0147-5967/ 2014 Association for Comparative Economic Studies. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

    Corresponding author at: Institute for Development and Agricultural Economics, Leibniz Universitt Hannover, Knigsworther Platz 1, 30167 Hannover,

    Germany. Fax: +49 511 762 2667.

    E-mail addresses: [email protected](T. Chakraborty), [email protected](B. Mirkasimov), [email protected](S. Steiner).1 Private transfers function like means-tested income redistribution flowing from better off to worse off households. They also act like risk-sharing

    mechanisms with income flowing to households that experienced income shocks (Cox and Fafchamps, 2008).

    Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705

    Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

    Journal of Comparative Economics

    j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a te / j c e

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2014.09.004mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2014.09.004http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/01475967http://www.elsevier.com/locate/jcehttp://www.elsevier.com/locate/jcehttp://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/01475967http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2014.09.004mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2014.09.004http://-/?-http://-/?-http://crossmark.crossref.org/dialog/?doi=10.1016/j.jce.2014.09.004&domain=pdf
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    2/16

    Sending a household member abroad is likely to decrease the households income variability because income is obtained

    from various sources. This makes the household less dependent on transfers from other households within the community

    (Morten, 2013). If, therefore, migration reduced the extent of private transfers provided within migrant sending communi-

    ties, this could have serious consequences for those households without migrants abroad. Policy makers should be aware

    that private transfers may have to be substituted by public transfers. On the contrary, households that receive remittances

    from migrants might transfer more money to other households in the community in order to insure them (Morten, 2013). If,

    then, migration increased the extent of private transfers made, this would mean that migration increased the welfare not

    only of migrant households but also of non-migrant households.2 The design of migration policies should take this potential

    effect into account.

    Despite the vast literature on migration on the one hand and private transfers on the other, only few study the connection

    between these two aspects.Gallego and Mendola (2013)explore whether migration affects households interactions within

    their social networks in Mozambique. They find that households receiving remittances participate more in groups, such as

    rotating savings and credit associations or women and youth groups, and in informal exchanges of goods and services with

    others in their community. The authors argue that remittances decrease participation costs in groups and increase commit-

    ment in informal mutual arrangements.Morten (2013)develops a dynamic model of risk-sharing with endogenous migra-

    tion. The model acknowledges that both risk-sharing transfers and migration are mechanisms for households to informally

    insure against shocks. Using data from rural India, the author finds that risk-sharing reduces migration but migration also

    reduces risk-sharing.

    In this paper, we investigate whether international migration weakens or strengthens the extent of private transfers

    made within migrant sending communities. Specifically, we compare the transfer behavior of households that have migrants

    abroad with that of households that do not have migrants abroad. Our focus is not only on risk-sharing transfers or, in other

    words, on transfers made in response to shocks as in Morten (2013). The transfers that we observe in our data are transfers

    made either in times of shocks or otherwise. The main contribution that we make to the literature is that, in contrast to the

    earlier studies, we distinguish between monetary and non-monetary (i.e. unpaid labor) private transfers. Gallego and

    Mendola (2013)summarize any transfers made in the form of money, gifts and services, while Morten (2013)only takes

    monetary transfers into account. We argue that a distinction between monetary and non-monetary transfers is, however,

    important to allow for the possibility that migrant and non-migrant households provide different forms of help to others.

    For example, it is possible that some households (potentially those that receive remittances) provide monetary transfers

    and other households (potentially those that do not have migrants abroad) return non-monetary help. Such behavior could

    not be identified by either ignoring non-monetary transfers or pooling monetary and non-monetary transfers together. 3

    The empirical analysis in this paper is focused on Kyrgyzstan, a low-income country located in Central Asia. A large num-

    ber of people from Kyrgyzstan move to Russia and Kazakhstan, mainly in search of better income-earning opportunities. Esti-

    mates range from 200,000 to more than one million migrants (Schmidt and Sagynbekova, 2008; Ablezova et al., 2009;

    Lukashova and Makenbaeva, 2009). For 2013, it is estimated that migrants sent US$ 2.3 billion as remittances back home,

    which translates into 31% of Kyrgyzstans GDP (World Bank, 2013). This makes the country number two worldwide in terms

    of remittances receipt. It is unclear how such massive outmigration changes the system of private transfers and mutual help

    that is common in Kyrgyzstan. Informal social networks based on kinship, friendship and neighborhood played a large role

    for obtaining access to information and goods in pre-Soviet times as well as during the Soviet period, and they are still

    important today in Kyrgyzstan (Coudouel et al., 1997; Kuehnast and Dudwick, 2002). Anecdotal evidence from Howell

    (1996) suggests that borrowing food and money from relatives and neighbors in times of economic stress is a common prac-

    tice in southern Kyrgyzstan, the part of the country with the currently largest migration rate.

    Empirical identification of the effect of migration on transfer behavior within migrant sending communities can be con-

    founded by simultaneity and unobserved heterogeneity. Simultaneity can be a problem if communities with more private

    transfers among households experience more or less out-migration. Unobserved heterogeneity is a serious concern because

    differences between migrant and non-migrant households might influence both migration and private transfer decisions

    (McKenzie et al., 2010). To address simultaneity concerns, we use longitudinal data from the Life in Kyrgyzstan (LIK) house-

    hold survey and run a lagged regression model. To address unobserved heterogeneity, we match migrant and non-migrant

    households on a wide range of variables using propensity score matching methods.

    Our findings show that migrant households are more likely than non-migrant households to provide monetary transfers

    to others. Furthermore, we find that migrant households are more likely than non-migrant households to receive labor assis-

    tance from others. We do not directly observe to whom these transfers are made and from whom they are received in our

    data. However, we provide suggestive evidence that migrant households, through their access to remittance income, insure

    their social networks against shocks or redistribute income to poorer households in the community and receive labor

    2 Ratha et al. (2011)provide an excellent review of the literature on the welfare implications of migration.3 In a lab experiment,Charness and Genicot (2009)find evidence of lower transfers in groups with higher ex ante within-group inequality. The experiment is

    restricted to the possibility of monetary transfers alone. It could be that if group members were allowed to reciprocate the monetary transfers made by richer

    group members with non-monetary transfers, transfers would increase with higher inequality.

    T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705 691

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    3/16

    transfers in return.4 If so, our findings indicate that differentiating between monetary and labor transfers is important to draw

    correct inferences about the reciprocity of transfers.

    The rest of this paper is organized as follows. We discuss alternative mechanisms for the relationship between migration

    and households transfer behavior in the next section. We provide background information on migration from Kyrgyzstan in

    Section 3. Section 4 discusses our empirical strategy, and Section 5 introduces the LIK data. Section 6 presents the estimation

    results. We here also conduct a number of robustness checks and elaborate on the reciprocity of transfers. We conclude the

    paper by summarizing our findings in Section7.

    2. Analytical framework

    We provide an overview of the mechanisms through which migration may influence household transfer behavior. We dis-

    tinguish between the effect of migration and the effect of remittances since having a migrant abroad does not necessarily

    have the same consequences for household welfare as receiving remittances. Furthermore, households that have migrants

    abroad do not always receive remittances, and households that receive remittances do not always receive them from close

    family members but possibly from extended family members or non-relatives.

    Migration may strengthen the extent of monetary transfers in migrant sending communities if there is a co-insurance

    scheme between the migrant and the household left behind (Stark and Lucas, 1988) and if other community members pro-

    vide part of the insurance that flows to the migrant (mechanism 1). Migration may weaken the extent of monetary transfers,

    however, because a high rate of migration at the community level decreases commitment in mutual transfer arrangements.

    Migration of community members decreases the credibility of future reciprocity, and reciprocity is necessary to sustain non-

    enforceable transfer arrangements (Ligon et al., 2002).5 Households may choose not to provide monetary transfers to others,

    who they think are likely to migrate because reciprocity would then be less possible in the future. Households may also reduce

    transfers to those with current migrants, if they think that the members left behind are less likely to reciprocate ( mechanism 2).

