Top Banner
The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Chief Economist Phoenix Center Phoenix Center [email protected] [email protected]
46

The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center [email protected].

Dec 23, 2015

Download

Documents

Valerie Flynn
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition

George S. Ford, PhDGeorge S. Ford, PhDChief EconomistChief EconomistPhoenix CenterPhoenix [email protected]@phoenix-center.org

Page 2: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

The Present Uncertainty

• Technology, FCC actions, court decisions, and the election have created considerable uncertainty for telecommunications policy– VOIP, Cable Telephony, Broadband over

Powerlines– Triennial Review Order, USTA Decision,

Brand X– Election

Page 3: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

A Sure Thing

• Regardless of uncertainty, current focus of modern utilities policy is the promotion of competition

Page 4: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

A Sure Thing

• An Act [t]o promote competition and reduce regulation in order to – secure lower prices and higher quality

services for American telecommunications consumers

– and encourage the rapid deployment of new telecommunications technologies.

Page 5: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

What is Competition?

• Competition has many characteristics and definitions, but competition always requires that there be more than just one firm offering goods/services to consumers

Page 6: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Benefits of Competition

Price

Competition => Number of Firms (N)

Innovation

Page 7: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

The Policy Objective: The End of the Monopoly

Present Future

ONEFIRM

MANYFIRMS

Entry by New Firms

Page 8: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How Many is Many?

• There exist an equilibrium number of firms in an industry (N*).

• N* is related to:– Size of the market (bigger market, bigger N)– Sunk Entry Costs (higher cost, fewer N)– Degree of Price Competition (more

competition, fewer N)

Page 9: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Entry Fee (F)

• Sunk Costs– Costs that cannot be recovered once incurred

• Akin to a non-refundable deposit• Network Deployment• Marketing• Product Development• Regulatory Compliance

– May be Endogenous • Caused by Incumbent• Caused by Regulator

Page 10: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Simple Example• Market Size (S) = $1,000,000• Variable Cost (C) = $10• Entry Fee (F) = $100,000• Monopoly Price (P) = $100• Each Additional Firm Reduces Price-Cost

Margin by 10%– Monopoly Margin is $90 = $100 - $10– 2 Firm Margin is $81 = $90 - 90(0.10)

This example is a simplification of the analysis presented by Sutton in Sunk Cost and Market Structure (1991).

Page 11: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Equilibrium Number of FirmsFirms (N) Price Profit

1 100.0 800,000

2 90.00 344,444

3 81.00 192,181

4 72.90 115,706

5 65.60 69,517

6 59.00 38,442

7 53.10 15,976

8 47.80 -1,134

Page 12: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Simple Example: Alternate Assumptions

• S = 1,000,000• C = $10• F = $100,000• PM = $100• Competition = 10%• N* = 7

• S = 2,000,000• C = $10• F = $100,000• PM = $100• Competition = 10%• N* = 12

Page 13: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Simple Example: Alternate Assumptions

• S = 1,000,000• C = $10• F = $100,000• PM = $100• Competition = 10%• N* = 7

• S = 1,000,000• C = $10• F = $200,000• PM = $100• Competition = 10%• N* = 4

Page 14: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Simple Example: Alternate Assumptions

• S = 1,000,000• C = $10• F = $100,000• PM = $100• Competition = 10%• N* = 7

• S = 1,000,000• C = $10• F = $100,000• PM = $100• Competition = 20%• N* = 6

Page 15: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Two Types of Entry Costs

• Exogenous Entry Costs (determined outside the system)– Some costs are just a necessary component of entry,

such as marketing, some legal expenses, licenses, office space, network, etc….

• Endogenous Entry Costs (determined within the system)– Incumbents can raise the entry costs, possibly through

regulation• Level Playing Field Rules• Regulatory Proceedings

Page 16: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How Many is Many?

• There exist an equilibrium number of firms in an industry (N*).

• This equilibrium number of firms depends on:– The size of the market in expenditures (+)

– The size and nature of production cost (-)

– The intensity of price competition (-)

Page 17: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

What Can be Done about Entry Costs? Advice from Economists

• The single most important element in the design of public policy for monopoly should be the design of arrangements which render benign the exercise of market power associated with operating sunk facilities. One way to avoid the exercise of monopoly power is to have the sunk costs borne by the government or municipality … or by mandating that sunk costs be shared by a consortium. … Virtually any method will do as long as there are contractual or other arrangements that are nondiscriminatory and permit easy transfer or lease or shared use of these cost commitments. E. Bailey, AER, 71 (1981).”

