Top Banner
Dried up livelihoods: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in India A thesis submitted to the University of Manchester for the degree of Doctor of Development Policy and Management in the Faculty of Humanities 2021 Ambarish Karamchedu Global Development Institute, School of Environment, Education and Development
324

The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

Jan 22, 2023

Download

Documents

Khang Minh
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

Dried up livelihoods: The political economy of the

“Liberalised Green Revolution” in India

A thesis submitted to the University of Manchester for the degree of Doctor of

Development Policy and Management in the Faculty of Humanities

2021

Ambarish Karamchedu

Global Development Institute, School of Environment, Education and

Development

Page 2: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

2

Table of Contents

List of figures ......................................................................................................................................... 5

List of tables........................................................................................................................................... 6

Abstract .................................................................................................................................................. 7

Declaration............................................................................................................................................. 8

Copyright statement ............................................................................................................................. 8

List of acronyms .................................................................................................................................... 9

Acknowledgements ............................................................................................................................. 11

Chapter 1 – Introduction .................................................................................................................... 13

1.1 Introduction ................................................................................................................................. 13

1.2 Theorising the Liberalised Green Revolution ............................................................................. 17

1.3 Bt cotton ...................................................................................................................................... 20

1.4 Tubewell irrigation ...................................................................................................................... 22

1.5 Non-farm livelihoods .................................................................................................................. 25

1.6 Telangana case study .................................................................................................................. 26

1.7 Thesis structure ........................................................................................................................... 27

Chapter 2 - Theoretical Framework and Literature Review .......................................................... 30

2.1 Introduction ................................................................................................................................. 30

2.2 Theorising the Liberalised Green Revolution ............................................................................. 31

2.2.1 Environmental setting .......................................................................................................... 39

2.2.2 Credit/debt relations in the Liberalised Green Revolution .................................................. 41

2.2.3 Market intermediaries and governments under agricultural liberalisation ........................... 45

2.3 The Liberalised Green Revolution in India ................................................................................. 51

2.3.1 Cotton in the Liberalised Green Revolution ........................................................................ 58

2.3.2 Bt cotton in India ................................................................................................................. 59

2.3.3 Pro-Bt cotton groups and their detractors ............................................................................ 61

2.3.4 Transitions in groundwater irrigation in India ..................................................................... 66

2.3.5 Tubewells and the Liberalised Green Revolution ................................................................ 69

2.3.6 Individual incentives and institutional failures .................................................................... 71

2.3.7 The Liberalised Green Revolution and the consequences for future agrarian livelihoods .. 74

2.3.8 Non-farm diversification ...................................................................................................... 75

2.3.9 The political economy of the “lost decade” in India and its consequences for rural

livelihoods ..................................................................................................................................... 77

2.4 Conclusion .................................................................................................................................. 79

Chapter 3 – Methodology ................................................................................................................... 81

3.1 Introduction ................................................................................................................................. 81

Page 3: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

3

3.2 Fieldwork preparation and site selection..................................................................................... 82

3.3 Scoping study .............................................................................................................................. 84

3.4 Main fieldwork phase ................................................................................................................. 84

3.4.1 Village profile ...................................................................................................................... 85

3.5 Using ethnography in a mixed method frame to investigate agrarian change ............................ 98

3.6 Positionality ................................................................................................................................ 99

3.7 Methods and techniques used in data collection ....................................................................... 100

3.7.1 Data collection summary ................................................................................................... 101

3.7.2 Fieldwork data collection process ...................................................................................... 102

3.7.3 Fieldwork data summary .................................................................................................... 102

3.7.4 Household surveys ............................................................................................................. 103

3.7.5 Interview household selection criteria ............................................................................... 104

3.7.6 Interviews ........................................................................................................................... 105

3.8 Data analysis ............................................................................................................................. 106

3.9 Ethics......................................................................................................................................... 107

3.10 Limitations of the fieldwork ................................................................................................... 108

Chapter 4 - What are the consequences of Bt cotton farming in the Liberalised Green

Revolution in Telangana? ................................................................................................................. 109

4.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 109

4.2 Economic motivations, ecology, and the switch to Bt cotton ................................................... 112

4.3 The rise of Bt cotton in Telangana ............................................................................................ 117

4.3.1 Cotton outcomes in Kacharam and Telangana ................................................................... 120

4.3.2 The consequences of Bt cotton failure in Kacharam and Telangana ................................. 131

4.3.3 Debt, risk and loss of economic control of rural livelihoods from Bt cotton ..................... 132

4.3.4 Input dealer, moneylender, and extension advisor ............................................................. 136

4.4 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................ 139

Chapter 5 – How has tubewell irrigation changed the political economy of agriculture in

Telangana? ........................................................................................................................................ 140

5.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 140

5.2 Tubewell adoption in the Liberalised Green Revolution in Telangana .................................... 144

5.2.1 The entry of tubewell irrigation in Kacharam .................................................................... 150

5.2.2 The political economy of tubewell failure in Kacharam and Telangana ........................... 154

5.2.3 Intermediaries and governments as key drivers of tubewell failure ................................... 159

5.2.4 The role of private firms and governments in tubewell failure in Kacharam .................... 160

5.3 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................ 175

Page 4: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

4

Chapter 6 – What are the implications of the Liberalised Green Revolution for future

agricultural livelihoods in Telangana? ............................................................................................ 176

6.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 176

6.2 Distress driven farm to non-farm transitions in Telangana and Kacharam ............................... 179

6.2.1 Rural youth and farming in Telangana and Kacharam ...................................................... 181

6.2.2 Contending with precarious non-farm employment in Kacharam and Telangana ............. 185

6.2.3 Risk indebtedness treadmills .............................................................................................. 193

6.3 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................ 196

Chapter 7 - Discussion ...................................................................................................................... 197

7.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 197

7.2 Revisiting and justifying the Liberalised Green Revolution ..................................................... 198

7.3 Technology adoption, agricultural commercialisation, and long-term farming outcomes ....... 202

7.3.1 Explaining agrarian change in the Liberalised Green Revolution in India ........................ 205

7.4 Limitations ................................................................................................................................ 215

7.5 Conclusion ................................................................................................................................ 216

Chapter 8 – Conclusion .................................................................................................................... 217

8.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 217

8.2 Thesis summary ........................................................................................................................ 217

8.3 Comparing and contrasting the thesis findings within India and beyond ................................. 219

8.4 Policy implications for Telangana and India ............................................................................ 222

8.5 Political economy implications for Telangana and India .......................................................... 224

8.6 Policy recommendations ........................................................................................................... 227

8.7 Areas for future research ........................................................................................................... 233

References .......................................................................................................................................... 234

Appendix ............................................................................................................................................ 269

Appendix 1 – List of interviewees .................................................................................................. 269

Appendix 2 – Interview coding example ........................................................................................ 273

Appendix 3 – Interview questions .................................................................................................. 274

Appendix 4 – Household survey questions ..................................................................................... 298

Appendix 5 – Consent form English ............................................................................................... 321

Appendix 6 – Consent form Telugu ................................................................................................ 323

Word count: 77,486

Page 5: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

5

List of figures

Figure 1 - Liberalised Green Revolution Framework ........................................................................... 18

Figure 2 - Private Agricultural Modernisation Framework .................................................................. 33

Figure 3 - Liberalised Green Revolution Framework ........................................................................... 38

Figure 4 - Cotton Yields in India 1950-2019 ........................................................................................ 63

Figure 5 - Cotton Area in India 1950-2019 ........................................................................................... 64

Figure 6 - Irrigation Area by Source in India 1950-2014 ..................................................................... 69

Figure 7 - Map of Telangana................................................................................................................. 86

Figure 8 - Nalgonda District ................................................................................................................. 87

Figure 9 - Kacharam ............................................................................................................................. 88

Figure 10 - Kacharam Village Map - New OBC Colony ...................................................................... 88

Figure 11 - Kacharam Village Map - Main OBC and SC colony ......................................................... 89

Figure 12 - Kacharam Village Map - ST colony .................................................................................. 89

Figure 13 - Caste Diagram of Telangana .............................................................................................. 90

Figure 14 - OBC Colony ....................................................................................................................... 91

Figure 15 - SC Colony .......................................................................................................................... 91

Figure 16 - ST Colony .......................................................................................................................... 92

Figure 17 - Dried Up Bt Cotton Under Red Laterite Soils in Kacharam .............................................. 93

Figure 18 - Tubewell Irrigation in Kacharam ....................................................................................... 94

Figure 19 - Decadal Groundwater Levels in Telangana, 2006-2015 .................................................... 95

Figure 20 - Climate Vulnerability Index Telangana ............................................................................ 96

Figure 21 - Telangana Sorghum and Pearl Millet Net Area 1955-2018 ............................................. 116

Figure 22 - Nalgonda Sorghum and Pearl Millet Net Area 1955-2018 .............................................. 116

Figure 23 - Telangana Cotton Area 1955-2018 .................................................................................. 118

Figure 24 - Nalgonda Cotton Area 1955-2018 ................................................................................... 119

Figure 25 - Celebrity Bt Cotton TV Advert 1 ..................................................................................... 121

Figure 26 - Celebrity Bt Cotton TV Advert 2 ..................................................................................... 121

Figure 27 - Dried-up Bt Cotton Field in Mid Monsoon in June 2019 ................................................ 125

Figure 28 - Telangana Monsoon Rainfall 1951-2016 ......................................................................... 127

Figure 29 - Nalgonda Monsoon Rainfall 1951-2016 .......................................................................... 128

Figure 30 - Telangana Cotton Yields 1970-2018 ................................................................................ 129

Figure 31 - Nalgonda Cotton Yields 1970-2018 ................................................................................. 130

Figure 32 - Local Input Shop in Nalgonda District............................................................................. 138

Figure 33- Dried Up Dug Well in Kacharam ...................................................................................... 145

Figure 34 - Tubewell Irrigation System in Kacharam ........................................................................ 146

Figure 35 - Submersible Pump for a Tubewell ................................................................................... 147

Page 6: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

6

Figure 36 - Telangana Irrigation Area by Source 1955-2018 ............................................................. 149

Figure 37 - Nalgonda Irrigation Area by Source 1955-2018 .............................................................. 149

Figure 38 - Telangana Dry Season Rice Area 1998-2019 .................................................................. 152

Figure 39 - Nalgonda Dry Season Rice Area 1998-2019 ................................................................... 153

Figure 40 - Main Debt Sources in Kacharam ..................................................................................... 161

Figure 41 - A Tubewell Drilling Rig in Mallepally, a Nearby Town to Kacharam ............................ 163

Figure 42 - Tubewell Shops in Towns Near Kacharam ...................................................................... 164

Figure 43 - Tubewell Shops in Towns Near Kacharam 2 ................................................................... 164

Figure 44 - A Price List for Tubewells by Depth ............................................................................... 166

Figure 45 - Deep Tubewell Density Map of India .............................................................................. 168

Figure 46 - Groundwater Electricity Costs by State in India .............................................................. 170

Figure 47 - Cotton Irrigated Area Telangana 1998-2018 .................................................................... 172

Figure 48 - Cotton Irrigated Area Nalgonda 1998-2018 ..................................................................... 172

List of tables

Table 1 - Green Revolution vs Liberalised Green Revolution in India ................................................ 52

Table 2 - Socio-economic Profile of Kacharam .................................................................................... 97

Table 3 - Data Collection Summary ................................................................................................... 101

Table 4 - Fieldwork Data Summary .................................................................................................... 102

Table 5 - Interview Household Selection Criteria............................................................................... 104

Table 6 - Bt Cotton Outcomes ............................................................................................................ 124

Table 7 - Tubewell Outcomes in Kacharam ....................................................................................... 155

Table 8 - Tubewell Deepening ............................................................................................................ 165

Table 9 - Non-farm Incomes ............................................................................................................... 179

Table 10 - Farming Futures Survey .................................................................................................... 182

Table 11 - Net Household Incomes in Kacharam ............................................................................... 191

Page 7: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

7

Abstract

This thesis argues that since the 1980s, agricultural policy in developing countries has

restructured around a new, “Liberalised Green Revolution”, premised on the principles of

economic liberalisation. It retains the same agricultural development model as the public sector

led Green Revolution from the 1960s, linking intensification of soils, crops and water with

higher productivity, economic growth, and the structural transformation of the economy.

However, this time, policy makers have placed the private sector as the focal point initiating

agrarian change, positioning the public sector as facilitators of market intermediaries who lead

the provisioning of inputs, seeds, irrigation, credit, and extension services. Most crucially,

proponents of the Liberalised Green Revolution have targeted the spatial expanse of farmers in

dryland subsistence smallholder settings, encompassing 40% of the world’s area and 1.5 billion

farmers across 55 countries who often subsist on less than $2 a day.

This thesis builds upon theoretical insights from political ecology and agrarian political

economy in theorising the Liberalised Green Revolution. I study the intersection of

environment, credit/debt relations, market intermediaries and governments in an economic

liberalisation context to critique normative agricultural modernisation models, underexplored

together in the literature thus far. Combining these together, I show that in certain contexts,

market intermediary led agricultural intensification in dryland smallholder settings accelerates

indebtedness, stagnating yields and deagrarianisation.

This thesis applies the Liberalised Green Revolution framework to India, where since economic

liberalisation in the 1990s, public sector retrenchment in agriculture has facilitated private

intermediaries to aggressively promote and disburse seeds, inputs, credit, irrigation, and

extension services in markets. Bt cotton, a pest resistant cotton biotechnology brought to India

by Monsanto in 2002, accelerated India to become the world largest cotton grower covering

48% of the global Bt cotton area, cultivated primarily by almost 6 million smallholder farmers.

Similarly, private sector led smallholder groundwater irrigation adoption since the 1990s

propelled India into the biggest groundwater user globally, consuming 37% of global

groundwater. Both agricultural technologies therefore are regarded by proponents as the

apotheosis of private sector smallholder development in India.

The thesis conducted eight months of village level ethnographic fieldwork via 84 interviews

and 151 household surveys in the south Indian state of Telangana, an agricultural backwater

that transformed into a smallholder Bt cotton and groundwater agrocapitalist system within two

decades. Yet, my fieldwork found the Liberalised Green Revolution increased technology

adoption but simultaneously saw stagnating Bt cotton and groundwater irrigation outcomes in

ecologically fragile terrain. Contrary to agricultural modernisation theory assumptions, the

thesis found that input and irrigation intermediaries heavily marketed the capital and resource

intensive technologies on cheap credit to the detriment of smallholders. For the poorest farmers

in Telangana, groundwater well failure rates of 89% and losses from Bt cotton for 65% of

households caused long-term stagnation in farming incomes, chronic indebtedness, and the

eventual abandonment of farming as a primary income. Farmers subsequently became trapped

within risk-indebtedness treadmills, doubling down on technology adoption to earn cash and

repay mounting high interest debts from farming losses. This drove environmental degradation

of multiple well and harvest failures and indebtedness further in agroecologically barren

landscapes that did not bring expected yields.

The chasm between the promise and reality of the Liberalised Green Revolution has dried up

farming as a viable livelihood for smallholders in certain rainfed areas in India amidst a bleak

future scenario of intensifying climatic extremes. It has forced farmers to rely on meagre non-

farm incomes to repay debts and earn incomes at a time when India also faces a jobs crisis in

the non-farm sector.

Page 8: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

8

Declaration

No portion of the work referred to in the thesis has been submitted in support of an application

for another degree or qualification of this or any other university or other institute of learning.

Copyright statement

The author of this thesis (including any appendices and/or schedules to this thesis) owns certain

copyright or related rights in it (the “Copyright”) and s/he has given The University of

Manchester certain rights to use such Copyright, including for administrative purposes.

Copies of this thesis, either in full or in extracts and whether in hard or electronic copy, may

be made only in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988 (as amended)

and regulations issued under it or, where appropriate, in accordance with licensing agreements

which the University has from time to time. This page must form part of any such copies made.

The ownership of certain Copyright, patents, designs, trademarks, and other intellectual

property (the “Intellectual Property”) and any reproductions of copyright works in the thesis,

for example graphs and tables (“Reproductions”), which may be described in this thesis, may

not be owned by the author and may be owned by third parties. Such Intellectual Property and

Reproductions cannot and must not be made available for use without the prior written

permission of the owner(s) of the relevant Intellectual Property and/or Reproductions.

Further information on the conditions under which disclosure, publication and

commercialisation of this thesis, the Copyright and any Intellectual Property and/or

Reproductions described in it may take place is available in the University IP Policy (see

http://documents.manchester.ac.uk/DocuInfo.aspx?DocID=2442 0), in any relevant Thesis

restriction declarations deposited in the University Library, The University Library’s

regulations (see http://www.library.manchester.ac.uk/about/regulations/) and in The

University’s policy on Presentation of Theses.

Page 9: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

9

List of acronyms

Anganwadi – School nutrition programme

BJP - Bharatiya Janata Party

Brahmin – Traditional scholar, priest caste

Bt - Bacillus thuringiensis

CGWB - Central Groundwater Board

DES - Department of Economics and Statistics

DNA - Deoxyribonucleic acid

FC - Forward caste

FDI - Foreign Direct Investment

GDP - Gross Domestic Product

GHG - Greenhouse gas

GMO - Genetically Modified Organism

Golla - Sheep and goat herder sub caste within Other Backward Caste

Goud - Palm wine tapper sub caste within Other Backward Caste

Gram Panchayat – Village council

GSDP - Gross State Domestic Product

GVA – Gross Value Added

Ha – Hectares

ICRIER – Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations

IFI - International Financial Institution

IMF - International Monetary Fund

ISAAA - International Service for the Acquisition of Agri-biotech Applications

Kamma – Traditional cultivating and landlord caste

KCR - Kalvakuntla Chandrashekhar Rao

Kharif – Wet season

Komati - Traditional business and trading caste

Lambadi – Traditional forest dwelling nomad tribe

Page 10: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

10

Madiga - Artisanal tannery, leatherworker and handicraft making sub caste within Scheduled

Caste

Mandal – Sub district administrative division

Mala - Agricultural labour sub caste within Scheduled Caste

MoWR - Ministry of Water Resources, Government of India

NEET - Not in employment education or training

NFHS - National Family Health Survey

NGO - Non-Governmental Organisation

NITI Ayog - National Institution for Transforming India

NSSO - National Sample Survey Office

OBC - Other Backward Caste

OECD - Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

PVC - Polyvinyl chloride

Rabi – Dry season

Reddy – Traditional cultivator and landlord caste

R&D - Research and Development

RQ - Research Question

Sarpanch – Village leader

SC - Scheduled Caste

ST - Scheduled Tribe

TDP - Telugu Desam Party

Thanda - Traditional Scheduled Tribe Hamlet

TRS - Telangana Rashtra Samithi

USA – United States of America

UK – United Kingdom

USD – United States Dollar

UN – United Nations

Velama – Traditional cultivator and landlord caste

WTO - World Trade Organisation

Page 11: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

11

Acknowledgements

This thesis is first and foremost dedicated to the people of Kacharam. Without the insights,

experiences, patience, help, energy, and time you gave to me between January and July in 2019

I would not be writing this thesis right now. You gave me everything and yet I can only give

back my gratitude. To my research assistant and friend Yadagiri, thank you for being the most

patient, helpful, inquisitive, and conscientious research assistant I could ask for. You opened

doors I never could for the fieldwork with your knowledge and your willingness to cater to my

every request (often food based) made my stay in Devarakonda more enjoyable. It became not

just a research trip but a chance to appreciate the culture and people of Telangana I never had

the chance to before, living outside of India for all these years. Finally, in India, I would like

to thank my extended family that took care of me in Hyderabad and Mahabubnagar. Radha

chinnamma and Madhu chinnanna thank you for your love and hospitality. Returning to

Hyderabad and Mahabubnagar each weekend on the three-hour RTC bus journey from

Devarakonda was worth it for the time I spent at home with you all. Thank you for taking care

of me.

I’d also like to thank my supervisors Admos Chimhowu and Ben Neimark for taking me on as

a fresh faced, excitable 24 year old in 2017, and moulding me into a more critical and concise

researcher. Thank you for providing me with excellent, timely, and critical guidance and

feedback throughout the thesis. Thank you, Phil Woodhouse for being a mentor and for your

rigorous and challenging questions and comments in all my annual reviews, it was a great

preparation ground.

Onto my PhD friends, thank you Sawyer, Daniel, Lena, Sarah, Matt, Erika, Amish and Emrah

for sharing the PhD process with me. It was made the more worthwhile for it, for all the highs

and lows we experienced and our discussions over lunches or drinks after work. My time in

Manchester would also not be the same without my Maine Road housemates Ashley and Mike,

thank you for all the chats, walks, movie nights and for making my time at home so fun. A big,

big, thank you also to my pals Max, AQ, Maillie, George, Richie, Jon and Raghav for all the

laughs, nights out, walks, Zoom quizzes, house parties and hang outs in London and

Manchester over the last three and a half years.

Page 12: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

12

Anil, you have been a role model, big brother figure and best friend to me. Thank you for

inspiring me to do the PhD and our time in Glasgow together. Thank you for all the chats we

have had over the years, the advice, and endless laughs. I am so happy to have you always be

there.

My family. Amma, nanna and Neeha you have trusted and supported my every decision on this

path and allowed me to follow my passions in life, unlike the pressures other Indian families

put their children under. This means the world to me I am so lucky. Thank you for giving me

the confidence and determination to do everything to the best of my ability and giving me every

opportunity in life I could have asked for; I promise this is only the beginning.

Finally, Em. It has been a wonderful journey. We have come through so much. Thank you for

all you have done for me and continue to do. For the support, companionship, adventures,

laughter, culinary delights, and most importantly being the biggest believer in my abilities,

especially in these last six months. Here’s to the next step.

Page 13: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

13

Chapter 1 – Introduction

1.1 Introduction

India was ground zero for agrarian change in the 20th century with the implementation of the

Green Revolution (Harwood, 2019). Emerging in response to looming famine and low

productivity agriculture in the 1960s, the Green Revolution involved the Indian government

importing new high yielding wheat and rice seeds and investing in irrigation, inputs, credit, and

extension services in agroecologically favourable regions and rich classes of farmers (Pingali,

2012). The sum of all these factors increased cereal crop yields and economic growth in India,

transforming the country from a food importer to exporter and towards structural

transformation of its economy (Evenson and Gollin, 2003). Similar increases in agricultural

yields and production also took place in rice and wheat in Mexico, the Philippines and Pakistan,

therein providing a blueprint for agricultural development through technology and agrarian

change (Stone, 2019).

The political economy context of agriculture however has changed irrevocably in India and

beyond since the 1980s under the rubric of economic liberalisation, defined as:

“new political, economic, and social arrangements within society that emphasize

market relations, re-tasking the role of the state, and individual responsibility…the

extension of competitive markets into all areas of life, including the economy, politics,

and society” (Springer, 2016: p2).

Facing decades of mounting debt levels, hyperinflation, and balance of payment problems from

oil price shocks, numerous developing countries in the 1980s were forced to seek an economic

bailout by the World Bank and IMF (De Janvry, 2010; Banerjee and Duflo, 2019). In exchange,

governments such as in India agreed to undergo a “structural adjustment” of their economy. In

the agricultural sector this included reducing public sector expenditure in credit, seeds, inputs,

and irrigation provision, alongside trade liberalisation, reorienting cropping patterns to export

cash crops, reducing import tariffs and providing a greater role to the private sector in input

and output markets (Reddy, 2006). In this thesis, I explore the political economy of this new

epoch of the Green Revolution I term the “Liberalised Green Revolution”, a private sector led,

decentralised agricultural modernisation phase since economic liberalisation. Political

economy for this thesis uses Akram-Lodhi’s (2018: p1) definition:

Page 14: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

14

“Changes in: agricultural production, most notably the distribution of assets, the capture

of the benefits of technical change by social forces, and processes of commodification;

the accumulation that emerges out of changing technical coefficients of production; and

the political implications, across a myriad variety of forms, of changing patterns of

production and growth.”

Like the original Green Revolution, the dominant narrative of improving productivity per acre

and output through the application of biochemical intensification, mechanisation, high yielding

seed varieties and irrigation remained (Moseley, 2017). However, under economic

liberalisation, the emphasis has been not only food security but the promotion of commercial

crops for exports to maximise profitability and economic growth towards structural

transformation (Van Der Ploeg, 2014).

Developing country government, development aid donors, bilateral and multilateral

organisations and NGOs have increasingly pivoted towards a private sector lead role in

improving agricultural productivity and economic growth in developing countries (Schnurr,

2019). This is to fill the gap of the government and promote new genetically modified (GM)

seeds, inputs, credit, irrigation, and extension services through decentralised market price

competition between private intermediaries and agribusiness (Zhou, 2010). Most importantly,

proponents have targeted subsistence smallholder farmers (farmers that own less than 2ha of

land) in marginal environments which are afflicted by poor productivity soils, erratic rainfall,

climatic extremes of drought and floods and rural poverty (Tripp, 2001; Pender, 2007). These

areas have been historically neglected in agricultural policy making but are numerically

significant, covering 40% of the world’s geographical area, spread across 55 countries and

supporting 1.5 billion farming livelihoods, the majority of which live on below $2 per day (Dar

et al, 2011; Kumar et al, 2019).

The thesis explores how smallholder farmers in marginal areas in India respond to agricultural

intensification and how the Liberalised Green Revolution shapes rural livelihoods and the

economy. Drawing upon insights from agrarian political economy (Jan and Harriss-White,

2012; Lerche, 2015; Levien et al, 2018) and political ecology (Watts, 1983; Taylor, 2013a,

2013b, Luna, 2020), I contest the assumption by proponents of agricultural modernisation that

agricultural technologies are scale and spatially neutral, working for smallholders as with large

farmers to accelerate agricultural growth (Birner and Resnick, 2010). Instead, I theorise in the

Liberalised Green Revolution framework that agricultural commercialisation by smallholder

Page 15: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

15

farmers in marginal settings can in some instances counterintuitively lead to yield stagnation

and incomes in the long term due to the agroecological unsuitability for intensification.

I apply the Liberalised Green Revolution framework to the case study of India and the two

technologies: Bt cotton, a pest resistant transgenic hybrid cotton variety engineered by

Monsanto, the US agribusiness giant, and approved in India in the 2000s (Flachs, 2016) and

tubewell irrigation, a form of groundwater irrigation that exploded in India since the 1990s

(Lall et al, 2020). These technologies are considered the flagship examples of decentralised

market led technology adoption in agriculture in India by economists and policymakers (Qaim

et al, 2009; Shah, 2010). Used together, the technologies are predicted to maximise yields and

increase profitability in rainfed smallholder settings (Glover, 2010a; Sharma et al, 2018).

Private expansion in India of these two technologies on the back of smallholder adoption in the

last few decades propelled India to become the biggest cotton grower by area and production

globally (Gutierrez et al, 2020), as well as the biggest groundwater user (Gleeson et al, 2016).

To study the political economy of the Liberalised Green Revolution I conducted a mixed

methods ethnographic case study fieldwork consisting of 84 interviews and 151 household

surveys in the state of Telangana, a smallholder semi-arid agricultural state in South India

(Aggarwal, 2008). Telangana liberalised its agricultural economy comparatively rapidly

relative to other states in India in the 1990s, transforming its agricultural growth in the process

(Vakulabharanam, 2005). Liberalisation of credit, irrigation, and input sectors (Mooij, 2007;

Taylor, 2013a) and the explicit promotion of biotechnology by the Chief Minister Chandra

Babu Naidu (Bowles, 2003) brought a private sector driven commercialisation of smallholder

farming via Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation, becoming the second biggest crop by area in the

state in two decades (Kranthi and Stone, 2020) and the single biggest source of irrigation

respectively (Rao, 2014).

This thesis will address the following three research questions:

1) What are the consequences of Bt cotton farming in the Liberalised Green

Revolution in Telangana?

2) How has tubewell irrigation changed the political economy of agriculture in

Telangana?

3) What are the implications of the Liberalised Green Revolution for the future of

agricultural livelihoods in Telangana?

Page 16: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

16

This thesis argues that technology does not exist in the abstract but is saturated with the

prevailing historical, political, social, economic, and geographical contexts (Sultana, 2013;

Glover et al, 2019). Technologies are rooted in material realities of socially differentiated

power relations, and mediated by factors such as gender, class, or social status (Ribot and

Peluso, 2003; Bernstein, 2010). This thesis explains how agricultural commercialisation can

potentially be adverse for smallholder farmers through implementing technological fixes in

contexts far away from the optimal conditions in which they are designed to work in (Glover

et al, 2017). In doing so, I also explore the long term economic and environmental implications

it has on rural livelihoods (Ellis, 2010).

To demonstrate why the Liberalised Green Revolution does not necessarily achieve an increase

in incomes and yields in the long term in marginal smallholder settings, I consider four key

intersecting political economy factors, which have been underexplored in the literature with

some exceptions (Taylor, 2013a, 2013b). First, I show how agricultural commercialisation can

in certain rainfed, semi-arid contexts fail to replicate in agroecological settings featuring

unsuitable soils, climate, and rainfall, and can exacerbate environmental degradation of

farmers’ resource base (Lopez, 2002).

Next, I show how barriers to agricultural intensification in marginal growing areas can become

entwined within credit/debt relations to informal credit and full market prices for financing

agricultural investments, relative to the original Green Revolution (Luna, 2019). In marginal

settings, the high input and production costs of commercial crops may not match the yields to

repay investments on credit (Byerlee et al, 1993). In this instance, rising indebtedness forces

farmers to further intensify their farm operations to earn cash, but also amplifies environmental

risk keeping them within debt relations to creditors in a “reproductive squeeze” (Watts, 1983).

This leaves them few options but to rely on non-farm livelihoods to earn a living and repay

debts (Natarajan et al, 2019), which nuances the linear prediction by agricultural modernisation

theorists linking technology, agrarian change and productivity led non-farm transitions (Chang,

2009).

Third, I posit that in the Liberalised Green Revolution, private intermediaries in many areas

take a lead role in providing credit, inputs, and extension services and output markets to farmers

in a context of a retrenched public sector under liberalisation (Ramamurthy, 2011). Private

market intermediaries for this thesis are placed at the centre of the agricultural

commercialisation process in the Liberalised Green Revolution.

Page 17: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

17

Finally, I show how governments under the Liberalised Green Revolution tend to facilitate

market activity in agriculture as an economic development goal and also intervene with welfare

policies and subsidies to encourage this, for example formal credit disbursal and irrigation

subsidies (Rajan et al, 2020). Putting these four factors together, I construct a political economy

framework of the Liberalised Green Revolution to show why normative models of agricultural

commercialisation need contextualising according to the agroecological scenario for

smallholder outcomes. Political economy and political ecology scholars have studied the link

between technology adoption, environmental risk, and debt (Taylor, 2011; Gerber, 2013;

Ramprasad, 2019), but I further study the lead roles of market intermediaries and governments

in understanding occurrences of unintended negative agricultural technology adoption

outcomes for smallholder farmers, instead increasing non-farm income reliance.

To explore the political economy of the Liberalised Green Revolution, this chapter will be

structured as follows. First, the chapter will overview the theoretical framework of the

Liberalised Green Revolution for the thesis. Following this, the chapter evaluates the political

economy debates on Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation and the implications of the Liberalised

Green Revolution for future agricultural livelihoods. This section also identifies the gaps in

existing debates in the literature and outlines how the thesis contributes novel findings.

Furthermore, I justify the choice of Telangana as a case study state for the thesis, providing a

background of the agricultural context. Finally, the chapter provides a chapter outline of the

subsequent chapters to follow.

1.2 Theorising the Liberalised Green Revolution

Since its implementation in the 1960s, the Green Revolution has served as the blueprint for

public sector led agricultural development in developing countries. The core tenets of this are

increasing yields and production per hectare with the application of biochemical fertiliser,

pesticides, high yielding seeds and irrigation, financed by credit (Patel, 2013). This forms a

crucial part of agricultural modernisation, of rising productivity leading to economic growth

(Musabanganji et al, 2016). A major proponent of this model was Mellor (1976), who explained

that technological intensification in agriculture increased agricultural production and incomes

for farmers, raising consumption demand for non-agricultural goods and services. Over time,

the high productivity and efficiency gains in agriculture would reduce the employment of the

workforce in agriculture and enable a structural transformation of the economy out of

agriculture into industrialisation (Byerlee et al, 2008).

Page 18: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

18

Under the Liberalised Green Revolution since the 1980s, the linear concatenation of

technology, agrarian change and economic growth has continued, but this time, policy makers

have placed the private sector as main implementers of agricultural development (Moseley,

2017). This refers to private market intermediaries of creditors, input firms and agribusiness

(Aga, 2018). Proponents envisage that decentralised private sector market competition, and

greater integration of smallholder farmers into global value chains via commodity crops can

transform the subsistence farmer in marginal areas into agrocapitalist entrepreneurs (Fairbarn

et al, 2014; Levien et al, 2018; Bergius et al, 2018).

Taking a more critical perspective, this thesis engages with agrarian political economy and

political ecology scholarship to point out that smallholder intensification in marginal areas

presents challenges, due to the social, environmental, and economic conditions of technology

adoption (Smale, 2017). I demonstrate that agricultural commercialisation does not always

linearly improve smallholder farming outcomes in marginal settings in the long term. Instead,

long term yields and economic outcomes can sometimes stagnate or decline, leading to higher

indebtedness, environmental degradation and non-farm livelihood dependence. I present the

framework in Figure 1 below.