    The same logic applies to non-monetary transfers; households may not provide labor to other households within their commu-

    nity if these already have migrants abroad or are expected to send household members abroad in the future ( mechanism 3). Yet,

    it is also reasonable to expect more labor transfers to households that have migrants abroad because usually young male adults

    migrate while the elderly, women, and children are left behind (mechanism 4). For example, grandparents who stay with their

    grandchildren are likely to use more outside labor to help with house repairs or accompany grandchildren to school when their

    adult children are absent.

    We turn to remittances. Remittances may increase the extent of monetary transfers because they provide access to

    income that is uncorrelated with income generated within the community. Remittance-receiving households may thus be

    better able to provide transfers to their networks and insure them against aggregate shocks (Morten, 2013) (mechanism 5).6 This

    argument builds onFoster and Rosenzweig (2001)who study the effect of different degrees of altruism and income variance

    between transfer partners on the size of transfers, using panel data from rural South Asia. They show that risk-sharing is

    achieved with a high degree of altruism and a low level of income correlation between transfer partners. Some risk-sharing even

    takes place in the absence of altruism. Alternatively, remittances may be positively related to monetary transfers because they

    may provide more stable income to the remittance-receiving household making it a low risk member in risk-sharing

    arrangements (Gallego and Mendola, 2013) (mechanism 6). If private transfers are made to redistribute income, rather than

    to share risk, more monetary transfers may be expected if the better off partner in the income redistribution network is the

    one who receives the remittances (mechanism 7). In contrast, households may reduce their monetary transfers for income

    redistribution if the remittance receiver is the previously worse off partner in the network ( mechanism 8).

    Remittances may decrease monetary transfers in the migrant sending community because they make the outside option

    of autarky more attractive for remittance-receiving households; risk-sharing is likely to fall whenever the value of autarky

    increases relative to the value of being in the contract (Albarran and Attanasio, 2003). Remittance-receiving households can

    use remittances to insure against shocks and do not need to engage in mutual transfer arrangements within the community

    (Morten, 2013) (mechanism 9). Remittances may allow receiving households to exchange money for labor (Schechter and

    Yuskavage, 2011). Specifically, households that receive remittances may transfer money to other households and receive

    labor in times of need. This seems particularly likely when the adult members of the household migrate ( mechanism 10).

    In sum, migration can have a positive or negative impact on household private transfers, and the relationship between

    remittances and private transfers is equally indeterminate. While we cannot clearly identify the mechanisms of how migra-

    tion and remittances affect transfers in our empirical analysis, given the nature of our data, we interpret our findings in light

    of these theoretical considerations.

    4 An alternative explanation is that the migrant households are better able to purchase labor services. However, the wording of the questions in our survey

    questionnaire clearly indicates that we were asking only for unpaid labor transfers.5 Ligon et al. (2002)assume that informal insurance arrangements are sustained by means of penalties for breach of contract. These penalties include peer

    group pressure or being brought before a village council with the threat of future exclusion from insurance at the community level.6 Remittances respond to income shocks of the receiving household and so have an insurance motive ( Lucas and Stark, 1985; Rosenzweig, 1988; Fafchamps

    and Lund, 2003; Yang and Choi, 2007).Giesbert et al. (2011)show that households, which receive remittances, are less likely to have formal insurance which

    also speaks for an insurance function of remittances. Du et al. (2011)find that remittances may even play a role in promoting interprovincial risk sharing. Whathas not been studied much is whether remittances sent for insurance are shared with the social network.

    692 T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    4/16

    3. Background: migration in Kyrgyzstan

    Kyrgyzstan is one of the poorest former Soviet Union republics. It is small (with a population of 5.6 million), mountainous,

    and landlocked. Sixty-five percent of the population live in rural areas. In contrast to neighboring Kazakhstan and Uzbeki-

    stan, Kyrgyzstan is not endowed with major stocks of natural resources (except for gold). According to the World Bank, 82%

    of the male population aged 1564 participated in the labor force in 2012, but only 59% of the female population. Among

    those employed, 34% worked in agriculture, 21% in industry, and 45% in services. The transition from a planned to a market

    economy, including the elimination of guaranteed employment, free education and health care, and special support servicesfor pensioners and mothers, has hit Kyrgyzstan very hard (Isabaeva, 2011). It has still not fully recovered to its pre-indepen-

    dent level of output. In 2012, 38% of the population lived below the national poverty line, up from 32% in 2009. 7

    Against this background, it is not surprising that many people migrate to more advantaged places in search of jobs and

    better living conditions. People move both domestically, from rural to urban areas, as well as internationally, typically to

    Russia and Kazakhstan. The exact number of migrants is difficult to determine, as domestic migrants tend to not register

    at their new place of residence and international migrants are often illegally in the destination country. However,

    Isabaeva (2011)claims that international migration has overtaken domestic migration numerically in recent years. Migra-

    tion is often temporary; ranging from a few months to several years, according to a survey among households in three com-

    munities in the Jalalabad region (Schmidt and Sagynbekova, 2008). The average duration appears to be around two years for

    international migrants, and shorter for domestic migrants.

    Atamanov and van den Berg (2012)analyse data from a nationally representative survey conducted in Kyrgyzstan by the

    Asian Development Bank in 2007. They investigate the determinants of seasonal (repeated episodes each with a duration of

    up to one year) and non-seasonal (duration of more than one year) international migration among rural households. Theyfind that education and land ownership are important drivers of migration decisions. Being better educated influences

    the decision to migrate for an extended period of time as compared to engage in farming, but it does not play a role for

    the decision to migrate seasonally. This indicates differential returns to education for the different migration forms. Land

    ownership positively determines both seasonal and non-seasonal migration, pointing to high migration costs which only

    the more affluent can afford to pay.

    4. Empirical strategy

    Our aim is to understand whether international migration and remittances help or hinder the degree of cooperation in the

    form of private transfers between households in the absence of formal credit markets. We investigate the extent to which

    migrant households differ from non-migrant households in their transfer behavior using the following specification:

    Yij a b1Mijb2Xijb3Dj eij 1

    whereYij is an indicator of whether transfers are provided (received) by householdi residing in communityj. We estimate

    separate models for monetary and non-monetary transfers and separate models for the provision and receipt of transfers.8

    Eq.(1)is thus estimated for four alternative dependent variables. In our first step, we defineMijas a dummy variable indicating

    whether householdi in communityj has a migrant member or not. A household has a migrant member if an adult member has

    been working abroad for more than a month in the last 12 months. In our second step, we defineMijas a dummy variable indi-

    cating whether a household receives remittances or not. A household is a remittance-receiving household if it has received any

    money from abroad during the last 12 months. The person who sends these remittances may or may not be a member of this

    household. We control for other household level variables,Xij, that may generate differential transfer behavior between migrant

    and non-migrant households or remittance and non-remittance households.

    We derive the control variables,Xij, from those used inGallego and Mendola (2013). Specifically, we include socio-demo-

    graphic variables, namely age, gender, marital status, education, and ethnicity of the household head. We also control forhousehold size, the ratio of dependents (i.e. members below the age of six and above the age of 69) in the household,

    and the ownership of wealth. The wealth index is constructed using principal components analysis based on ownership

    of household assets such as land, a car, a computer, a washing machine, and the number of livestock. It is possible that

    involvement in social networks drives both the migration decision and transfer behavior. To address this concern, we control

    for membership in a number of social groups (such as professional unions, credit and savings groups, neighborhood commit-

    tees, and sports groups).

    The community is assumed to be the potential network of a household. We define the community as the local community

    (called aiyl okrug), which is the lowest administrative level in Kyrgyzstan and consists of four villages on average. According

    to the 2009 Census, an average local community has a population of 367 households. We control for community fixed effects,

    Dj, which allows us to compare the behavior of migrant and non-migrant households, or remittance and non-remittance

    7 All numbers provided in this paragraph are taken from the World Development Indicators (World Bank).8

    If households both give and receive transfers, they appear with the outcome variable equal to 1 both in the giving and the receiving regressions. See Section5for details on the extent of this overlap.