Page 18: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

What Can be Done about Entry Costs? Advice from Economists

• One of the main points that emerges from the discussion is that sunk costs are often not pervasive in an industry, but rather are centered in a particular sector of its operations, such as airports in air transportation. By isolating the activities with which the heavy sunk costs are associated, their damaging consequences can be quarantined. By placing relations with the remainder of the industry at arm’s length … it may be possible to leave the operations of the bulk of the industry safely to the free market, drawing a regulatory net over only the segment of the activities of the industry that are inextricably associated with heavy sunk costs. Baumol, Panzar, Willig, Contestable Markets (1988), at 483.

Page 19: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Goal of the Telecom Act of 1996

“to eliminate the monopolies”(Verizon v. FCC)

“reorganize markets deliberately” is an “end in itself” (Verizon v. FCC)

Page 20: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

The Act’s Strategy

Wholesale

Vertically Integrated

Local Exchange

Retail

WholesaleSegment

RetailSegment

Market for Telecom Plant (UNEs)

Page 21: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Why do we need an Act?

• Industry Structure in the Local Exchange Markets tends toward monopoly– Economies of Density– Sunk Costs (risk)– First-mover advantages (i.e., municipal barriers to entry)– Timing of entry expenditures and realization of

revenues– Product Differentiation (i.e., incumbent already has all

the customers)– Vertical Integration (entry must occur at retail and

wholesale level)

Page 22: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

The Act’s Strategy

WholesaleSegment

RetailSegment

N* > 0, ????

N* > 0, Relatively Easy

Entry economics of retail changed dramatically with unbundling and interconnection, since sunk network costs were “quarantined.” Entry economics of wholesale have improved due to technology and law, but the change is more subtle.

Where did they get this idea? …

Page 23: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Where Did They Get This Idea?• Number of Toll Carriers in Year 2001 = 805

– >900 now– Trends Report, IXCs plus resellers

• Number of Nationwide Toll Networks in Year 2001– AT&T– MCI-Worldcom – Sprint– Global Crossing (Ret. MS < 1%)– Williams (Ret. MS < 1%)– Qwest (Ret. MS < 3%)– Broadwing (Ret. MS < 1%)– Level 3 (Ret. MS < 1%)

About 100:1 Ratio of Retail to Wholesale

Firms in Long Distance

About half of the wholesale firms are bankrupt (N > N*)

Page 24: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Getting More Wholesalers, Facilities-Based Entry

• How do we get more wholesalers (networks)?– In long distance, all but the three largest long distance

networks were built to serve other companies’ demands, not the own-demand of the network owner.

– End-users don’t demand network, telecommunications firms do.

– ILECs will serve their end-users with their own network, so entrant’s have no demand.

– Entrant demand is from the non-incumbents serving end users (so, we should encourage this).

Page 25: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Non-Incumbent Demand for Network

• Retail LECs (RLECs) accumulate market share for the Wholesale LECs (WLEC or ADCo).– RLECs want multi-firm supply– ILECs (today) are reluctant suppliers (full price is higher

than wholesale price)

• Facilities-based entry on a meaningful scale is made more possible with successful RLECs

• RLECs cannot all be expected to deploy their own facilities– Consider market structure in long distance (100:1

Retail/wholesale)

Page 26: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Non-Incumbent Demand for Network

• If we don’t have unbundling building as a means to build a demand for alternative network, how will this demand develop?

Page 27: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How to Use the Theory at Work

• Is the proposed policy going to increase or decrease the market available to potential entrants?

Page 28: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How to Use the Theory at Work: Example

• FCC Restriction on availability of unbundled switching in Top 50 MSAs.– An Empirical Examination of the Unbundled Local Switching

Restriction, Z-Tel Policy Paper No. 3, March 2002.– Does Unbundling Really Discourage Facilities-Based Entry? An

Econometric Examination of the Unbundled Local Switching Restriction, Z-Tel Policy Paper No. 4, February 2002.

– Mandated Access and the Make-or-Buy Decision: The Case of Local Telecommunications Competition, T. R. Beard, G. S. Ford, and T.M. Koutsky, QREF Forthcoming.

Page 29: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How to Use the Theory at Work

• Is the proposed policy going to increase the cost of entry, particularly those costs that cannot be recovered? – Is the policy debate itself raising entry costs?– Am I, as a regulator, allowing the incumbent to

raise entry costs or contributing to the problem?

Page 30: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How to Use the Theory at Work

• Is the proposed policy affecting the intensity of price competition?– Price cuts are generally a good thing, but there

are price cuts that can harm the competitive process

– Is the price cut intended to squash nescient entry?

Page 31: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How to Use the Theory at Work: Implications

• Given the large entry costs of facilities-based entry, it is unreasonable to expect a large number of entrants.

• Observed entry does not imply successful entry, and does not imply further entry is feasible (there is an equilibrium N).