Figure 1 - Liberalised Green Revolution Framework

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2021)

Page 19: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

19

I locate the causality of why this is the case down to four intersecting factors. The first is the

agroecological constraints of marginal areas of erratic rainfall, drought and flood propensity

and poor productivity soils unconducive to long term intensification (Lopez, 2002). In these

settings, capital and input intensive crops face high risk of harvest failures relative to the

optimal climate and water conditions in which commercial crops are tested in (Glover et al,

2017).

Second, the heighted environmental risk ties with financial risk for the smallholder farmer, as

the capital and input intensive crops are often financed by high interest informal credit, as

smallholder farmers cannot afford cash investments (Jaleta et al, 2009). In marginal settings,

unproductive returns on their investments in unsuitable soil and climate conditions means

farmers often can become indebted to intermediaries. Additionally, faced with rising farming

and household consumption costs in a market economy (Jakobsen, 2019), farmers become

compelled to continue commercial cultivation to recoup their crop debts but, in the process,

can be further entrenched into debt relations the more they intensify. In this particular scenario,

agricultural commercialisation may not create economic growth or rising productivity, but

adverse technology adoption can induce farmers to seek non-farm daily wage labour to cope

with farm losses (Harriss-White, 2020).

Third, under economic liberalisation, the diminished role of the public sector in favour of

market intermediaries makes the latter the lead provider in credit, inputs, irrigation, and seeds

(Srinivasulu, 2015). Often, the motivation of market intermediaries is to maximise profitability

through higher sales of inputs and credit, regardless of the agroecological suitability of the

technologies (Aga, 2019). Agricultural commercialisation occurs through interlocked private

factor markets, where farmers finance inputs on credit, in exchange for purchasing the crop at

harvest at a guaranteed price from the intermediary (Jan and Harriss-White, 2012). In marginal

areas however, this can increase debt and interest repayments for smallholder farmers to

creditors if they achieve low yields relative to investment costs (Taylor, 2011).

Finally, the role of government. On the one hand, governments in agricultural policy emphasise

the market driven agricultural development and a relaxation of regulations in agriculture to

achieve economic growth. Concurrently, for political ends, governments also invest in welfare

programmes and subsidies as palliative measures to keep smallholder farmers afloat through

loan waivers or formal credit disbursal, amidst the market led agricultural intensification

persisting (Vasavi, 2019). Taken together, I argue using the political economy framework of

Page 20: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

20

the Liberalised Green Revolution that agricultural commercialisation in marginal smallholder

settings may potentially lead to adverse outcomes in the long run. This finding is pertinent

given the large populations of marginal smallholder farmers globally that are being integrated

into agricultural commercialisation programmes in contemporary development discourse

(Byerlee et al 2008), for example the attempts to bring a private and GM technology led

“African Green Revolution” to the continent in the last decade (Moseley et al, 2017).

Next, the thesis focuses on two key technologies of the Liberalised Green Revolution in India,

Bt cotton (see Chapter 2 and 4) and tubewells (see Chapter 2 and 5).

1.3 Bt cotton

A key private sector innovation in agriculture since the 1980s has been the ‘gene revolution’

(Parayil, 2003). These comprise advances in genetic biotechnologies for commercial crop

breeding by private agribusiness such as Monsanto, a US agribusiness giant, with the goal of

increasing technology adoption in smallholder contexts, food security and economic growth

(Glover, 2010b; Moseley et al, 2017). Bred for traits including drought and pest resistance and

higher yields, biotechnology proponents envision these crop breeding advances as the future

of smallholder agriculture in developing countries. Planted by almost 17 million farmers across

24 developing countries since 1996 (ISAAA, 2019), the three biggest crops by area in the gene

revolution in developing countries are soy and maize in Brazil and Bt cotton in India (ibid).

India was historically a major of cotton producer globally since the 16th century, but witnessed

a rapid increase in yields and area the 1990s through the introduction of new high yielding crop

breeding techniques (Menon and Uzramma, 2017). Public research organisations created

higher yielding hybrid varieties of cotton in the 1970s in Gujarat, but it only took off in the

1990s (Stone et al, 2007). Liberalisation in agriculture in the 1990s enabled the entry of private

sector input firms that iterated, patented and marketed hybrid cotton to smallholder farmers in

India via private markets, selling thousands of cotton seed varieties (ibid).

India’s membership in the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 1995 also opened the cotton

market in international commodities for farmers (Vakulabharanam, 2004). Supported by

private input firms who sold, marketed and financed cotton investments on low collateral

informal credit to farmers, cotton adoption amongst smallholders began rapidly spreading in

rainfed semi-arid areas of India (Ramamurthy, 2011). By the early 2000s however, hybrid

cotton was afflicted by pest problems, failing harvests, and diminishing returns on investment

Page 21: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

21

relative to pesticide usage, as cotton contributed only 5% of the cropped area in India but used

up 50% of the pesticides of all crops (Flachs, 2020).

As a technological fix for hybrid cotton, the Indian government approved and imported Bt

cotton in 2002, a pest resistant GM cotton strain created by Monsanto. Bt cotton adoption in

India reflected wider GM commercial crop varieties adopted in Africa, South Asia and Latin

America in the 2000s (Kouser and Qaim, 2013; Schnurr, 2019; Norberg, 2020). Due to Bt

cotton, India jumped from 3rd to 1st globally for cotton production at over 6 million tonnes, and

more importantly it was grown by 6 million mostly smallholder farmers in rainfed and semi-

arid states in India (ISAAA, 2019).

NITI Ayog (2015: p21-22), the Indian government’s economic policy thinktank, commented

on Bt cotton’s success and the role of GM crops as a key driver of agricultural growth, stating:

“The success of Bt cotton in India and many more GM seeds elsewhere in the world

testifies to the potential of GM technology in giving a major boost to productivity in

agriculture… As a part of its strategy to bring a Second Green Revolution, India must

return to permitting proven and well-tested GM technologies with adequate

safeguards… as conventional technologies have not helped in raising output to keep

pace with country’s requirements.”

Though Bt cotton brought higher incomes initially for millions of farmers, numerous scholars

in the literature contest its legacy (Stone and Flachs, 2018; Kranthi and Stone, 2020). In

controlled field trials, proponents of Bt cotton found reductions in pesticide usage and costs

and higher yields relative to earlier hybrid cotton strains (Qaim et al, 2009; Gruere and

Sengupta, 2011). Therein, the rapid smallholder adoption of Bt cotton self-evidently showed

smallholder farmer’s desire for higher yields and market prices (Herring and Rao, 2012).

Political ecology and development studies scholars on the other hand pointed to Bt cotton’s

numerous flaws from their ethnographic work (see Chapter 2 and 4). A key problem was the

incentives for intermediaries in promoting and selling Bt cotton within a deregulated market

(Ramamurthy, 2011). Thousands of near identical varieties sold by local input firms and rapid

turnover of seeds made farmers dependent on input dealers for applying the correct quantity of

pesticide and fertiliser, resulting in what Stone et al (2014) called “agricultural deskilling”. For

input dealers, profit incentives saw input dealers provide extension advice prescribing overuse

of fertilisers and pesticides, earning more interest on credit disbursed to smallholder farmers

(Chaudhuri, 2019).

Page 22: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

22

Furthermore, the majority of Bt cotton grown globally was in marginal and rainfed conditions

(see Chapters 4, 5 and 7), which increased financial risk for farmers in being unable to repay

their investments on the input and capital intensive crop (Gray and Dowd Uribe, 2013). For

instance, aggregate figures in adopting countries in India, Burkina Faso and South Africa show

yield increases with Bt cotton levelling off within a decade after being introduced (Schnurr,

2012; Luna, 2020; Kranthi and Stone, 2020). In India, outbreaks of new pests and monsoon

variability in rainfed conditions have stagnated yields in the past 5-10 years, while fertiliser

and seed consumption for Bt cotton keeps increasing (Ramani et al, 2015).

This thesis will address key literature gaps that currently exist on Bt cotton. First, I will

investigate the role of private input dealers and governments in driving unsuitable adoption

choices for Bt cotton with regards to irrigation, debt and cropping patterns. I also look at the

implications for indebtedness from Bt cotton investments and how climate and agroecological

conditions affect Bt cotton yields in India and Telangana in rainfed environments (see Chapter

4 and 5). Finally, the thesis contributes to agrarian political economy literature on Bt cotton by

exploring the long-term economic and social outcomes of Bt cotton adoption for example

increasing non-farm reliance amongst smallholder farmers from unremunerative investments

and rising debts from the crop in rainfed conditions.

1.4 Tubewell irrigation

The second technology of the Liberalised Green Revolution I explore in this thesis is tubewell

irrigation. Groundwater irrigation had existed for millennia in India through rudimentary hand

dug and oxen powered wells that extracted water from underground aquifers (Shah, 2010).

Since the 1990s, liberalisation accelerated the adoption of a new technology, tubewells, that

relied on electric submersible pumps that extracted water from 5x the depths and 3x the acreage

in comparison to hand dug wells (Narayanamoorthy, 2015; MoWR, 2017).

Temporally, tubewell irrigation took off in India since the 1990s via the entry of decentralised

price competition between private irrigation firms (see Chapter 2 and 5) that sold pumps and

pipes, drilled for groundwater, and provided irrigation extension (Birkenholtz, 2007). Price

competition drove down tubewell prices from $10,000 to $1,000 between the 1970s and 2000s

(Freed and Freed, 2002; Jacoby, 2017), in addition to informal credit making tubewells

accessible for smallholder farmers without adequate collateral (Vasavi, 2020). Furthermore,

rural electrification in India also helped create stable power supply to electric submersible

pumps that powered tubewells, amongst other welfare benefits for rural households (Sidhu et

Page 23: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

23

al, 2020). The increase in tubewell area therefore “democratised” irrigation for smallholder

farmers, reducing rural poverty via increasing agricultural productivity in marginal growing

environments (Narayanamoorthy, 2006; Taylor, 2013).

Via these developments, groundwater’s share of absolute irrigated area increased from 5% in

the 1950s, to 67% today (DES India, 2018). Groundwater irrigation is spread over 20 million

wells in 90 million households in India, making it the biggest groundwater user in the world,

making up 37% of global groundwater consumption (Sidhu et al, 2020; Gleeson et al, 2020).

Furthermore, as the MoWR (2017) notes, 87% of all wells in India in 2013 were owned by

smallholder farmers, corroborating the observation of a smallholder groundwater revolution in

agriculture since liberalisation. Globally, groundwater irrigation makes up 43% of the irrigated

area for agriculture (Siebert et al, 2010), the largest freshwater source and used by 2 billion

people (Cuthbert et al, 2019). Between 1960 and 2000, groundwater abstraction triple

worldwide, fuelled by irrigation expansion in India and China (Wada et al, 2012).

However, 66% of the groundwater area in India is in hard rock aquifers (Mukherjee, 2018) (see

Chapters 2, 5 and 7). This aquifer type has low rainfall recharge via percolation, high rates of

runoff and intermittent water availability from the rock substrata (Marechal, 2010), requiring

multiple drill attempts to successfully access groundwater (Hora et al, 2019). For aquifers

groundwater levels to be replenished, the monsoon is a crucial source, making up 67% of total

aquifer recharge (Asoka et al, 2018). In semi-arid areas however, rainfall is erratic and laterite

soil types dominate, which are prone to poor infiltration capacity, meaning much of the

rainwater is lost through evaporation in hot and dry weather (Bassi et 2008). The growth of

tubewells in a scenario of increasing climate and monsoon variability (Mishra et al, 2020) and

the inherent problems from groundwater development in hard rock aquifer areas demonstrates

the hydrogeological risks from tubewell expansion in the Liberalised Green Revolution.

In addition, liberalisation enabled the competition and growth of tubewell firms in India but

this took place in a lax regulatory environment in both electricity and water use for

groundwater. In India today, 85% of the 20 million tubewells in use are powered by electricity

(Sidhu et al, 2020). Despite liberalisation of markets in irrigation, political incentives by state

governments in India heavily subsidised electricity prices to appease groundwater adopters.

This has exacerbated groundwater depletion and electricity consumption in India, forming what

Dubash (2002) calls the “energy-irrigation nexus”. As tubewell expansion in India occurred at

such a fast rate, it became logistically infeasible for governments to administer electricity

Page 24: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

24

charges to farmers, as well as creating political constraints for state governments (Scott and

Sharma, 2009). The overexploitation problems caused by electricity subsidies in India are also

prevalent in South Asia (Shah et al, 2006) and the Middle East (Karimi et al, 2012; Al-Naber

and Molle, 2017).

From the farmers side, the desire to improve profitability from irrigated cash crop agriculture,

availability of cheap credit and nominally “free” extraction costs in India deepened socio-

ecological vulnerabilities from tubewells (Sishodia et al, 2016). In water stressed semi-arid and

hard rock aquifers areas, intensive well drilling competition for scarce groundwater have

created numerous tubewell failures and mounting debts for smallholder farmers in India (see

Chapters 2, 5 and 7). Intensifying droughts and rainfall variability from climate change (Mishra

et al, 2020), markets and public policy have engrained farmers in debt relationships with

creditors. The overreliance on informal credit to finance capital intensive tubewells and cash

crops in rainfed areas have in some instances failed to realise their potential (Taylor, 2013a).

In this thesis, I tackle several gaps in the literature on tubewells. For instance, aside from a few

authors (Taylor, 2013a; Vasavi, 2020), ethnographic work into hard rock aquifers in semi-arid

India has remained underexplored, despite constituting a significant proportion of the

agricultural area in India (Mukherjee, 2018). Finally, the thesis brings new findings on the role

of private irrigation firms in promoting, selling, and providing extension advice on tubewells

to farmers in India, which only a few scholars have studied ethnographically (Birkenholtz,

2007). The limited remit of groundwater departments to dispense water and crop management

advice to farmers has only exacerbated the problem in the Liberalised Green Revolution

(Pahuja et al, 2010), leaving farmers to rely on irrigation firms for help, whose profit incentives

are to increase irrigation sales despite risky hydrogeological settings. The thesis therefore

positions private irrigation firms in enabling the adoption and overexploitation of aquifers

through tubewell expansion in water stressed regions of India (see Chapter 5), in conjunction

with government electricity subsidies.

Page 25: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

25

1.5 Non-farm livelihoods

Despite the agricultural commercialisation in parts of India in the Liberalised Green

Revolution, agriculture as a sector has diminished in its share of GDP, pushing farmers to rely

on non-farm incomes. The primary cause of this non-farm diversification in rural livelihoods

are instances of un-remunerative returns from agricultural intensification in marginal areas (see

Chapters 4, 5, 6 and 7). Tubewell overexploitation for example has forced farmers into greater

indebtedness from agriculture and to rely on non-farm livelihoods (Jacoby, 2017; Blakeslee et

al, 2020). Thereby agricultural employment in India remains high at 43% (DES India, 2018),

but is a form of ‘disguised underemployment’ with farmers relying more on wage labour in

construction and agriculture than cultivating crops (Himanshu, 2019).

In rural India, non-farm incomes make up 65% of household incomes (Chand et al, 2017).

Within rural households, increasing access to education for younger generations has also

propagated a major intergenerational shift in social mobility and aspirations towards non-farm

livelihoods and away from agriculture, owing to their smallholder farmers parent’s risky forays

into agricultural commercialisation (Jakimow, 2014; 2016) (see Chapter 2, 6 and 7). The share

of graduates amongst the educated population in India now stands at over 25%, a figure alike

developed countries (Jose Thomas, 2020). With the encouragement of their parents, attaining

education and exiting agriculture for salaried jobs has been the top priority for many rural youth

in India (Agarwal and Agrawal, 2017).

The bulk of non-farm livelihoods in India however, both to educated rural youth and to farmers,

are informal, seasonal, and insecure (Mehrotra and Parida, 2019). For the older farming

generation, unskilled wage labour is often the only choice available to earn a supplementary

income to agriculture (Jakimow, 2014). For younger, educated generations too, the aspiration

for a formal job has been unfulfilled, as India sits deep within a period of jobless economic

growth since the global financial crisis in 2008 (Mehra, 2019) (see Chapter 6). This has left

rural youth few options but to engage in menial work such as rickshaw driving or drop out of

the labour force altogether (Sanghera, 2019). This phenomenon of youth underemployment

and unemployment amidst demographically young countries is also evident in Ethiopia and

Uganda (Ahaibwe et al, 2013; Bezu and Holden, 2014).

In this thesis I connect agricultural commercialisation with non-farm livelihood transitions, and

subsequently ask how farming households cope given the unremunerative incomes from both.

This thesis also looks at agricultural commercialisation as a driver of intrahousehold aspirations

Page 26: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

26

for social mobility and prosperity, linking investments made in education by farmers for their

children with unproductive technology investments in agriculture (see Chapter 6 and 7). The

thesis therefore looks at how failures and debts from the Liberalised Green Revolution drove

farmers and youth to rely on non-farm livelihoods to survive, but structural labour market

problems in India have left few viable and secure sources of income.

1.6 Telangana case study

To analyse the effects of the Liberalised Green Revolution in India, this thesis uses the case

study of Telangana, a state in South India. I chose Telangana for this thesis as smallholder

intensification has rapidly progressed since economic liberalisation in the 1990s (Aggarwal,

2008) (see Chapter 3). Originally a region within the state of Andhra Pradesh, Telangana was

an historically rainfed and marginal subsistence farming environment (Pingle, 2011), featuring

a semi-arid climate and hard rock aquifers (Sishodia et al, 2017). In 2014, Telangana was

granted independent statehood from Andhra Pradesh, after decades of political agitation and

marginalisation from unequal river water allocation, irrigation expansion and agricultural

expenditure in comparison to the coastal regions of Andhra Pradesh (Reddy et al, 2014a;

Prasad, 2015; Benbabaali, 2016).

In the 1990s, Telangana became the forefront of agricultural liberalisation in India, referred by

the Economist (Taylor, 2011: p489) as “the state that would reform India”. In partnership with

the World Bank, the Andhra Pradesh Chief Minister Chandra Babu Naidu instituted a plan in

1999 called “Vision 2020”, which aimed to transform the state into a service sector economy,

reorient agriculture to commercial biotechnology crops for exports and cut agricultural

subsidies (Bowles, 2003; Mooij, 2007). Adoption of cash crops such as cotton propelled

Telangana’s agricultural growth to 4.5% between 1985 and 2001, higher than the Indian

average during this timeframe (Vakulabharanam, 2005). Driven by the state’s 85% smallholder

population, cotton area increased from less than 13% of the cropped area in the state in the

1990s to almost 40% by 2018, becoming the third largest state in India for cotton (Kranthi and

Stone, 2020) (see Chapter 3).

Similarly, Telangana’s rainfed lands were watered in the Liberalised Green Revolution through

tubewell irrigation, increasing economic growth via irrigated agriculture. As late as 1988, only

25% of Telangana’s cultivated area was irrigated, less than 5% from tubewells (DES

Telangana, 2016). From a policy perspective, expanding tubewells in Telangana democratised

access in irrigation and agricultural technologies through the private sector to smallholders,

Page 27: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

27

maximising economic growth (The Hans India, 2020). By 2018, tubewells became the biggest

irrigation source in Telangana, contributing to 57% of the total irrigated area at 1.2 million

hectares, of which 80% is owned by smallholder farmers (MoWR, 2017; DES Andhra Pradesh,

2006; DES Telangana, 2019a).

Importantly however, agricultural commercialisation created unforeseen effects for rural

livelihoods in Telangana. Telangana has the second highest indebtedness rate amongst

agricultural households in India at 89% in 2013, up from 80% in 2002, with household debts

increasing 7x in this period (Reddy, 2014). This is compared to an average of 57% for India

(Reddy et al, 2019) (see Chapter 3, 5 and 6). Moreover, debt to asset ratios in the state are 6 to

1 and cotton cultivation costs are amongst the highest of any state in India (DES India, 2018),

demonstrating the effects of Bt cotton adoption on debts for rural households in Telangana.

Unremunerative returns, climate change and rising debts from commercial crops has brought

many farmers in Telangana to join nationwide protests against new laws introduced by the

Indian government in 2020 to further deregulate agricultural markets for crops in India (Deccan

Chronicle, 2020). This is in addition to the state having a 25% unemployment rate amongst

youth, the 5th highest in India (Reddy, 2020b). Declining monsoons and groundwater tables in

the last few decades (CGWB Telangana, 2019) have also underlined the agroclimatic and

hydrogeological constraints of agricultural intensification. Telangana is one of the nine hotspot

states in India for highest groundwater depletion (Rajan et al, 2020). The choice of Telangana

as a case study for the thesis is therefore salient in understanding the intersectional political

economy dynamics of the Liberalised Green Revolution of debt, agroecological setting, market

intermediaries and governments and the subsequent long-term rural livelihood implications.

1.7 Thesis structure

Chapter 2 details the Liberalised Green Revolution theoretical framework and literature review.

It theorises the Liberalised Green Revolution as a distinct epoch of agricultural modernisation

relative to the Green Revolution. The chapter then explores the Liberalised Green Revolution

in the Indian context, exploring Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation as flagship technologies of

the era. In the final section of the literature review, I examine the Liberalised Green Revolution

in the context of the increasing role of non-farm livelihoods in rural settings. Tying the

literature together, the chapter identifies gaps and justifies the remit of the research questions

for the thesis.

Page 28: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

28

Chapter 3 details the methodology for the thesis and explains the chosen mixed methods case

study ethnographic approach to the fieldwork. I provide background data for my fieldwork

village Kacharam, unveiling the socio-economic and socio-ecological characteristics of the

village. Next, I explain the process of data collection for the thesis through household surveys

and interviews. The chapter subsequently discusses how the data was analysed using thematic

coding and presented for the analysis chapters. This is followed by a discussion of the ethical

considerations, regarding consent, power, and representation. Finally, the chapter observes the

limitations of the fieldwork process and how I mitigated these.

Chapter 4 answers the question: “What are the consequences of Bt cotton farming in the

Liberalised Green Revolution in Telangana?”. The chapter charts the antecedent conditions of

Bt cotton adoption in Kacharam and the push and pull factors for the transition. It then

examines Bt cotton adoption in the village through debt relations, household incomes and

farmer knowledge. This is entwined with the changing agroecological conditions for the Bt

cotton outcomes and policy context during the Liberalised Green Revolution. The chapter also

explores the intermediary relations between moneylenders, input dealers and farmers as an

explanation for long term Bt cotton outcomes.

Chapter 5 answers the question “How has tubewell irrigation changed the political economy of

agriculture in Telangana?”. The chapter starts with a discussion of policy and farmer

motivations for irrigated agriculture in Telangana and fieldwork village that led to the adoption

of tubewells in the Liberalised Green Revolution. The chapter proceeds to explain the

environmental and economic consequences of tubewell adoption at the village level and in

Telangana, supported by climate and hydrogeological data. The chapter then explores why it

has been adverse, explaining the intersection of cropping decisions, climate, tubewell

exploitation, public policy incentives and intermediary roles of drilling firms in encouraging

the expansion of tubewell overexploitation and well drilling.

Chapter 6 answers the question: “What are the implications of the Liberalised Green

Revolution for the future of agricultural livelihoods in Telangana?”. The importance of non-

farm incomes for households in the fieldwork village and in Telangana is shown to be both a

distress induced decision from Liberalised Green Revolution technologies that have influenced

intergenerational aspirations in educated rural youth to leave agriculture. Next, the chapter

delineates the inadequacy of non-farm livelihoods to make ends meet for rural households and

why this is so, linking both distress in agriculture and non-farm livelihoods to structural

Page 29: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

29

problems in the Indian labour market. The chapter then looks at the strategies employed by

farmers to repay debts and meet their household expenditures considering the joblessness and

underemployment problems faced by both farmers and their educated children.

Chapter 7 summarises the findings from the thesis in Chapters 4 to 6. It discusses the results

from the fieldwork and connects the findings from the three chapters. The chapter not only

discusses the chapters in relation to each other, but also to the gaps and debates in the literature

it fills, contests, agrees, or improves on. Chapter 7 concludes with a discussion on the

limitations of the findings from the thesis and how they were mitigated.

Finally, Chapter 8 concludes the thesis by asking what the empirical findings from the thesis

mean for broader understandings of technology and agrarian change in the wider literature and

policy, detailing the implications of the thesis findings for further research.

Page 30: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

30

Chapter 2 - Theoretical Framework and Literature Review

2.1 Introduction

Chapter 1 introduced the political economy of the Liberalised Green Revolution and outlined

the research questions, debates, and gaps in the literature for the rest of the thesis to address.

This chapter theoretically unpacks the political economy framework in more depth, before

applying it to the case study of India and the adoption of Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation. This

sets up the theoretical and empirical debates and gaps in more detail for the empirical chapters

4, 5 and 6 of the thesis to address.

This chapter examines the political economy processes within the Liberalised Green

Revolution. It nuances the agricultural commercialisation model, which argues that private

sector led agricultural technology adoption and market integration of smallholder farmers

increases yields, incomes and enables the economic transition towards non-farm livelihoods

(Zhou, 2010). Combining insights from agrarian political economy (McMichael, 2009; Jan and

Harriss-White, 2012; Aga, 2018; Sinha, 2020) and political ecology (Taylor, 2011, 2013b,

2020a; Luna, 2019; Ramprasad, 2019; Green, 2019, 2020), I demonstrate that agricultural

commercialisation in dryland smallholder settings does not always deliver long term yield and

income increases. In particular instances I demonstrate, it leads to rising indebtedness and a

distress induced transition from agriculture to non-farm livelihoods as a primary income.

The chapter emphasises that agricultural commercialisation does not exist merely in the

abstract but is embedded in its political economy context (Sultana, 2013). This consists of the

intersection of the agroecological setting (Ruben and Pender, 2004), credit/debt relations

(Ramprasad, 2019) and the role of private intermediaries and governments (Glover, 2007;

Kashwan et al, 2019; Sinha, 2020) in understanding the commercialisation process. I argue that

the Liberalised Green Revolution must be understood as the sum of these parts, a theoretical

novelty in the literature left underexplored. Furthermore, the role of market intermediaries as

lead actors in spreading agricultural commercialisation to smallholder settings has not been

explored in the literature thus far either, with some exceptions (Aga, 2018).

The chapter applies the Liberalised Green Revolution framework to the case study of India,

focusing on agricultural liberalisation since the 1990s and the widespread smallholder adoption

of Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation technologies. These are regarded as the two flagship private

sector agricultural technologies that have contributed to India becoming the biggest cotton

grower and groundwater irrigation user in the world, but for some in the literature has burdened

Page 31: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

31

smallholders with detrimental long term economic and environmental consequences (Gutierrez

et al, 2020; Rajan et al, 2020). Finally, the chapter ends by linking the outcomes of agricultural

technology adoption in the Liberalised Green Revolution and the reliance on non-farm

livelihoods as their primary income, which are themselves often informal and insecure in tenure

(Harriss-White, 2012). Through the exploration of the theory and empirics of agricultural

commercialisation in India and other developing countries, the chapter identifies key gaps to

be addressed by the empirical chapters 4, 5 and 6 in this thesis. The empirical chapters focus

on the south Indian state of Telangana as a case study for the political economy of dryland

smallholder intensification where it rapidly transformed from a rainfed to smallholder

commercial farming state on the back of Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation (Pingle, 2011; Stone

and Flachs, 2018).

2.2 Theorising the Liberalised Green Revolution

This section theorises the political economy of the Liberalised Green Revolution. Since the

Green Revolution in the 1960s, the model for agricultural modernisation in developing

countries has been premised on the application of high yielding seeds, biochemical

intensification via fertilisers and pesticides, and irrigation (Murgai et al, 2001). The goal of

technological intensification is to achieve higher yields from the same land area, improving

productivity per acre, food security and profitability for smallholder farmers (Posani, 2009).

The Green Revolution however was largely delivered through public sector investments in

seeds, inputs, irrigation, and credit and occurred in favourable climatic and irrigated areas

amongst richer classes of farmers (Lerche, 2011).

Over the last three decades, increasing agricultural policy attention has been paid to

smallholder farmers in marginal growing environments, the final frontier to replicate the Green

Revolution in (Moseley, 2017). Marginal growing environments are defined here as arid and

semi-arid agroecological zones that have a low annual average rainfall and short growing

season at 60-120 days per year (Pender, 2007). These farmers are spread across 55 countries in

Asia, Latin America and Africa, where one billion farmers survive on less than 2ha land and

make under $2 per day from agriculture (Dar, 2011). Distinct from the original public sector

driven Green Revolution, policy and government discourse in recent decades has advocated

for the central role of the private sector to deliver agricultural commercialisation, under the

ideological and policy lever of economic liberalisation, what I call the Liberalised Green

Revolution.

Page 32: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

32

Following a number of macroeconomic crises in the 1980s, numerous developing countries in

Africa, Asia and Latin America underwent structural adjustment policies from the IMF and

World Bank (Easterly, 2005). In exchange for economic bailouts, country governments agreed

to reduce public expenditure, privatise public assets, liberalise trade policy and stabilise prices

and inflation (Banerjee and Duflo, 2019). In agriculture, this involved the opening up of

agricultural commodity export markets, removal of public subsidies, incentivisation of cash

crop agriculture, deregulation of foreign direct investment in agricultural technologies and

food, reducing import tariffs and strengthening value chain integration (Ramachandran, 2011).

The basic tenets of these agrarian reforms came from economic theory that lower prices, higher

profits, and greater efficiency are driven by decentralised private market competition and an

undistorted price system (Boudreaux, 2014). The price system was key in determining which

crops to grow and sell on the international market and allocate resources to (Vakulabharanam,

2004). The agricultural sector it was assumed, would increase economic growth through market

integration and commercialisation of cropping patterns. To achieve this, liberalisation in

agriculture included creating greater incentives for the private sector at local, national, and

international levels in seeds, extension services, fertilisers, pesticides, and credit (Sahay, 2010).

This is reflected in the World Bank’s flagship annual report from 2008 (Byerlee et al, 2008:

p25), where it described the new private sector agricultural agenda for reducing poverty and

maximising economic growth:

“Objective 1. Improve access to markets and establish efficient value chains

Objective 2. Enhance smallholder competitiveness and facilitate market entry

Objective 3. Improve livelihoods in subsistence farming

Objective 4. Increase employment in agriculture and the rural nonfarm economy;

enhance skills”

The assemblage of technologies and practises could lead to the growth of the agricultural

economy and towards structural transformation, following agricultural modernisation theory

(Schultz, 1964; Mellor 1976). Akram-Lodhi (1998: p136) defines structural transformation as

the:

Page 33: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

33

“changes in the pattern of production, with a shift from an economy dominated by

agriculture to an economy driven by industrial manufacturing; produced inputs, with a

shift towards capital intensive production techniques and technologies in both the

agricultural and the non-agricultural sectors; employment, with a shift from agricultural

to non-agricultural occupations; and demand, with the formation of a home market

capable of sustaining accumulation”

Agricultural modernisation theorists have pointed to a number of causal processes via

agricultural development towards to wider structural transformation. Carlson (2018) lists the

various roles of agricultural modernisation as providing surplus from commodity exports for

financing imports of goods and services, food supplies for urban centres, investments into other

sectors, and greater domestic market via rising agricultural productivity. Mellor (1976)

explains that increased agricultural production would lead to greater incomes for farmers,

thereby increasing demand for non-agricultural goods and services. This would generate

greater employment in non-agricultural sectors both in rural and urban areas, a spill over effect

caused by rising household consumption expenditure by farmers benefiting from the

agricultural commercialisation and eventual exit from agriculture and into non-farm work

(Chang, 2009). Figure 2 below shows the stylised model of agricultural modernisation.

Figure 2 - Private Agricultural Modernisation Framework

Source: Zhou (2010: p4)

Page 34: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

34

As shown by the diagram, the low input/low output subsistence farming system is transformed

into a high input (capital, technology, fertilisers, energy, water) and high output system of

commodity agriculture (Akram-Lodhi, 2008). Via agricultural modernisation, climate

extremes, pests, disease, and low soil fertility could be overcome by technological innovation

in new chemical fertilisers and insect/drought resistant seeds (Van Der Ploeg, 2014).

Agricultural modernisation by its proponents was a scientific formula that was replicable,

reliable, and produced maximum yield and output of high value agricultural commodities

(Dutta, 2012). The end point for this is structural transformation, which tackles how agriculture

can be restructured to generate economic growth for this transition.

Exactly how this causal process works, the role of smallholder farmers within agriculture in

economic development under capitalism and implications for developing countries has

garnered much empirical and theoretical debate in the agrarian political economy literature.

Key Marxist thinkers such as Lenin and Kautsky (Akram-Lodhi and Kay, 2010b) in the 19th

century envisaged the integration of smallholder farmers into capitalism as the transition from

peasant farming for subsistence into wage labourers. They predicted that farmers would be

dispossessed of their land and sold to larger landholder operations, and they would seek full

time work in daily wage labour activities in cities (Kumar, 2017). Agricultural development

had the potential to differentiate the erstwhile subsistence peasant into a first group that adapted

and competed within agricultural commodity markets for capital accumulation (Carlson, 2018).

The second group however could not survive in market competition and continued with

subsistence farming, but rising cost of living forced them to sell their land and labour to large

farm operations and work in cities. Kautsky (Ghosh and Meer, 2020), coining the term

“agrarian question”, observed that as capital entered agriculture and as urbanisation and

industrialisation proceeded it would lead to the structural transformation of an economy.

A key theorist developing this debate under the context of neoliberalism since the 1980s has

been Byres (1991; 1995; 2009; 2016) with his work on the agrarian question, analysing the

transition of historical nation states in Europe, Japan, and the USA from primarily agrarian

societies to industrialisation. This entails the dynamics behind how and why capitalism

progresses in agriculture historically in generating economic growth for industrialisation and

the differentiated trajectories it has taken in contemporary developing countries (ibid).