    T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705 693

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    5/16

    households, within each community. This controls for heterogeneity between communities. In Table A1in theAppendix A,

    we define all variables that we use in the estimations and present summary statistics.

    b1is the coefficient of our interest. Ifb1 is positive, migrant households provide (receive) more private transfers than non-

    migrant households. The same applies to remittance-receiving vs. non-remittance-receiving households.

    5. Data and descriptive statistics

    The data we use in our empirical analysis come from the Life in Kyrgyzstan (LIK) survey. This is a panel survey conducted

    annually between 2010 and 2012 by the German Institute for Economic Research (DIW Berlin) in collaboration with Hum-

    boldt-University of Berlin, the Centre for Social and Economic Research (CASE-Kyrgyzstan) and the American University of

    Central Asia (Brck et al., 2013). The LIK includes data from all seven Kyrgyz provinces (oblasts) and the cities of Bishkek and

    Osh. Data are collected at the community, household, and individual levels of the sampled households. At the time of our

    data analysis, the first two waves (20102011) of the LIK were finalized. We mainly use data from the second wave because

    this provides more information on private transfers than the data from the first wave. In the second wave, 2863 households

    in 120 urban and rural communities and 8066 adult individuals within these households were interviewed. This is in com-

    parison to 3000 households who were interviewed in 2010. Out of the 137 households that dropped out between 2010 and

    2011, around 7% had at least one migrant household member in 2010. The total population in the 2011 sample households

    (including children) is 13,693.

    The interviewed households were asked whether any of their regular members had been living abroad for more than one

    month (excluding business trips, vacations, and visits) during the last 12 months. Out of the 2863 households, 485 reported

    to have one or more migrants, and 712 migrants were reported in total. This translates into 5% of the total sample being

    migrants. Table 1 provides information on the characteristics of the observed migrants. The average age of a migrant is

    29 years. Two thirds of the migrants are male and almost half are married. Three quarters of the migrants are of Kyrgyz eth-

    nicity, and the majority of them come from the South (Osh city, Osh, Jalalabad, and Batken oblasts) of the country. Ninety

    percent of the migrants have a secondary education degree or higher. They usually go to Russia and work in either construc-

    tion or trade and repair. The average migrant is outside the country for 8.8 months per year. Note that there is a substantial

    Table 1

    Characteristics of migrants. Source: Authors illustration based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Variables All migrants

    Agea 29.04

    (9.51)

    Maleb 68.3

    Marriedb 44.9

    Kyrgyzb 71.1

    Uzbekb 21.1

    Russianb 1.7

    Other ethnicityb 6.1

    Basic education or belowb 9.7

    Secondary educationb 76.8

    University degreeb 13.5

    In Russiab 91.9

    In Kazakhstanb 6

    In another countryb 2.1

    Comes from the South of Kyrgyzstanb 84.7

    Comes from rural areab 69.9

    Works in construction sectorb 40.2

    Works in trade and repairb 23.1

    Works in hotels and restaurantsb 10.7

    Works in another sectorb 26

    Number of months abroad in the last year 8.8

    Frequency of remittances in the last yeara 5.5

    (3.24)

    Amount of remittancesa,c (in Kyrgyz Soms) 54,055

    (51,370)

    N 712

    Note: Only migrants aged 15 and aboveare considered. Some of the characteristics arebased on

    only migrants that are abroad at the time of the survey. The LIK does not collect data on the

    country of destination, the economic sector and the remittances sent from migrants that have

    returned.a Mean with standard deviation in parentheses.b Proportion of migrants.c

    1 USD

    45 KGS.

    694 T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    6/16

    difference between migrants that had returned by the time of the survey (which account for 21% of all migrants) and

    migrants who were still abroad (79% of all migrants). The mean number of months abroad is 6.8 (median is 7) for the

    returned migrants; the mean number is 9.3 (median is 11) for the current migrants. 9 Migrants send money home frequently,

    almost once every two months. The average amount of remittances was 54,000 Kyrgyz Soms (equivalent to approx. US$ 1200)

    per year as of 2011. For the average household that receives remittances, they account for one third of its total household

    income.

    From the total sample of 2863 households, we drop 42 households that have missing information on our key variables.

    We also restrict our analysis to rural areas. Typically, credit and insurance markets are more developed in urban areas, mak-

    ing private informal transfers less important for urban households. In addition, communities in urban areas are characterized

    by fewer repeated interactions and more information asymmetries compared with rural locations, which makes the

    exchange of private transfers more difficult (Cox and Jimenez, 1998; Albarran and Attanasio, 2003). Moreover, most of

    the migrants in Kyrgyzstan stem from rural areas. Compared to 21% of rural households, only 12% of urban households have

    a migrant abroad. Hence, we expect the relationship between migration and informal transfer behavior to be less relevant in

    the urban context. To be sure, we ran the regression of Eq. (1)for urban households. There is indeed no difference in the

    transfer behavior of migrant and non-migrant households as well as of remittance and non-remittance households.

    We exclude the 1168 urban households from our sample which leaves us with 1653 households. Of these, 341 (i.e. 21%)

    had a migrant abroad in the 12 months prior to the 2011 survey.10 Of these migrant households, 70% received remittances. In

    turn, of all households that received remittances (these are 304 households), 86% had household members that were abroad.

    These are very high shares, which imply that the effects of migration are not easily distinguishable from the effects of remit-

    tances. In the estimation, we compare the transfer behavior of (a) households that have a migrant abroad with households that

    do not have a migrant abroad (341 vs. 1312 households), and (b) households that receive remittances with households that do

    not receive remittances (304 vs. 1349 households). Given that these categories overlap to a large extent, we do not expect the

    results to deviate much from each other.

    The following questions about transfer behavior are asked in the individual questionnaire of the 2011 LIK:

    To how many people did you give any financial help during the last 12 months?

    From how many people did you receive any financial help during the last 12 months?

    To how many people did you give any non-financial help (e.g. repairing house, preparing celebrations, homework help)

    during the last 12 months?

    From how many people did you receive any non-financial help (e.g. repairing house, preparing celebrations, homework

    help) during the last 12 months?

    We compute four alternative household-level dummy variables (our dependent variables in the below estimations) from

    these four questions by aggregating information over the individual household members. The resulting dummy variables

    indicate whether or not any household member provided transfers to others or received transfers from others. We do not

    use the absolute number of transfers, given or received, as an outcome variable because of the following concerns. First, there

    is the danger of double counting, as two or more individuals within the same household might report the same transfer. Sec-

    ond, when we compare the maximum number of transfers reported in 2010 with that reported in 2011, we find a fourfold

    increase. Such a questionable increase is not observed when we investigate whether or not a household gave or received at

    all.

    We obtain the following four outcome variables. The first two variables (hh_give_finhelp and hh_rec_finhelp) take the value

    of 1 if any member of a particular household reported to have made or received a monetary transfer in the last year, and 0

    otherwise. The other two variables (hh_give_nonfinhelpand hh_rec_nonfinhelp) take the value of 1 if any member of a partic-

    ular household reported to have made or received a non-monetary transfer in the last year, and 0 otherwise. Through the use

    of examples (repairing the house, preparing celebrations, and help with homework) in the questions referring to non-

    monetary transfers, we ensure that people do not report paid labor. In Kyrgyzstan, the listed activities are typically

    conducted by relatives, friends and neighbors without payment.

    The LIK contains some information about the transfer partners. Individuals were asked to what group their transfer part-

    ners mainly belonged. Partners were mostly relatives (between 60% and 73% for the four transfer categories). Other relevant

    groups are neighbors and friends, with neighbors being more important in the case of non-monetary transfers. This is in line

    with previous research, which found that family and kinship networks are most important to households transfer behavior

    and that geographic proximity matters (Fafchamps and Lund, 2003; De Weerdt and Dercon, 2006; Fafchamps and Gubert,

    2007; Munshi and Rosenzweig, 2009; Mazzocco and Saini, 2012).