Page 32: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How to Use the Theory at Work: Implications

• Facilities-based entry will occur when few facilities (low entry costs) can serve large demands (large market size)– E.g., dedicated trunks to big businesses– Facilities entry occurs when there is a large size

to entry costs ratio

Page 33: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How to Use the Theory at Work: Implications

• Minimum market share for a facilities-based local provider of mass market local service is large, suggesting high concentration in that market.

• Facilities based entrant for mass market will require large market share (20 - 50%).

• Where will a potential facilities based entry get 20-50% market share?

Page 34: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How to Use the Theory at Work: Summary

• What does this do the market size available to entrants?

• What does this do to entry costs?

Page 35: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

FCC Order: Bad Economics

• Larger fixed and sunk costs imply that fewer firms are able to survive profitably in the industry (TRO, ¶ 80). OK

• If more facilities-based carriers have entered the market than can be supported by market demand, creating overcapacity and generating low prices, none of the carriers may be profitable (TRO, ft. 320). OK

Page 36: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

FCC Order: Bad Economics

• Limiting our high-capacity loop triggers to only one competitor runs the risk of failing to accommodate unusual circumstances unique to that single provider that may not reflect the ability of other competitors to similarly deploy. Establishing a higher number, for example three, would likely render our high-capacity loop triggers meaningless for the many customer locations where the potential aggregate customer demand would never support more than two competitive alternatives to the incumbent LEC (TRO, ft. 974).

Page 37: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

FCC Order: Bad Economics

• if there is no collocation space available for additional competitive LEC equipment, further competitive entry may be impossible (TRO, ¶ 503).

Page 38: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

FCC Order: Bad Economics

• We find that the presence of facilities-based competitors is the best indicator that requesting carriers are not impaired (TRO, ¶ 498).

Page 39: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

FCC Order: Bad Economics

• evidence of actual deployment indicates barriers to entry can be overcome (TRO, 331)

• We establish the number of competitors to the incumbent LEC necessary to satisfy each trigger for high-capacity loops subject to a finding of impairment at two in order to ensure that multiple competitive entry at each location is feasible (TRO, ¶ 330).

Page 40: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

The Act

• An Act [t]o promote competition and reduce regulation in order to – secure lower prices and higher quality

services for American telecommunications consumers

– and encourage the rapid deployment of new telecommunications technologies.

Page 41: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Lower Prices, Higher Quality?

• PHOENIX CENTER POLICY BULLETIN No. 8: The $10 Billion Benefit of Unbundling: Consumer Surplus Gains from Competitive Pricing Innovations (27 January 2004).

Page 42: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Investment• George S. Ford and Lawrence J. Spiwak, The Positive

Effects of Unbundling on Broadband Deployment, PHOENIX CENTER POLICY PAPER NO. 19 (September 2004).

• PHOENIX CENTER POLICY BULLETIN No. 6: UNE-P Drives Bell Investment - A Synthesis Model (17 September 2003)

• PHOENIX CENTER POLICY BULLETIN No. 5:  Competition and Bell Company Investment in Telecommunications Plant: The Effects of UNE-P (Originally released 9 July 2003 and updated 17 September 2003)

• PHOENIX CENTER POLICY BULLETIN No. 4: The Truth About Telecommunications Investment after the Telecommunications Act of 1996 (24 June 2003).

Page 43: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Investment

• Mandated Access and the Make-or-Buy Decision: The Case of Local Telecommunications Competition, T. R. Beard, G. S. Ford, and T.M. Koutsky, December 2002.

• Pursuing Competition in Local Telephony: The Law and Economics of Unbundling and Impairment, T. R. Beard, R. B. Ekelund Jr., and G.S. Ford, Journal of Law, Technology, and Policy, Spring 2004.

• Unbundling and Facilities-Based Entry by CLECs: Two Empirical Tests, G. S. Ford and M. D. Pelcovits, July 2002.

Page 44: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Extension: Consolidation and Entry

MARKET L• S = 1,000,000• C = $10• F = $400,000• PM = $100• Competition = 10%• N* = 2

MARKET D• S = 1,000,000• C = $10• F = $100,000• PM = $100• Competition = 10%• N* = 7

Page 45: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

Extension: Consolidation and Entry

MARKET L• N* = 2

MARKET D• N* = 7

MARKET L+D• S = 2,000,000• C = $10• F = $500,000• PM = $100• Competition = 10%• N* = 3

Assumes no scale or scope economies.

Bundling pulls the entire marketto the most concentrated element of it.

Page 46: The Telecom Act, State Action, and the Realization and Prospects for Competition George S. Ford, PhD Chief Economist Phoenix Center George.ford@phoenix-center.org.

How to Use the Theory at Work: An Extension

• Simple economics tells us that a bundled local/LD/Data market will be more concentrated than the long distance market, but potentially less concentrated than the local market.