Agriculture is a crucial part of the economy as it accelerates economic development and

increases the domestic food supply for urban areas, as well as these surpluses used for

Page 35: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

35

investments into goods and services elsewhere in the economy. For Byres (1995), agriculture

in developing countries today has largely failed to generate the surpluses needed to stimulate

an agrarian transition, and unlike in previous generations such as the Green Revolution,

governments under neoliberalism have not facilitated agricultural development. Traditional

linkages between agriculture and industry have frayed in the political economy of developing

countries today, throwing into focus the implications for smallholder farmer livelihoods as a

result. Byres’ (1991) problematic therefore is why capitalism’s entry into agriculture has not

accelerated this process of dispossession into wage labourers at the same time as agriculture

not producing surpluses for industrialisation.

Nuancing and adding to this debate on agrarian transitions under capitalism, Bernstein (1996;

2004; 2006; 2010) has emphasised a focus away from the linkages between agriculture and

industrialisation, pointing to the dominance of globalisation in determining economic growth

in agriculture. In recent decades under neoliberalism he argues, the relaxation of trade barriers

in agricultural policy in developing countries through the lobbying of the IMF, World Bank

and WTO has incentivised foreign direct investments by the private sector into agriculture. In

this context, Bernstein (2006) explains that globalisation has upended the agrarian question of

capital, namely how agriculture generates the economic growth for industrialisation. Key parts

of globalisation include the increasing organisation of agriculture within the remit of global

value chains, incentivised by harmonisation of trade barriers and liberalisation of agribusiness

in inputs to enter and invest into developing countries to tie farmers into market relations for

both inputs and outputs (Bernstein, 2010). The effects on smallholder livelihoods from

globalisation is in fact greater insecurity and uncertainty due to price fluctuations for

commodity crops and rising cost of inputs backed by credit.

Global capital flows facilitate capital accumulation in agriculture through the import of new

private sector technologies, helping power agricultural growth without domestic investment,

and allowing the import of foods, goods and services (Ghosh and Meer, 2020). This has been

the model espoused by the World Bank within the Liberalised Green Revolution (Byerlee et

al, 2008). Similarly, industrialisation in developing countries has been proceeding without

agricultural development, shifting the focus of the agrarian question from capital to labour

(Akram-Lodhi and Kay, 2010b). A more pressing issue therefore for Bernstein (2004) for

agriculture in the 21st century is the agrarian question of labour, the fates of smallholder farmers

in agriculture in a sector not required for economic development. What has been happening is

the subsumption of agrarian classes into a spectrum of “classes of labour”, all occurring within

Page 36: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

36

commercial agriculture and market relations. The classes of labour created within agriculture

mean that farmers rely more on wage labour than from agriculture, which are because of the

differentiated returns from capitalism in agriculture in the 21st century, where for Bernstein

(2006: p455), farmers:

“especially in the "South," pursue their reproduction, that is, through insecure and

oppressive - and in many places increasingly scarce - wage employment, often

combined with a range of likewise precarious small-scale farming and insecure

"informal sector" ("survival") activity, subject to its own forms of differentiation and

oppression along intersecting lines of class, gender, generation, caste, and ethnicity. In

short, most have to pursue their means of livelihood/reproduction across different sites

of the social division of labour: urban and rural, agricultural and non-agricultural, wage

employment and self-employment.”

In contemporary agrarian development, many smallholder farmers continue to work in

agriculture and non-farm work, not fully transformed into wage labourers despite agricultural

commercialisation under neoliberal globalisation (Kumar, 2017). At the same time, nor has the

linkage between agricultural growth and industrialisation occurred from government policy but

more through private capital entering developing countries. This has according to Bernstein

(2006) circumvented smallholder farmers in favour of larger scale farming by agribusiness,

leaving the former to engage in a fragmented set of rural and non-rural livelihoods to survive

(Levien et al, 2018). Smallholders within capitalist agriculture often persist as “petty

commodity producers”, selling their labour and entering market relations in agriculture but

without adequate income from either. They require a patchwork of livelihood income sources,

of which agriculture is just one.

Differentiation within agriculture in under neoliberalism has been delineated by Akram-Lodhi

and Kay (2010b) into two forms of production systems. First, they explain, are tightly

integrated export commodity farmers, producing high value commodity crops for cash for

foreign markets. This group for example has benefited from liberalisation, as agricultural

policy making has incentivised greater adoption of export commodity crops. The second are

petty commodity producers, smallholder farmers that are integrated into commodity cropping

patterns but do not necessarily gain from market relations like the first group. Instead, the

process of agricultural commercialisation creates differentiation as smallholder farmers.

Page 37: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

37

According to Lerche (2013), differentiation within agriculture has occurred between politically

connected landlord classes that have benefited from agricultural commercialisation through the

private sector, versus smallholder farmers that have seen minimal improvements in their rural

livelihoods (Sinha, 2020). Although many smallholder farmers ostensibly have access to land,

private property, markets and technologies, conditions of work both within agriculture and

outside of it under agricultural capitalism has only intensified the struggle for a decent

livelihood in rural areas in developing countries.

A key reason for the lack progression of agricultural development in poor countries has been

the growing population of smallholder farmers and shrinking land sizes. Without land reforms,

smallholder farmers facing climate change, rising cost of living and high input costs in

agriculture persist in capitalist agriculture without remunerative returns, forced to seek non-

farm livelihoods to supplement their incomes (Carlson, 2018).

In this thesis, I add to and develop a causal process of why smallholder commercialisation has

not proceeded successfully in certain dryland areas in India. In doing so, I critique the

normative assumptions of technology adoption driving increases in yields and incomes for

farmers in all contexts. Utilising insights from political ecology and agrarian political economy,

I argue that agricultural commercialisation must be embedded in the political economy context

of the intersection between the resource intensification in marginal agroecological settings

(Lopez, 2002), the credit/debt relations farmers enter in to finance technologies (Green, 2020)

and the role of market intermediaries and governments in promoting market integration and

technology adoption to smallholder farmers (Glover, 2007; 2010a). These have not been

studied together theoretically in the literature in explaining agrarian change, so I theorise them

within a Liberalised Green Revolution frame. In this, I link agricultural commercialisation with

long term increases in indebtedness, stagnation/decline in yields and incomes due to the

incumbent agroecological setting being unviable for long term intensification. This pushes

farmers towards non-farm livelihoods out of distress from commercialisation, rather than

agricultural commercialisation driving economic growth, as agricultural modernisation

theorists predicted (De Janvry, 2010). This is shown in Figure 3 below.

Page 38: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

38

Figure 3 - Liberalised Green Revolution Framework

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2021)

Additionally, I show that under economic liberalisation markets coexist in pockets alongside

government intervention (Jakobsen, 2018), with each set of actors maximising their own

economic outcomes but potentially making smallholder farmers worse off in two directions.

Agricultural commercialisation was promoted by market intermediaries (Aga, 2018; 2019) in

inherently risky agroecological environments constrained by poor fertility soils, scarce water

resources for irrigation and unreliable monsoons (Taylor, 2013b). Through the application of

resource and capital-intensive agricultural technologies, it only increased incomes in the short

term, in exchange for longer term economic and environmental risk of unsustainable yields for

smallholder farmer adopters.

In the Liberalised Green Revolution, the lead role of market intermediaries in input, credit and

seed provision dispersed power in a decentralised manner to intermediaries, mediated by social

structures of class, caste, and gender (Guerin et al, 2012; Taylor, 2011; Pattenden, 2018). I

show that despite recent development policy efforts to expand formal credit access to the urban

and rural poor through the “financial inclusion” agenda (Demirguc-Kunt and Klapper, 2012),

informal credit remains the dominant source of credit for smallholder farmers in developing

countries (Dermirguc-Kunt et al, 2018). In marginal agroecological settings, intensification did

not often sustain yield and income improvements in the long term for smallholder farmers

Page 39: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

39

(Dhanagare, 2016). These operations were financed by high interest informal credit, so

unremunerative yields and indebtedness locked farmers into debt relations with creditors and

forced them to earn non-farm livelihoods to repay debt obligations (Natarajan et al, 2019).

Furthermore, cultural shifts with economic liberalisation such as the desire for material

prosperity and household consumption also increased the economic obligations for rural

households (Luna, 2019; Jakobsen, 2019). Commodity crops were grown to meet these costs,

but in unsuitable climatic settings, farmers often amplifying environmental risk and

indebtedness again by cultivating these crops (Taylor, 2013b). This maximised profitability for

private intermediaries through sustained input investments and to richer classes who had better

risk bearing capacities to absorb unproductive harvests, plus leveraging favourable credit terms

relative to smallholder farmers (Sinha, 2020). Where the government existed, they facilitated

capital accumulation in markets and intervened in politically expedient ways such as by

expanding subsidies to incentivise unsustainable commodity cropping and retain voting bases

in electoral competition (Sanyal, 2008).

The following sections break down the Liberalised Green Revolution political economy

framework in more detail, discussing agroecological settings and technology adoption,

credit/debt relations and market intermediaries and governments in the process of adverse

agricultural commercialisation.

2.2.1 Environmental setting

A crucial aspect of the Green Revolution in developing countries was the selection of specific

fertile, climatic, and irrigated/stable rainfall agroecological growing environments for

implementing agricultural modernisation (Chambers, 1984; Harris-White and Janakarajan,

1997). Therefore, the material biophysical and geographical setting in which agriculture takes

place mediates beneficial agricultural technology adoption (Myers et al, 2020). Therein, we

begin to see why the Liberalised Green Revolution faces an acute set of agroecological

constraints.

Smallholder farmers in marginal growing areas must contend with not only a low asset and

resource base from their cultivation area but also the biophysical characteristics that bring

added environmental and economic risk in practising commercial farming (Rao, 2008).

Farmers in marginal environments can only rely on a maximum of 120 days a year for a

growing season, that too with variability in monsoon rainfall (Pender, 2007). Within this short

growing season, farmers must negotiate poor productivity soils that can only sustain cultivation

Page 40: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

40

and nutrient uptake for short periods before being prone to long term soil degradation (Lopez,

2002). In addition, semi-arid and arid zones face low and unreliable annual rainfall of 500-

800mm, often concentrated in a short, intense monsoon period of three to four months (Kumar

et al, 2019). Out of this rainfall however, only 30-40% is utilised by crops, with the rest lost to

the atmosphere in evapotranspiration and in the form of runoff overland (Kuchimanchi et al,

2019).

Agriculture in arid and semi-arid areas is regulated by the timing and quantity of rainfall in a

very short window, where any deviation outside of this can render a failed harvest (Taylor and

Bhasme, 2020). Planting too early before the monsoon arrives or leaving the sowing and

weeding of land too late into the growing season present farmers with an extremely small

margin of error in which to plant and harvest a cash crop (Gine et al, 2008). As Bharucha (2019)

describes, in marginal growing environments the determinant of a good season can be down to

missing rain in one part of the village by a few days. In instances where farmers have access to

irrigation, it is often limited to groundwater supplies as smallholder farmers in marginal regions

are often left outside of government canal irrigation projects (Tripp, 2001; Ruben and Pender,

2004). The overall groundwater supplies over time however are regulated by the type and

amount of monsoon recharge. Too little rain can produce insufficient aquifer recharge. On the

other hand, too much rainfall is lost to evapotranspiration and runoff (Lall et al, 2020). This

makes water unable to percolate to aquifers through low storage and infiltration capacity soils

such as laterite red soils, found in large parts of Africa, India, South East Asia and South

America (Mohamed and Paleologos, 2018).

These exogenous risks of low and unpredictable precipitation, drought and poor productivity

soils are only set to be worsened by climate change in the future. Globally, the increased

frequency of droughts and hotter temperatures in semi-arid regions are predicted to reduce

average crop yields by up to 50% (Sharma et al, 2014), destabilising and creating further

uncertainty for farmers to grow crops. As Li et al (2020) explain, increase in temperatures in

marginal agricultural zones globally will exacerbate the severity and frequency of drought

events and extreme rainfall events, with dryland regions set to increase in absolute area by an

average of 17% between now and 2100 (ibid).

Concomitantly, agricultural intensification in marginal settings can in particular scenarios

further undermine the fragile resource base farmers possess. For instance, Sishodia et al (2018)

link the expansion of increased groundwater pumping and irrigation area in India with the long

Page 41: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

41

term well drying in semi-arid areas, so in this instance technology adoption causes groundwater

depletion through pressures on low yielding hard rock aquifers. Furthermore, the biophysical

characteristics of soils in marginal environments mean they are unable to retain nutrients, are

prone to erosion and are low in productivity, limiting the extent to which they can be

intensified. As Lopez (2002: p1216) explains:

“This [soil] fragility imposes restrictions on the pace of intensification…Tropical soils

are not only fragile but they are also subject to threshold effects. That is, if degradation

reaches a certain point, the process accelerates and becomes irreversible…agricultural

intensification without protective investments can induce short term gains at the cost of

rapid degradation of soils, which may lead to great income losses in the long run.”

Contrary to agricultural liberalisation’s proponents, the linear increases in yields and incomes

from agricultural intensification are unlikely to be replicated in marginal areas given the

inherent environmental risks from climate, soils, and water stress that farmers face (Singh et

al, 2018). Not only this, but continued agricultural intensification in these areas can even

permanently degrade the natural resource base of soils and groundwater, leading to long term

losses in income and yields (Poulton et al, 2006; Sharma et al, 2018). For political ecologists,

this shows how the one size fits all approach of transforming agriculture for economic

development cannot be extricated from how the biophysical and geographic setting co-

produces and influences agricultural technology adoption (Schnurr, 2012). Agricultural

technologies cannot be transplanted into nor can they overcome agroecological contexts with

the same expectation of outputs and yields in favourable settings (Kumar et al, 2019).

Nonetheless, the continued pursuit of the intensification model of the Green Revolution persists

in contemporary development discourse as the normative goal for developing countries for the

structural transformation from agrarian society to industrialisation (Moseley, 2017).

2.2.2 Credit/debt relations in the Liberalised Green Revolution

The Liberalised Green Revolution since the 1980s has also brought new opportunities for

smallholder farmers to finance their agricultural investments via credit (Ramprasad, 2019).

Credit is essential for investing in inputs, labour, and irrigation, due to the low asset base and

cash savings held by smallholder farmers in marginal areas (Dorward et al, 2004). In the

Liberalised Green Revolution, seeds, inputs, pesticides, mechanisation, irrigation, and

chemical fertiliser have become externalised to input dealers and market actors, as well as for

commodity markets for sale and export (Bernstein, 2014).

Page 42: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

42

Commodity crops such as soybeans, cotton and tobacco fetch high market prices but also

require high capital investments. Cash crops often require intensive fertiliser and pesticide

applications, requiring the land to remain fallow after the growing season and allowing only

one crop per monsoon season to be grown (Dowd-Uribe and Schnurr, 2016). This leaves the

entire economic return for cash crops for food and household consumption to their successful

harvest in the market. In all this, credit is the crucial lubricant for the commercial agricultural

system and sustaining agricultural investments (Jan and Harriss-White, 2012).

To facilitate the integration of rural livelihoods into markets, policy discourse in the economics

literature has centred around increasing availability and access to formal credit in developing

countries (Demirguc-Kunt et al, 2018). Credit has been channelled through microfinance,

mobile payments, and formal bank account access in developing countries under the “financial

inclusion” agenda (Taylor, 2011; 2012). Between 2011 and 2017, 1.2 billion people in 25

developing countries gained access to one of the three credit sources as part of formal credit

expansion, increasing the share of adults with formal credit access by 9% in this period

(Demirguc-Kunt et al, 2018).

For its proponents, the “financial inclusion” agenda opens credit access to the rural poor with

limited assets and collateral, giving them the ability to invest in their livelihoods through

individual entrepreneurship (Green, 2019). However, Reddy et al (2019) find in the Indian case

that the expansion of formal credit has done little to change the demand for informal credit in

smallholder settings. They explain that that although 79% of people in rural India had access

to a bank account in 2017, only 17% borrowed from banks to sustain their household (ibid).

Other scholars explained that formal credit often accrued to large landowners due to their caste

and class networks with bank officers. Many of these farmers were also moneylenders, who

often used bank loans to reinvest in their informal lending operations back to smallholder

farmers (Guerin et al, 2012; Surendra, 2020).

The Liberalised Green Revolution has brought credit relations to the forefront of rural life.

Theoretically, agricultural commercialisation promises profitability and higher yields from

agricultural technology adoption, enabling farmers to repay creditors and make a profit on their

investment (Harriss-White, 2020). Yet as shown above, in marginal settings, the yield return

on investment is uncertain relative to more favourable environments, often undermining the

fragile resource base farmers must survive on. This has the effect of thereby increasing the

Page 43: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

43

environmental and economic risk from unrealised returns from agricultural commercialisation

(Watts, 1983).

In one instant, credit can transform into indebtedness due to intensification in unsuitable

drought prone areas, erratic rainfall, and climatic change.

As Taylor (2013b: p323) explains:

“On the one hand, taking on loans to rent extra land, purchase inputs, drill wells or settle

existing consumption expenses appears as an immediate and necessary escape from the

constraints placed on marginal households. However, debt simultaneously functions as

a core form of dependency, locking households into relations that provide a source of

ongoing surplus extraction for the holders of capital. These relationships create the

grounds for escalating debt traps, where households take multiple, overlapping loans

without any realistic expectation of being able to pay them off in the medium term.”

In these marginal environments, the more farmers invest in intensification, the greater chance

they fall into deeper debt relations, combining ecological and economic distress cycles to

worsen farmer livelihoods in the long run (Natarajan et al, 2019). In switching to cash crops,

farmers rely on the high market price to repay the debts on investments in seeds, fertiliser,

pesticides, mechanisation, irrigation, and labour (Jakimow, 2014). Yet, commodity crops are

prone to market price fluctuations as well environmental risks (Mosse, 2007), so there is also

a chance it can drive smallholder farmers into further debt.

Hedging their investments and consumption needs on cash crops in volatile commodity

markets in marginal settings may also create dependency on commodification. Political

ecologists such as Watts (1983: p255) call this a “reproduction squeeze”, explaining how the

mutually reinforcing processes of environmental decline and rising indebtedness compel

farmers to deepen their intensification to keep afloat and earn cash for the household,

integrating them further into markets out of desperation for cash and thus repeating the cycle.

The economic and environmental risks from commercial agriculture also bring social

consequences for rural households, having to contend with the social individuation of

indebtedness. As Vasquez (2020) explains from studying Colombian smallholder coffee

commercialisation, the failure to repay debts leads to a loss of face and honour at the village

setting when creditors enforce pressures publicly for farmers to repay (Vasavi, 2009; 2014). In

India for example, Nilotpal (2011) reports how smallholder farmers beholden to debts face

Page 44: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

44

public humiliation, violence, threats for not repaying, disciplining the individual farmer in front

of the whole village (ibid).

Finally, under economic liberalisation in developing countries, credit and cash expenditure in

rural areas have become a fundamental part of everyday life not only in agriculture but for

market relations for everyday household consumption and goods and services (Harriss-White,

2013). Demand for material goods and services such as private school education, TVs,

motorbikes, cell phones, fridges and more expensive weddings in rural areas all feature in rural

household credit and cash needs (Deb et al, 2014; Kingdon, 2020). As Jakobsen and Nielsen

(2019) explain, increasing material consumption in rural households in this era has been driven

by the desire for social mobility for smallholder farmers in emulating higher classes in rural

and urban areas and as a cultural symbol of material success (Bennike et al, 2020). This has

been mediated by the cultural influence and spread of mass media and communications through

TV, internet and radio, alongside greater urban and rural linkages via migrant labour that have

exposed rural households to the cultural osmosis of material consumption (Jodhka, 2014).

The rising economic obligations in debt repayment in social and economic life only further

increase the reliance on quick incomes via commodity cash crop agriculture in marginal

settings to cover household consumption demands (Luna, 2019). This underlines the

intersection of credit/debt relations, agrarian and environmental change for understanding why

the agricultural commercialisation model may not replicate in marginal smallholder settings.

The final two components of the political economy framework presented in this section are the

wider political and institutional factors that farmers interact with in the process of agricultural

intensification. Relative to the previous Green Revolution model of the government leading

investments in seeds, inputs, irrigation, credit and extension services, economic liberalisation

remade the purpose of the state (Sanyal, 2008). Under economic liberalisation, the technology-

led agricultural transformation of smallholder farmers occurred through the lead role of the

private sector and market intermediaries, seen by proponents as key actors in integrating

farmers into value chains and commodity markets (Bergius and Busteth, 2019).

Page 45: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

45

2.2.3 Market intermediaries and governments under agricultural liberalisation

Market intermediaries in agriculture refer to a heterogenous set of actors that operate in both

input and output markets in agriculture, spanning different scales of operations and power

(Lerche, 2015). These include input dealers, irrigation firms, moneylenders, market traders of

agricultural produce and agribusiness. In agrarian political economy literature, market actors

are at times problematically located at the national or global level in the form of hegemonic

corporate agribusinesses forcing smallholder farmers into agricultural commercialisation as

part of a corporate global agenda (McMichael, 2009). Aga (2018) and Sinha (2020) on the

other hand, position intermediaries as locally situated and socially differentiated classes,

ethnicities and castes. They exist frequently as petty commodity producers who operate as

single person small-scale self-employed enterprises in small towns at the rural peripheries,

positioned within an “awkward” class in capitalist development (Harriss-White, 2018).

I argue that this decentralised geographic scale is where the process of market integration has

primarily operated in the Liberalised Green Revolution. In the previous section, I explained

how credit and debt relations were key in understanding the intersection of how debt shapes

commodity cropping patterns in marginal areas. The mechanism through which credit/debt

relations, agricultural intensification and environment is reinforced at the local level is through

intermediaries in interlocked factor markets. This is explained by Jaleta et al (2009: p16) as:

“In some cases, smallholders may not be able to obtain purchased farm inputs like

seeds, fertilizer and other chemicals due to shortage of liquidity or higher transaction

costs associated with these input markets. Moreover, they may not be able to have

access to output markets due to similar or other problems. Interlocked transaction is an

institutional arrangement meant to reduce transaction costs through tying agricultural

credit and input supply to the delivery of product at harvest..”

In the economics literature, interlocked factor markets are an ideal mechanism for smallholder

integration into commodity agriculture (Swain, 2000). According to this view, credit advanced

from input dealers allows farmers to finance their agricultural technology investments without

cash, and the intermediary also provides an output market at a guaranteed price in advance

from the farmer, reducing transportation costs and barriers to entry into output markets (Shami,

2012; Pal, 2015; Khanna and Majumdar, 2020). In summary, interlocked relations are seen by

advocates as mutually beneficial arrangements between intermediaries and farmers to

maximise economic outcomes (Jan and Harris-White, 2012).

Page 46: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

46

Critiquing these assumptions, political ecology and agrarian political economy scholars

contend that interlocking factor markets are disciplining devices trapping farmers into cyclical

debt relations (Gerber, 2013). They argue that interlocking factor markets exacerbate

environmental risks in marginal environments through a “reproductive squeeze” the more they

intensify (Harriss-White, 2020). Farmers typically must pay interest repayments of 36-60% per

year on top of the principal loan for investments. Drought prone, low fertility soils or extreme

rainfall events may diminish yields or even lead to failed harvests, which means the farmer has

nothing to sell to the intermediary at the end of the season (Taylor, 2013b).

With limited other cash earning opportunities to repay their investments, farmers are tied into

repaying the cumulative loan amount in the next season. To meet the household financial

obligations, farmers often reinvest in the same cash crop or sell assets to stay on top of their

debt repayments (Gray and Dowd-Uribe, 2013). This keeps them indebted to intermediaries

until their debt is repaid, and can mutually exacerbate environmental degradation and distress

selling of assets such as land or jewellery to repay debt (ibid). Social differentiation by class

also means that larger farmers often can negotiate prices more favourably with traders, as well

as having access to lower interest credit from formal sources in comparison to informal credit

for smallholders (Ramprasad, 2019; Sinha, 2020).

Finally, the multiple interconnected roles played by the private market intermediaries under

economic liberalisation enables technology adoption in smallholder settings. Under a

retrenched public sector, private intermediaries promote agricultural technologies, supply

inputs, disburse credit, purchase harvests, and provide extension services, being involved at

every stage of the input and output market (Ramamurthy, 2011). Each role the intermediary

plays has the end goal of profit maximisation and maintaining revenue streams from a customer

base of farmers. In Ethiopia for example, Asfaw et al (2012) show how private seed firms had

little motivation to promote local crop varieties that farmers could save seeds for future harvests

and use local inputs within the farm. The interests of private intermediaries are to maximise

sales of inputs, and orient farmers to commodity crops to meet their profit goals (Glover, 2007).

Taking advantage of their monopoly position, intermediaries often market a new seed variety,

pesticide, or fertiliser even if it was unrelated to solving the farmer’s needs (Stone and Flachs,

2018). The dearth of public sector extension services gives farmers few options but to follow

intermediary advice (Aga, 2019). As promoters of agricultural technology adoption and

providers of credit, inputs and extension, intermediaries are frequently the drivers of

Page 47: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

47

agricultural commercialisation of smallholders in marginal environments. In this scenario, the

benefits of technology adoption maximisation accrues to intermediaries more than for

smallholder farmers, who face an intersection of debt relations and environmental risk over the

long term by practising commodity agriculture (Bownas, 2016).

The final part in the political economy framework are governments. In the early phase of

economic liberalisation in the 1980s, policy reforms advocated for the rollback of the state to

allow markets to operate (Easterly, 2005). In agriculture, this included the privatisation and

decentralisation of power away from central governments and to market intermediaries and

corporations (Bernstein, 2014; Fairbarn et al, 2014). Evidence from developing countries

however suggests that government institutions are always involved in the politics of market

reform. Liberalisation exists within interstitial spaces of capital accumulation amidst state

intervention (Kashwan et al, 2019). In the Liberalised Green Revolution, market reform had

proceeded in a complex and uneven manner whereby political and agribusiness elites, as well

as market intermediaries used class, caste, and ethnic coalitions to benefit from agricultural

commercialisation (Sinha, 2020). The outcomes for smallholder farmers on the other hand, is

less of an intentional goal for governments.

As Shah and Harris-White (2011: p17) describe:

“The state has an incoherent project, encouraging small-scale livelihoods, destroying

them, protecting them, ignoring them, or allowing them to survive as an unintended

consequence of other intentions altogether.”

Despite the long term economic and environmental implications from commercial agriculture

for smallholders in marginal settings, economic liberalisation in agriculture has now become

an accepted norm in policy agendas at government levels to integrate farmers deeper into

markets (Levien et al, 2018).

Importantly however, governments simultaneously have intervened with welfare policy

promises for political aims. Vasavi (2019) for the Indian case demonstrates how the state and

central government levels in recent years have pursued an expansive public spending regime

in welfare policies such as cash transfers, loan waivers, minimum support prices and fertiliser

subsidies for farmer constituents. These amount to what Sanyal (2008) calls “welfare

governmentality”, the promotion of welfare to stem agrarian crisis and revolt from smallholder

farmers, whilst maintaining the primacy of marketisation in agriculture as a goal of economic

development. This also obviates any meaningful political reform such as land reforms (Patel,

Page 48: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

48

2013). Agricultural liberalisation therefore is a contradictory mix of governments facilitating

market integration and welfare governmentality instead of the linear replacement of

governments with markets as was initially expected by policymaker proponents (Dhanagare,

2016).

Promoting agricultural commercialisation to resource poor areas of developing countries

imposes a technological fix to agriculture, expecting a linear increase in yields and incomes for

adopting smallholders (Bergius and Busteth, 2019). Focusing on market reforms however

missed out whether areas were agroecologically viable for growing commodity crops (Timmer,

2002). Within delimited contexts described earlier, agricultural commercialisation has

produced rising indebtedness, cultivation costs and unremunerative returns from technology

adoption in developing countries. Farming within an economic liberalisation context has in

many instances ceased to be a primary income for households, instead having to rely on non-

farm incomes for survival. In the literature, this process has been referred to as

deagrarianisation, defined by Hebinck (2018: p3-4) as:

“A process producing social, material, and biophysical conditions that are not

conducive to the reproduction of agrarian livelihoods…agriculture increasingly

provides insufficient income and employment opportunities, pushing people to work

off farm.”

Due to the declining returns from agriculture, Hu and Rahman (2014) explain how agriculture

is now one of many incomes for rural households in contemporary capitalism. Globally, a

survey of 54 developing countries in Africa, Asia, and Latin America (Haggblade et al, 2010)

found non-farm earnings make up 35-50% of rural household incomes. In the literature

however, the focus on deagrarianisation is in relation to the unremunerative returns from

subsistence agriculture (Poulton et al, 2006) and the importance of non-farm livelihoods for

risk diversification and smoothing household cash flows.

This thesis agrees that non-farm incomes are an increasingly important in marginal smallholder

settings but locates the causal mechanism to agricultural intensification pushing smallholder

farmers to rely on non-farm livelihoods out of distress (Harriss-White, 2020). Migration out of

agriculture to non-farm livelihoods is not a function of rising productivity and income from

technology adoption as agricultural commercialisation theorists espouse, or by subsistence

farmers being squeezed out of agriculture. In the Liberalised Green Revolution frame I propose,

it is instead driven by unremunerative returns from agricultural intensification in marginal

Page 49: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

49

settings. In the case of Cambodia for example, Natarajan et al (2019) find that climate change

and the expansion of formal microcredit access has driven cycles of debt bondage and migrant

labour by farmers to repay failed agricultural investments.

By proponents such as the World Bank, formal, salaried non-farm livelihoods were to be the

result of agricultural intensification via increasing yields and incomes. Instead, I argue that in

the Liberalised Green Revolution what can happen is what Singh and Bhogal (2016: p285)

refer to as “distress induced transformation”, defined as:

“crisis driven factors such as falling productivity, increasing costs and decreasing

returns, unemployment and underemployment and indebtedness. These “push factors”

force the agriculture workforce towards non-farm activities…”

Market driven intensification in agriculture can increase cultivation costs without relative

economic returns, leaving farmers to engage in non-farm incomes to meet obligations.

Empirical evidence of agricultural liberalisation in developing countries also refutes the idea

that market integration in smallholder settings improved long term economic outcomes. In a

survey of 20 developing countries in Africa, South Asia and Latin America that underwent

liberalisation by the IMF and World Bank, Easterly (2005) showed that none between 1980-

1999 had improved their rural poverty rates. This was no more evident than in the World

Bank’s own World Development Report (Byerlee et al, 2008: p138) where they reflected on

agricultural liberalisation:

“Structural adjustment in the 1980s dismantled the elaborate system of public agencies

that provided farmers with access to land, credit, insurance, inputs, and cooperative

organization. The expectation was that removing the state would free the market for

private actors to take over these functions . . . Too often, that didn’t happen. In some

places, the state’s withdrawal was tentative at best, limiting private entry. Elsewhere,

the private sector emerged only slowly and partially – mainly serving commercial

farmers but leaving smallholders exposed to extensive market failures, high transaction

costs and risks, and service gaps. Incomplete markets and institutional gaps impose

huge costs in forgone growth and welfare losses for smallholders, threatening their

competitiveness and, in many cases, their survival.”

For advocates of agricultural liberalisation, the lesson to be learnt from this was that farmers

did not integrate into markets enough in agriculture, rather than the failures of it (Dorward et

al, 2004). This shows how economic liberalisation continues as the normative paradigm in

Page 50: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

50

developing countries, navigating its way through policy discourses at the international,

national, and local levels (Aalbers, 2013; Kashwan et al, 2019). Two additional components to

the model of agricultural commercialisation in the last decade have been to bring biotechnology

to smallholder agriculture and to integrate smallholder farmers into corporate value chains via

contract farming as a solution for food security and agricultural growth.

As Moseley et al (2015) observe, biotechnology and corporate value chains have formed the

foundation of an “African Green Revolution” in the last decade, bringing together private

sector agribusiness, philanthropic organisations, and international financial institutions in

support of the initiative (Bergius and Busteth, 2019). The emphasis has been to drive adoption

of GM crops with pest and drought resistance qualities, predicted to improve yields, reduce

pesticide costs, and increase profitability while meeting food security goals (Schnurr, 2015).

Since 1996, GM crops such as cotton, soyabeans, maize and canola have been adopted in 24

developing countries globally by 17 million farmers, over an area of 160 million acres (ISAAA,

2019). Political ecology analyses in South Africa and Burkina Faso however have already

shown that in less than two decades since their introduction, smallholder farmers in semi-arid

areas abandoned Bt cotton (Schnurr, 2012; Dowd-Uribe and Schnurr, 2016). High input costs,

rainfall variability, credit expenses, volatile commodity prices and low quality of the cotton

unsuitable for garment export exhausted GM technologies. Nonetheless, Bt cotton adoption

has spread to six countries in Africa, with Mozambique and Kenya at advanced stages of

approving new drought tolerant GM maize and cassava crops (ISAAA, 2019).

Moseley (2017) summarises that biotechnology and value chains are but new components to

the existing agricultural liberalisation model since the 1980s, continuing to emphasise the

market integration of smallholders and adoption of high yielding seed varieties for maximising

production and profitability. These have also been envisioned as the solution for improving

smallholder farming outcomes in Indian, Latin American, and Asian contexts, demonstrating

the universality of this model for agricultural development in reaching a multiplicity of

agricultural contexts globally, regardless of the outcomes (Glover, 2010b; Norberg, 2020; Luna

2020).