    Out of the total number of rural households, about half provided monetary transfers to others, and half provided non-

    monetary transfers to others (Table 2). Forty percent of the households received monetary transfers, and 45% received

    non-monetary transfers. Households are not necessarily either pure givers or pure receivers. Of all those households that give

    or receive monetary transfers, 28% both give and receive. Among those that give or receive non-monetary transfers, 40% both

    9 A seasonal pattern is clearly established for the returned migrants: most of them had been abroad between February and June. For the current migrants,

    there is no such well-defined seasonality.10 This is very close to the estimate by Atamanov and van den Berg (2012): They find that 17.3% of rural households had a migrant abroad in 2006.

    T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705 695

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    7/16

    give and receive. Cox et al. (1998) studied private transfers in Kyrgyzstan in the early 1990s. They find that only 12% of all sur-

    veyed households were net recipients and 9% net givers. However, their reference period is only 30 days, much shorter than

    ours.Fig. A1 in the Appendix A sheds some light on the difference between migrant and non-migrant households in terms of

    transfers made and received. The shares of migrant and non-migrant households are significantly different for all four transfer

    variables. Fig. A2 illustrates differences in transfer behavior between remittance and non-remittance households. Remittance

    and non-remittance households differ significantly on receiving monetary transfers and providing non-monetary transfers.

    InTable 3(Panel A), we present descriptive statistics for the control variables, separately for migrant and non-migrant

    households; we test for differences in these characteristics in the two groups.11 Migrant households differ from non-migrant

    households on age and ethnicity of the household head as well as household size.12 Note that household size counts the resident

    members only. Migrant households may be larger than non-migrant households either because only very large households send

    migrants abroad or because household members left behind by migrants join other households. The second option seems likely

    in the Central Asian context where the wife of a migrant is expected to co-reside with her parents-in-law when her husband is

    abroad. This is supported by the fact that migrant households have on average less dependents as a share of the total number of

    household members than non-migrant households. Additionally, Table 4shows a detailed age breakup of the share of male

    members in the migrant and non-migrant households. As expected, migrant households have a much lower fraction of adult

    men between the age of 20 and 50, the prime migration age, than non-migrant households. As we show below, this absence

    of adult men might be driving non-monetary transfer behavior of households within migrant communities.

    6. Estimation results

    6.1. Baseline estimation

    The results of the estimation of Eq.(1)for migrant vs. non-migrant households as well as remittance vs. non-remittance

    households are shown inTable 5.13 The number of observations varies from the 1653 sample households and across the col-

    umns because some community fixed effects perfectly predict the dependent variable. There are some communities where

    either all or none of the respondent households give or receive transfers. All households within such communities are omitted

    from the probit estimation.

    Migrant households are 12 percentage points more likely than non-migrant households to provide monetary transfers. In

    addition, migrant households are 13 percentage points more likely than non-migrant households to receive non-monetary

    transfers. However, migrant households do not differ from non-migrant households in terms of receiving monetary help or

    giving non-monetary help. We repeat the analysis with an indicator of whether a household receives remittances. House-

    holds that receive remittances are 7 percentage points more likely than their non-receiving counterparts to make monetary

    transfers to others. However, there is no significant difference between remittance and non-remittance households in terms

    of receiving non-monetary help.14

    Additionally, the survey provides information on the amount of remittances received by households. This allows us to

    look at the effect of remittances on transfer behavior at the intensive margin. The results from this analysis are reported

    inTable 6. When remittance receipt increases by 1000 Soms (approx. US$ 22), households are 2.4 percentage points more

    likely to give monetary transfers and 1.4 percentage points more likely to receive non-monetary help.

    Table 2

    Prevalence of private transfers. Source: Authors illustration based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Monetary transfer Non-monetary transfer

    How many households provided help?(%)

    Yes, provided help 47.9 51.5

    No, did not provide help 52.1 48.5

    How many households received help? (%)

    Yes, received help 39.6 45.0

    No, did not receive help 60.4 55.0

    11 Comparing the means of the control variables for remittance and non-remittance households shows a very similar pattern. SeeTable A2in theAppendix A.12 In 27 of our 341 migrant households, the head is a migrant who is still abroad at the time of the survey. For these households, we re-define the head to be

    the second oldest person in the household (if the head was the oldest, which is most often the case) in order to compute the household heads characteristics to

    be used as control variables in the estimations.13 All probit estimations report marginal effects evaluated at the mean.14 In principle, domestic migration may have similar impacts on private transfers as international migration. In our sample, we observe that 9% of all

    households, or 12% of rural households, had domestic migrants. However, we find no differential transfer behavior between households with and without

    domestic migrants. We think that this is because (1) the identification of domestic migrants in the data is based on a much shorter reference period than that of

    international migrants and (2) domestic migrants can return home more easily and frequently so that adjustments within the community in response tomigration are less likely.

    696 T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    8/16

    We check for the possibility that our results are driven by a simple wealth effect. Migrant (remittance-receiving) house-

    holds may transfer more monetary help than households without migrants (not receiving remittances) because they are

    wealthier and not because their income comes from uncorrelated sources. To address this concern, we run the regression

    of Eq.(1)without the wealth index. If it is the difference in wealth that drives our results, the marginal effect of the migra-

    tion/remittance indicator should be larger when the wealth index is not controlled for. However, the marginal effects remainalmost unchanged (compared to those reported in Table 5) after removing the wealth index variable. The results are reported

    inTable A3in theAppendix A.

    What do these results imply in terms of the mechanisms outlined in Section2? If we assume that migrant households

    behaved like non-migrant households before migration, we can conclude that migration and remittances increase the extent

    of monetary transfers and non-monetary transfers made within the community. We observe more monetary transfers made

    by migrant (remittance) households compared with non-migrant (non-remittance) households, which could mean that

    migrant (remittance) households insure their social networks against shocks (mechanism 5) or that they redistribute income

    to poorer households in the community (mechanism 7). In terms of non-monetary transfers, we find that migrant households

    are more likely to receive labor help from other households which seems to indicate that migrant households require more

    labor help in the absence of co-residing adult members (mechanism 4).15 With regard to the amount of remittances, we find

    Table 3

    Summary statistics. Source: Authors illustration based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Panel A: Unmatched sample Panel B: Matched sample

    Non-migrant households

    (N= 1312)

    Migrant households

    (N= 341)

    Difference Non-migrant households

    (N= 1311)

    Migrant households

    (N= 338)

    Difference

    headage 51.5 53.5 2.01 53.7 53.6 0.10

    (14.7) (11.7) (2.34) (0.14)

    headmale 0.767 0.760 0.007 0.767 0.766 0.001

    (0.423) (0.428) (0.31) (0.02)

    headmarried 0.741 0.798 0.057 0.787 0.796 0.009

    (0.438) (0.402) (2.17) (0.28)

    headkyrgyz 0.723 0.751 0.028 0.757 0.757 0.000

    (0.448) (0.433) (1.01) (0.01)

    headuzbek 0.098 0.196 0.098 0.184 0.189 0.005

    (0.297) (0.397) (5.08) (0.16)

    headrussian 0.063 0.009 0.054 0.011 0.009 0.002

    (0.244) (0.093) (4.05) (0.28)

    headother 0.116 0.044 0.072 0.048 0.044 0.004

    (0.320) (0.205) (3.94) (0.20)

    yrs_schooling 10.39 10.27 0.12 10.25 10.26 0.01

    (2.68) (2.60) (0.73) (0.04)

    hhsize 5.11 5.38 0.27 5.41 5.39 0.02

    (2.10) (2.12) (2.14) (0.13)

    depend 0.183 0.141 0.042 0.144 0.142 0.02

    (0.207) (0.164) (3.50) (0.17)

    wealth_index 0.325 0.398 0.073 0.398 0.403 0.005

    (0.829) (0.679) (1.51) (0.09)

    anygroupmem 0.082 0.091 0.008 0.087 0.089 0.002

    (0.275) (0.288) (0.51) (0.07)

    Note:Mean with standard errors in parentheses. Difference with t-statistics in parentheses.