The next section applies the Liberalised Green Revolution framework to the case study of

economic liberalisation in India since the 1990s. I use the case studies of Bt cotton and tubewell

irrigation in semi-arid India to show that technology adoption potentially reinforces long term

indebtedness and stagnation in agricultural incomes from market integration (Blakeslee et al,

Page 51: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

51

2020; Gutierrez et al, 2020). This, combined with rising costs of living relative to agricultural

incomes, has propagated the diversification towards multiple non-farm income sources.

2.3 The Liberalised Green Revolution in India

With the advent of the Green Revolution in the 1960s, agricultural policy making and farming

practices in developing countries underwent a rapid transformation, with the centrepiece being

India (Venkateshwar and Bandopadhyay, 2016). The sum of investments in seeds, inputs,

irrigation, mechanisation and subsidies plus institutional support increased rice and wheat

yields and output per hectare in India, transforming it from a food importer to exporter by the

1980s (Evenson and Gollin, 2003). However, for its detractors, the Green Revolution was

criticised for being concentrated within the richest, highest class/caste farmers (Lerche, 2011)

and geographically limited to 20 agroecologically favourable districts in three states in India

(Harriss-White and Janakarajan, 1997).

The long-term culmination of macroeconomic instability and the failure to repay debts to

international creditors brought India to an untenable economic scenario in 1991 (Banerjee and

Duflo, 2019). Agriculture was seen by liberalisation’s proponents to be afflicted by low

productivity, inefficiency and protectionist trade and price policies by the 1980s, when Green

Revolution yield returns began declining despite fertiliser, irrigation, credit, and power

subsidies making up 10% of agricultural GDP (Mukherjee and Kuroda, 2003; Panagariya,

2004; Fan et al, 2008). In exchange for a $6 billion bailout loan from the IMF to avoid

defaulting, the IMF and central and state governments India set out to liberalise the economy,

most notably the agricultural sector (ibid). Agricultural policy in the 1990s in India irrevocably

changed due to economic liberalisation in India. Agricultural reforms included scaling back

public sector credit, extension, and input subsidies, loosening of foreign direct investment

(FDI) in seeds, opening up export markets and enabling private sector competition in

agriculture (Reddy, 2006).

The Liberalised Green Revolution emphasised a private sector and decentralised market

competition driven agricultural intensification model (Alagh, 2018). The key differentiator was

the reach of agricultural technologies to the poorest of the poor of farmers in marginal regions

of India that were overlooked in the original Green Revolution. Dryland areas in India were

largely left out of the Green Revolution in irrigation and crop investments in favour of more

fertile regions (Bharucha, 2019), yet cover 53% of India’s geographical area, inhabited by

almost 400 million people (Harriss-White & Garikipati, 2008; Todmal 2019). Table 1 below

Page 52: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

52

provides a comparative summary between the Green Revolution and Liberalised Green

Revolution.

Table 1 - Green Revolution vs Liberalised Green Revolution in India

Sources: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019); Vakulabharanam (2004); Ramachandran (2011);

Taylor (2013a); Chaudhuri (2019).

The reduced role of the public sector in the Liberalised Green Revolution created the entry and

competition of private sector intermediaries to take a lead role in credit, irrigation, seeds, input,

and extension services, driving a marketized, price competitive and decentralised form of

agricultural intensification (Srinivasulu, 2015). Millions of smallholder farmers in India

thereby transformed their subsistence cropping systems into commercial agriculture, entering

Green Revolution Liberalised Green Revolution

1960s-1970s 1990s-present

Public sector investments from central and state

governments in seeds, irrigation, credit, input

subsidies and extension services.

Decentralised intermediary led agricultural

intensification through private seed, credit, irrigation,

inputs and extension services

Aim to maximise yields and production of wheat and

rice for food security through hybrid high yielding

seeds, fertiliser, pesticides, and irrigation.

Adoption of Bt cotton, sugarcane, chillies, tobacco for

profit maximisation, exports, through hybrid GMO

seeds, fertiliser, pesticides and irrigation.

Institutional and public policy support to make inputs,

credit, irrigation, extension services work as a sum of

their parts.

Private sector intermediaries each functioning

separately for profit maximisation; adoption of credit,

inputs, seeds, irrigation without complementarity.

Targeted at large landholding classes and castes in

agroecologically favourable regions with alluvial soils

and aquifers and within canal command areas, high

irrigation coverage. Twenty districts in three states in

India.

Targeted at smallholder farmers in agroecologically

marginal regions, making up 86% of all landholdings,

covering 53% of geographical area of India.

High collateral and risk absorption capacity for large

landholders through access to subsidies in irrigation,

seeds and inputs. Low interest loan terms, price

supports from government in mitigating economic

risk from investments.

Low collateral, poor risk absorption capacity for

smallholder farmers. Reliance on high interest

informal credit to finance investments, little support

from government in crop price supports, exposure to

commodity price changes, full market prices to be

paid for inputs, irrigation, seeds.

Government the controller of markets, highly

interventionist in spending 10% of annual agricultural

GDP on subsidies.

Government the facilitator of markets since 1990s, but

in 2000s more interventionist in palliative welfare

policies for electoral support e.g., subsidies in

electricity, expansion of formal credit. Still premising

markets as driver of agricultural growth.

Page 53: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

53

market relations completely for inputs, irrigation, extension, and harvest sale (Aggarwal,

2008). Proponents of liberalisation envisaged the teleological progress of agriculture in India

around three core tenets of privatisation, marketisation and technological intensification to

achieve higher growth, profitability, and yields. This was to culminate in the structural

transformation of the economy from agriculture to industrialisation (De Janvry, 2010). A

crucial part of this was the proliferation of credit in agriculture since the 1990s in India.

Historically in rural India, traditional trading and moneylending castes disbursed informal

credit at 24% to 36% interest rates to smallholder farmers at the village level, due to the poor

formal credit provision by the Indian government and their limited landholdings and collateral

size (Olsen, 1993). Credit was only used in emergency circumstances by pledging their land,

jewellery, or their own labour as exchange between moneylending landlord classes/castes and

lower castes over several years (Breman, 1994; Mohan, 2015). However, between the 1970s

and 1980s, the expansion of credit cooperatives and rural bank branches expanded formal credit

provision from 32% to 63% in rural India (Shah et al, 2007).

Economic reforms in the 1990s saw public sector credit decline again from 64% in 1991 to

57% in 2002, bringing moneylending to the fore again in rural India but expanded in scale and

size beyond the village level. Liberalisation diluted rigid caste structures at the village level

and saw moneylending castes migrate to cities to seek new business activities (Parthasarathy,

2013). This broadened moneylending to lower, Other Backward Castes (OBC) and expanded

the practise from the village level to towns, bringing thousands of providers eager to compete

and provide credit to finance the new private sector led growth in new commercial crop

varieties and irrigation (Vakulabharanam and Motiram, 2014). See Chapter 3 for an

explanation of the caste system in India.

For smallholder rainfed farmers, credit was offered by moneylenders and input dealers with

flexible terms such as minimal collateral requirements and long repayment terms in exchange

24% to 60% annual interest (Taylor, 2013b). In the 2000s, the Indian government reversed

public sector credit withdrawal in agriculture, in recognition of the financial distress and rising

levels of indebtedness caused by the monopolisation of the informal sector, increasing the share

of formal credit from 57% in 2002 to 72% in 2015 (Gulati and Juneja, 2019) as part of its

“financial inclusion” agenda to expand microcredit and bank accounts to the poor (Taylor,

2011; 2012).

Page 54: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

54

In extension services, India mirrored global trends in public sector Research and Development

(R&D) investment slowdowns from the 1980s onwards, as the private sector was privileged as

the key innovator in agricultural technologies (Woodhouse, 2009; Oya, 2011). Agricultural

extension expenditure in India dropped from 7% of agricultural GDP per year in the 1980s to

2% per year between 1990 and 2005 (Sahay, 2010). Overall, real public sector expenditure

rates in agriculture were almost flat in the 1990s at 0.05% per year, in comparison to 3.71%

increase in private sector expenditure in agriculture (Mohan, 2015). In the 2000s, the Indian

government reversed its scaled back role in extension services, admitting in an agricultural

policy review in 2005 that agricultural growth in the 1990s was kept low by “weakened support

systems” and:

“unresponsive agricultural research, nearly broken-down extension [and] inadequate

seed production, distribution and regulation” (Ramakumar, 2009: p25).

In response to this, public spending on extension services doubled between 2007 and 2018,

while fertiliser subsidies increased by 3x in real terms to from $3.5 to $10.5 billion respectively

between 2000 and 2020 (OECD, 2018).

The Indian government’s spending increases in agriculture in the 2000s ostensibly revealed a

change in policy stance to pursue liberalisation less aggressively than in the 1990s (Himanshu,

2019). This was reflected in the government’s acknowledgement that agricultural growth in the

1990s was below expectations (Fan et al, 2008). In 11 rainfed states in India for example (where

>50% of crop area is unirrigated), agricultural growth declined from 3% between 1985-95 to

0.43% between 1996-2005 (Indian Planning Commission, 2008). Following the large increases

in public spending in agriculture in the early 2000s, real farm incomes once again grew by

6.1% per year from 2005-16, compared to only 2.4% per year between 1994-2005 (Chand,

2017).

However, as Jakobsen (2018) argues, although public investments into agriculture have

increased in recent decades, the government has still emphasised agricultural growth through

smallholder integration into markets. Empirical evidence suggests the general shift towards

agricultural commercialisation in India. For example, agricultural commodity exports

increased from $9 billion in 2005 to $33 billion in 2015, as the share of agricultural exports of

GDP in agriculture in India increased from 5% in 1990 to 16% in 2016 (OECD, 2018;

Himanshu, 2019). OECD data also showed that over 80% of the seed market is supplied by the

private sector, including 77% of all fertiliser sales (ibid), reflecting the dominance of the private

Page 55: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

55

sector in agriculture. High value crops such as maize, soybeans, cotton, fruits, and vegetables

all increased in cultivated area and yield in rainfed areas between 1995-2005, while traditional

subsistence food crops such as pigeon peas, millets and sorghum production and yields

declined since the 1990s (Bhalla and Singh, 2009; Kannan and Sundaram, 2011). Consumption

of fertiliser also increased dramatically from 17.3 million tonnes in 2002 to 26 million tonnes

in 2017, reflecting the greater intensity of input application in agriculture (Gulati et al, 2020).

For farmers, agricultural commercialisation presented higher market prices but also increasing

cultivation costs of cash crops relative to traditional crops. For example, subsistence rainfed

crops pigeon pea, sorghum and castor cost $1.50 for pesticides and $3.50 in seed costs per

hectare (Michler, 2020). In comparison, soybeans cost $200 per hectare for pesticides and an

average of $50 per hectare in seed costs (ibid). The profit opportunity for private informal

lenders and input firms incentivised the marketing of agricultural technologies and credit to

smallholders (Bownas, 2016). As these cash crops required intensive application of inputs, it

guaranteed a revenue stream from an untapped market in smallholder farmers who made up

80% of India’s farmers in 1991 (NSSO, 1992).

Alongside agricultural liberalisation, the rural village in recent decades has also undergone

significant cultural and economic change with the entry of market transactions for household

consumption (Jodhka, 2014; Jakobsen and Nielsen, 2019). In rural India, increased rural

household expenditure on durable goods as a share of annual household spending increased

from 2.7% in 1993-4 to 6.1% in 2011-12 (NSSO, 2013a). Moreover, a rise in private

educational opportunities in nearby towns to rural villages also presented new opportunities for

social mobility for rural children but consequently higher household expenditures for

households (Azam et al, 2013; Kingdon, 2020). Longitudinal national household survey data

from agricultural households showed that investments in commercial agriculture and

household expenditure on durable goods, healthcare and education increased household

indebtedness by 7x from $109 in 1991 to $796 in 2020 (Surendra, 2020).

Much of this debt for smallholder farmers has been financed by informal credit, despite the

expansion of formal credit in recent decades. In India, 75% of medium and large farmers use

formal credit as their main source in India, relative to 49% for smallholder farmers (Gulati and

Juneja, 2019). Smallholder farmers borrow from informal creditors at high cumulative interest

rates, financing both agricultural and non-agricultural increases in household spending (Guerin

et al, 2013).

Page 56: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

56

Despite the trajectory in India towards greater smallholder integration into markets and

commercialised cropping patterns, the inherent agroecological fragility of rainfed areas have

in some areas worsened the long term environmental and economic risks facing farmers

(Dhanagare, 2016). Commodity price risks and rising production costs in seeds, fertiliser, and

inputs have often not been met by the promises of higher market prices from high value crops

(Alagh, 2018). This is reflected in the rising indebtedness in smallholder households in recent

decades, increasing from 25% in 1992 to 57% in 2013 (Reddy et al, 2019).

Agricultural commercialisation in India since the 1990s has also had a minimal impact on rural

poverty reduction. As Datt et al (2020) find, agriculture contributed to 9% of the total poverty

reduction between 1991-2012, despite 43% of India’s workforce working in agriculture as a

main income (DES India, 2018). In addition, on average 25% of Indian smallholder farmers

would fall below the poverty line if not for non-farm incomes (Rahman and Mishra, 2019),

indicating heightened indebtedness via market integration without adequate income

improvements from the Liberalised Green Revolution. This is also clear in the composition of

agriculture in household farming incomes declining from 50% to 43% between 2002-16 (Gulati

et al, 2020). What has happened, Lerche (2015) observes, is that agricultural commercialisation

has created winners in richer classes and castes of farmers in favourable environments, while

creating agrarian crisis for smallholder farmers and heightening rural class and caste

differentiation in agriculture.

Finally, the environmental risks from agricultural intensification in recent decades have also

afflicted the sector. 37% of the total land area in India is affected by environmental degradation,

including 25% from desertification from factors such as excessive use fertilisers and pesticides,

over tillage and mechanisation of soils and poor irrigation management (OECD, 2018). Climate

change is also predicted to increase income volatility from agriculture. The frequency of floods

in India tripled between 1950-2012, as well as the severity and occurrences of drought events

(Adve, 2019). Extreme weather events are predicted to affect 25 million farmers in India

through yield losses and harvest failures, with India ranking fifth globally in the Climate

Vulnerability Index (India Spend, 2019).

Rainfall variability, climate shocks, higher temperatures are predicted to reduce agricultural

productivity between 10% and 40% by 2100, translating into 15-25% declines in production in

cash crops such as cotton (OECD, 2018). This is already becoming evident in pockets of rural

India, as yield growth in high value cash crops such as maize, soybeans and sugarcane has

Page 57: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

57

declined from 3% per year from 2000-2005 to -5% between 2011-16 (ibid). Growth rates in

farmer incomes increased at 5.5% between 2005 and 2012, but slowed to 1.36% per year

between 2011-18, as the gross value-added figure of the crop sector increased at only 0.5% per

year from 2014-18 (Himanshu, 2019). This shows how the Liberalised Green Revolution is

already hitting economic and environmental trade-offs from intensification in India, even

before the effects to come from climate change in the future.

Although the government has scaled up the total volume of public sector investments in

numerous areas in the 2000s, the emphasis on market integration, commercial cropping to

transform the Indian smallholder continues in development discourse. This is despite emerging

evidence of higher indebtedness, yield and growth decline, environmental degradation, climate

change and the persistence of rural poverty in marginal and smallholder contexts in parts of

India almost three decades since liberalisation began. Vasavi (2019: p35-41) concludes:

“The hegemony of this ‘productivity-economic growth-high technology’ spectrum that

is the focus of all recent major agricultural and rural policies has several implications

for the viability of India’s agriculture, the sustainability of its ecological base, the social

bases of rural life…Using productivity as the key trope for agricultural, rural and

economic development of the nation has meant the promotion of dominant (external

input and capital-based) forms of agriculture, which defy the established agro-

ecological patterns of India’s agriculture… Agriculture has become, subsequent to such

technological interventions, an extractive economy failing to ensure either ecological

sustainability or economic viability.”

The following sections will explore the case studies of Bt cotton and groundwater irrigation

technologies in India. Under the aegis of the Liberalised Green Revolution, price competition,

informal credit access and marketing by private firms to the poorest farmers in semi-arid India

has propelled the country to become the biggest cotton grower and groundwater consumer

globally within a few decades (Gleeson et al, 2016; Flachs, 2020). Through an exploration of

environmental factors, credit/debt relations, market intermediaries and governments, the

chapter will attempt to understand how and why the technologies were adopted, with what

effect in marginal smallholder settings, and their implications for future rural livelihoods.

Page 58: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

58

2.3.1 Cotton in the Liberalised Green Revolution

Cotton, referred to as “white gold” in India (Shah, 2012) has been heralded by Indian

agricultural policymakers as one of the key private sector success stories in the liberalisation

era. Cotton adoption and production accelerated amongst rainfed smallholder adopters via the

competition and expansion of local input and seed firms in the 1990s and 2000s (Stone and

Flachs, 2018; Chaudhuri, 2019). Today, India is the largest cotton producer by area and

production in the world at 11.6 million hectares (ISAAA, 2019), concentrated in the most

marginal regions of India.

Cotton production in India has a long history, with India being the export leader in the world

for raw cotton and textiles in the 17th century (Menon and Uzramma, 2017). The centrepiece

of the cotton story in India however was not the crop itself, but the politics of the seeds grown

to cultivate it (Kloppenburg, 2005). For much of India’s history, local cotton seeds were the

dominant variety, requiring low input use, saved between harvests each year and resistant to

local pests, but low yielding (Stone et al, 2007). From the 1970s onwards, government efforts

to replicate Green Revolution successes improve productivity in cotton saw the creation of high

yielding hybrid cotton varieties in Gujarat public universities (Stone et al, 2007; 2011).

Towards the late 1980s and 1990s, India pivoted to a more marketised agricultural policy in

seeds as the economy began to liberalise. In 1988, India implemented the New Policy on Seed

Development, a framework for accelerating private sector seed investments, and allowed 100%

FDI in the seed sector (Spielman et al, 2014). Private sector seed firms in India expanded

rapidly in the 1990s as a result. Private firms used the public sector hybrid cotton genetic

material, but iterated on them and bred new varieties for proprietary use and sale (Stone et al,

2014). Private input dealers marketed, sold, and proliferated cotton adoption amongst

smallholder farmers in India (Bownas, 2016), being a key driver of why the crop took off in

the Liberalised Green Revolution. Chapter 4 of the thesis examines this in further detail in the

case of Telangana.

A key aspect of hybrid cotton seeds was that seeds needed to be replaced each year and were

input intensive. Private seed sellers therefore expanded to selling inputs as well as seeds to

maximise profits, giving “pricing control to the seed company and also ensur[ing] a continuous

market” (Siddiqui, 2020: p1). The loosened regulations in the seed market and public sector

extension cutbacks in the 1990s however opened marketing practises such as companies selling

identical seeds under multiple different brands to farmers, expanding their product line and

Page 59: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

59

revenue streams (Scoones, 2006). Decentralised seed firm competition and marketing

increased private hybrid cotton area in India from 33% to 66% of total cotton area between

1996 and 2004 (Stone, 2011).

Hybrid cotton seeds were also much more labour intensive than their indigenous varieties,

requiring the hiring of labour for the various stages of the growing process. In their study of

female cotton labourers in Andhra Pradesh in the 1990s, Venkateshwarlu and Da Corta (2001)

find that over a typical cotton season, hybrid cotton required 2,216 labour days compared to

250 days for indigenous cotton. Much of the labour was done by women and children, chosen

for their compliance to discipline on the farm and ability to work for lower wages (Da Corta

and Venkateshwarlu, 1999). Even despite using cheap and exploitable labour force of women

and children, labour costs were extremely expensive for even landlord classes, in part due to

the labour intensive nature of the crop (ibid).

Private hybrid cotton adoption in India had a number of effects in terms of risk, debt and

vulnerability for the farmer. Although cotton only occupied 5% of India’s total cropping area,

it accounted for around 50% of all pesticide use in the country in the 1990s, as the crop was

prone to pests such as the bollworm (Flachs, 2020). This offset high yields from cotton with

high costs from pesticide use. By the late 1990s, the government sought a technical fix to the

hybrid cotton pest problem via private sector innovation (Ekers and Prudham, 2018), without

changing the dynamics within the seed market, bringing Bt cotton.

2.3.2 Bt cotton in India

Hybrid cotton increased farmer yields, growth, and profitability in India but these were

tempered by rising debts from increasing pesticide usage to handle predation by the bollworm

pest (Ramani et al, 2015). In reaction to this, the Indian government turned to biotechnology

under the “gene revolution” (Parayil, 2003).

Bt cotton emerged out of several domestic and international developments. As far back as the

1980s, the Indian government recognised that biotechnology was a potential replacement to fix

the diminishing returns from Green Revolution technologies (Bhuyan and Pray, 2019). It

created the Department of Biotechnology under the Ministry of Science and Technology in the

late 1980s, a research, policy and regulatory body for the development and approval of

transgenic crops (ibid). Activity on the biotechnology front however did not pick-up pace until

the late 1990s, when the public then private iterations of hybrid seeds were hitting biophysical

Page 60: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

60

limits. As Suresh et al (2013: p45) explain, the Indian government moved to put in place the

Cotton Technology Mission towards the end of the 1990s, whose aim was:

“To increase the production and productivity of cotton by increasing the yield, farm

income, domestic availability and exports by research and technology transfer,

development of infrastructure and technology upgradation and modernization in

processing sector.”

The state’s role was to facilitate capital accumulation, to create the conditions for the market

to find a way to innovate (Jakobsen, 2018) and fix the pest problems afflicting hybrid cotton

through biotechnology. The market leader globally in cotton biotechnology development was

Monsanto, a US based agri-business firm. In the 1990s they developed and marketed Bt cotton,

a genetically engineered cotton strain containing a soil bacterium that bound to bollworm pest

DNA and killed it after the cotton leaf or bud was ingested (Flachs, 2016). In 1998, Monsanto

bought a 26% stake in Mahyco, an Indian seed firm, forming the joint venture Monsanto-

Mayhco Biotech for use of existing Indian hybrid cotton strains to breed Bt cotton for India.

This also ensured easier regulatory approval through Mayhco’s extensive government

connections (Bownas, 2016). By 2005, Bt cotton was approved for sale across India, despite

much protest and controversy by anti-GM groups (Scoones, 2006). Bt cotton was marketed as

solving the bollworm pest predation and bring higher yields, lower pesticide cost and greater

farmer profitability compared to non-Bt strains (Herring and Rao, 2012). In exchange, Bt

cotton required higher seed and fertiliser costs, which were entirely borne by the farmer

(Ramamurthy, 2011).

In just under two decades, Bt cotton covered 95% of India’s cotton area (Kukanur et al, 2018)

across 10 cotton growing states. This occurred through a decentralised network of private

sector seed firms promoting, marketing, and selling Bt cotton directly to farmers in thousands

of towns and village peripheries across India (Chaudhuri, 2019). Since Bt cotton was

introduced, India went from the 4th highest cotton producer and area in the world to the 1st,

making up 48% of the global Bt cotton area and increasing yields from 300kg/ha to 542kg/ha

between 2000 and 2018 (Sharma et al, 2018; Siddiqui, 2020). Bt cotton in India however is

deeply contested, making India the centrepiece of ongoing GM debates in the world (Scoones,

2008). Stone (2012) characterises these debates as the battle over the “construction of facts”,

as each side validates their victory through various institutional, ideological, and

methodological means (Glover, 2010b; Schnurr, 2017; Luna and Dowd-Uribe, 2020).

Page 61: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

61

2.3.3 Pro-Bt cotton groups and their detractors

Bt cotton evangelists comprised of industry and government agricultural scientists, economists,

biotechnology firms, and policy makers in India and the USA (Gutierrez et al, 2020). The main

arguments in favour of Bt cotton were the resistance to bollworm pests, reducing pesticide

burdens compared to non-Bt cotton (Dowd-Uribe, 2017). Gruere and Sengupta (2011) found

income increases of 54%, reduction in pesticide costs by 45%, and a 39% increase in yield

relative to non-Bt cotton, in exchange for 15% higher cultivation costs. Studies using a six-

year panel data in four states in India between 2003-8 also found a 24% increase in yield per

acre, 50% higher profits and 52% pesticide reduction, which caused an 18% increase in

household consumption expenditure (Qaim et al, 2009; Kathage and Qaim, 2012). Rainfed Bt

cotton also produced higher yields than rainfed non-Bt cotton in Telangana, while irrigated Bt

cotton showed 35% higher yields than irrigated non-Bt cotton (Dev and Rao, 2007).

Bt cotton supporters concluded that smallholder farmer outcomes and welfare improved with

Bt cotton (Herring, 2008). Evidently, as Herring and Rao (2012) argue, there was no reason for

6 million smallholder farmers in India to adopt Bt cotton if it did not bring yield, pesticide, and

profitability improvements. Bt cotton was the best of a limited set of options for smallholders,

and so farmers were willing to take on high capital and debt risks in exchange for higher profits

(Wield et al, 2010). Finally, the willingness of smallholder farmers to adopt Bt cotton for its

supporters was proof of their agency in improving their own material conditions and aspiring

for a better life through these new technologies (Shah, 2012; Luna, 2019).

Bt cotton’s most ardent opponents were anti-GM groups. These comprised of local and

international NGOs, consumer activist groups, academics, and farmer groups in India, using

organised protests, reports, articles and studies by journalists and NGOs to oppose Bt cotton

(Scoones, 2006). Fischer et al (2015) point out that anti-GM groups warned of higher corporate

concentration within the seed industry, higher input prices, intellectual property regimes that

made it illegal for farmers to save and reuse seeds and takeover of agriculture via corporate

globalisation (Herring and Paarlberg, 2016). The aim for anti-GM groups was not only to

change the public sentiment against Bt cotton in India and win the moral debate, but to unveil

the reality of Bt cotton adoption for farmer welfare (Scoones, 2008).

Fears by anti-GM groups of corporate takeovers were mixed. For instance, most Bt cotton sales

happened through Monsanto-Mahyco licensing their seeds to 42 national level private sector

seed companies in India (Chauduri, 2019). These firms then resold their seeds to thousands of

Page 62: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

62

local affiliate input and seed firms, who sold to the farmer directly (Ramamurthy, 2011). Bt

cotton increased the private sector’s influence, but by expanding the total size of the market

and increasing decentralised competition between thousands of local seed firms, rather than

concentration of multi-national firms (Spielman et al, 2014).

Another critique by anti-GM groups was that intellectual property traits of Bt cotton made it

illegal for farmers to save, exchange and reuse seeds year on year. Yet, as Monsanto engineered

Bt cotton used existing private hybrid cotton strains from Mahyco, it just represented a

continuation of proprietary hybrid seeds in India from the 1990s by private seed firms

(Siddiqui, 2020). The real problem therefore was not intellectual property, but the lack of

regulation in the seeds industry, evident since the 1990s with cotton. Local seed firms were in

fact the propagators of Bt cotton expansion, rather than the much feared national and

international seed firms by the anti-GM groups (Stone and Flachs, 2015; Chaudhuri, 2019).

Finally, a set of scholars in academia have argued for an intermediate approach to evaluating

Bt cotton in India. Their main argument is the acknowledgement that Bt cotton does bring

profitability in some cases, but little is discussed about the political economy context of how,

where, and why it was adopted and who benefits (Dowd-Uribe, 2017; Smale, 2017). The first

factor studied by this group was the implications of liberalisation and the private seed market.

Upon Bt cotton’s introduction in India in 2002, the explosion of competition, light regulation

and growth of the private seed sector created 1128 varieties of Bt cotton as of 2015, covering

95% of all cotton area in India (Kukanur et al, 2018).

The rapid expansion of the seed market and promotion by seed sellers led to “agricultural

deskilling” of the farmer in making seed selections, unable to comprehend the rapid changes

in the market. Input dealers marketed new seed fads through word of mouth and promoting the

seeds to the large and high caste landowners in a village, who then spread it via word of mouth

(Flachs, 2016). Maertens (2017) reveals through her research in Maharashtra that after these

first adopters grew Bt cotton in the village, 91% of lower caste and class cotton farmers copied

them and adopted Bt cotton within a year. Farmers relied on a hierarchical form of social

learning from input dealers and first adopter farmers, replacing any individual learning,

iteration, or experimentation (Stone et al, 2014). The constant disruption, unrecognizability,

and proprietary nature of Bt cotton seeds prevented farmers from learning how to cultivate Bt

cotton crops (ibid).

Page 63: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

63

Ethnographic fieldwork from Andhra Pradesh also revealed that seed dealers made 10-15%

profit margin on each seed packet sold, incentivising them to maximise seed and input sales

(Bownas, 2016). Input dealers promoted higher pesticide and fertiliser use for guaranteed

higher yields (Stone and Flachs, 2018). Furthermore, as Chaudhuri (2019) explains, national

seed companies that distributed and licensed the seeds offered sign on bonuses for new seed

dealers to enter the market. Names for the seeds like Diamond and Force and different colours

for the packets were all ways in which seed firms differentiated and market identical seed types

(Scoones, 2006).

The marketing and sales tactics in Bt cotton to maximise farmer adoption at any cost runs

counter to proponents’ claim that adoption was the farmer’s agency based on its profitability

and self-evident performance (Wield et al, 2010). Farmers trusted the authority of input dealers

given the absence of the government in regulation or extension services in Liberalised Green

Revolution. This thesis also identifies a gap of the third role input dealers played, as not only

salesperson and extension advisor but also credit provider, helping to finance Bt cotton for

smallholders. In Chapter 4, the thesis explores the reinforcing debt relations and Bt cotton profit

maximising extension advice given by input dealers as the key factor for farmer indebtedness

and heavy investments in inputs. Moreover, scholars also questioned the yield improvements

in Bt cotton claimed by pro-Bt groups, a key selling point of the crop. Figures 4 and 5 below

shows cotton yields and area in India from 1950-2019, with the period after 2002 representing

the Bt cotton era.

Figure 4 - Cotton Yields in India 1950-2019

Source: DES India (2018; 2019b)

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

19

50-5

1

19

52-5

3

19

54-5

5

19

56-5

7

19

58-5

9

1960-6

1

19

62-6

3

19

64-6

5

19

66-6

7

19

68-6

9

19

70-7

1

19

72-7

3

19

74-7

5

19

76-7

7

19

78-7

9

19

80-8

1

19

82-8

3

19

84-8

5

19

86-8

7

19

88-8

9

19

90-9

1

19

92-9

3

1994-9

5

19

96-9

7

19

98-9

9

20

00-0

1

20

02-0

3

20

04-0

5

20

06-0

7

20

08-0

9

20

10-1

1

20

12-1

3

20

14-1

5

20

16-1

7

20

18-1

9

Yie

ld (

Kg/H

a)

Year

Page 64: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

64

Figure 5 - Cotton Area in India 1950-2019

Source: DES India (2018; 2019b)

In the Bt cotton era, Figures 4 and 5 show that yields markedly improved between 2002-7, but

stagnated since, even though Bt cotton area continued to increase. Also, India still has one of

the lowest average yields in the world at 563kg/ha compared to the world average of 784 kg/ha,

bettered by many non Bt-cotton countries (Sharma et al, 2018). Kranthi and Stone (2020)

summarise that since 2005 when Bt cotton yields almost peaked, per hectare seed costs

increased by 78%, pesticide costs increased by 158%, fertiliser costs increased by 245% and

labour costs increased by 275% due to also increases in agricultural labour wages via

MNREGA (ibid). Glover (2010b) argues that whilst Bt cotton may have reduced pesticide

usage and controlled the bollworm pest problem, new secondary pests have emerged in recent

years which have been the limiting factor for yields. Advice from input dealers to continue

over spraying and fertilising has led to farmers increasing their financial risk and indebtedness

with limited yield improvement (Gutierrez et al, 2018).

Furthermore, 66% of Bt cotton area was in semi-arid, low rainfall environments with

unpredictable monsoons. This thesis explores the gap of why Bt cotton is rainfed and argues

how this is the key factor in its failure in adopting areas. In Chapters 4 and 5 of this thesis, I

argue that the role of the input dealer as salesperson and extension advisor increased Bt cotton

adoption in semi-arid areas under worsening monsoons, despite the risks to the farmer of

growing such a capital and input intensive crop in these conditions. As Smale (2017) concludes,

rather than problems with Bt cotton, the bigger factor in causing the failure of Bt cotton has

been social and agroecological context of technology adoption for smallholder farmers.

0

2000000

4000000

6000000

8000000

10000000

12000000

14000000

1950-5

1

1952-5

3

1954-5

5

1956-5

7

1958-5

9

1960-6

1

1962-6

3

1964-6

5

1966-6

7

1968-6

9

1970-7

1

1972-7

3

1974-7

5

1976-7

7

1978-7

9

1980-8

1

1982-8

3

1984-8

5

1986-8

7

1988-8

9

1990-9

1

1992-9

3

1994-9

5

1996-9

7

1998-9

9

2000-0

1

2002-0

3

2004-0

5

2006-0

7

2008-0

9

2010-1

1

2012-1

3

2014-1

5

2016-1

7

2018-1

9

Hec

tare

s

Year

Page 65: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

65

Hybrid and Bt cotton were key Liberalised Green Revolution technologies, spreading to rainfed

and semi-arid areas of India and adopted by millions of poor and marginal farmers. In the

1990s, liberalisation in the cotton sector proliferated private sector competition, as input firms

marketed and sold high yielding cotton seeds, while also selling complimentary inputs and

disbursing credit. Hybrid seeds promised higher yields but were not reusable year-to-year,

requiring annual reinvestments and intensive input requirements. In the long term, it was the

lack of pest resistance to the bollworm that drove up harvest failures and pesticide costs with

hybrid cotton by the end of the 1990s.

Turning to the market to fix the mess they had a role in making through deregulation (Ekers

and Prudham, 2018), the Indian government pursued private sector biotechnology innovation

in cotton. This led to Monsanto’s Bt cotton entry into India in 2002, a genetically modified pest

resistant cotton seed variety. For supporters, evidence showed that Bt cotton reduced pesticide

costs, leading to higher incomes versus non-Bt cotton. Furthermore, the uptake by smallholder

farmers was an active desire by farmers to adopt this new technology and improve their

profitability. More scrutiny over time however has revealed many negative effects of Bt cotton.

Non-reusable traits from hybrid cotton were retained, so farmer deskilling persisted and

accelerated as private competition in seeds increased rapidly, creating thousands of

unrecognisable, unverified, and increasing volume of seed brands.

Incentives to maximise seed and input sales at any cost for the input dealer drove over

fertilisation and pesticide use, locking in farmers to increasing input costs and debts taken from

input dealers on high interest informal credit. The adoption of water intensive Bt cotton in

rainfed and semi-arid areas also exacerbated farmer risk. Ultimately, Bt cotton yields stopped

increasing after 2007, while fertiliser use, cropping area and pesticide use all increased.

Expectations of capital, water and input intensive technologies to succeed in semi-arid

environments has instead created insecurity through Bt cotton in the Liberalised Green

Revolution. In this section, I also identified several gaps in the Bt cotton literature to investigate

in Chapters 4 and 5, namely why it is rainfed, the credit and debt relations between input dealers

and farmers, and the triple role of input dealers as creditor, salesperson and extension advisor.

The story of groundwater irrigation, the second flagship Liberalised Green Revolution

technology, shall be explored in the next section, revealing many of the same patterns as Bt

cotton, but with distinctive differences.

Page 66: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

66

2.3.4 Transitions in groundwater irrigation in India

For much of India’s history, irrigation was the remit of the government, pursued via dams and

canals (Mollinga, 2008). Between 1950-1993, 85% of all government spending on irrigation

projects were dedicated to surface irrigation, and India also received $33 billion in World Bank

loans for dam construction projects during this period (Shah, 2010). Yet, the majority of India

was still left untouched by public sector irrigation as millions of farmers were located outside

of canal command areas, with access to water only possible from the monsoon, or from

groundwater from underground aquifers (Vasavi, 2020). Since the 1970s however, a series of

policy changes and the liberalisation of the irrigation sector has enabled the vast expansion and

affordability of groundwater irrigation in India, making up 84% of all new irrigated area created

in India in this time (Pahuja et al, 2010). Compared to canals and dams, groundwater irrigation

provides private and decentralised access to water, requiring no additional infrastructural

investment other than an energy supply, pipes, and a pump (Lall et al, 2020). The most

significant of these has been the tubewell, a technologically advanced form of groundwater

irrigation that relies on submersible pump system that draws water from hundreds of feet

underground powered by electricity or diesel supplies (MoWR, 2017).

Tubewells were an import from the UK during the British colonial era in the 19th century,

promoted and sold by the Indian government to wealthy farmers to irrigate commercial crops

through favourable loans and subsidies (Subramanian, 2015). However, as a share of the total

irrigation area, tubewells only contributed to 10% of the total irrigated area in 1970, a big

reason down to their prohibitive cost of $10,000 (Freed and Freed, 2002; DES India, 2018).

In the 1990s, liberalisation induced a shift from public sector surface irrigation to a private and

decentralised “democratised” groundwater irrigation (Taylor, 2013a). As with Bt cotton, the

growth of informal credit also paved the way for private sector firms to enter market

competition in tubewell irrigation. In the Liberalised Green Revolution, market competition

and profit incentives for irrigation firms maximised farmer adoption in semi-arid environments

by smallholder farmers who were a large target market and had access to credit to invest in the

technology (Vakulabharanam, 2004). Overall, groundwater irrigation created 3x more gross

irrigated area since the 1970s than surface irrigation created in the previous 150 years (Shah,

2009). So far however, the literature has paid little attention on the role of private irrigation

firms as drivers of tubewell expansion in India. Chapter 5 of the thesis explains the key role of

private irrigation firms in the tubewell political economy in the Liberalised Green Revolution.

Page 67: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

67

The shift for Shah (2010) was from a supply driven, government led and managed irrigation,

to a demand driven, smallholder led and managed, private, and decentralised irrigation.

Smallholder farmers in semi-arid areas financed irrigation on informal credit, and benefited

from price competition of tubewell pumps in 1990s, coming down from $10,000 in the late

1970s to $1,000 in 1999 (Alary, 1999). The transformation of rainfed agriculture into irrigated

agriculture also shifted cropping patterns towards cash crops, increasing rural incomes and

helping to reduce rural poverty in India (Narayanamoorthy, 2015). Today, tubewells make up

51% of total irrigated area in India at 31 million hectares (DES India, 2018). Moreover,

groundwater irrigation helps produce 49% of the rice and 72% of wheat grown in India,

(Smilovic, 2015), playing a pivotal role in agricultural production.

However, 66% of the tubewell area is underlain by hard rock aquifers (Mukherjee, 2018) and

feature a semi-arid climate, where rainfall is scarce. In hard rock aquifer areas, groundwater

availability is highly unpredictable, and aquifers have a low storage capacity, so groundwater

is found in limited quantities in interstitial cracks and fissures and in the rock, requiring

multiple drill attempts to successfully extract groundwater (Marechal, 2010; Fishman et al,

2011). Low aquifer storage can be depleted by erratic monsoon seasons and intensive drilling

if the extraction rates exceeded rates of recharge from rainfall (Asoka et al, 2018). In semi-arid

hard rock areas therefore, aquifer overexploitation becomes worse as the number of farmers

adopting tubewells increases, intensifying demand for the same aquifer (Jacoby, 2017). In

addition, the high capital investments for the irrigation system are often by financed by

smallholder farmers through informal, high interest credit, whose repayment structures rely

upon irrigated cash crop agriculture (Taylor, 2013a).

Drill failures and aquifer overexploitation has often pushed farmers into simultaneous

indebtedness from crop and irrigation investments in semi-arid areas. This cycle of risk and

debt in certain cases drove farmers to drill further in a chance to strike water and recoup their

losses, perpetuating the problem once more (Blakeslee et al, 2020). Climatic trends in the future

in India are likely to see increased drought events and shorter monsoons, which will only add

to the biophysical barriers of tubewell expansion in semi-arid and hard rock aquifer regions

(Hora et al, 2019). In the literature however, few authors have explained how farmers came to

drill wells so intensively. In Chapter 5, I show the pivotal role of informal credit and private

irrigation firms acting as salesperson and extension advisor and encouraging intensive drilling,

as with input dealers and Bt cotton in Chapter 4.

Page 68: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

68

Equally, tubewell overexploitation has also been driven by political economy contradictions in

Indian policy making. In India, common law from the British colonial era allowed private

landowners unlimited water rights to groundwater under their land, whereas the aquifer is a

common pool resource for all users (Sekhri, 2011). In the Liberalised Green Revolution, this

incentivised farmers to drill for water in a zero-sum game on their farm, creating competition

for a finite water source in a deregulated drilling economy (Shah, 2010). Exacerbating the

problem further, the bureaucratic and transaction costs to register, price and police individual

farmers and wells for their water use has become a logistical impossibility in India (Mukherji

and Shah, 2005), a country with 20 million wells owned by 90 million households (Sidhu et al,

2020).

Electricity policy has also created similar perverse incentives for groundwater overexploitation

in India. In the 1960s, governments could charge market rates for electricity as enforcement

was manageable with a low number of irrigation users. However, rapid groundwater adoption

made the costs of metering, regulating, and collecting electricity revenues at the individual

farmer level untenable (Shah et al, 2012). The growing groundwater farmer base also created

a powerful voting bloc who advocated for subsidised electricity. So, to solve the political and

governance problem, many state governments since the 1970s enacted a subsidised flat tariff

rate, which removed the price signal for farmers in regulating their electricity and groundwater

use (Sishodia et al, 2016).

Even in the liberalisation era, these policies persisted alongside liberalisation elsewhere in

agriculture as electricity subsidies increased from $4.4 billion per year in 1996 to $11.4 billion

in 2013, accounting for 25% of the national fiscal deficit (Sidhu et al, 2020). Chapter 5

addresses a gap in the literature by linking both irrigation firms and electricity subsidies in

driving up well densities and overexploitation through creating a zero-marginal cost for drilling

groundwater.

This section has shown tubewell extraction must be understood as a hybrid of ecological and

political economy factors in India (Swyngedouw, 2009). The next section explores the political

economy of why the expansion of tubewell irrigation has taken place the way it did in India.

Page 69: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

69

2.3.5 Tubewells and the Liberalised Green Revolution

Groundwater irrigation access in India has been critical for millions of farmers outside of canal

and dam catchment areas, who reside in low rainfall semi-arid areas. By the early 1990s,

economic liberalisation policies incentivised private irrigation firms to market and maximise

irrigation adoption by smallholder farmers in semi-arid areas and hard rock aquifers, financed

by the informal credit (Vasavi, 2020).

Figure 6 shows the growth of tubewells in India from 1950-2014, as tubewells overtook canals

in 1995 to become the dominant irrigation type, making up 51% of total net irrigated area in

India or 31 million hectares as of 2018 (DES India, 2018). For its role in agricultural growth,

Shah (2010) estimates that groundwater irrigation contributes to $8.6bn per year in agricultural

productivity.

Figure 6 - Irrigation Area by Source in India 1950-2014

Source: DES India (2018)

Much of the growth in tubewell irrigation has been in hard rock aquifer environments. These

are characterised by heterogeneity in groundwater availability, low recharge capacity, low

storage capacity, and deeper depths required to locate reliably yielding aquifers in the rock

(Shah, 2012). The dominant regions with hard rock aquifers are also in semi-arid climates.

Semi-arid climates are often drought prone and exhibit unreliable or failing monsoons in timing

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

195

0-5

1

195

2-5

3

195

4-5

5

195

6-5

7

195

8-5

9

196

0-6

1

196

2-6

3

196

4-6

5

196

6-6

7

196

8-6

9

197

0-7

1

197

2-7

3

197

4-7

5

197

6-7

7

197

8-7

9

198

0-8

1

198

2-8

3

198

4-8

5

198

6-8

7

198

8-8

9

199

0-9

1

199

2-9

3

199

4-9

5

199

6-9

7

199

8-9

9

200

0-0

1

200

2-0

3

200

4-0

5

200

6-0

7

200

8-0

9

200

9-1

0

201

1-1

2

201

3-1

4

Mil

lio

n H

ecta

res

Year

Canals Tanks

Tubewells Other Wells

Other Sources

Page 70: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

70

and length, typically also having higher evapotranspiration rates than precipitation received,

therefore a low recharge of rainfall into aquifers (Deb et al, 2014). These are precisely the areas

where intensive competition, expanding area, increasing numbers of adopters and harsh

climatic conditions have caused water tables to deepen (Jacoby, 2017). To find a working

aquifer source requires drilling hundreds of metres and multiple times until successful, costing

up to $1,000 (Blakeslee et al, 2020).

The density of numbers of tubewells in hard rock aquifer regions has created what Shah (2010)

terms “zero sum competitive deepening”, where the groundwater scarcity has made farmers

double down on well drilling, in the process deepening water tables and drying out aquifers.

Kumar et al (2011) estimate that in Andhra Pradesh, rising tubewell densities have reduced the

average irrigated area created by tubewells from 1.8ha in 2001 to 1.07ha in 2011. Often,

smallholder farmers grew cash crops to repay their irrigation investments and maximise

returns. Yet in a semi-arid competitive drilling environment, this further deepened indebtedness

and risk if both crop and irrigation system fail (Taylor, 2013a). Chapter 5 uncovers the

additional role of irrigation firms in encouraging drilling and rising tubewell densities by

smallholder farmers and the debt implications this has.

One key technological change under the Liberalised Green Revolution were the expansion of

submersible pump technologies, a superior pump technology that was capable of pumping

water from up to 300m, up to 10x previous pump technologies (MoWR, 2017). In the 1990s,

market competition from private irrigation firms drove down the price of submersible pumps

(Narayanamoorthy, 2015). Fieldwork from Punjab by Tiwary and Sabatier (2009) found that

submersible pumps became ubiquitous for tubewell users in the 1990s and 2000s because of

declining water tables, necessitating deeper wells to be drilled. While submersible pumps

enabled farmers to tap into deeper groundwater tables, in hard rock areas, this only exacerbated

tubewell overexploitation.

As early as the 1960s, hard rock aquifers were recognised as unsuitable for intensive

groundwater development (Rao, 2014). A major problem in semi-arid and hard rock aquifer

areas is the availability of groundwater confined to minimal spaces, cracks, and fissures in rock

formations, requiring multiple attempts to drill a successful well. Kumar et al (2011) also note

that red laterite soils in semi-arid areas have a poor infiltration capacity and the depth of the

water tables in hard rock aquifers make recharge and percolation from rainfall difficult. Bassi

Page 71: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

71

et al (2008) estimate that only 4-10% of total rainfall in hard rock areas flows back to recharge

aquifers.

Tubewell overexploitation has been a persistent problem for adopting farmers in semi-arid hard

rock areas. This has been evident not only in India, but globally too, in Iran, Jordan, Mexico

and Pakistan (Shah et al, 2006; Karimi et al, 2012; Al-Naber and Molle, 2017; Hoogesteger,

2018). In a study in the state of Karnataka in India, Blakeslee et al (2020) found that drilling

wells cost double the median household cash income of smallholder farmers, and that wells on

average failed within 5 years of drilling. Households that had failed wells had to sell assets or

fall into debt, having to offset agricultural losses through non-farm incomes (ibid). Other

scholars found in India that if their wells failed, the sunk costs were too high to revert to rainfed

agriculture, inducing further tubewell and crop investments to recoup losses (Ferrant et al,

2014).

2.3.6 Individual incentives and institutional failures

The limits to growth of tubewell irrigation in the Liberalised Green Revolution cannot simply

be attributed to the underlying biophysical characteristics of adopting areas. Resource

degradation in marginal areas are determined by an interlocking set of physical, social,

economic, and demographic factors that explain why farmers practise these livelihood

strategies (Kuchimanchi et al, 2019). In India’s political economy in the Liberalised Green

Revolution, the outcomes of aquifer depletion can also be explained by policy decisions at the

state and national level. As Sultana (2013: p343) notes:

“Technologies and the social formations they are embedded in reflect the political

rationality and development trajectories of the state. No water technology is neutral; it

is saturated with historical, geographical, political, and social imaginaries… Water

technologies are developed, rolled out, fought over, reformed, dismantled, and

redesigned in various ways through the social histories of place, networks of power,

and discourses of development.”

Reflecting the above passage, tubewell irrigation expansion was a function of the political

economy dynamics in India. One the one hand, the opening of irrigation and credit markets

incentivised irrigation and informal credit expansion by private intermediaries in the

Liberalised Green Revolution, occupying the space left by the state in irrigation infrastructure

expansion. At the same time, the government incentivised groundwater development through

the electricity subsidy lever.

Page 72: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

72

Hoogesteger and Wester (2015) delineate intensive groundwater development into two

interrelated factors: the first being the material reconfiguration of rainfed agriculture from a

subsistence cropping system to a irrigated commercial agricultural system. The second are the

policies and policy discourse that enable the first. In India, this has centred around electricity

subsidies.

Initially, in the 1960s and 1970s, electricity for groundwater was charged at a metered rate,

with monitoring and revenue collection managed by electricity boards at the state government

level (Mukherji and Shah, 2005). As tubewell expansion rapidly accelerated into the 1980s and

1990s, increasingly powerful farmer lobbies pressured state governments to subsidise

electricity tariffs in groundwater irrigation (Dubash, 2002). Facing pressure from this new

major political constituency, several state governments in India set a fixed tariff for electricity

(Sidhu et al, 2020). This move was also forced for state governments facing huge transactions

costs to monitor, price, regulate and collect electricity revenues in a rapidly rising tubewell

boom (Scott and Shah, 2004).

Hence, a fixed rate tariff was the solution to a political and governance problem. Unfortunately,

this move was financially disastrous and politically irreversible, as the cost of maintaining and

increasing electricity generation for a mass of tubewell users caused state governments to face

huge losses from subsidising electricity (Rajan et al, 2020). Yet, political pressure from farmers

meant they could not increase tariffs (Shah et al, 2012). For instance, in 1998, as Taylor (2013a)

explains, the Andhra Pradesh TDP Chief Minister, backed by the World Bank, proposed

electricity pricing for groundwater as part of liberalisation reforms, but thousands of farmers

protested throughout the state to force a policy reversal back to subsidised electricity by 2000.

By the next elections state elections in 2004, the ruling party lost, and the winning Congress

party gained power based on their electoral promise of 7 hours of free electricity per day for

groundwater users (ibid).

Even at a time of fiscal restraint elsewhere in the Liberalised Green Revolution, electricity

subsidies for groundwater irrigation continued to drain on public finances (Siegfried et al,

2010). Between 1960-2016, electricity consumption for groundwater increased 235x,

compared to total electricity usage increase of 77x in the same period (Sidhu et al, 2020).

Moreover, groundwater governance of water has had similar difficulty in enforcing regulation

and pricing as electricity (Sekhri, 2011). Groundwater is a common pool resource, but

following a colonial era law in India from the 1860s, farmers have unlimited access to

Page 73: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

73

groundwater on their private land (ibid). Additionally, it is impossible to control the flow of

groundwater given the heterogenous availability of water within fissures and differing depths.

This makes it difficult to exclude farmers who overexploit as there is no way of disaggregating

which farmer uses more than others (Scott and Sharma, 2009), incentivising a zero sum well

competition amongst users.

For farmers, the near zero cost of electricity and limited regulation incentivised greater

groundwater use, driving them to competitively drill for tubewells to recoup their investments

in inputs and irrigation technologies financed by high interest informal credit (Taylor, 2013a;

Sishodia et al, 2017). In hard rock aquifer environments, farmers already faced scarce

groundwater resources, so the added desperation to repay debtors means farmers often doubled

down on tubewells to their detriment of well failures (Blakeslee et al, 2020).

Although the Indian government has been active in electricity subsidy policy, provision for

extension services for irrigation has been absent. Pahuja et al (2010) note that groundwater

irrigation departments in India have long been underfunded, plagued by vacancies and their

remit being limited to technical groundwater surveying and mapping, rather than sharing

groundwater management advice with farmers (Mukherji and Shah, 2005). In Chapter 5 of the

thesis, like with Bt cotton, I show how the Liberalised Green Revolution political economy has

left the extension advice to the irrigation firms, who are also the irrigation salesperson. I

demonstrate how the monopoly of irrigation firms encouraged tubewell expansion in

Telangana despite the unsuitability of the climate and aquifer conditions.

Climate effects are predicted to increase rainfall intensity, droughts and shorten monsoon

seasons, alongside uncertainty in timing, length, and reliability of rainfall in the monsoon

(Mishra et al, 2020). As 67% of aquifer recharge in India comes from rainfall (Asoka et al,

2018), climate change is likely to exacerbate harvest and aquifer failures and the desperation

of drilling behaviour if groundwater is scarcer (Ferrant et al, 2014). Rajan et al (2020) also find

that groundwater electricity consumption alone contributes to 10-12% of India’s annual GHG

emissions, concentrated in nine states where electricity is subsidised the heaviest and where

groundwater decline is the highest in India.

Overall, in India, populist political incentives, poor regulation capacity, hydrogeological and

agroecological conditions and private markets created tubewell expansion and

overexploitation. In the Liberalised Green Revolution, market forces and public sector

withdrawal saw private irrigation firms promote water intensive crops and tubewells to

Page 74: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

74

smallholder farmers in semi-arid and hard rock areas with little risk bearing capacity. Irrigation

investments required high capital investments reliant on informal credit. In many cases

however, the risks and investment were increased without return, as farmers faced repeated

well failure and indebtedness cycles due to the fragile ecological settings where tubewell

expansion occurred. Therein, agricultural intensification in the Liberalised Green Revolution

took place in a significantly riskier environmental and socio-economic setting relative to the

Green Revolution.

Within this, the government was involved in a limited but consequential way. Subsidised

electricity increased competition for groundwater in a water scarce aquifer landscape. Farmers

drilled for tubewells multiple times to find a working water source, maximising their water

consumption to recoup farm and irrigation investments. The burden of electricity subsidies

alleviated expenses in the short term for farmers but exacerbated overexploitation of aquifers,

and drove up fiscal deficits at the state level. The chapter also unveiled a few gaps to be

explored in later chapters. The final section of this literature review will explore the

consequences of the Liberalised Green Revolution for rural livelihoods in India.

2.3.7 The Liberalised Green Revolution and the consequences for future agrarian

livelihoods

In part due to the political economy conditions of the Liberalised Green Revolution,

dependence of farmers on agriculture in India has decreased in the 21st century, placing greater

emphasis on non-farm incomes to supplement agriculture (Rahman and Mishra, 2019). In rural

India, this move towards non-farm livelihoods is also part of the structural transformation of

the economy in India out of agriculture and into higher value-added sectors such as service

work (Lanjouw et al, 2013). This is especially the case within the younger, educated

generations in farming households who have sought out social mobility and a life outside of

labour intensive agriculture by their parents (Jakimow, 2014; Agarwal and Agrawal, 2017).

However, the Indian labour market and economy has also faced non-farm stagnation in the last

decade, creating what economic commentators’ term as the “lost decade” for India’s economy

(Kaul, 2019). Since the financial crisis in 2008, job creation has been slow and limited to low

paid and low skilled construction or agricultural labour, unable to meet the formal, city-based

job demands of young, educated rural jobseekers (Mehra, 2019). Economic growth has not

been in pace with formal job creation, causing high rural underemployment and unemployment

Page 75: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

75

amongst educated youth (Jose Thomas, 2020). This section explores the political economy of

rural livelihoods in India in the Liberalised Green Revolution era.

2.3.8 Non-farm diversification

Diminishing land sizes, rising costs of cultivation, debt, climate risk and output and price

instability have made farmers diversify into non-farm work in the Liberalised Green

Revolution to supplement agricultural incomes (Sanghera, 2019). Agriculture is increasingly

the remit of older, lesser-educated generations of rural households, whereas educated younger

generations have favoured non-farm livelihoods (Hebinck, 2018). Agriculture remains a

primary occupation in India for 43% of India’s workforce (DES India, 2018) but is often

unremunerative for smallholder farmers.

On the other hand, for those classes of farmers that have benefited from capitalism in

agriculture, such as larger landholding classes, they have mobilised politically and

economically to diversify and reinvest their agricultural surpluses into different industries. In

India, large landholding classes in the 1960s and 1970s that benefited from improved

agricultural productivity in the Green Revolution in rice and wheat crops diversified into real

estate, agricultural trading, politics and moneylending (Damodaran, 2008; Parthasarathy, 2013;

Prasad; 2015).

This has not been the case however for most smallholder farmers who dominate Indian

agriculture. Farmers with 1 ha or less in India has increased from 69% to 75% of the total

landholdings between 2002-3 and 2012-13, despite only increasing their share of total land

owned from 23% to 29% in this period. This indicates that the vast majority of farmers in India

are cultivating smaller landholdings over time despite increasing in absolute numbers (NSSO,

2014a). It also means that the growing rural workforce are not being absorbed into urban sectors

fast enough, so many farmers remain in agriculture as a form of disguised unemployment due

to the unremunerative returns (Carlson, 2018). In India, between 1993-4 and 2017-18, absolute

numbers employed in agriculture dropped from 236m to 205m, whereas the total numbers in

non-agricultural sectors (manufacturing, service sectors) increased from 133m to 260m in the

same period. Agriculture in this time span dropped from 64% to 44% in the share in

employment and 30% to 12% of the national income (Mehrotra and Parida, 2019; Kannan,

2020).

Page 76: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

76

The failure to realise the gains from agriculture has forced farmers to rely on non-farm

livelihoods. Foster and Rosenzweig (2004) found the share of non-farm incomes in rural India

increased from 19% to 48% between 1971 and 1999, rising to 65% of rural household incomes

today (Chand et al, 2017). Such is the importance of non-farm income for rural households that

25% of India’s smallholders would fall under the poverty line if not for non-farm incomes

(Rahman and Mishra, 2019).

A key non-farm livelihood has been construction work. Rapid urbanisation has created demand

for real estate and infrastructural projects in India since the 1990s (Jose Thomas, 2020). Jobs

in construction increased from 25.6 million in 2004-5 to 58.9 million in 2017-18, becoming

the second largest occupational category in rural areas outside of agriculture (Dhanagare, 2016;

Mehrotra and Parida, 2019). In addition, often unremunerative returns from farming have also

motivated farmers to educate their children and not follow them into agriculture as a future

livelihood (Agarwal and Agrawal, 2017). For farmers and younger educated generations of

rural households, this desire for social mobility has triggered an intergenerational occupational

shift out of agriculture. With some exceptions (Jakimow, 2014), few in the literature have

explored these changes within rural households. Chapter 6 addresses this by exploring the

aspirations for social mobility from farmers for their children to leave agriculture and the

impact it has on rural livelihoods.

For millions of rural households in India, education offers the best avenue out of marginality

and poverty in agriculture via the non-farm labour market (Jakimow, 2016). This is reflected

by the increase in absolute numbers of youth entering education in India from 56.8 million in

2004-5 to 127 million in 2017-18 (Mehrotra and Parida, 2019). In the last decade however,

despite increasing educational attainment, economic growth in India has not created enough

non-farm formal jobs to meet the increasing numbers of educated rural youth entering the job

market. Moreover, most opportunities available in the non-farm sector have been informal,

casual, low paid and low skilled.

Page 77: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

77

2.3.9 The political economy of the “lost decade” in India and its consequences for rural

livelihoods

Since the 2008 financial crisis, India has faced an acute non-farm labour market stagnation

(Mehra, 2019). The inability of capital to absorb surplus labour from agriculture and create

decent work in cities leaves many in rural India to become what Breman (1994: p1) terms as

“wage hunters and gatherers”. This has had reverberations for farmers and educated rural youth

alike, as it has eroded the safety net expected from non-farm livelihoods. Non-farm job creation

since liberalisation in the 1990s has largely been informal, characterised by low pay, insecure

tenure, and casual labour conditions. Since 1991, 92% of the 61 million jobs in India in the

non-farm sector have been informal (India Spend, 2019). Kannan (2020) describes the nature of

wage labour shifts from agriculture to non-agriculture to be largely horizontal in terms of social

mobility, with work being slightly better paid but still insecure and informal in cities and non-farm

work. Exiting agriculture may not produce better outcomes as Breman (2009: p29) describes

much wage labour opportunities found in Indian cities are often:

“informal labour, characterized by casualized and fluctuating employment

and piece-­‐rates, whether working at home, in sweatshops, or on their own

account in the open air; and in the absence of any contractual or labour rights,

or collective organization. In a haphazard fashion, still little understood,

work of this nature has come to predominate within the global labour force

at large.”

Much of India’s rapid growth in the non-farm sector has generated jobs, but not necessarily

desirable ones. The diversification into non-farm livelihoods therefore has presented farmers

with a new form of insecurity, rather than improving overall conditions. The occupational

diversity has involved a further subsumption into the capitalist process, working harder and in

more occupations but with progressively greater income insecurity (Lerche and Shah, 2018).

Macroeconomic trends since the 2010s has seen a shrinking workforce, slowdown in job

creation in all non-farm sectors and rising youth unemployment in the labour market (Mehrotra

and Parida, 2019; Jose Thomas, 2020). Himanshu (2019) finds that wages in non-agricultural

labour and construction only grew at 0.23% and 0.02% per year between 2014 and 2018,

indicating slow income growth.

Page 78: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

78

This period saw the potential non-farm job seeking workforce increase from 14 million a year

from 2005-12 to 17.5 million a year between 2012-18, but job creation in construction, services

and industry declined from 6.3 million a year between 2005-12 to 4.5 million a year from 2012-

18 (Jose Thomas, 2020). The biggest losers from this economic slowdown have been rural

youth.

The young and rural population of India have faced the brunt of this slowdown, unable to fulfil

their aspirations of securing a job to match their educational qualifications and skills in the

labour market (Aga, 2019). Youth unemployment in India has increased sharply from 5% in

2011-12 to 17% in 2017-18 (Kaul, 2019), an almost 4x increase in absolute terms from 6.7

million to 21.1 million. Inadequate job creation, slowing wage growth and the largely

undesirable nature of jobs in the non-farm sector have stymied the expectations and desires of

educated youth jobseekers in the labour market (Reddy, 2020a). In particular, the numbers of

youth that are classified as not in education, employment, or training (NEET) has increased

sharply from 69 million to 100 million between 2004-18, signifying that rural youth are pulling

out of the labour market altogether, unsatisfied at the available job prospects (Mehrotra and

Parida, 2019).

The dual impact of agricultural and non-farm stagnation for rural household incomes however

has not been discussed in the literature. In Chapter 6, I link the farm to the non-farm.

Smallholder farmers’ educational investments in their children’s education has not paid off,

nor have their agricultural investments in the Liberalised Green Revolution. I show how the

inadequacy of non-farm incomes to make up for losses in agriculture have forced rural

households to engage in risky strategies such as asset sales, doubling down on Bt cotton and

loan stacking in a desperate attempt to earn short term cash. I demonstrate that these strategies

only undermine their economic position further as they run the risk of eroding their asset base

and increasing their indebtedness as economic and environmental risk of intensification

remain. This links the consequences of the Liberalised Green Revolution and non-farm

livelihood stagnation because of the wider political economy of the labour market in India.

The emergence of the non-farm sector in India has provided rural households with crucial

income diversification options in the face of agricultural marginality. More importantly,

younger generations within rural households have attempted to transition to non-farm

livelihoods permanently via education, which is shared by their farmer parents. However, the

nature of non-farm job creation since liberalisation has largely been informal, casualised and

Page 79: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

79

low wage daily labour, with limited social protection guarantees and job benefits. In many

cases therefore, non-farm incomes are sought out of desperation for rural households, rather

than the jobs being better financially. Macroeconomic trends in the last decade moreover have

stalled job creation in the non-farm sector, seeing an absolute decline in the number of jobs

available and slowing wage growth. The non-farm sector is increasingly unable to meet the job

demand by educated rural youth, creating a large swathe of disaffected young and educated

rural jobseekers.

Neither agriculture nor non-farm sector in rural India today offer a route to prosperity, rather

simply keep rural households out of poverty. These conditions in the non-farm sector have

vastly increased the underemployment, unemployment and shrinking of the labour market

altogether, with rural youth in particular worst hit and choosing to drop out of the labour

market. The last decade in India has not only continued the problems of Liberalised Green

Revolution in agriculture, but has also burdened farmers and younger generations with non-

farm precarity outside of agriculture. Through surveying the literature, this section has also

identified a number of gaps to be explored in Chapter 6.

2.4 Conclusion

This chapter first introduced the concept of the Liberalised Green Revolution, a new epoch of

the Green Revolution under conditions of economic liberalisation since the 1980s. The

assumption of the Liberalised Green Revolution was that market integration of smallholder

farmers in marginal settings would increase agricultural growth and kick start the structural

transformation of the economy. However, this assumption was complicated and nuanced by

the political economy factors of the intersection between the unsuitable environmental and

economic risk context of capital and input intensive crops in marginal regions that smallholder

farmers financed with informal credit. This was combined with the self-interest of private

intermediaries to spread technologies to unsuitable agroecological areas and the entwining of

unequal debt relations between intermediaries and smallholders, worsening environmental risk

and indebtedness for the latter. Finally, the role of the government as a facilitator of markets

and politically expedient intervener in electricity subsidies in the Liberalised Green Revolution

often saw unrealised gains from agricultural intensification and dependence on non-farm

livelihoods to survive.

Next, the chapter explored the Liberalised Green Revolution in India, studying Bt cotton and

tubewell irrigation technologies. Bt cotton, a GM crop imported to India by US agribusiness

Page 80: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

80

giant Monsanto, was marketed and sold by local level private seed firms to subsistence

smallholder farmers in rainfed and poor soil settings. The unregulated nature of the cotton seed

market and absence of the government saw private input firms lead the push for the adoption

of Bt cotton, a high market price but capital, water and input intensive crop, financed by high

interest informal credit. This maximised Bt cotton adoption at the cost of indebtedness and

failed returns on investments for smallholder farmers as growing Bt cotton in marginal regions

exacerbated harvest failure risks for farmers via monsoon variability. The literature on Bt

cotton also revealed gaps for this thesis to address in Chapter 4 through the fieldwork case

study in Telangana.

Tubewell irrigation in the Liberalised Green Revolution had a similar story to Bt cotton.

Tubewell irrigation expanded via a private sector decentralised market competition, as private

irrigation firms maximised smallholder adoption in semi-arid and hard rock areas. These areas

were prone to erratic rainfall and poor aquifer storage. The desire to grow cash crops and repay

capital investments pushed farmers to competitively drill for accessing finite groundwater in

aquifers. This was also accelerated through populist policy incentives from the government,

increasing tubewell exploitation in adverse ecological semi-arid and hard rock environment.

Risk and indebtedness soon rose as farmers overexploited aquifers to failure amidst worsening

monsoons and deepening groundwater tables. In addition, the literature on tubewell irrigation

identified underexplored areas to address in Chapter 5, where I explore the political economy

of tubewell irrigation in the case study of Telangana.