    Table 4

    Household composition. Source: Authors illustration based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Share of males in different age

    groups (in percent)

    Non-migrant households Migrant households

    09 51.84 52.24

    1019 50.58 50.112029 48.31 43.24

    3039 48.05 42.25

    4049 50.00 40.55

    5059 44.14 45.55

    6069 45.20 48.75

    70 and above 40.17 45.45

    15

    Ablezova et al. (2009)provide evidence for elderly people living alone or with grandchildren in many Kyrgyz villages. In-depth interviews with the elderlyshow that migration of their adult children is a serious challenge for them.

    T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705 697

    http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    9/16

    that higher remittances lead to a higher probability of receiving non-monetary help and giving monetary help. This is in line

    with our expectations. We would expect the households with higher remittances to receive more non-monetary transfers if,

    for instance, non-monetary transfers were made in reciprocation to monetary transfers.

    6.2. Endogeneity

    One concern with the above analysis is the possibility of simultaneity, or reverse causality. Some communities might

    experience more out-migration in response to stronger links (proxied by transfers) between households, biasing the esti-

    mates upwards. To ameliorate such concerns, we exploit the panel structure of our data and run a lagged model where

    the migration decision is taken ahead of the observed transfers of a household. Specifically, we estimate the effect of migra-

    tion status of a household in 2010 on transfer behavior in 2011. Similarly, we also estimate the effect of remittances received

    Table 5

    Association of migration and remittances with private transfers. Source: Authors calculation based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Probit model, reported are marginal effects

    Variables Give monetary help Receive monetary help Give non-monetary help Receive non-monetary help

    migrant_hh 0.1227*** . 0.0232 . 0.0229 . 0.1328** .

    (0.0382) . (0.0427) . (0.0432) . (0.0537) .

    remitt_hh . 0.0740* . 0.0007 . 0.0296 . 0.0718

    . (0.0382) . (0.0506) . (0.0457) . (0.0447)

    headage 0.0034** 0.0035** 0.0010 0.0010 0.0002 0.0002 0.0040** 0.0040***

    (0.0014) (0.0014) (0.0012) (0.0012) (0.0015) (0.0015) (0.0016) (0.0015)

    headmale 0.0903* 0.0832 0.0618 0.0587 0.0423 0.0414 0.1002 0.1059

    (0.0519) (0.0521) (0.0502) (0.0498) (0.0688) (0.0679) (0.0696) (0.0685)

    headmarried 0.0966** 0.1075** 0.0394 0.0362 0.0302 0.0296 0.1969*** 0.2050***

    (0.0486) (0.0485) (0.0506) (0.0502) (0.0666) (0.0663) (0.0633) (0.0620)

    headkyrgyz 0.0598 0.0566 0.0597 0.0599 0.0460 0.0474 0.0610 0.0562

    (0.0844) (0.0843) (0.0812) (0.0812) (0.1011) (0.1014) (0.1165) (0.1166)

    headuzbek 0.0216 0.0137 0.0120 0.0089 0.0049 0.0059 0.1277 0.1347

    (0.1353) (0.1343) (0.1308) (0.1300) (0.1222) (0.1222) (0.1304) (0.1309)

    headrussian 0.0554 0.0624 0.0947 0.0954 0.0808 0.0795 0.1977 0.2025

    (0.1039) (0.1038) (0.0688) (0.0682) (0.1006) (0.1004) (0.1585) (0.1566)

    hhsize 0.0267*** 0.0266*** 0.0093 0.0093 0.0622*** 0.0622*** 0.0305*** 0.0310***

    (0.0097) (0.0099) (0.0090) (0.0090) (0.0102) (0.0102) (0.0100) (0.0100)

    depend 0.1036 0.1171 0.0274 0.0243 0.2201** 0.2182** 0.0448 0.0603

    (0.0865) (0.0868) (0.1016) (0.1015) (0.0992) (0.0991) (0.0941) (0.0932)

    yrs_schooling 0.0076 0.0074 0.0048 0.0047 0.0115 0.0116* 0.0078 0.0077

    (0.0071) (0.0070) (0.0075) (0.0075) (0.0070) (0.0070) (0.0080) (0.0079)

    anygroupmem 0.1960*** 0.1932*** 0.1439** 0.1430** 0.1103 0.1099 0.1023 0.1028

    (0.0504) (0.0496) (0.0636) (0.0636) (0.0850) (0.0844) (0.0841) (0.0855)

    wealth_index 0.1007*** 0.1021*** 0.0307 0.0301 0.0277 0.0277 0.0038 0.0044

    (0.0241) (0.0243) (0.0214) (0.0215) (0.0289) (0.0288) (0.0248) (0.0245)

    N 1607 1607 1584 1584 1374 1374 1341 1341

    Pseudo-R2 0.247 0.244 0.298 0.298 0.353 0.353 0.343 0.340

    Note:Constant and community fixed effects are included. Numbers in brackets are standard errors (adjusted for clustering). The number of observations

    varies across the columns and from the total number of sample households because some community fixed effects perfectly predict the dependent variable.* Significant at 10%.** Significant at 5%.*** Significant at 1%.

    Table 6

    Association of remittance amount with private transfers. Source: Authors calculation based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Probit model, reported are marginal effects

    Variables Give monetary help Receive monetary help Give non-monetary help Receive non-monetary help

    remitt_amount 0.0236*** 0.0026 0.0033 0.0140**

    (0.0069) (0.0064) (0.0073) (0.0063)

    Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes

    N 1607 1584 1374 1341

    Pseudo-R2 0.249 0.298 0.351 0.340

    Note:Constant and community fixed effects are included. Numbers in brackets are standard errors (adjusted for clustering). The number of observations

    varies across the columns and from the total number of sample households because some community fixed effects perfectly predict the dependent variable. Significant at 10%.** Significant at 5%.*** Significant at 1%.

    698 T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705

    http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    10/16

    in 2010 on transfer behavior in 2011.Table 7reports the results from these lagged regressions. The effect of migration and

    remittances on providing monetary transfers remains similar. However, the effect of migration on receiving non-monetary

    transfers is now imprecisely estimated. This is plausible because households that had a migrant abroad 1224 months ago

    are unlikely to require labor help in the last 12 months, i.e. after the migrant had possibly returned.

    While this lagged model reduces concerns of simultaneity, the estimates may be biased due to unobserved differences

    between migrant and non-migrant households. This is a cause of concern for us since the migrant and non-migrant house-

    holds vary significantly across several observed socio-demographic dimensions, as shown in Panel A ofTable 3. We address

    this concern by matching the migrant and non-migrant households (as well as the remittance and non-remittance house-

    holds) using propensity score matching. We provide estimates of the effect of migration and remittances on private transfers

    using the matched sample (results below).

    As an alternate strategy, we also estimate a linear probability model with household fixed effects using the longitudinal

    structure of the data. However, when running the fixed effects model, we are restricted to using the two outcome variables

    on giving transfers (hh_give_finhelp and hh_give_nonfinhelp) because information on receiving transfers is not available in the

    2010 wave of the LIK. The fixed effect results (not reported) do not show any significant effect of migrant status on transfer

    behavior. This could be driven by very little variability due to (1) the use of only two time periods, (2) few households chang-

    ing their migration status between 2010 and 2011 (about 150 migrant households in 2011 did not have migrants in 2010),

    and (3) one year being too short a time period for observing significant changes in transfer behavior of a household. Our pre-

    ferred way of addressing concerns of unobserved heterogeneity is therefore the matching.