Despite the deeper integration into markets and the access to agricultural technologies in the

Liberalised Green Revolution, farmers in India now rely more on non-farm incomes as a

primary income, educating their children in a bid for them to escape agriculture permanently.

Most non-farm work available in India however has been low paid, insecure, and insufficient

for rural households to repay debts from agriculture and sustain the household. Moreover, since

the financial crisis in India in 2008, non-farm income growth and job creation slowed down

rapidly, exacerbated rural youth unemployment and underemployment. Facing marginality in

agriculture and outside of it, this paints a bleak picture for India’s rural livelihoods. The chapter

also revealed gaps in the non-farm literature, to be addressed in Chapter 6 of the thesis where

I look at the impact of the Liberalised Green Revolution on future farm livelihoods. The next

chapter will provide the methodological plan and background to the case study state of

Telangana, setting it up for the empirical chapters 4, 5 and 6.

Page 81: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

81

Chapter 3 – Methodology

3.1 Introduction

Chapter 2 explored the theoretical framework and literature review for the thesis. I introduced

the concept of the Liberalised Green Revolution, a new epoch of the Green Revolution that

came out of liberalisation policies since the 1980s in developing countries including India. The

Liberalised Green Revolution saw private intermediaries such as informal moneylenders, input

and irrigation firms replace the public sector in seeds, inputs, irrigation, credit, and extension

services. Private firms competed to promote agricultural intensification, targeting subsistence

farmers in marginal environments. Widespread informal credit availability at flexible terms

made it possible for smallholder farmers to convert their farms to commercial agriculture.

Chapter 2 applied the Liberalised Green Revolution to the case study of Bt cotton and tubewell

irrigation in India, key technologies that drove smallholder intensification in the 1990s.

Smallholder adoption in the Liberalised Green Revolution drove India to become the world’s

largest Bt cotton grower and groundwater user. However, Chapter 2 revealed that the political

economy conditions of technology adoption in marginal smallholder settings often caused

indebtedness and resource degradation as areas were not suited to prolonged agricultural

intensification. With diminishing returns from agriculture, farmers now rely on non-farm

incomes to survive, themselves low paid and informal.

This chapter discusses the methodology used to collect fieldwork data in the case study state

of Telangana. The thesis utilised a mixed methods case study based ethnographic fieldwork

approach consisting of 84 interviews and 151 household surveys. The data was collected over

an 8-month period split into two phases. The first was a one-month scoping phase in August

2018 and the second the seven-month fieldwork phase between January and July 2019. The

main fieldwork was conducted in the village of Kacharam, Nalgonda district, in the south

Indian state of Telangana. Kacharam is a typical semi-arid and hard rock aquifer village in

Telangana dominated by smallholder farmers growing monocrop Bt cotton and tubewells,

transitioning from subsistence crops in the 2000s. The village reflected cropping and irrigation

dynamics at the district level as 49% of the total cropped area was made up of Bt cotton (DES

India, 2019b), 59% of the irrigated area used by tubewells, and 85% of farmers owned less than

1 hectare (DES India, 2019a; 2019b). Thereby, Kacharam is a salient case study and microcosm

of the widespread adoption of Bt cotton and tubewells and smallholder agricultural

intensification in the Liberalised Green Revolution.

Page 82: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

82

This methodology chapter will be structured as follows. The chapter is divided into three main

sections. The first section justifies the choice of Telangana and the village site of Kacharam for

study for the thesis. The second section presents the methods used and describes the process of

data collection and analysis during fieldwork. The third section offers a reflection of the

fieldwork experience including some of the ethical challenges and lessons learnt.

3.2 Fieldwork preparation and site selection

All research was carried out in the south Indian state of Telangana, a newly created state in

2014 and formerly part of Andhra Pradesh (Benbabaali, 2016). The choice of Telangana for

the thesis was influenced by three main factors: location (rural and rainfed), process (a region

where smallholder agricultural intensification occurred during the Liberalised Green

Revolution) and that it is a primarily agrarian economy. In part due to smallholder adoption,

Bt cotton in Telangana is the single biggest crop by area at 32%, with tubewell irrigation

making up 51% of total irrigated area and the average landholding at 1.2ha (DES India, 2019a;

2019b). This has made Telangana the third largest Bt cotton and fifth highest tubewell state by

area in India by 2019 (DES India, 2018; 2019b; Kranthi and Stone, 2020). Reflecting the

adoption of high capital-intensive technologies, Telangana also has the second highest rural

indebtedness rate in India, with 89% of mostly small and marginal farmers indebted to loans,

and with debts at 6x their asset values (NSSO, 2013a).

Telangana was selected as it was a region at the forefront of economic liberalisation in India in

the 1990s (Posani, 2009). Agricultural intensification took place in an agroecologically and

economically underdeveloped state dominated by subsistence farmers. It has a semi-arid

climate characterised by erratic monsoons and frequent droughts, while also featuring low

fertile laterite red soils which have poor water storage and infiltration capacity (CGWB Andhra

Pradesh, 2013). Hydrogeologically, most of Telangana is comprised of hard rock aquifers,

which makes it expensive to drill for groundwater irrigation, and has low aquifer storage

capacity, deemed unsuitable for intensive groundwater development as early as the 1960s (Rao,

2014).

Within Telangana, I chose Nalgonda district, a remote semi-arid and hard rock aquifer frontier

district. Within two decades of the 1990s, the district transformed from a subsistence cropping

system to a commercialised Bt cotton and groundwater intensive system, which occupied 49%

and 59% of the cultivated and irrigated areas respectively as of 2019 (DES India, 2019a;

2019b). This was important for the thesis as it allowed me to examine how and why the

Page 83: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

83

Liberalised Green Revolution proceeded as quickly as it did and what the ramifications were

for smallholder farmer risk and debt.

Despite the specific characteristics of Telangana and Nalgonda, the findings from the fieldwork

matter beyond the Indian context. For instance, the rapid uptake of Bt cotton is a microcosm

of the spread of genetically modified technologies in developing countries, as over 24

developing countries globally grow GM crops, by 17 million farmers (ISAAA, 2019). This is

representative of private sector efforts to modernise agriculture in smallholder contexts in

developing countries, for example explicit attempts to institute a new “African Green

Revolution” in the past decade (Moseley et al, 2017). Studying an agriculturally

underdeveloped region as I do in the thesis therefore can help shed light as to how the process

of agricultural intensification occurs and the consequences of it. Moreover, the marginal

growing environment present in Telangana and Nalgonda represents the dynamic of rainfed

and semi-arid agricultural regions of the world. This helps shed light on why agricultural

commercialisation can increase economic risks in the long run if implemented in unsuitable

agricultural settings (Pingali, 2012). The key points this thesis emphasises however is how the

local political economy context and social differentiation intersects with the agroecological

features of a given region to determine its long-term agricultural outcomes.

Finally, the choice of studying a village using a long-term ethnographic approach for

understanding agricultural political economy is the following. As Harriss-White and Harriss

(2007: p16) argue, village studies “can be used (critically or not) to exemplify economic,

political, sociological and cultural processes”. Observing variances and social differentiation

at individual village settings can help critique and inform theory (ibid). Village studies can help

locally situate economic policies and macro trends in agriculture, for example Bt cotton and

tubewell irrigation adoption within the everyday context of how farmers interact with the

technologies. Rigg et al (2012) therefore posit that understanding rural life requires both large

scale and statistically representative household surveys and long term intensive ethnographic

fieldwork case studies to observe agrarian change. In the Indian context, the village remains a

focal point and unit of analysis, as almost 70% of the population still live in rural areas today

and 43% work in agriculture (DES India, 2018).

Page 84: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

84

3.3 Scoping study

The first stage of the fieldwork was a scoping study. This took place in August 2018 in

Hyderabad, the capital city of Telangana, and Kattangoor, a village in Nalgonda district in

south Telangana. I first carried out eight interviews with academics and NGOs in Hyderabad

to discuss groundwater irrigation, Bt cotton, and agrarian change in Telangana. They gave their

own fieldwork reflections on these topics as well as discussing agriculture and irrigation policy

in the state. These interviews were my entry into fieldwork as it gave a background context of

the agrarian setting in Telangana. Furthermore, these preliminary interviews helped me

navigate the logistics for the fieldwork as I gained contacts for research assistants in Nalgonda

district which would prove invaluable for the main fieldwork phase in 2019.

After these initial interviews in Hyderabad, I spent three weeks conducting fieldwork in

Kattangoor, a village 15km from Nalgonda city, the capital of Nalgonda district. The village

was chosen through snowball sampling via research assistants and NGO contacts. Snowball

sampling was chosen as it has the advantage of locating hard to reach populations (Heckathorn,

2011), in my case for carrying out long term ethnographic fieldwork in remote and marginal

villages in Telangana. In Kattangoor village, I conducted ten interviews with farmers across

different castes, classes, religions, and genders. My scoping study fieldwork in Kattangoor

gave me a testing ground for my interview questions. These questions were the draft template

for my final interview questions for the main fieldwork phase. I collected empirical data on Bt

cotton cropping patterns, tubewell access and informal credit relations, all features of the

Liberalised Green Revolution. The findings were checked informally against Kacharam to see

if patterns could be observed across villages. In all, I collected 18 interviews in the scoping

study, which were used for Chapters 4-6 as empirical material.

3.4 Main fieldwork phase

In January 2019 in preparation of the main fieldwork phase, I next began the selection of the

district and village. I continued with Nalgonda district as I had already developed contacts with

NGOs and research assistants in the scoping phase. I recruited a research assistant who worked

for a local NGO in Devarakonda based on scoping contacts, a town in Nalgonda district, so

Devarakonda was chosen as a base. We chose a village nearby for the fieldwork site taking

account of the following.

Page 85: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

85

First, the village had to be roughly representative of rural Nalgonda with regards to cropping

patterns, climate, and hydrogeological characteristics. This was to fit the purpose of the

research to study tubewell irrigation and Bt cotton in semi-arid and hard rock aquifer regions,

the dominant crop, climate, aquifer, and irrigation type respectively in Nalgonda and

Telangana. The village also had to have a cross section of castes and classes of farmers like in

Nalgonda and Telangana, where lower caste Other Backward Castes (OBCs), Scheduled Castes

(SCs) and Scheduled Tribes (STs) made up 90% of the population as did smallholder farmers

(Benbabaali, 2016). These castes have the lowest landholding sizes, literacy rates and rural

household incomes on average in rural India relative to higher classes and castes (Himanshu et

al, 2016). I also used the latest district level census figures from 2011 for rural Nalgonda to

compare with the village census data to make sure the village was generally representative.

Next, the village had to be outside a command area of canal irrigation, to study the effects of

groundwater irrigation alone, which makes up 85% of Telangana’s irrigated area. These socio-

economic, climate, aquifer and cropping criteria for a village in Telangana acted as a

microcosm for wider trends of smallholder intensification of the Liberalised Green Revolution.

3.4.1 Village profile

With the above criteria in mind, I chose Kacharam. It is located 15km from the town of

Devarakonda in Nalgonda District in South Telangana, 63km south from Nalgonda city, the

district headquarters and 110km from Hyderabad, the state capital. The village location is

shown below.

Page 86: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

86

Figure 7 - Map of Telangana

Source: Wikipedia (2021)

Telangana

Page 87: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

87

Figure 8 - Nalgonda District

Sub district map showing

Devarakonda mandal (sub

district) where Kacharam is

located

Source: DES Telangana (2019)

Nalgonda District

Page 88: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

88

Figure 9 - Kacharam

Source: Google Maps (2019)

Figure 10 - Kacharam Village Map - New OBC Colony

Source: Google Maps (2019)

Page 89: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

89

Figure 11 - Kacharam Village Map - Main OBC and SC colony

Source: Google Maps (2019)

Figure 12 - Kacharam Village Map - ST colony

Source: Google Maps (2019)

Page 90: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

90

Geographically, the village is split into three sections according to caste. The first part of the

village off the main road into Kacharam are 10 newly built households inhabited by the Goud

and Golla sub castes from the Other Backward Castes (OBC), who form the dominant caste

group in the village. Traditionally Gouds engaged in palm wine makers and Gollas in

shepherding goat and sheep alongside farming. In the main part of the village are Golla OBCs

and Scheduled Castes/Dalits (SCs) from the Mala and Madiga sub castes. Malas were

traditionally basket weavers, cobblers, and Madigas worked as bonded agricultural labourers

for higher castes. Caste occupations are largely not practised anymore in the village as most

households engage in agricultural labour or farming on their own land. The exceptions are

Golla and Goud households who rear sheep and goats and sell palm wine for additional income.

Finally, around 2 km from the village lived 10 Scheduled Tribe households (ST) in a traditional

hamlet called a thanda. These were traditionally nomadic and forest dwelling groups that

settled in Kacharam to practise farming. Figure 13 below shows a caste diagram of Telangana

and Figures 14-16 show the different parts of Kacharam village.

Figure 13 - Caste Diagram of Telangana

Source: Srinivasulu (2002), Suri (2002), Vakulabharanam and Motiram (2014), Prasad (2015),

Times of India (2019).

Page 91: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

91

Figure 14 - OBC Colony

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Figure 15 - SC Colony

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 92: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

92

Figure 16 - ST Colony

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Kacharam sits at an altitude of 224m. It is 1km from the nearest public bus route and has a

government primary school in the village. Kacharam gained its village status in January 2019,

when the newly elected person became the first ever Sarpanch (village leader), representing

the Telangana Rashtra Samiti (TRS), the incumbent political party ruling Telangana.

Previously it came under the jurisdiction of Kondabheemanapalle, a village 7km away. The

houses are mostly pucca (cement and brick) and received piped drinking water supplies under

the Mission Bhageeratha scheme in 2018, a TRS state government initiative to provide free

piped drinking water to villages in Telangana. Groundwater is also used for drinking from open

wells and hand pumps. The village was electrified 20 years ago and receives mobile coverage.

The village also has three corner shops, a government school nutrition programme centre

(Anganwadi) and a village government office (Gram Panchayat).

Occupations wise, older generations of farmers (40+) mostly work in agriculture in the

monsoon season from June to October. In the dry season for the remaining year, farmers work

as agricultural labourers in nearby villages and in construction work in Devarakonda, the

nearest town, approximately 15km away. Both male and female older generations farm in the

monsoon and in the dry season females work predominantly in agricultural labour and males

in construction labour. Younger generations of rural households work in Devarakonda town in

Page 93: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

93

non-farm jobs as fertiliser shop assistants or rickshaw drivers. Average household incomes in

Kacharam for 2018 were ~$2100, of which 39% to 70% came from non-farm sources.

The fieldwork took place between January and July, so it covered both the rabi (dry season)

and kharif (monsoon season). This was important so I could see how farmers negotiated an

entire farming calendar year, covering both Bt cotton in the monsoon and tubewell irrigated

rice in the dry season, as shown in Chapters 4 and 5 of the thesis. In addition, in the dry season

I could observe their non-farm livelihoods too, as investigated in Chapter 6. Kacharam has a

semi-arid and drought prone climate, with predominantly hot and dry weather and 69% of

annual rainfall falling in the monsoon between June and October. The village received

approximately 505mm of rain during the monsoon in 2019, slightly higher than Nalgonda

district average of 474mm but much lower than the Telangana average of 791mm (CGWB

Telangana, 2019). Kacharam is in the south Telangana agro-climatic zone, which has lower

rainfall, and is hotter and drier than other regions in the state at up to 50C in the summer (DES

Telangana, 2016). Kacharam features predominantly red laterite and sandy soils, with red soils

making up 85% of the soils in the state (CGWB Andhra Pradesh, 2019). Red laterite soils have

low fertility, low storage, low infiltration capacity and high runoff rates in comparison to sandy

and black alluvial soils (Gine et al, 2008).

Figure 17 - Dried Up Bt Cotton Under Red Laterite Soils in Kacharam

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 94: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

94

Kacharam also features hard rock aquifers, made up of granite, gneiss, and limestone (CGWB

Telangana, 2017). Groundwater is found within fractures and weathered regions in the rock at

15-20m depths but can be found as deep as 80m (CGWB Andhra Pradesh, 2013). Hard rock

aquifers cover 66% of India’s aquifer area, making them the dominant aquifer type (Mukherjee,

2018). Sourcing groundwater in hard rock aquifers is highly variable, prone to climatic change,

shallow aquifer storage capacity, erratic monsoon recharge and expensive due to the density of

the rock relative to alluvial aquifers (Shah, 2010; Blakesee et al, 2020).

Figure 18 - Tubewell Irrigation in Kacharam

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 95: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

95

Figure 19 - Decadal Groundwater Levels in Telangana, 2006-2015

Source: CGWB Telangana (2017)

Figure 19 from the CGWB in Telangana (2017), the main groundwater state government level

authority, revealed that groundwater levels decreased by 0-2m in the monsoon period in 2015

relative to 2006, indicating dropping groundwater levels in the region and Kacharam. Rajan et

al (2020) moreover reveal that Nalgonda is one of the 27 most exploited groundwater districts

in India and Telangana is one of the 9 most overexploited states in India.

The choice of Kacharam as a village and Telangana as a case study is useful beyond the Indian

context as it expresses how the most marginal rural areas adapt to scarce resources and

groundwater depletion under an adverse climatic setting. Groundwater depletion is a major

problem in other semi-arid and arid regions such as in the Middle East (Al Naber and Molle,

2017) where farmers face similar agroecological and groundwater constraints as the case study

in Telangana.

Nalgonda District

Page 96: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

96

In addition, Telangana has faced droughts in at least one region for 23 out of the last 30 years

(DES Telangana, 2016). This is an important factor in explaining Bt cotton yields under rainfed

conditions in Chapter 4, aquifer depletion in Chapter 5 due to erratic rainfall recharge and shift

in the nature and pattern of livelihoods away from agriculture in Chapter 6 of this thesis.

Finally, Kumar et al (2018) in Figure 20 have also identified Nalgonda district as very high on

the climate exposure index, based on interviews in rural Telangana, and data on temperature

changes, heat & cold wave events, rainfall variability, and changes in the frequency or intensity

of consecutive dry and wet days. This indicates that Kacharam is an agroecologically and

hydrogeologically fragile environment.

Figure 20 - Climate Vulnerability Index Telangana

Source: Kumar et al (2018)

The case study for this thesis helps unveil how farmers address semi-arid and drought prone

conditions in India, with 33% of the country located in these areas (Todmal, 2019). Beyond

India, semi-arid regions constitute 10% of the global agricultural area, home to 2.5 billion

people who rely on drylands for agriculture and rearing livestock (Stewart, 2016). Dryland

areas are also set to increase by 10% by 2050 due to climatic change affecting rainfall

variability (Li et al, 2020). Hence examining how smallholder farmers in Telangana manage

Nalgonda

Page 97: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

97

resources in marginal conditions and adapt to a worsening climate can provide lessons beyond

the Indian context.

Finally, the table below shows background socio economic statistics for the village based on

household surveys I conducted. It reveals high rates of illiteracy, low land sizes and below

poverty per capita income per day. OBCs are the dominant caste group in the village, with the

village leader coming from an OBC caste and as well as the largest landholder. The low literacy

rates, caste breakdown and average landholdings track with census data at the district and state

level, so the village is representative of an average village in the region.

Table 2 - Socio-economic Profile of Kacharam

Category Total

Total Population 630

Total Households 151

Adult Literacy Rate (%) 35

Adult Literacy Rate Male (%) 39

Adult Literacy Rate Female (%) 29

Average Household Size 4

Per Capita Income Per Day ($) 1.20

Farming Households 105

Non-Farm Households 46

SC Households 38

ST Households 23

OBC Households 88

Muslim Households 2

Total Land Area (Acres) 443

Gross Cropped Area (Acres) 369

Average Landholding Size (Acres) 3.5

Average Age of Household Head 47

Landless Households 16

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

This section will explain data collection methods used in the fieldwork.

Page 98: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

98

3.5 Using ethnography in a mixed method frame to investigate agrarian change

This thesis utilises an ethnographic fieldwork in a mixed method frame to investigate agrarian

change in India. Ethnography is a branch of qualitative research that assumes that knowledge

is socially constructed (Creswell, 2007). Ethnography generates a complex multiplicity of

understandings, meanings, and relations from participants through long term data fieldwork

(Guba and Lincoln, 1994). Fieldwork in Kacharam took place over 7 months of repeated

encounters with farmers to ensure data validity as it unveiled and refined my interpretations of

change over time in the field and in the participants’ lives.

This is because from aggregate figures, Bt cotton, tubewell growth in agriculture in Telangana

and India have rapidly increased through smallholder adoption in the Liberalised Green

Revolution, implying that market integration has been successful. However, these quantitative

assessments miss farmer perspectives of the rapid transformation from subsistence to

commercial agriculture and its impacts on indebtedness, risk, and farming knowledge. In a

political economy and agroecological context such as Telangana, ethnography is of analytical

importance in understanding the processes, mechanisms and factors underlying agrarian

change and the socially differentiated outcomes from it (Harriss, 2011).

I used an ethnographic frame with mixed methods for the thesis, consisting of quantitative

household surveys and qualitative interviews. Relying on quantitative approaches alone

abstracts problems to a collective, missing nuance and socially differentiated household context

of class, caste, or gender. In addition, relying entirely on qualitative data from a small sample

of interviewees would not be suitable for quantifying general trends at the village level or for

extracting descriptive data. For this reason, I used household surveys that covered 98% of the

village population sample to summarise observations from the village and the Liberalised

Green Revolution. I then used quotes to provide a thick description, defined as the:

“process of paying attention to contextual detail in observing and interpreting social

meaning…thick description involves looking at the rich details of the case, sorting out

the complex layers of understanding that structure the social world” (Dawson, 2010:

p942-944).

This provided a longitudinal account of an individual farmer’s experiences of harvest failure

or groundwater depletion for example. This gave me a combination of the strengths of both

qualitative and quantitative data for providing a narrative of agrarian change for Kacharam.

This also ensured data triangulation and reliability as I could corroborate my findings with

Page 99: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

99

different data sources in the fieldwork and with secondary data from aggregate data and

agrarian change fieldwork in Telangana.

Finally, a key part of ethnography is to account for the positionality of the researcher and the

power relations between researcher/participant. In relation to agrarian change research in India,

this includes assumptions during the analysis of fieldwork data, power relations in the field,

and bias of the researcher via class, religion, and gender dynamics (Watson, 2013).

Positionality will be explored in greater detail in the next section.

3.6 Positionality

My positionality as a male, Telangana born, urban, upper caste Brahmin from a middle-class

background is important to state considering the motivations behind the research. This affected

positionality during fieldwork, as in Telangana, low caste, and class OBC, ST and SCs make

up 90% of the population (Benbabaali, 2016). Skelton (2001: p89) defines positionality as:

“our race and gender, but also our class experiences, our levels of education, our

sexuality, our age…all of these have a bearing upon who we are, how our identities are

formed and how we do our research”.

Although Indian, I am what Mohammad (2001) calls “an indigenous insider”, where I lie in

between a local and a foreigner due to my Indian ethnicity and background but different class

and cultural upbringing in the UK. My caste background is easily identifiable by my surname

and imbued with social status and privilege, especially in rural India where caste forms the

social structure of a village (Himanshu et al, 2016).

In Kacharam however, my caste and UK identity were not of importance relative to my class.

Due to my proficiency in Telugu while talking to villagers, my caste identity and background

was assumed to be an urban, educate elite from Hyderabad, the capital city of Telangana, and

not as a foreigner. However, my class identity had implications during the fieldwork as farmers

frequently expected compensation for participating in interviews. I made it clear to the villagers

that I cannot offer money as I was a PhD student, even though the endless patience and interest

many villagers showed in the research process made my research possible. However, to give

back in a small way, I plan to return to Kacharam after the PhD and disseminate an executive

summary of the thesis with policy recommendations for the village.

Page 100: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

100

A key way in which access and positionality in the village were made easier was through the

village leader and local research assistants enabling familiarity with the villagers, especially in

my interactions with women. Rural India is socially conservative with regards to interactions

between unmarried male strangers and women (Nilotpal, 2011). This issue was greatly

mitigated through employing a female research assistant from the village while conducting the

household surveys. In fact, 35 out of 65 interviews (54%) were conducted with women, so the

previous concerns of my positionality as a male in a conservative village setting were resolved

in the interview phase. Women were much more forthcoming and comfortable as we sequenced

the research to start with surveys with local research assistants before interviews by myself and

my research assistant.

The next section details the data collection process.

3.7 Methods and techniques used in data collection

This section discusses the process of fieldwork data collection for the thesis in Telangana. The

fieldwork consisted of a mixed methods case study-based approach utilising 151 quantitative

household surveys in the fieldwork village of Kacharam and 84 semi structured qualitative

interviews with farmers in Kacharam, tubewell firms and input firms in Devarakonda and

Mallepally (towns close to Kacharam) and academics, and NGOs in Hyderabad. The section

provides a summary of the methods and data pertaining to each research question before going

into the fieldwork data collection process.

Page 101: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

101

3.7.1 Data collection summary

The thesis outlines the three research questions below and how I collected the data using

interviews, household surveys and secondary data to answer them.

Table 3 - Data Collection Summary

Research Question Data Collected Methods Used

1) What are the consequences

of cotton farming in the

Liberalised Green

Revolution in Telangana?

Bt cotton debt, long term

yields, extension advice, input

costs, rainfall patterns, farmer

knowledge on Bt cotton

cultivation, Bt cotton political

economy conditions

84 Semi structured interviews

with farmers, input dealers,

academics, NGOs

151 Household surveys with

farmers in Kacharam

Secondary government

statistics on cotton,

ethnographic fieldwork on Bt

cotton in Telangana

2) How has tubewell

irrigation changed the

political economy of

agriculture in Telangana?

Tubewell debt, well depth,

total wells drilled, wells

working, wells failed, drilling

costs, extension advice,

cropping patterns, rainfall

patterns, aquifer conditions,

political economy conditions

84 Semi structured interviews

with farmers, academics,

NGOs, tubewell firms

151 Household surveys with

farmers in Kacharam

Secondary government

statistics, ethnographic

fieldwork on tubewell

irrigation in Telangana

3) What are the implications

of the Liberalised Green

Revolution for the future

of agricultural livelihoods

in Telangana?

Non-farm incomes, total

household incomes vs debt and

expenses, farmer debt

repayment strategies,

intergenerational aspirations,

education, future livelihoods

for rural youth

84 Semi structured interviews

with farmers

151 Household surveys with

farmers in Kacharam

Secondary government labour

market data, ethnographic

fieldwork on non-farm

livelihoods in Telangana

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Following this summary of the methods and data collected for the thesis, the next sections will

detail the steps and processes involved in the fieldwork.

Page 102: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

102

3.7.2 Fieldwork data collection process

The fieldwork consisted of a mixed methods case study-based approach utilising quantitative

household surveys and semi-structured qualitative interviews. This phase utilised a snowball

sampling approach to recruit participants through contacts with NGOs and local research

assistants and at the village level. Snowball sampling was a practical necessity as the

participants were hard to reach in remote rural villages in Telangana and therefore not able to

pre-arrange or contact prior to the fieldwork. In addition, case studies help investigate in depth

in a delimited context (e.g., a geographic area or population) how or why a particular issue or

process occurs and applies a multidimensional perspective in understanding it (Baxter and

Jack, 2008). The use of multiple sources in the case study helped to paint a picture of agrarian

change in a descriptive quantitative fashion in conjunction with the “thick description” from

ethnographic findings. I will give a summary of the data collected using each of the methods

of household surveys and interviews before going into depth as to how the data was collected.

3.7.3 Fieldwork data summary

Below in Table 4 I summarise the data collected for household surveys and interviews in the

fieldwork:

Table 4 - Fieldwork Data Summary

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Interview Data Summary Household Survey Data Summary

Thematic Round 1 - I covered livelihood strategies, inputs, cropping

patterns, intergenerational changes in farming, and monsoon

patterns.

Part 1 - The first half of the survey

collected GPS data, yields, input and

expenditure costs, cropping patterns, land

use, annual household incomes, opinion

surveys on climate and groundwater and

debt levels.

Thematic Round 2 - I focused on credit, debt, incomes and how they

manage debt repayments for irrigation and farming costs. From the

household survey I could already build an income and consumption

profile so the interview questions were the farmers’ own strategies,

worries and aspirations for their household economic security and

farming future.

Part 2 - The second half of the survey

focused on irrigation investment costs, well

depths, credit sources, interest, well failure

rates, groundwater depletion coping

strategies, as well as welfare policies that

the household benefited from.

Thematic Round 3 – I focused on groundwater irrigation investment

decisions, cropping pattern shifts, groundwater depletion and future

livelihoods for rural youth. I carried out the irrigation round in July

during the monsoon season to observe changes in cropping patterns

and irrigation use compared to the survey period in January/February

and the monsoon season from 2018.

Page 103: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

103

3.7.4 Household surveys

The fieldwork in Kacharam was split into two phases: 151 household surveys, followed by 73

interviews. The household surveys recorded detailed information (as outlined in Table 4 above)

for 98% of the village population, useful for descriptive data in conjunction with interview

quotes. Two research assistants were hired from the village for the surveys upon

recommendation from the village leader. We conducted the household surveys on every

weekday over a two-month period in February and March. For the first week of surveys, I

conducted enumerator training with the research assistants. The data was collected on paper

surveys after consent forms and information sheets in Telugu were handed out to the

households or verbally agreed upon via audio recording prior to the survey commencing. The

survey data was then uploaded at the end of each day onto an Excel spreadsheet. We revisited

some households at the end of the survey period to follow up on missing data or any errors we

made. On average the surveys lasted one to two hours per household.

The household surveys gave in depth household profiles of the entire village at a coverage rate

of 98%, or 151 out of 155 households, so findings could be generalised at a village level. We

could not cover the remaining 2% as two households refused to participate, one elderly

widower household passed away after the household survey and one household permanently

migrated. They covered the recall for the agricultural year 2018 so we could compare monsoon,

cropping patterns and groundwater irrigation with the 2019 season.

The next phase of the research was semi-structured interviews, for which I used a purposive

sampling technique to recruit interviewees. Purposive sampling was the chosen strategy as I

aimed to interview a cross section of households in relation to Bt cotton and tubewells. I

achieved a balance of a quantity deemed to be a good sample size at roughly 50% of the village

population, but also practicality of the fieldwork timeframe of seven months (Nilotpal, 2011).

The interview criteria and justifications are listed below in Table 5.

Page 104: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

104

3.7.5 Interview household selection criteria

Table 5 - Interview Household Selection Criteria

Participant Group Selected Justification

50/50 men and women Gendered differentiation was an important factor

to consider e.g., in intra household decision

making in crop choices, irrigation, household

finances and investment decisions.

ST, SC, OBC castes Important to get a cross section of castes due to

the differentiation in landholding size, assets,

income, and social relations in the village.

Widowed women I could see the intersectional effects of

landholding, caste and gender and the impact it

had on debt, income, and farming outcomes

Successful farmers To study how farmers with higher yields and

incomes compared on groundwater irrigation

management and cropping methods to less

successful farmers.

Multi tubewell drillers Households who drilled multiple times for wells

were likely to be highly indebted due to high

failure rates from their wells, and the

consequences for household economic security.

Currently working tubewells Observing farming outcomes for households

with working irrigation and the effect on debts,

incomes, yields.

Failed tubewells I wanted to study their coping mechanisms from

groundwater depletion, e.g., further tubewell

investments, changes to cropping patterns,

migration or abandoning farming as a primary

livelihood.

Marginal farmers <1 ha

Small farmers 1-2 ha

Medium farmers 2-5 ha

Large farmers >5 ha

A class-based analysis was an important criterion

for comparing yields, incomes, cropping

patterns, irrigation investments, welfare schemes

and credit sources.

Highly indebted farmers >$4000 I chose the figure of $4000 as it was twice the

average income per year for Kacharam’s farmers,

an unsustainable amount due to interest

accumulation and unpredictable farm incomes. It

was also important to examine the source and

cause of indebtedness e.g., farming, marriage, or

health

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 105: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

105

Based on the criteria above, we selected 65 households, or 42% of the total households in

Kacharam. I chose 65 households as it was a practically achievable target per month balancing

my time, financial resources, data saturation and the farmer availability during the daytime.

We visited each household three times over three months from April to July to cover the three

thematic rounds. In total we spent ninety minutes to two hours interviewing each household.

The reason for spacing out the interviews was that we did not want to fatigue and inconvenience

the farmer by visiting them multiple times per month. We settled on visiting one household

every month for the interview stage as a good balance. The household surveys were analysed

using Excel for descriptive statistics to provide supportive evidence to the interviews and

generalise findings at the village level.

3.7.6 Interviews

The interviews took place between April and July with a week gap in May due to the national

elections held in India. I used semi-structured interviews for the fieldwork. They allowed me

to have a structure of covering the three thematic rounds pertaining to the research questions

and corroborate findings from the literature review on Bt cotton, tubewells and agrarian change

in Telangana (Vakulabharanam, 2004; Stone and Flachs, 2018). In addition, they also gave me

flexibility and freedom to allow pre-planned topics to change if the farmer wanted to discuss a

topic outside of the round. Interviews helped to convey farmers perspectives about Bt cotton

and tubewell irrigation and enhanced the understanding of farmers’ experiences with the

technologies, while also giving a rich narrative of the field setting so the reader can see the

contextual factors of the research.