    The migration literature identifies many characteristics that affect the probability to migrate (Gibson et al., 2013). Follow-

    ing this literature, our set of covariates for matching includes household demographics (household size, fraction of depen-

    dents in total household size, age, gender, ethnicity, education, occupation and marital status of the household head), the

    households network participation (any group membership), migration experience (migration status of the household head)

    and wealth of the household. Furthermore, we try to limit the bias due to locational differences by matching within a prov-

    ince. In addition to these covariates used in the previous migration literature, we also match on the households risk taking

    ability. Evidence suggests that migrants are more risk-taking (Jaeger et al., 2010).16 We assume that after controlling for these

    characteristics, migrant and non-migrant, as well as remittance and non-remittance, households are comparable. In other

    words, we assume that unobserved differences between migrant and non-migrant (as well as remittance and non-remittance)

    households are reflected in the differences in these observed characteristics.

    We define our treated group as households with migrants (remittances) in the last 12 months and the control group as

    non-migrant (non-remittance) households. Using the kernel matching function, we construct propensity scores to match the

    control group to the treatment group.17 The kernel function takes the weighted averages of the observations in the controlgroup as the counterfactual outcome for each observation in the treatment group. For the case of matching migrant and

    non-migrant households, we lose three observations because they are off common support. For the case of matching remittance

    and non-remittance households, we lose two observations. Panel B ofTable 3reports the mean household characteristics for the

    migrant and the non-migrant households in the matched sample. In contrast to the unmatched sample in Panel A, the migrant

    and non-migrant households do not vary significantly across any observed dimension in the matched sample. The same picture

    emerges when comparing remittance with non-remittance households (Table A2in theAppendix A).18

    The regression estimates based on the matched sample are reported in Table 8. Migrant households are 15 percentage

    points more likely than non-migrant households to give monetary help and 15 percentage points more likely to receive labor

    help. Using an indicator for remittances received instead of migrant status provides similar results. Households receiving

    Table 7

    Association of lagged migration and remittances with private transfers. Source: Authors calculation based on 2010 and 2011 LIK survey data.

    Probit model, reported are marginal effects

    Variables Give monetary help Receive monetary help Give non-monetary help Receive non-monetary help

    migrant_hh (lag) 0.0830** . 0.0665 . 0.0105 . 0.0475 .

    (0.0415) . (0.0409) . (0.0468) . (0.0572) .

    remitt_hh (lag) . 0.1228*** . 0.0243 . 0.0220 . 0.0615

    . (0.0447) . (0.0392) . (0.0482) . (0.0514)

    Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    N 1607 1607 1584 1584 1374 1374 1341 1341

    Pseudo-R2 0.244 0.246 0.299 0.298 0.353 0.353 0.339 0.340

    Note:Constant and community fixed effects are included. Numbers in brackets are standard errors (adjusted for clustering). The number of observations

    varies across the columns and from the total number of sample households because some community fixed effects perfectly predict the dependent variable. Significant at 10%.** Significant at 5%.*** Significant at 1%.

    16 At this stage, we lose one household due to a missing value for risk-taking.17

    The results of the probit model are reported inTable A4in theAppendix A.18 Table A5provides further evidence on the quality of matching.

    T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705 699

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    11/16

    remittances are 16 percentage points more likely to provide monetary help and 9 percentage points more likely to receive

    labor help. The latter result, which was insignificant in the unmatched sample, is now statistically significant at the 10% level.

    Overall, the matching results indicate that the results in our baseline specification in Table 4 are biased downwards by a few

    percentage points. One possibility for this bias is that households characterized by a higher risk-loving attitude are morelikely to have migrants abroad (and, hence, to receive remittances) and less likely to informally insure themselves against

    shocks. If much of the transfer behavior is driven by risk-sharing motives, the households tending to take more risk are less

    likely to engage in transfers.

    6.3. Reciprocal transfers

    Overall, our findings show that migrant households (remittance households) are more likely than non-migrant house-

    holds (non-remittance households) to provide monetary transfers to others and receive labor assistance from others. One

    possible underlying mechanism is reciprocity migrant households, through their access to remittance income, give mon-

    etary help to non-migrant households who cannot afford to return monetary help but instead reciprocate by providing non-

    monetary help. Since many households in our data both give and receive transfers, we use this information to shed light on

    the underlying mechanism. Particularly, we explore whether households that give monetary help are the ones that receive

    non-monetary help and whether this effect is larger for migrant households compared to non-migrant households. We

    Table 8

    Association of migration and remittances with private transfers, matched sample. Source: Authors calculation based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Probit model, reported are marginal effects

    Variables Give monetary help Receive monetary help Give non-monetary help Receive non-monetary help

    migrant_hh 0.1465*** . 0.0349 . 0.0327 . 0.1538*** .

    (0.0401) . (0.0372) . (0.0472) . (0.0494) .

    remitt_hh . 0.1579*** . 0.0514 . 0.0053 . 0.0923*

    . (0.0405) . (0.0386) . (0.0499) . (0.0509)

    Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    N 1603 1604 1580 1581 1371 1372 1337 1338

    Pseudo-R2 0.267 0.259 0.290 0.300 0.374 0.389 0.387 0.402

    Note:Constant and community fixed effects are included. Numbers in brackets are standard errors (adjusted for clustering). The number of observations

    varies across the columns and from the total number of sample households because some community fixed effects perfectly predict the dependent variable.* Significant at 10%. Significant at 5%.

    *** Significant at 1%.

    Table 9

    Reciprocity of private transfers. Source: Authors calculation based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    OLS model, reported are coefficients

    Variables Dependent: receive non-monetary help Dependent: receive monetary help Dependent: receive non-monetary help

    givefinXmig 0.0860 . 0.0157 . . .

    (0.0532) . (0.0597) . . .

    givefinXrem . 0.1305** . 0.0234 . .

    . (0.0535) . (0.0656) . .

    hh_give_finhelp 0.1045*** 0.0991*** 0.2087*** 0.2068*** . .

    (0.0245) (0.0240) (0.0386) (0.0384) . .

    givenonfinXmig . . . . 0.0262 .

    . . . . (0.0625) .

    givenonfinXrem . . . . . 0.0369

    . . . . . (0.0549)

    hh_give_nonfinhelp . . . . 0.4311*** 0.4292***

    . . . . (0.0534) (0.0536)

    migrant_hh 0.0039 . 0.0103 . 0.0528 .

    (0.0342) . (0.0337) . (0.0347) .

    remitt_hh .

    0.0486 .

    0.0041 . 0.0177. (0.0312) . (0.0402) . (0.0314)

    Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    N 1653 1653 1653 1653 1653 1653

    R2 0.497 0.497 0.374 0.374 0.585 0.584

    Note:Constant and community fixed effects are included. Numbers in brackets are standard errors (adjusted for clustering). Significant at 10%.** Significant at 5%.*** Significant at 1%.

    700 T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705

    http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    12/16

    regress the receipt of non-monetary help on migrant status (remittance receipt), the provision of monetary help, an inter-

    action term of these two variables (givefinXmigandgivefinXrem) and all the control variables included in Table 5.19

    We find that there is substantial reciprocity in transfers. Those households that give monetary help are more likely to

    receive labor assistance compared with those that do not give monetary help. This is even more so for remittance-receiving

    households. Those remittance-receiving households that provide monetary help are significantly more likely to receive labor

    assistance compared with households that do not receive remittances. Even though the interaction term is also positive for

    migrant households, it is not statistically significant. In the latter columns ofTable 9, we also investigate reciprocity for the

    respectively same type of transfer. Again, there is significant reciprocity: Households that provide monetary help are more

    likely to receive monetary help, and households that provide labor assistance are more likely to receive labor assistance.

    However, there is no differential behavior across migrant (remittance) and non-migrant (non-remittance) households here.

    We acknowledge that we cannot clearly identify the full extent of reciprocity in our data, since we do not observe which

    particular households the transfers are going to and coming from. Nevertheless, we argue that the evidence provided here

    is suggestive of the fact that households, which receive remittances, provide money to their social networks and receive

    labor assistance in return.