The interviews were broken into three thematic rounds as listed above in Table 4 and we

completed one round roughly per month over a five-day working week. The interviews took

place between 7am and 10am to suit farmers’ working day in agriculture or wage labour. After

completing information and consent forms, we began the interview. I asked questions and took

notes and the research assistant recorded via a dictaphone. The thematic rounds improved and

expanded on the scoping study structure but kept some of the same order of topics and

questions. In total I interviewed 65 households in Kacharam over the three months and took a

purposive sampling approach in selecting from of the 151 households.

Page 106: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

106

After the three rounds of interviews with farmers we carried out supplementary interviews with

tubewell firms and input dealers, totalling 11 interviews. These were the key private

intermediary actors in the Liberalised Green Revolution in Telangana providing credit,

technology and extension support to farmers for Bt cotton and tubewells. The interviewees

were based in nearby towns to Kacharam such as Devarakonda and Mallepally, and we visited

these during the day after we conducted farmer interviews in the morning. The total number

was only 11 due to the difficulty in gaining consent from interviewees when we approached

them for interview. The interviews took place at their preferred location, so within input or

irrigation shops. These supplementary interviews provided an in-depth discussion with private

sector intermediaries, whose crucial role in the political economy of the Liberalised Green

Revolution had been under explored in the literature.

In total including the scoping and final interview phase I carried out 84 interviews and 151

household surveys for the fieldwork, utilising a majority for the final write up. The interview

recordings were translated and transcribed from Telugu to English. The interviews were then

split thematically into three folders pertaining to each round, which were used to organise the

analysis phase. A list of all interview participants, questions and dates and a detailed summary

of the household surveys can be found in Appendix 1, 3 and 4.

3.8 Data analysis

The next stage of the methodology was data analysis, which this section will justify and outline

in more detail.

Thematic analysis creates themes that emerge from the data in relation to the research

questions. Themes are useful in “bringing together components or fragments of ideas or

experiences, which often are meaningless when viewed alone” (Aronson, 1995: p1). The three

research questions for this thesis were on cotton, tubewell irrigation and non-farm livelihoods,

so I sorted the interview transcripts into the three thematic rounds correspondingly. The

analysis phase required coding the transcripts within each thematic round to find connections

to the literature and original contributions the interview data made to the research questions.

An example of the coded sheet can be found in Appendix 2.

The interview transcripts were coded manually for the thematic analysis as it allowed me to

get to know the data better than NViVo, and I was able to make better connections between the

interview data and the household survey data. Linking back to the literature review topics, the

codes for each thematic round summarised interview responses according to its relation to the

Page 107: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

107

literature and the research questions. The thematic rounds I selected served as a large enough

umbrella under which various codes could fit under, but also specific enough that each major

idea related to the research question made the theme unique (Attride-Stirling, 2001). This way

I could paint a narrative from the data for the analysis chapters.

3.9 Ethics

Fieldwork is a messy process laden with ethical challenges pertaining to power, representation,

and consent. I took the following steps to mitigate these to the extent possible during the

fieldwork. Prior to engaging in interviews, I conveyed the purpose of the research both written

and verbally in Telugu or English based on the preference of the participant. Given 125 out of

151 household heads (85%) in Kacharam were illiterate, they gave oral consent for the surveys

and interviews. I read out the consent form and information sheet in Telugu for farmers and

market intermediaries, whereas academics and NGO professionals in Hyderabad read and

signed them in English. A copy of the consent form can be found in Appendix 5. Within this,

I articulated the rights of the participant to not be recorded or photographed, to pull out of the

study at any time and to anonymise their identity by default. The need for anonymising

participant names is clear for my research, given the persistent socio-political influence of caste

and class at the village level which creates power hierarchies between villagers as well as their

relationships with private intermediaries or government officials (Himanshu et al, 2016).

The interview transcripts were anonymised and arranged into a coding system in relation to the

thematic round and the interview number. For example, scoping interviewees were numbered

A1-8, round one interviews in Kacharam numbered B1-65, round two interviews in Kacharam

numbered C1-68 and round three interviews numbered D1-69. The supplementary interviews

took place in rounds two and three so were labelled either C or D. Interviewees were cited as:

(D1, farmer, 24/3/19), giving the interview number and round, the primary occupation of the

interviewee and the date it was carried out. The interview transcripts, audio recordings, paper

surveys and household survey data Excel sheets were either stored locally in a password

protected safe or password protected online as per GDPR regulations and not shared or

accessed by anyone except myself. The data was backed up in three different locations

including encrypted USB sticks and encrypted University of Manchester cloud storage

accounts, requiring two-factor authentication. A list of all anonymised interviewees can be

found in Appendix 1.

Page 108: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

108

3.10 Limitations of the fieldwork

This section will explore the limitations of the fieldwork and how I mitigated them.

The main limitation was the fieldwork’s focus on one village, rather than a comparative study

across different villages. This approach is not statistically representative to the wider political

economy of agrarian change in Telangana or India. However, studying a village helps explore

external dynamics of agrarian change through intensive study of day-to-day inner workings

(Harriss-White, 2012). The purpose of the research was to observe the lived reality of Bt cotton

adoption and tubewell irrigation in the Liberalised Green Revolution for smallholder farmers

in Telangana, reflecting their status as the dominant class, crop and irrigation technologies at

the state level and India. Intensive ethnographic fieldwork in one village and supplementary

interviews over 8 months provided a rich picture of the processes within the broader political

economy trends in agriculture in the Liberalised Green Revolution.

Secondly, I did not conduct any focus groups during fieldwork. This was due to logistical

problems as households were unwilling to give more than an hours’ time for interviews and we

were unsure of their availability in advance. Farmers were only available between 7am and

10am, and even then, we intruded on their morning household activities. Logistical problems

made bringing together villagers for focus groups at set times not possible. To mitigate this, I

surveyed the 98% of the village in household surveys and interviewed almost 42% of the

households in the village so I could corroborate the experiences shared across households

which would approximate the benefits of focus groups.

Finally, I could not interview any moneylenders, government groundwater department officials

or government agricultural extension officers despite repeated attempts in person and over the

phone. However, I obtained extensive information on the role of informal moneylenders as

private intermediaries in the Liberalised Green Revolution and the absence of government

officers in extension in tubewells and Bt cotton. Hence, I came away with a good idea of the

predatory informal credit markets and the absent government role in the area and how they

operate. The next chapters 4, 5 and 6 are the empirical chapters that will answer the research

questions for the thesis.

Page 109: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

109

Chapter 4 - What are the consequences of Bt cotton farming in the

Liberalised Green Revolution in Telangana?

4.1 Introduction

Chapter 3 detailed the methodology of the thesis, justifying the choice of an ethnographic

mixed methods case study comprised of interviews and household surveys. Chapter 3

subsequently outlined the fieldwork data collection and field site selection process in

Telangana before providing a profile of Kacharam, the village selected for this thesis. Finally,

Chapter 3 described positionality, ethics, and limitations of the fieldwork. This chapter is the

first of three empirical chapters for the thesis that answers the first research question: “What

are the consequences of Bt cotton farming in the Liberalised Green Revolution in Telangana?”.

Historically, the state of Telangana featured a predominantly rainfed subsistence farming

environment with low rainfall and unreliable monsoons, alongside poor productivity laterite

soils. Due to its marginal environment where only 20% of the cropped area was irrigated even

as late as 1980 (DES India, 2019a, b), Telangana missed out on the Green Revolution, as policy

makers focused on more favourable agroecological regions for crop and infrastructure

investments (Bharucha, 2019). Agriculture consisted of cultivating sorghum and millets;

traditional dryland food crops well suited to drought prone environments (Louis, 2015).

The Liberalised Green Revolution entered as the state faced economic crisis in the 1990s, as

debt levels had increased from $4.7 million to $10.5 million between 1980 and 1995, increasing

the interest repayments by 12x in this period (Mooij, 2007). In response to this, the newly

elected Chief Minister Chandra Babu Naidu from the incumbent TDP party sought to reform

the state economy after this crisis, as the national government faced a macroeconomic crisis

too in 1991 (Banerjee and Duflo, 2019). The new model for the state was to increase economic

growth through privatisation, reduce public spending and increase private investment,

including in agriculture (Vaditya, 2017). This culminated in a 1999 collaborative report with

the World Bank titled “Vision 2020” which argued for the reduction of agricultural subsidies

in rice, electricity for groundwater and opening up international commodity markets

(Bandhopadhyay, 2001). In doing so, Andhra Pradesh implemented structural reforms under

the aegis of the World Bank at a scale and veracity unlike other states since 1995 (Posani,

2009).

Page 110: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

110

This chapter argues that cotton farming was a key element of the Liberalised Green Revolution

in Telangana since the 1990s. Key reforms in the cotton sector in India in the 1990s included

permitting 100% FDI from international seed firms, removal of import tariffs on cotton seeds

and the opening of the domestic cotton sector to international commodity markets, creating a

boom in private sector cotton development (Mohanakumar, 2010). Hybrid seeds were patented

to be replaced each year and worked only in optimal conditions of high input and pesticide

application, guaranteeing sales for private input dealers (Siddiqui, 2020). In addition, input

firms also sold inputs on credit in interlocked factor markets, guaranteeing a harvest price with

farmers in the output market (Sinha, 2020). For farmers, credit availability, the prospect of a

high market price, and the marketing of cotton seeds by local input firms transformed semi-

arid Telangana into the centre of smallholder cotton capitalism in India (Ramamurthy, 2011).

By the 2000s however, widespread pest problems from the bollworm pest, a common pest in

India for cotton, in private hybrid seed technologies reduced yields in the cotton sector

(Venkateshwarlu and Da Corta, 2001). To solve the crisis, the Indian government imported and

approved Bt cotton or Bacillus Thuringiensis, a GM hybrid cotton created by US agribusiness

giant Monsanto, that was bred with pest resistance qualities to tackle the bollworm (Gutierrez

et al, 2020). It retained hybrid properties like its predecessor, which continued the guaranteed

seed and input market for input dealers on an annual basis (Glover, 2010b). Following

regulatory approval in 2002, Bt cotton was quickly adopted in Telangana, making up 95% of

all cotton grown in the region by 2015 (Stone and Flachs, 2015). This boosted cotton growth

in Telangana to 4.5% between 1990-2008 (Reddy, 2011). Cotton in Telangana became the

biggest crop by area at almost 2 million hectares by 2018 from just 163,000 hectares in 1985,

and the third biggest cotton growing state in India (DES India, 2018; 2019a, b).

In the fieldwork village of Kacharam, farmers relied on subsistence rainfed crops sorghum,

millets, and castor. But by the late 1990s and early 2000s a culmination of factors prompted

the transition to Bt cotton. Push factors such as pests, harvest failures, disease, low market

prices and the rising cost of household expenditure on goods and services necessitated a shift

away from subsistence agriculture. Equally, the high market price of Bt cotton and aspirations

of material prosperity drove farmers to adopt Bt cotton. The withdrawal of the public sector in

agriculture saw input firms as seed salesmen, creditor, and extension advisor to push up

adoption rates amongst rainfed smallholder farmers in Kacharam.

Page 111: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

111

Within 20 years of introduction since the mid-2000s, 85% of the village relied on Bt cotton as

a monocrop cash crop. Bt cotton provided commensurate profitability within the first five years

of adoption, but gradually, the capital and input intensive crop increased cotton yield instability

as farmers hedged their bets on one crop. This was also the case for Nalgonda district and

Telangana more widely, as well as in India, as shown in Chapter 2 (DES India, 2018; Kranthi

and Stone, 2020). Worsening monsoon variability and low yields from growing a capital

intensive cash crop in rainfed conditions perpetuated cycles of indebtedness from high interest

informal credit, with farmers renewing loans annually to cover their losses, household

expenditures and repay interest. In the fieldwork survey year 2018, 65% of farmers made a loss

from cotton, across all castes, classes, and gender categories.

The absence of the government in extension services made farmers rely on private input dealers

for extension advice and to buy inputs and seeds on credit. Input firms recommended

maximising fertiliser and pesticide application or buying new seeds whenever Bt cotton failed,

rather than to irrigate the crop with their tubewells, as I demonstrate in Chapter 5. They used

their monopoly role in credit, extension, and input provision to increase sales of inputs and

seeds despite the agroclimatic unsuitability of Bt cotton. Overall, Bt cotton in Kacharam in the

Liberalised Green Revolution saw the universal adoption of the crop but increased

indebtedness and yield stagnation in the long term, making farmers to rely on non-farm

incomes to make ends meet. This was the opposite of the linear increase in yields and structural

transformation as was expected by proponents of private sector led technology growth in

agriculture (Zhou, 2010).

In answering the research question: “What are the consequences of Bt cotton farming in the

Liberalised Green Revolution in Telangana?”, I will structure the chapter as follows. First, I

will analyse the antecedent events and decisions by farmers in Telangana and Kacharam for

adopting Bt cotton so rapidly in the early 2000s. Second, I will focus on the cotton outcomes

for farmers in Kacharam across different categories. Finally, I look at the processes involved

in its adoption and production and the constraints facing farming livelihoods in Telangana

before concluding.

Page 112: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

112

4.2 Economic motivations, ecology, and the switch to Bt cotton

Agriculture in Kacharam reflected much of semi-arid and dryland parts of rural India in the

centuries-long continuity of subsistence farming (Roy, 2007). Red laterite soils and fleeting

monsoon rains from June to September regulated the choice of crop to be drought resilient and

able to survive in poor soils (Gine et al, 2008). The emphasis of farming was on household

food security, and so sorghum and pearl millet were the traditional crops of Telangana under

rainfed and semi-arid environments. Sorghum and millets also provided fodder for livestock,

which in turn provided the fertiliser for growing crops (Freed and Freed, 2002). Seeds were

saved between each harvest and exchanged in kind for labour or food between different castes

according to their caste occupations e.g. cobblers, basket weavers, shepherds, pot makers, palm

wine makers and agricultural labourers. As a middle-aged male OBC farmer in Kacharam

explained:

“People used to grow mostly millets and castor…we also used to rely mostly on the

crops we grew…we didn’t used to go outside. There were no debts then people didn’t

have money so they would trade their food crops for other things they needed.” (C61,

farmer, 28/6/19)

The practice of exchanging seeds in kind for harvests from food crops or for labour between

castes in Kacharam were also the systems of exchange and subsistence livelihood elsewhere in

Telangana (Flachs, 2016). Soon however, growing subsistence crops became unviable at the

turn of the 1990s. Economic liberalisation brought markets to the forefront of agriculture and

rural society, affecting profound social and cultural change at the village level (Jodhka, 2014).

New options for goods and services entered the village, including private and English medium

schools (Kingdon, 2020), access to medical care and more expensive dowries for marriages in

the village, increasing household expenditure into the 1990s and creating a commercial society

in rural India (Jakobsen, 2018). Moreover, changing desires and aspirations for material

consumption through liberalisation in the 1990s and the diffusion of middle-class lifestyles in

nearby cities via migration labour also increased demand for durable goods such as motorbikes,

TVs, and mobile phones (Servet and Saiag, 2013). This matched the trends in rural Telangana

and India as spending on durable goods increased as a share of annual household spending

from 2.7% in 1993-4 to 6.1% in 2011-12 in India (NSSO, 2013d), as well as rising ownership

of TVs, mobile phones, and motorbikes in rural Telangana (NFHS, 2016).

Page 113: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

113

The entry of consumerism into the village necessitated a shift in the subsistence agricultural

system that prevailed in Kacharam, putting economic and social pressure on farmers to grow

commodity crops to keep up with rising household costs. As Louis (2015) also notes in her

ethnographic work in Medak district in Telangana, growing sorghum was no longer tenable for

farmers having to pay school fees, medical expenses, and dowry in a marketized society,

forcing farmers to adopt cash crop agriculture.

The entry of Bt cotton in Kacharam came in the early 2000s. Cotton was sought after as a cash

crop in semi-arid parts of India due to its high yields and market price. In the 1990s,

liberalisation in the entry of FDI for seeds, opening of the domestic cotton market for

international exports and the proliferation of private seed and input firms and widely available

informal credit brought cotton to the centre stage in rainfed regions of India, including

Telangana (Vakulabharanam, 2004).

Given the opportunity cost of switching to cotton, the aspiration and belief in the new profitable

cotton crop was often seen as the ticket to a better, more affluent life. As Herring (2008) notes

in Warangal district in Telangana, farmers are active participants in technological adoption and

higher incomes when it was made available to them. Moreover, the reality of subsistence

farming for many was a difficult livelihood of uncertainty and hardship. Farmer B7, an OBC

farmer with 1 ha land reflected on the drudgery and hardship of his parents. Farming in the past

was not a rural idyll, as he described:

“The family had to work hard we were hand to mouth then, [My] father worked even

harder [than me]…but the yield was not that high we used to take loans to eat food.”

(B7, farmer, 5/2/19)

The high market price of cotton and ability to grow it in rainfed conditions was the silver bullet

out of subsistence and into prosperity. Cotton was the only option for farmers for their financial

obligations but also was a symbol of upward mobility and desire, summed up by farmers by

the phrase “manchi kalam”, meaning a good life. Therefore, sorghum and millet cultivation

was juxtaposed by the potential market incentives of Bt cotton in Kacharam, and so the choice

to switch was a simple one. For an elderly female OBC farmer in Kacharam, the economic

incentives were too great to pass up compared to continuing with sorghum and millets:

“[Sorghum] did [bring food for the household] but cotton had a higher market price so

everyone switched to that. Sorghum, millets…their time has gone. Now it is the time

for cotton.” (B2, farmer, 2/5/19)

Page 114: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

114

The practical realities of subsistence farming in an increasingly marketized economy is also

echoed in other ethnographic work in Telangana. Reddy (2011) for example shows how

sorghum was only an option for farmers due to the lack of other available alternatives and

possibilities. Furthermore, Herring and Rao (2012) explain from Warangal district in

Telangana that farmers often had landholdings of less than 1 ha which required farmers to

maximise their returns from what they had, and cotton provided that as a high yielding cash

crop. Although farmers knew the high risk of capital and input intensive cotton agriculture, it

was a risk worth taking if it meant high market prices and a better life (Shah, 2012).

The economic incentive was significant for farmers to switch to Bt cotton in a rapidly

monetised consumer economy. On top, environmental push factors also played a role in

Kacharam. During interviews, 100% of the 65 participants reported that the gradual exhaustion

of sorghum and millet yields were due to their inability to control pests and predation of the

crop by birds. As one farmer recounted:

“No one else [is] planting sorghum if one person plants it then the birds will come and

we can’t plant alone”. (B11, farmer, 30/4/19)

Sorghum was an important food and fodder crop but also attracted birds which stripped fields.

Farmers needed their children to stand guard in the fields when the crop reached harvest time.

However, farmers in Kacharam felt that as their children now attended school, they no longer

had the labour to take care of the fields and look after livestock (B12, farmer, 1/5/19). In

addition, as more farmers grew Bt cotton, the task of protecting the crop against birds became

even harder, concentrating the pest problem on the remaining farmers growing subsistence

crops (Freed and Freed, 2002). The pest problem was compounded by the difficulty in

processing millets and castor, the secondary non-food crop grown before cotton in Kacharam.

Interviewee B3, an elderly female OBC farmer explained that in her parents’ generation women

primarily threshed the millets:

“It is easier now. They had to crush and thresh the seeds for millets it was very time

consuming they used to dry then pick the[m].” (B3, farmer, 1/5/19)

Interviewee B14, an elderly male OBC farmer concurred:

“For millets you have a lot of steps you have to deshell it process it carve it many things

then the birds eat it”. (B14, farmer, 1/5/19)

Page 115: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

115

The process of pressing castor into oil shared similarities in its difficulty for farmers.

Interviewee B2, an elderly female OBC farmer explained the difference in traditional crops

and Bt cotton when it came to harvest time:

“Now it is leisurely they plant cotton they come and take it from their house directly.

Now if you plant sorghum millets castor you have to dry it deshell it beat it pour liquid

on it that is hard work so we plant cotton.” (B2, farmer, 2/5/19)

In my interviews with farmers in Kacharam, it was evident that the elderly female farmers of

all castes felt that traditional crops were extremely laborious to process and the work was

gendered so females were tasked with this. The prospect of cotton being bought by the buyer

directly from the fields straight after harvest, plus at a higher market price was an easy choice

to make at the time to move away from sorghum and other prevailing crops grown in

Kacharam. Finally, the problems with crop predation were also compounded by the variability

in monsoons which often caused harvest failure in Kacharam, and remained a problem for Bt

cotton too.

The problems with sorghum and millets and changing market conditions in Kacharam lead to

the decline in cropping area for these traditional subsistence crops. The decline of sorghum and

millet farming is also seen in aggregate figures in Telangana and the Nalgonda, indicating the

changes in Kacharam to be representative of wider agrarian change. Figures 21 and 22 show

the absolute decline in area of sorghum and pearl millets in both Telangana and Nalgonda. As

Reddy et al (2014a) note, sorghum was the biggest crop grown traditionally in Telangana as a

rainfed food crop, making up almost 60% of the total cropped area in the 1960s. Due to changes

mentioned in this section, sorghum not only declined as a share of total cropped area but also

in absolute terms to less than 2% as of 2017 (DES Telangana, 2017).

Page 116: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

116

Figure 21 - Telangana Sorghum and Pearl Millet Net Area 1955-2018

Source: DES Andhra Pradesh (2006), DES Telangana (2016), DES India (2018; 2019a, b)

Figure 22 - Nalgonda Sorghum and Pearl Millet Net Area 1955-2018

Source: DES Andhra Pradesh (2006), DES Telangana (2016), DES India (2018; 2019a, b)

Rising household expenditure, environmental factors and changing aspirations and economic

incentives drove the shift away from subsistence farming to Bt cotton in Kacharam.

0

200000

400000

600000

800000

1000000

1200000

1400000

1600000

1800000

20000001

95

5-5

6

195

7-5

8

195

9-6

0

1961-6

2

196

3-6

4

196

5-6

6

196

7-6

8

196

9-7

0

197

1-7

2

197

3-7

4

197

5-7

6

197

7-7

8

197

9-8

0

198

1-8

2

198

3-8

4

198

5-8

6

198

7-8

8

198

9-9

0

199

1-9

2

199

3-9

4

199

5-9

6

199

7-9

8

199

9-0

0

200

1-0

2

200

3-0

4

200

5-0

6

200

7-0

8

200

9-1

0

201

1-1

2

201

3-1

4

201

5-1

6

201

7-1

8

Hec

atre

s

Year

Telangana Sorghum Telangana Pearl Millet

0

50000

100000

150000

200000

250000

300000

195

5-5

6

195

7-5

8

195

9-6

0

196

1-6

2

196

3-6

4

196

5-6

6

1967-6

8

196

9-7

0

197

1-7

2

197

3-7

4

197

5-7

6

197

7-7

8

197

9-8

0

198

1-8

2

198

3-8

4

198

5-8

6

198

7-8

8

198

9-9

0

199

1-9

2

199

3-9

4

199

5-9

6

199

7-9

8

199

9-0

0

2001-0

2

200

3-0

4

200

5-0

6

200

7-0

8

200

9-1

0

201

1-1

2

201

3-1

4

201

5-1

6

201

7-1

8

Hec

tare

s

Year

Nalgonda Sorghum Nalgonda Pearl Millet

Page 117: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

117

4.3 The rise of Bt cotton in Telangana

This section outlines the political economy conditions in which cotton adoption took place in

Kacharam and Telangana. Andhra Pradesh was one of the first states in India to introduce Bt

cotton after approval in 2002. For the Chief Minister Chandra Babu Naidu, adopting

biotechnology was a key step to agricultural modernisation, part of the “Vision 2020” plan for

the state government to reform agriculture from subsistence to export oriented commercial

cropping.

As Bowles (2003: p421-422) describes:

“Regarding, biotechnology, Naidu has said, “I want [Andhra Pradesh] to be [number

one] in biotech. That is our goal. I think we are marching ahead”. In its effort to become

the new headquarters of biotechnology, the state has implemented incentives such as

“single-window” system for biotechnology licensing and approvals…Andhra Pradesh

has adopted a development plan, Vision 2020, which includes an outline of the state’s

long term plans and goals for biotechnology and for agriculture. Vision 2020 calls for

Andhra Pradesh to become a powerhouse of Indian agriculture…as agriculture itself

becomes more productive, efficient and technology intensive, and moves from a

subsistence activity to an economic one.”

The state government’s vision was to facilitate private sector biotechnology for the structural

transformation of the state towards commercial farming for economic growth, much alike the

Maharashtra and Gujarat did during the Liberalised Green Revolution (Shah, 2005; 2008; 2011;

Chaudhuri, 2019).

In Kacharam, farmers began adopting Bt cotton in the early 2000s soon after its approval in

India. Local input dealers in nearby towns began to market and sell Bt cotton seeds, which

spread via word of mouth in the village. After being adopted by higher class farmers in the

village, other farmers began imitating and adopting Bt cotton. This also reflects the trajectory

of Bt cotton diffusion in Maharashtra (Maertens, 2017). In under two decades, Bt cotton

increased cotton adoption in Kacharam from 0% to 100% across all castes, classes and gender

categories. Furthermore, 85% of the 105 farming households in the village planted Bt cotton

as a monocrop. For smallholder farmers in Telangana, Bt cotton was a high market price cash

crop that could survive high temperatures in semi-arid conditions (Ramamurthy, 2011).

Informal credit access also helped them finance cotton investments with no collateral and small

landholding sizes (Stone and Flachs, 2018).

Page 118: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

118

The rapid increase of Bt cotton also occurred at the Nalgonda district level and Telangana as

shown in Figures 23 and 24 below. In particular, after Bt cotton’s introduction in 2002, the

cotton area increased by almost 5x by 2019 in Nalgonda and by 3x in Telangana. In Nalgonda

district, Bt cotton by 2019 made up 49% of the total cropped area, reflecting the rapid expansion

of cotton in Kacharam in just two decades. In Telangana, Bt cotton area increased to almost 2

million hectares by 2019, becoming the single biggest crop by area in the state at 32% of the

total cropped area (DES Telangana, 2020), more than rice which only made up 20%. Bt cotton

also drove Telangana to become the third biggest cotton grower in India via smallholder

farmers (DES India, 2018).

Figure 23 - Telangana Cotton Area 1955-2018

Source: DES Andhra Pradesh (2006), DES Telangana (2016), DES India (2018; 2019a, b)

0

200000

400000

600000

800000

1000000

1200000

1400000

1600000

1800000

2000000

195

5-5

6

195

7-5

8

195

9-6

0

196

1-6

2

196

3-6

4

196

5-6

6

196

7-6

8

196

9-7

0

197

1-7

2

197

3-7

4

197

5-7

6

197

7-7

8

197

9-8

0

198

1-8

2

198

3-8

4

198

5-8

6

198

7-8

8

198

9-9

0

199

1-9

2

199

3-9

4

199

5-9

6

199

7-9

8

199

9-0

0

200

1-0

2

200

3-0

4

200

5-0

6

200

7-0

8

200

9-1

0

201

1-1

2

2013-1

4

201

5-1

6

201

7-1

8

Hec

tare

s

Year

Page 119: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

119

Figure 24 - Nalgonda Cotton Area 1955-2018

Source: DES Andhra Pradesh (2006), DES Telangana (2016), DES India (2018; 2019a, b)

This chapter argues that in a deregulated seeds market, thousands of private sector input firms

quickly entered the market and iterated, duplicated the original Bt cotton strain from Monsanto-

Mahyco (Bownas, 2016). In Kacharam, farmers followed early adopter high caste/class farmers

by hierarchical learning, as well being enticed by the high market price (Maertens, 2017).

However, Bt cotton also required annual repurchasing of seeds plus intensive capital and input

investments. Furthermore, the absence of extension services from government also meant

farmers relied on input dealers for advice who prescribed intensive application of inputs and

purchasing new seed brands as the solution to farmer’s harvest failures, instead of advising on

the problem of leaving the crop to be rainfed. Reflecting changes at the district and state level,

increasingly variable and declining monsoons for rainfed Bt cotton made it prone to frequent

harvest failures and rising indebtedness. For the year 2018, household surveys revealed that

65% of all households made a loss from Bt cotton across all castes, classes, and genders.

However, flexible credit terms from moneylenders kept supplying credit to farmers to renew

loans annually as long as they repaid the interest repayment.

0

100000

200000

300000

400000

500000

6000001955-5

6

1957-5

8

1959-6

0

1961-6

2

1963-6

4

1965-6

6

1967-6

8

1969-7

0

1971-7

2

1973-7

4

1975-7

6

1977-7

8

1979-8

0

1981-8

2

1983-8

4

1985-8

6

1987-8

8

1989-9

0

1991-9

2

1993-9

4

1995-9

6

1997-9

8

1999-0

0

2001-0

2

2003-0

4

2005-0

6

2007-0

8

2009-1

0

2011-1

2

2013-1

4

2015-1

6

2017-1

8

Hec

tare

s

Year

Page 120: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

120

Desperate to recoup their losses, farmers risked further Bt cotton investments and loans,

increasing their debt burden and interest repayments further. Many farmers were entrapped in

interlocked factor markets, where they purchased inputs on credit and sold their harvests to pay

back their loans (Harriss-White, 2020). Extension advice to keep replanting new varieties and

apply inputs more intensively increased interest repayments too (Aga, 2018). Given 85% of all

farmers grew Bt cotton as a monocrop, hedging all their bets increasingly failed to bring the

income needed for meeting household expenditure. Within two decades in the Liberalised

Green Revolution, farmers depended on selling assets or working in non-farm wage labour to

stay afloat with debt repayments from Bt cotton. The following sections explore the

consequences of Bt cotton adoption and failed outcomes.

4.3.1 Cotton outcomes in Kacharam and Telangana

Bt cotton came to Kacharam and Telangana in the early 2000s soon after its introduction in

India through thousands of local level input dealers who set up in towns peripheral to villages.

For example, in Kacharam, the nearby town of Devarakonda had just three input shops up until

the 2000s, but after Bt cotton was introduced, the number of input dealers quickly increased to

15 by the year 2019. A local fertiliser shop owner corroborated this:

“[Only two input dealers were there before Bt] after Bt came there were many.”

(C21, input dealer, 4/6/19)

Input dealers began promoting and marketing Bt cotton to nearby villages, as well as increasing

input shops and spreading adoption through word of mouth and targeting the largest

landholders in the village. I observed that seed firms also promoted Bt cotton and pesticides

through TV adverts featuring celebrity endorsements, encompassing both a local and national

level push to maximise Bt cotton adoption. Figures 25 and 26 show some of the examples of

Bt cotton marketing.

Page 121: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

121

Figure 25 - Celebrity Bt Cotton TV Advert 1

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Figure 26 - Celebrity Bt Cotton TV Advert 2

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 122: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

122

The culmination of marketing efforts from input dealers provided the impetus for farmers to

switch. Many input firms sold not only seed but also diversified as into selling inputs and credit.

Farmers often bought seeds and inputs on credit and sold back their harvest to the input dealer

at an advanced fixed market price plus 24-36% annual interest in an interlocked factor market

(Jaleta et al, 2009; Taylor, 2013b). This financing mechanism made it possible for smallholder

farmers with minimal assets and collateral to invest in Bt cotton. From the farmer’s perspective,

the economic necessity to leave subsistence farming, higher market prices and farmers

observing the adoption of the crop by neighbours started the wave of adoption throughout the

village. This was emphatically stated by an elderly female farmer OBC farmer who witnessed

the rapid transition to Bt cotton in the village, confirmed also with 50 out of 65 (77%) farmers

in interviews:

“Everyone plants cotton now… cotton had a higher market price so everyone switched

to that one by one people switched.” (B2, farmer, 2/5/19)

The ability to access Bt cotton was universal amongst farming households due to the proximity

of input dealers in Devarakonda less than 15km away and as input dealers sold inputs on credit.

Hence after hearing about Bt cotton, farmers could adopt it quickly and finance it for the short

term. This trend of Bt cotton adoption in Kacharam followed other examples in the state of

Telangana. Dev and Rao’s (2007) study in Nalgonda and Warangal districts found that the most

common way for Bt cotton to spread was for farmers to imitate their neighbours at 46%. In

their work in Warangal, Stone et al (2014) referred to the flood of Bt cotton as farmers

“following the herd”, basing adoption on what their neighbours were planting, regardless of

whether it was successful.

Farming was conducted as a household unit for cotton mono cropping households, with the

husband and wife dividing different tasks within cotton production process. This is compared

to farming production systems in other contexts in India and Africa whereby the male usually

grows the cash crop and the female grows the household food crops (Rao et al, 2020). In

Kacharam, the men tilled the soil with tractors, weeded with oxen, distributed the seeds,

purchased the inputs and sprayed pesticides. The females picked the cotton at the harvest period

and also weeded but by hand.

In the first five years after adoption, Bt cotton brought the expected yields and profits for all

classes and castes of farmers, confirmed by 55 out of 65 (85%) interviewees. Even though the

cost of cultivation was high, the yields compensated for investments. Farmer C57, a middle

Page 123: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

123

aged OBC divorcee woman with 1 ha land, detailed the prosperity Bt cotton brought to her

family after initially planting crop, stating:

“After cotton came, [life] was better [as] we had [economic] security. We couldn’t

repay any debts [back] then we had poor houses and lived in poverty. After cotton came,

I could repay debts and buy some land….the expenses are higher but it is better now as

we can make money with cotton.” (C57, farmer, 10/6/19).