    7. Conclusion

    Economists have long engaged in understanding the role of migration and inter-household private transfers for managing

    householdsrisk in developing countries where insurance andcredit marketsare typicallyweak. Littleis known about theinter-

    action of these two risk management strategies in the communities of migrants origin. Given the massive out-migration from

    many developing countries, it is important to know the impact of migration on widely established private transfer systems.In this paper, we empirically assess the relationship between international migration and private transfers among house-

    holds left behind in the migrant sending communities of rural Kyrgyzstan. We find that migration is unlikely to lead to a

    weakening of private transfers. Migrant households are more likely than non-migrant households to provide monetary

    transfers to others. This could be an indication that migrant households insure non-migrant households against income

    shocks or redistribute income to them. If so, our findings reveal a significant positive externality at the community level,

    resulting from out-migration of some adult community members. Migration and consequent remittances then increase

    the welfare not only of migrant households but also of non-migrant households. Welfare estimations of migration should

    take this potential positive externality into account.

    As noted in Section 1, if migration decreased the extent of private transfers within migrant sending communities, the gov-

    ernment would have an active role to play by substituting private transfers with public transfers. However, our results indi-

    cate that there is no decrease in private transfers; migration may instead even lead to an increase in the extent of private

    transfers. This implies that government intervention, in terms of public transfers, is less needed in communities with intact

    social structures, such as those of rural Kyrgyzstan. On the other hand, policies facilitating temporary migration and easinginternational transfer of remittances may be helpful to reduce wealth inequalities in communities characterized by informal

    transfer systems.

    A deeper look into our results suggests that targeted public transfers might actually disturb the private equilibrium in

    societies with traditional transfer systems. Given that migrant households are net givers of monetary help and net receivers

    of labor help, it is possible that the labor transfers come from non-migrant households. This, in turn, suggests that in the

    absence of male adults in migrant households, the non-migrant households provide labor help to the migrant households

    in times of need and receive financial assistance in return. In this situation, a public transfer program targeted toward the

    financially poorer non-migrant households would be likely to disturb the equilibrium. Non-migrant households would then

    no longer depend on migrant households for financial help and would in turn no longer offer labor help to the people left

    behind in migrant households.

    While we provide some suggestive evidence in support of the idea that migrant households exchange money for labor, we

    cannot clearly identify this with our data. In order to correctly determine the partners in transfer arrangements and the

    motives of private transfers, future research and more detailed information on household transfer behavior in migrant send-ing communities are required.

    Acknowledgments

    This paper was written within the research project Economic Transformation, Household Behavior and Well-Being in

    Central Asia. The Case of Kyrgyzstan, which was funded by the Volkswagen Foundation and coordinated by DIW Berlin. We

    are grateful to Kathryn Anderson, Ainura Asamidinova, Charles Becker, Margherita Comola, Shamsia Ibragimova, Mariapia

    Mendola, Laura Schechter andtwoanonymousrefereesfor helpful comments on earlier versionsof thepaper. We alsoreceived

    crucial feedback from participants of workshops and conferences in Moscow, Chicago, Bonn, Delhi, Einsiedeln, Bishkek,

    19 Given that the interpretation of interaction terms in non-linear models is not as straight-forward as in linear models ( Norton et al., 2004), we run this

    regression as an OLS model (reported here in Table 9) and also produce marginal effects as well as standard errors for a probit model (unreported) using theSTATA command inteff. The results do not differ qualitatively.

    T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705 701

    http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    13/16

    Madison, and Almaty. Furthermore, our colleagues at the DIW Department for Development and Security provided invaluable

    comments.Wealso thank theGermanResearch Centrefor Geosciencesin Potsdam, Eugene Huskeyand Mohammad Hamayoon

    Majidi for providing us with different types of data and Philipp Jaeger and Zalina Sharkaeva for excellent research assistance.

    Appendix A

    See Figs.A1, A2andTables A1A5.

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    Migrant Non-migrant Migrant Non-migrant Migrant Non-migrant Migrant Non-migrant

    Give monetary Receive monetary Give non-monetary Receive non-monetary

    No

    Yes

    Fig. A1. Transfer behavior in migrant vs. non-migrant households. Source:Authors illustration based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    Remittance Non-remittance

    Remittance Non-remittance

    Remittance Non-remittance

    Remittance Non-remittance

    Give monetary Receive monetary Give non-monetary Receive non-monetary

    No

    Yes

    Fig. A2. Transfer behavior in remittance vs. non-remittance households. Source: Authors illustration based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Table A1

    Description of variables. Source: Authors illustration based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Variable Definition Mean SD Min. Max.

    migrant_hh 1 = having had a migrant in the past 12 months, 0 = otherwise 0.21 0.41 0 1

    remitt_hh 1 = having received remittances in the past 12 months, 0 = otherwise 0.18 0.38 0 1

    headage Age of household head in years 51.9 14.1 18 99

    headmale 1 = household head is male, 0 = otherwise 0.77 0.42 0 1

    headmarried 1 = household head is married, 0 = otherwise 0.75 0.43 0 1

    headkyrgyz 1 = household head is Kyrgyz, 0 = otherwise 0.73 0.44 0 1

    headuzbek 1 = household head is Uzbek, 0 = otherwise 0.12 0.32 0 1headrussian 1 = household head is Russian, 0 = otherwise 0.05 0.22 0 1

    headothereth 1 = household head is of another ethnicity, 0 = otherwise 0.10 0.30 0 1

    yrs_schooling Years of schooling of household head in years 10.36 2.66 0 15

    hhsize Household size (# of individuals currently in the HH) 5.16 2.10 1 15

    depend Ratio of household members older than 69 or younger than 6 in total household size 0.17 0.20 0 1

    wealth_index Households wealth index based on PCA (household assets) 0.34 0.80 2.83 7.16

    anygroupmem 1 = household has any group member, 0 = otherwise 0.08 0.28 0 1

    headrisk Standardized value for self-assessed willingness to take risks 0.03 0.96 1.62 1.83

    headagri 1 = household head engaged in agriculture, 0 = otherwise 0.35 0.48 0 1

    headnonagri 1 = household head engaged in non-agriculture, 0 = otherwise 0.30 0.46 0 1

    headunemp 1 = household head unemployed or inactive, 0 = otherwise 0.35 0.48 0 1

    headmobility 1 = household head born in the oblast of current residence, 0 = otherwise 0.91 0.29 0 1

    hh_give_finhelp 1 = household provided monetary transfer, 0 = otherwise 0.48 0.50 0 1

    hh_rec_finhelp 1 = household received monetary transfer, 0 = otherwise 0.40 0.49 0 1

    hh_give_nonfinhelp 1 = household provided non-monetary transfer, 0 = otherwise 0.52 0.50 0 1

    hh_rec_nonfinhelp 1 = household received non-monetary transfer, 0 = otherwise 0.45 0.50 0 1

    702 T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705

    http://-/?-
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    14/16

    Table A3

    Robustness check: independence of the results of wealth. Source: Authors calculation based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Probit model, reported are marginal effects

    Variables Give monetary help Receive monetary help Give non-monetary help Receive non-monetary helpmigrant_hh 0.1132*** . 0.0063 . 0.0428 . 0.0860* .

    (0.0376) . (0.0468) . (0.0421) . (0.0498) .

    remitt_hh . 0.1085*** . 0.0361 . 0.0108 . 0.0651

    . (0.0406) . (0.0445) . (0.0394) . (0.0421)

    headage 0.0043*** 0.0043*** 0.0008 0.0007 0.0001 0.0000 0.0040*** 0.0040***

    (0.0014) (0.0014) (0.0012) (0.0012) (0.0015) (0.0015) (0.0015) (0.0015)

    headmale 0.0878* 0.0843 0.0598 0.0655 0.0443 0.0488 0.1037 0.1069

    (0.0529) (0.0527) (0.0500) (0.0502) (0.0689) (0.0684) (0.0688) (0.0681)

    headmarried 0.1095** 0.1141** 0.0407 0.0451 0.0317 0.0283 0.2020*** 0.2048***

    (0.0505) (0.0499) (0.0499) (0.0502) (0.0673) (0.0668) (0.0630) (0.0621)

    headkyrgyz 0.0471 0.0537 0.0615 0.0632 0.0386 0.0384 0.0604 0.0632

    (0.0804) (0.0811) (0.0807) (0.0807) (0.0999) (0.1000) (0.1167) (0.1176)

    headuzbek 0.0006 0.0098 0.0145 0.0220 0.0009 0.0013 0.1290 0.1276

    (0.1336) (0.1350) (0.1292) (0.1306) (0.1210) (0.1207) (0.1317) (0.1322)

    headrussian 0.0521 0.0456 0.0991 0.0965 0.0826 0.0820 0.1981 0.1967

    (0.1007) (0.1037) (0.0684) (0.0696) (0.0997) (0.0996) (0.1574) (0.1600)

    hhsize 0.0326*** 0.0326*** 0.0074 0.0074 0.0642*** 0.0640*** 0.0314*** 0.0316***

    (0.0093) (0.0095) (0.0092) (0.0092) (0.0100) (0.0100) (0.0103) (0.0103)

    depend 0.1270 0.1276 0.0309 0.0344 0.2275** 0.2255** 0.0588 0.0602

    (0.0871) (0.0866) (0.1019) (0.1016) (0.0985) (0.0988) (0.0930) (0.0937)

    yrs_schooling 0.0095 0.0099 0.0055 0.0056 0.0123* 0.0122* 0.0076 0.0078

    (0.0069) (0.0068) (0.0076) (0.0075) (0.0069) (0.0069) (0.0080) (0.0079)

    anygroupmem 0.2035*** 0.2001*** 0.1411** 0.1415** 0.1130 0.1147 0.1043 0.1006

    (0.0485) (0.0485) (0.0644) (0.0640) (0.0847) (0.0854) (0.0854) (0.0865)

    N 1607 1607 1585 1585 1375 1375 1341 1341

    Pseudo-R2 0.236 0.236 0.297 0.297 0.352 0.352 0.341 0.340

    Note:Constant and community fixed effects are included. Numbers in brackets are standard errors (adjusted for clustering). The number of observations

    varies across the columns and from the total number of sample households because some community fixed effects perfectly predict the dependent variable.* Significant at 10%.** Significant at 5%.*** Significant at 1%.

    Table A2

    Summary statistics (remittance vs. non-remittance households). Source: Authors illustration based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Panel A: Unmatched sample Panel B: Matched sample

    Non-remittance

    households (N= 1349)

    Remittance

    households (N= 304)

    Difference Non-remittance

    households (N= 1348)

    Remittance

    households (N= 302)

    Difference

    headage 51.4 54.3 2.9 54.8 54.4 0.40

    (14.5) (12.2) (3.31) (0.34)

    headmale 0.775 0.727 0.048 0.742 0.732 0.10

    (0.418) (0.446) (1.77) (0.30)

    headmarried 0.749 0.770 0.021 0.763 0.768 0.005

    (0.434) (0.422) (0.77) (0.16)

    headkyrgyz 0.723 0.757 0.034 0.759 0.758 0.001

    (0.448) (0.430) (1.20) (0.03)

    headuzbek 0.107 0.164 0.057 0.162 0.162 0.000

    (0.310) (0.371) (2.79) (0.01)

    headrussian 0.059 0.020 0.039 0.020 0.020 0.000

    (0.236) (0.141) (2.81) (0.03)

    headother 0.111 0.059 0.052 0.060 0.060 0.000

    (0.314) (0.236) (2.68) (0.05)

    yrs_schooling 10.38 10.28 0.10 10.21 10.26 0.05

    (2.65) (2.72) (0.61) (0.23)

    hhsize 5.13 5.31 0.18 5.33 5.32 0.01

    (2.08) (2.22) (1.32) (0.06)

    depend 0.179 0.152 0.027 0.160 0.154 0.006

    (0.205) (0.172) (2.12) (0.45)

    wealth_index 0.324 0.412 0.088 0.407 0.410 0.003

    (0.822) (0.689) (1.74) (0.04)

    anygroupmem 0.079 0.105 0.026 0.099 0.103 0.004

    (0.270) (0.307) (1.47) (0.14)

    Note:Mean with standard errors in parentheses. Difference with t-statistics in parentheses.

    T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705 703

  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    15/16

    References

    Ablezova, Mehrigul, Nasritdinov, Emil, Rahimov, Ruslan, 2009. The Impact of Migration on Elderly People. Grandparent-Headed Households in Kyrgyzstan.

    Report by Help Age International Central Asia and Social Research Center, American University of Central Asia. (last accessed 23.06.14).

    Albarran, Pedro, Attanasio, Orazio P., 2003. Limited commitment and crowding out of private transfers: evidence from a randomised experiment. Economic

    Journal 113 (486), C77C85.

    Atamanov, Aziz, van den Berg, Marrit, 2012. International labour migration and local rural activities in the Kyrgyz Republic: determinants and trade-offs.

    Central Asian Survey 31 (2), 119136.

    Brck, Tilman, Esenaliev, Damir, Kroeger, Antje, Kudebayeva, Alma, Mirkasimov, Bakhrom, Steiner, Susan, 2014. Household survey data for research on

    well-being and behavior in Central Asia. Journal of Comparative Economics 42 (3), 819835.

    Charness, Gary, Genicot, Garance, 2009. Informal risk sharing in an infinite-horizon experiment. Economic Journal 119 (537), 796825 .

    Table A4

    Propensity score estimation: probit regression for migration and remittances. Source: Authors calculation based on 2011 LIK

    survey data.

    Variables Dependent: migration Dependent: remittances

    headage 0.0103*** 0.0107***

    (0.00377) (0.00416)

    headmale 0.551*** 0.580***

    (0.174) (0.153)

    headmarried 0.574***

    0.501***

    (0.195) (0.174)

    headkyrgyz 0.114 0.148

    (0.178) (0.186)

    headuzbek 0.292 0.0907

    (0.227) (0.200)

    headrussian 0.227 0.0404

    (0.370) (0.357)

    hhsize 0.00344 0.00965

    (0.0226) (0.0223)

    depend 0.833*** 0.554**

    (0.278) (0.240)

    yrs_schooling 0.0122 0.0245

    (0.0180) (0.0178)

    anygroupmem 0.132 0.315*

    (0.154) (0.185)

    wealth_index 0.0167 0.0551(0.0568) (0.0622)

    headrisk 0.106* 0.0651

    (0.0555) (0.0568)

    headagri 0.00426 0.0494

    (0.137) (0.135)

    headnonagri 0.226* 0.348***

    (0.131) (0.117)

    headmobility 0.016 0.139

    (0.212) (0.216)

    N 1652 1652

    Pseudo-R2 0.155 0.145

    Note: Constant and province (oblast) fixed effects are included. Numbers in brackets are standard errors (adjusted for

    clustering).* Significant at 10%.** Significant at 5%.*** Significant at 1%.

    Table A5

    Summary of matching quality. Source: Authors calculation based on 2011 LIK survey data.

    Before matching After matching

    Migration

    Mean standardized bias 14.0 1.0

    Median standardized bias 13.1 1.0

    Pseudo-R2 0.069 0.001

    Remittances

    Mean standardized bias 12.8 1.3

    Median standardized bias 11.3 0.8

    Pseudo-R2 0.052 0.001

    704 T. Chakraborty et al. / Journal of Comparative Economics 43 (2015) 690705

    http://src.auca.kg/pdf/The_impact_of_migration_on_elderly_people.pdfhttp://src.auca.kg/pdf/The_impact_of_migration_on_elderly_people.pdfhttp://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h0010http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h0010http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h0015http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h0015http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h9000http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h9000http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h0025http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h0025http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h9000http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h9000http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h0015http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h0015http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h0010http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0147-5967(14)00089-4/h0010http://src.auca.kg/pdf/The_impact_of_migration_on_elderly_people.pdfhttp://src.auca.kg/pdf/The_impact_of_migration_on_elderly_people.pdf
  • 7/24/2019 Transfer behavior in migrant sending communities

    16/16