Bt cotton in initial years delivered higher incomes and profits than subsistence crops, allowing

farmers to reinvest their profits into their household, as well as being able to repay debts. For

the initial years of Bt cotton, the high input costs were compensated by incomes and the

freedom to improve their economic situation, something which subsistence farming did not

provide. Looking to Telangana more widely, Rao and Dev (2007) found in Nalgonda and

Warangal districts that yields from Bt cotton increased 32% relative to non-Bt cotton, with net

incomes increasing by 83%. However, they also found that while pesticide costs reduced by

18% via Bt cotton’s in-built pest resistance to the bollworm pest, overall production costs

increased by 17% from rising costs from seeds and labour for sowing, pollinating, and

harvesting the crop (ibid). Similarly, Stone (2011) studied four villages from 2003-7 in

Warangal district, finding a yield increase of 18% and decrease in pesticide usage with Bt

cotton relative to existing cotton varieties.

Bt cotton’s positive returns in Kacharam however stopped after five years of planting, with

farmers finding that monsoon variability and declining quantity of rainfall over the years made

harvest failures more common. For the year 2018, household surveys I conducted suggested

that 65% of farmers across all social categories of class, caste and gender made a loss from Bt

cotton. This was based on a 98% sample representative of the entire village. Table 6 below

presents the outcomes from Bt cotton in Kacharam for 2018 in more detail.

Page 124: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

124

Table 6 - Bt Cotton Outcomes

Category Total

Farming

Households

Average

Area

(Ha)

Profit

(%)

Break

Even

(%)

Loss

(%)

Average

Income

Per Ha

($)

Average

Expenses

Per Ha

($)

Net

Income

Per Ha

($)

All Farmers 105 1.45 33 (31) 4 (4) 68 (65) 411 511 -102

OBC 74 1.60 25 (34) 4 (5) 45 (61) 409 510 -106

SC 23 1.07 6 (26) 0 (0) 17 (74) 447 521 -112

ST 8 1.11 2 (25) 0 (0) 6 (75) 347 502 -126

Widow 11 1.11 5 (45) 0 (0) 6 (55) 485 494 -8

Non-Widow 94 1.49 26 (26) 4 (4) 64 (69) 396 513 -117

Marginal (<1

ha)

33 0.57 11 (33) 2 (6) 20 (61) 698 837 -209

Small (1-2 ha) 56 1.56 19 (34) 2 (3) 35 (63) 433 534 -101

Medium

(>2-5 ha)

16 2.63 3 (19) 0 (0) 13 (81) 278 367 -89

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019).

The lack of social differentiation across all castes, classes, and genders in losses from Bt cotton

meant that yields across all farmers were badly hit, enough to result in negative net incomes.

Rather than 2018 being just a one-off bad harvest year in Kacharam, 50 out of 65 (77%) farmers

interviewed consistently reported that the problem of Bt cotton failures was a recurrent

phenomenon in the last four to five years.

The specific problem for farmers in Kacharam were erratic monsoons afflicting Bt cotton in

recent years. Farmer C2, an elderly OBC female farmer with 0.1 ha of land, lost $182 in 2018,

which she put down to worsening rainfall:

“We didn't get enough rainfall to have a good harvest and recover our investments. It

is not because of pests in fact only if there was a lot of rainfall would there be a problem

of pests. The problem we have is that we plant the seeds anticipating the rainfall but

then the rain comes sporadically and the seeds dry up. We cannot plant a second time

and try again as it is too late by now.” (C2, farmer, 12/6/19)

Dev and Rao (2007) observed that Bt cotton grown in rainfed villages in in Telangana during

the year 2004-5 also had equal losses between all castes, classes and genders as input costs

exceeded yields. With Bt cotton, the differences between farmer yields in rainfed areas were

limited as monsoon rains affected yields for all groups equally. Farmer C2 recognised pests to

Page 125: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

125

also be an issue causing poor yields, but Bt cotton drying up midway through the harvest was

more of a problem. In a household survey 57 out of 65 (87%) farmers interviewed felt that

monsoons were worsening with increasing frequency in the last five years, leaving their debt

fuelled investments in fertiliser, seeds, and pesticides to become unrealised and forcing them

to rely on non-farm incomes to make up for the losses. Good Bt cotton yields depended on at

least 500mm of rainfall in the monsoon season over four months through from June to October

(Sharma et al, 2018), which is higher than the Nalgonda district average of 474mm (CGWB

Telangana, 2019). This account from farmer C56, an OBC female farmer with 1.5 ha whose

household made a loss of $367 in 2018, noted the temporality of Bt cotton yields:

“Since we have planted cotton initially it has been good but only if there is rain…for

the last four years we haven’t had good harvests from cotton…we haven’t been able to

absorb input costs….we made a loss this year. The lack of rainfall is the biggest problem

we face now.” (C56, farmer, 11/6/19)

Semi-arid areas are characterised by hot and dry weather all year round and a growing period

of only four months from June to September, as 70-80% of total rainfall each year fell during

this period (DES Telangana, 2016). The rainfed environment was also compounded by

Telangana’s frequent periods of drought in the monsoon season, making even monsoons

unreliable to grow rainfed crops. In the last 30 years in Telangana for example, every single

year has seen a drought in an at least one sub-district region (ibid). This meant that even in

good monsoon years, drought still occurred within Telangana.

Figure 27 - Dried-up Bt Cotton Field in Mid Monsoon in June 2019

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 126: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

126

The entry of Bt cotton in the village brought the promises of high market prices and profitability

from a cash crop, an option farmers never before. Each Bt cotton harvest involved large

investments to be recouped as a minimum to make a profit and for the gamble to pay off. In

2018, 69% of farmers made a loss or broke even from farming, so the gamble didn’t pay off

due to worsening monsoons. The expectation of a good monsoon in Kacharam used to be a

regular occurrence during subsistence agriculture, but with cotton, it was hit and miss. Bt

cotton’s main draw was the possibility of high yields and profits for the adopting farmer, but

this did not come to fruition if the crop did not get enough rainfall. For farmer B6, a young

OBC farmer with 1.5 ha, 2018 brought Bt cotton losses of $212, pushing her to work in

agricultural labour in the dry season and her husband as a stonemason to make up for the losses.

She revealed:

“There is a good rate for cotton but it is useless if the cotton doesn't grow… if we had

good yields then yes we would benefit from it but that hasn't been the case now for

many years.” (B6, farmer, 24/6/19)

In addition to the rainfall problems, other authors mention that new pests outside of the

bollworm developed resistance to Bt cotton, so even if there was good rainfall, yields were still

low due to pests (Kranthi and Stone, 2020). Bt cotton is a very fickle crop to grow in rainfed

conditions, requiring consistent rainfall and application of pesticides and fertiliser at various

stages of the four-month growing cycle between June and September. As Gray and Dowd-

Uribe (2013: p696-697) found in semi-arid smallholder Bt cotton environments in Burkina

Faso:

“Cotton is a risky crop. Farmers can do most things right and still be at risk of a poor

harvest. Many of the risks are environmental and thus out of a farmer's direct control.

Drought at crucial points in the plant's lifecycle can reduce yields.”

If at any stage of the growing process Bt cotton did not receive enough rainfall, it would dry

up. In addition to the quantity and consistency of rainfall over time, the timing of the rainfall

was also crucial for farmers. In the fieldwork year of 2019 for example, farmers did not plant

cotton at all even as late as July 31st, meaning that adequate rainfall did not arrive even two

months after the traditional June start. In an interview with farmer C23, an elderly OBC female

with 1 ha, she revealed that in 2019 the monsoons were over a month late, not falling even

towards the end of June, when they were usually expected to come in late May:

Page 127: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

127

“…We haven't even started planting this year the rains are so late.” (C23, farmer,

18/6/19)

The growing season of Bt cotton had to match the monsoon rains. If it was delayed, the harvest

would not come as the monsoon became weaker into October, unable to sustain a harvest (Gine

et al, 2008). If the growing season was delayed by more than two weeks, it damaged the harvest

that year. For the thesis, I used long-term district level monsoon trends in Nalgonda and

Telangana as indications of what is happening to the quantity of monsoon rainfall in Kacharam,

owing to a lack of village level rainfall data. Figures 28 and 29 below shows the trends for both

Nalgonda district and Telangana. In both cases, the long-term trend lines slope downwards

overt time, in agreement with farmers sentiments in Kacharam, confirming qualitative insights

into how farmers have experienced a declining monsoon.

Figure 28 - Telangana Monsoon Rainfall 1951-2016

Source: DES Andhra Pradesh (2006), DES Telangana (2016)

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

19

51

19

53

19

55

1957

19

59

19

61

19

63

19

65

19

67

19

69

19

71

19

73

19

75

19

77

19

79

19

81

19

83

19

85

19

87

19

89

19

91

19

93

19

95

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

20

09

20

11

20

13

20

15

Ra

infa

ll (

mm

)

Year

Actual

Linear (Actual)

Page 128: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

128

Figure 29 - Nalgonda Monsoon Rainfall 1951-2016

Source: DES Andhra Pradesh (2006), DES Telangana (2016)

Longitudinal meteorological analysis by Shashikala (2015) in Nalgonda district also reveals

that between 1988-2012, 18 out of 25 years had below average rainfall years. Finally,

longitudinal ethnographic studies in Mahabubnagar district between 1990 and 2013 found that

farmers perceived monsoons were getting more erratic and declining over time in 2013 relative

to the 1990s study visit (Surendra et al, 2014). An econometric model by Guntukula (2020)

shows that 76% of cotton yields are determined by climate variables, in particular rainfall and

temperatures, so cotton yields decrease with lower rainfall and temperatures. With climate

change, rainfall variability, climate shocks and higher temperatures are set to reduce

agricultural productivity between 10% and 40% by 2100, with Bt cotton production predicted

to decline by 15-25% by 2050 (ICRIER, 2018). This makes rainfed Bt cotton cultivation an

even riskier economic prospect in the future than what we have seen in Kacharam.

The culmination of declining quantity, consistency and timing of monsoon rainfall has been

the socio-ecological driver of declining Bt cotton yields in Kacharam. The phenomenon of

declining Bt cotton yields in Telangana has been posited as a pest problem for Stone and Flachs

(2015), who noted that new pests emerged after 2007 in Warangal that halted Bt cotton yield

growth. However, in Kacharam, declining monsoons in a rainfed environment mainly caused

Bt cotton to dry up. This was shown clearly by the 65% losses across all groups of farmers and

the failure of rains to arrive in 2019 even up to July 31st, as farmers abandoned the Bt cotton

crop as a result.

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

140019

51

19

53

19

55

19

57

19

59

19

61

19

63

19

65

19

67

19

69

19

71

19

73

19

75

19

77

19

79

19

81

19

83

19

85

19

87

19

89

19

91

19

93

19

95

19

97

19

99

20

01

20

03

20

05

20

07

20

09

20

11

20

13

20

15

Ra

infa

ll (

mm

)

Year

Actual

Linear (Actual)

Page 129: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

129

Bt cotton outcomes in Kacharam over time have seen fleeting successes followed by persistent

failures. More broadly, Kranthi and Stone (2020) argue that Bt cotton yields have stagnated at

a Telangana and India level while input costs in seeds, fertiliser and pesticides have all

continued to intensify, due to erratic rainfall and pests in semi-arid growing environments such

as Telangana. This is also backed by the aggregate trends in Bt cotton across Nalgonda and

Telangana. Figure 30 below shows that after consistent increases in Bt cotton from the early

2000s, Bt cotton yields peaked in Telangana in 2008 at 460kg/ha. After this period, yields

stagnated, never reaching this peak again as of 2018, the latest year for recorded data. In

Nalgonda, Figure 31 shows Bt cotton yields increased up to the year 2014 at 393kg/ha, and

since this peak has declined and stagnated (Vakulabharanam, 2004; DES India, 2019a, b). Both

the trends in Nalgonda and Telangana reflect the farmer’s sentiments in Kacharam of declining

yields in the last five years.

Figure 30 - Telangana Cotton Yields 1970-2018

Source: Vakulabharanam (2004) and DES India (2019a, b)

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

500

Yie

ld (

Kg

/Hec

tare

)

Year

Telangana Cotton Yields 1970-2018

Page 130: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

130

Figure 31 - Nalgonda Cotton Yields 1970-2018

Source: Vakulabharanam (2004) and DES India (2019a, b)

Overall, Bt cotton did not deliver the results it promised in Kacharam and Telangana, creating

a non-farm reliance in the long run. Despite the rapid spread and adoption by 100% of farmers

in the village, the Liberalised Green Revolution technology has resulted in a brief rise followed

by a sustained and deep stagnation in yields and outcomes. In Kacharam, this resulted in 65%

of farmers across all classes, castes and genders making a loss from Bt cotton in 2018,

corroborating with other village level studies in Telangana and aggregate data at the state and

district levels. Decreasing rainfall in the monsoon season as well as increasingly erratic timing

of rainfall in the monsoon made harvest failures common for Bt cotton. Monsoon data from

the state and district level as well as longitudinal ethnographic evidence has also corroborated

the declining rainfall in Kacharam. The next section will look at political economy factors of

why this occurred and the consequences for farmer livelihoods, alongside the socio-ecological

factors already discussed. It explores the role of informal debt and input dealers as input seller,

credit provider and extension advisor in a deregulated Bt cotton market.

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

Yie

ld (

Kg

/Hec

tare

)

Year

Nalgonda Cotton Yields 1970-2018

Page 131: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

131

4.3.2 The consequences of Bt cotton failure in Kacharam and Telangana

The shift to cotton changed many things in Kacharam in a space of two decades. For the 85%

of farmers in Kacharam who grew it as a monocrop, it shifted the purpose of farming from

household food security and fodder to cash cropping for profitability. Bt cotton fetched a high

market price at $73 per 100kg, 3-5x the returns from traditional food crops (Dhanagare, 2016).

However, due to monsoon variability, farmers largely could not recoup these prices from the

input and seed investments they put into the crop. Profit, and you can overlook the costs of Bt

cotton and live on to the next harvest, but lose, then you face a torrent of insurmountable

problems.

Interlocking debt relations with input dealers added to the problem of Bt cotton. Most farmers

were unable to afford the cost of Bt cotton investments, so purchased seeds, fertiliser, and

pesticides on credit from input dealers. At the end of the harvest season, farmers sold their

cotton harvest at fixed price to the input dealer plus 24%-36% annual interest charged on top

of the repayment. Profits made net of these costs was could be used for household expenditure,

reinvestment, or savings. In recent years however, Bt cotton crop harvests increasingly failed

from erratic monsoons. This forced farmers to extend loans for another year from input dealers,

hoping that next year’s harvest repaid all the cumulative debts for the farmer. As that harvest

has increasingly not arrived, farmers have become engrained in debt relationships with input

dealers each time a Bt cotton crop fails (Gray and Dowd-Uribe, 2013). This perpetual debt

relation between input dealers and farmers represents a cycle of economic discipline and

control (Gerber, 2013; Vasquez, 2020) in the Liberalised Green Revolution. This has been

propagated by unreliable monsoons and harvests, high capital risks and cumulative interest

accruals from each loan.

Furthermore, the rollback of extension services in Telangana in the Liberalised Green

Revolution has also left farmers to depend on input dealers for extension advice. Profit

incentives from the input dealers however saw them recommending intensive application of

inputs, while leaving Bt cotton to be rainfed in Kacharam’s risky agroecological environment

to enter agricultural commercialisation. This final section therefore explores how these input

firms acted as input dealers, credit firms and extension officers to exacerbate the agroecological

risks from cultivating Bt cotton in a semi-arid environment.

Page 132: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

132

4.3.3 Debt, risk and loss of economic control of rural livelihoods from Bt cotton

For farmers, yields were insufficient relative to the input expenses they invested, making them

indebted from Bt cotton. The short-term credit dispersal for inputs enabled farmers to access

the seeds and inputs to cultivate Bt cotton, but farmers pinned their debt repayment hopes on

its high yields (Srinivasulu, 2015). If farmers were unable to repay, the input lender renewed

the loan for another year for the next harvest with 24% to 36% interest on top. Farmer B2, an

elderly OBC farmer cultivating just 0.13 ha, lost $183 from Bt cotton in 2018, receiving 10x

lower yields than she expected at only 200kg, pushing her family to renew their loans from

input dealers until next year and use non-farm incomes to repay the interest amount. She

explained:

“Profit or loss we have to deal with it. [The input dealer] does not [relieve] a rupee of

the loan he adds it onto the next year he takes 3% interest per month.” (B2, farmer,

5/2/19)

If the farmer profits, then the inputs and interest is repaid, and the farmer takes a new loan out

for the coming season. If a farmer faces a harvest loss, they face short-term calm, being obliged

only to repay the interest immediately. This only delays the debt as interest accumulates into

the next harvest year. Although Bt cotton promised profitability, it also concentrated the risk

into one crop as harvest failures increased indebtedness amongst all farmers. Indebtedness in

Kacharam reflects the rise in rural indebtedness overall in Telangana. Between 2002 and 2013

for example, average rural debt in Telangana increased almost 6x across all size classes (Reddy,

2014). Telangana has among the highest rural indebtedness rates in India at 89%, compared to

an all-India average of 57% (NSSOa, 2013). This has been linked to a large extent to cash crop

cultivation and intensification such as Bt cotton by smallholders who adopted it rapidly in

recent decades (Kranthi and Stone, 2020).

Gray and Dowd-Uribe (2013: p699) explain the process of interlocked debt relations with Bt

cotton in semi-arid smallholder settings in Burkina Faso:

“Poorer farmers, dependent on cotton production for income and access to inputs, face

cycles of indebtedness, responding to deficits in their biophysical environment by self-

exploiting and mortgaging their crops to fulfil needs for both improved soil quality and

household livelihoods. Once indebted, farmers have diminished access to inputs on

Page 133: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

133

credit, inhibiting their ability to pay back their cotton loans and making them more

prone to fall into debt again.”

Bt cotton was a capital intensive and debt fuelled cash crop that at one stage promised

profitability but increasingly failed to deliver in Kacharam, leaving farmers with debt. Yet they

were compelled to invest in Bt cotton to repay their debt and interest obligations and face

environmental uncertainty and risk of further debt from monsoon conditions referred to as a

“reproductive squeeze” (Watts, 1983; Green, 2019). The process of rural indebtedness in this

way created a self-reinforcing cycle, where the farmer fell into further debt each time they had

a harvest failure.

In less than two decades since its introduction, Bt transformed the agricultural landscape of

semi-arid and rainfed Telangana to become the single biggest cultivated crop in Nalgonda at

49% of the total cropped area and 32% for Telangana (DES India, 2019a, b). As Nagaraj et al

(2014) explain however, the shift to Bt cotton in the long run has only increased crop instability

and vulnerability by hedging all their bets on high input and high capital crops in a severely

agroecologically constrained environment.

In recognition of the indebtedness problems from informal credit in Telangana, efforts to

improve financial inclusion in India and Telangana have seen the expansion of formal rural

credit through banks and microcredit. Between 2007 and 2013 for example, the share of

institutional credit increased in rural Telangana from 33% to 50% across all classes (Reddy,

2014). In Telangana, this financial inclusion effort tried to reach lower castes such as OBCs,

STs and SCs who made up almost 90% of the state’s population (Benbabaali, 2016) in addition

to smallholder farmers owning <2ha land who made up 85% of the state’s farmers (DES

Telangana, 2016). Bank account access for ST, SCs and OBCs reached a high of 71% in

Telangana and 80% in Nalgonda district in 2013 (Kannibiran et al, 2017).

In Kacharam however, this increase in formal credit access belied the crucial role informal

credit plays (Guerin et al, 2012; 2013). Despite the expansion and availability of formal credit

which offered lower interest rates of 12-24% per year, farmers preferred input dealers to

finance Bt cotton for several reasons. First, microcredit and bank credit had strict collateral

terms based on landholdings and repayment timelines to repay the principle plus interest to

secure a new loan (Taylor, 2011; 2012). Microcredit also often only issued smaller loans of up

to $750 per year, which only just covered the total cost of Bt cotton expenses each year of $746

in Kacharam. These conditions were onerous on the farmer especially if they faced harvest

Page 134: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

134

losses. Furthermore, farmers reported large amounts of paperwork, bribery and time taken to

get bank loans issued for low caste and low-class farmers relative to richer, more well-

connected farmers (C36, SC farmer, 21/6/19).

In comparison, input dealers offered to renew current loans even if the principle was untouched,

if the interest repayments were on time. For farmers, input dealers’ flexibility in offering new

loans without repayment allowed farmers to borrow to cover harvest failures. Farmers were

willing to tread water and pay off the interest year on year even though the interest rates charged

were much higher at up to 36% per year compared to 24% for formal sources. The calculus of

taking credit from input dealers in times of harvest failures was rationalised by farmer C56, an

elderly OBC female farmer, who last achieved a good Bt cotton harvest four years ago:

“The issue is we can't find loans [from banks] on time when we need them, we need to

therefore go to moneylenders even if it [is] higher interest. The bank doesn't lend when

we need it, but the moneylender does.” (C56, farmer, 11/6/19)

For cash poor farmers, input dealers were the unanimous choice for Bt cotton financing, despite

the cycles of indebtedness they created. The ability to extend the debt repayments to another

year and reinvest in Bt cotton by taking out new loans was a highly risky decision, but it also

offered temporary relief from debt repayment pressures. Furthermore, the sheer number of

input dealers in nearby towns to Kacharam made accessing credit the fastest and easiest

method. Informal credit was preferred to formal sources even though farmers knew they were

trapped in a cycle of debt if harvests failed. For informal creditors, it was also in their interest

to sustain credit flows year on year and keep interest repayments coming than foreclose on

farmer collateral if they fail to repay (Ramamurthy, 2011; Gerber, 2013). The maintenance of

a large customer base repaying interest was preferred to losing customers, as farmer C61, a

middle aged OBC farmer who last made a profit from Bt cotton three years ago explained:

“We pay the interest we don't have the money to pay the principle. That is what the

brokers want too they don't want you to pay the principle they want you to pay the

interest.” (C61, farmer, 28/6/19)

The prevalence of informal credit is also confirmed in Telangana wide aggregate statistics.

Among small and marginal farmers in Telangana, a national sample survey found that 46% of

the total cotton sold in 2013 was via input dealers (NSSO, 2013c). In addition, informal

moneylenders made up 53% of all credit in rural Telangana in 2013 across low caste OBCs,

ST and SC households (ibid). Finally, the amount of credit invested in informal moneylenders

Page 135: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

135

for agricultural and other purposes in rural Telangana was between 2-5x higher than in banks

(Kannibiran et al, 2017), indicating the importance of input dealers and informal credit for rural

households in Telangana.

The preference for moneylenders did not take away from the overall indebtedness crisis caused

by Bt cotton, but merely delayed it. As Taylor (2011: p494) explains, the process of smallholder

agricultural intensification saw:

“engrained and hierarchical social relationships on the basis of class, caste and gender,

in which debt plays a key role in structuring the appropriation of agrarian surpluses and

in consolidating relationships of domination.”

As adopting farmers were also from the poorest classes and OBC, SC and ST castes, it

represented a constellation of conjugated oppression of class and caste (Lerche and Shah,

2018). Compared to the original Green Revolution, debt in the Liberalised Green Revolution

with Bt cotton was marketized and unsubsidised and the only route out was by participating in

the market again to get a successful Bt cotton harvest the following year. This was relative to

the original Green Revolution where the government subsidised inputs and targeted favourable

growing environments (Stone, 2019). Therein, the economic losses felt by farmers with Bt

cotton were far more severe and consequential for debt and risk relative to previous generations

in the Green Revolution. The switch to Bt cotton in Kacharam promised higher prices and

higher yields than sorghum, in exchange for higher expenses to cultivate it. Yet now, as farmer

B15 described, with a young family to feed, higher expenses in keeping the household running

and diminishing returns from the high cultivation costs of Bt cotton, farmers today faced the

worst of both worlds:

“Back then the income was low but costs were also low now the income is low and

costs are high”. (B15, farmer, 5/4/19).

Previously, farmers had minimal returns from sorghum but also minimal costs from cultivation,

sourcing seeds, oxen labour and fertiliser from within the farm. With Bt cotton, high input costs

and climatic extremes caused harvest failures and deepened interlocked debt relations in

Telangana (Ramprasad, 2017). Losses from Bt cotton in Kacharam unfolded in the worst way

possible, leaving farmers in a worse position than prior to planting the crop with regards to

trenchant indebtedness problems. The final section of this chapter explains the key role of input

dealers acting as moneylender, salesperson and extension advisor in driving the continued cycle

Page 136: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

136

of Bt cotton cultivation. This has worsened smallholder farmers’ economic and agroecological

fragility and caused them to survive off the farm.

4.3.4 Input dealer, moneylender, and extension advisor

Market intermediaries such as input dealers have been the key driver of agricultural

commercialisation in the Liberalised Green Revolution, stepping in to fill the government’s

role in credit, seeds, inputs, and extension services. Through the mechanism of interlocked

factor markets, they provide credit for inputs for cash poor smallholders to invest in and a

guaranteed output market by buying the harvest back from the farmer. I claim that local market

intermediaries are the key enabler of agricultural technologies such as Bt cotton to spread to

semi-arid settings, driven by a profit ethos in each of the multiple roles they play as creditor,

input dealer and extension advisor. This follows work by Aga (2018) on input dealers in

Maharashtra, who finds that intermediaries are often petty commodity producers themselves,

existing as one-man enterprises and farming part time. However, the number of intermediaries

in a decentralised manner monopolises their position in rural peripheries as the go-to person

for advice in lieu of government extension officers in the liberalisation era (ibid).

The political economy conditions of deregulated Bt cotton growth in Telangana brought an

explosion of Bt cotton adoption in the last two decades. The deregulated seeds market and

absent role of the government in extension advice however kept farmers reliant on input dealers

for extension advice. The input dealer simultaneously served as input dealer, extension advisor,

harvest buyer and creditor, using all these elements to entrench their own income streams after

introducing Bt cotton in an agroecologically unsuitable Kacharam in the first place

(Ramamurthy, 2011). For example, Chaudhuri (2019) reports in her study of Bt cotton in

Maharashtra that input dealers were incentivised with 10-15% bonuses to meet sales targets

and for promoting specific brands of seeds over others.

The profit ethos was evident in that despite harvest failures from leaving Bt cotton rainfed,

input dealers provided extension advice to farmers to double down on their next seed and input

investments. An exchange with a local input dealer C61 who had been trading for five years in

the nearby town of Devarakonda revealed:

“The farmer [comes to me] four to five times. Once for seeds, twice for fertiliser and

twice for pesticides…there is no such thing as a loss because of the cotton it is due to

rain…it is according to the rain this year it was not good this year is a minus…[we have

Page 137: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

137

gained expertise] through observation and trial and error. Only if [the farmer] gets a

good yield can we make good business.” (C60, input dealer, 4/6/19)

For the input dealer, farmers’ losses from Bt cotton were due to the variability of the rain, and

not anything wrong on their side. However, the extension advice of the input dealer did not

recommend farmers to irrigate Bt cotton and instead focused on increase input sales. Input

dealers in fact made money despite the yields that farmers achieved, as farmers in Kacharam

purchase inputs annually regardless of a bounty or failure. All this time, input dealers keep

renewing loans and business for another year, getting repeat investments in Bt cotton while the

risks of doing so in a rainfed environment only created uncertainty and further losses from

cultivating the crop. An additional mechanism through which input dealers exercised their

economic control over farmers was the proprietary nature Bt cotton seeds, which meant farmers

could not reuse seeds due to patents (Siddiqui, 2020), having to buy new seeds and pesticide

combinations each year that fit with input dealers’ current sales targets (Aga, 2018). For the

input dealer, this represented a continuous income stream of seed and input sales as seed saving

was not possible by design.

Extension advice was theoretically the job of public extension support workers, but discussions

with farmers revealed that their interactions with extension workers were limited to only a few

days of demonstrations and workshops per year in the village. Farmers lamented the lack of

one-to-one contact time. When they tried to call the extension officer in times of crisis, the line

was always engaged. I too failed to get in contact with the local agricultural extension officer

in the nearby town of Devarakonda via phone or face to face for an interview. This was because

there was just one agricultural officer and a few extension officers for the entire mandal area

of Devarakonda, which covered a jurisdiction of tens of villages. The absence of extension

officers contrasted with input sellers who manned their shops at all hours during the day and

were contactable by phone, making them accessible to farmers. The lack of alternative and

their constant presence made farmers rely on them for each aspect of the input and output

markets for Bt cotton.

Page 138: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

138

Figure 32 - Local Input Shop in Nalgonda District

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

The culmination of agroecological, climatic, debt and market intermediaries made Bt cotton a

failure as a technology in the long run in Kacharam, as agricultural intensification was applied

in a decontextualised manner to this semi-arid and rainfed village. Moreover, the reliance on

input dealers for extension advice locked farmers further into dependency relationships with

input dealers who sought to maximise input and seed revenues year on year at the expense of

appropriate cropping patterns and irrigation application that could have helped farmers. The

plight caused by Bt cotton was summarised by farmer B15, a young OBC farmer with 1.6 ha

land who took losses of $583 from Bt cotton in 2018. Needing to provide for his young family

and fed up with the repeated failures from Bt cotton investments, he was forced to seek incomes

from outside the farm to keep the household running and repay debts:

“Farming doesn’t bring much return it falls on our heads…in this time whatever work

we are putting in we are not realising the results. For me it is enough to pay the input

costs and my children’s costs that’s it...what can we do? I go driving every day even in

the rainy season…we do agricultural labour [to make ends meet].” (B15, farmer,

5/4/19)

Out of 65 interviews throughout the village, 100% of farmers echoed this sentiment about the

crop they invested their hopes and financial futures in. Farmers in Kacharam, betrayed by

agriculture after twenty years of Bt cotton experimentation in the Liberalised Green

Revolution, could no longer depend on empty promises. Instead of increasing incomes, Bt

Page 139: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

139

cotton forced farmers away from the farm to make ends meet, far from what agricultural

modernisation proponents predicted (Bergius et al, 2018).

4.4 Conclusion

This chapter has answered the question: “What are the consequences of Bt cotton farming in

the Liberalised Green Revolution in Telangana?”. The adoption of Bt cotton came at the critical

juncture of the exhaustion of sorghum as a viable crop amidst rising household expenses in an

increasingly marketized economy. In the process of adoption itself, I showed that Bt cotton

outcomes have not exhibited linear progress, but a chaotic, boom and bust cycle. Farmers

across caste, gender and class lines were trapped into growing an input intensive but rainfed

cash crop prone to the vagaries of a declining monsoon. Moreover, the externalisation of inputs

from the farm to the input shop was entirely privately sourced and financed, unlike previous

Green Revolution iterations in India. The draw of high yields and profits from Bt cotton

prompted farmers to risk their whole livelihood on the cash crop as farmers delved knee deep

into risky high interest debt from input dealers to fund Bt cotton. In turn, Bt cotton’s failures

only made the risk more severe and plunged farmers into heavy losses and debts and doubling

down on Bt cotton in a recurring debt cycle to recoup losses.

To exacerbate the problem of Bt cotton failure, the deregulated input markets, and profit

incentives of input dealers reinforced debt relations for farmers. In the Liberalised Green

Revolution, the rollback of the public sector in extension services, credit and inputs meant the

input dealer was the sole source of information for farmers, creating a conflict of interest where

the input dealer played three roles: the creditor, the salesperson and extension advisor. The

input dealer geared each role he played for profitability at the futility of the farmer growing Bt

cotton in unsuitable semi-arid and rainfed conditions. Losses for 65% of all farmers in 2018

pushed them to make ends meet with non-farm wage labour outside the farm, thereby ending

agriculture as the primary income in Kacharam despite agricultural commercialisation.

Chapter 5 will focus on the adoption and outcomes of tubewell irrigation in Kacharam as part

of the Liberalised Green Revolution, tying the central limiting factor of Bt cotton and tubewell

failure to monsoon variability within complex political economy conditions. Moreover, the

chapter also reveals how despite tubewell adoption farmers keep cultivating Bt cotton in rainfed

conditions and chose to irrigate rice, a household food crop, leaving them unable to recoup

investment costs from both technologies and furthering the reliance on non-farm livelihoods.

Page 140: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

140

Chapter 5 – How has tubewell irrigation changed the political economy of

agriculture in Telangana?

5.1 Introduction

In Chapter 4 I explored the introduction of Bt cotton in Kacharam and Telangana in the

Liberalised Green Revolution since the 2000s. Bt cotton spread to Telangana via the

liberalisation of the cotton sector by a state government eager to promote private sector

technologies for economic growth. This facilitated the entry of private input dealers who sold,

and marketed inputs on credit and provided extension advice, replacing the role of the public

sector in agriculture. Aspiring towards a high market price crop, farmers in Kacharam took

advantage of the informal credit availability and switched from subsistence crops. In the long

term, Bt cotton failed in Kacharam due to the semi-arid agroecological conditions of erratic

monsoons and by farmers leaving it rainfed, making farmers beholden to creditors and forced

to rely on non-farm incomes to repay debt. Input dealers pushed for the crop to be continually

grown in rainfed conditions, accumulating profits at the expense of farmers. Chapter 5 of this

thesis therein answers the question: “How has tubewell irrigation changed the political

economy of agriculture in Telangana?”.

From the 1970s onwards, groundwater irrigation in India has fundamentally reconfigured the

socio-ecological fabric of the country (Vasavi, 2020). This was epitomised by the tubewell in

the 1990s, an advanced form of groundwater irrigation spread to marginal areas by private

sector irrigation firms. Tubewells extracted water from underground aquifers through

submersible electrical and diesel pumps (MoWR, 2017), piping the water onto fields through

PVC tubes. In creating more absolute irrigated area than public surface irrigation technologies

managed in the preceding 150 years, proponents have referred to it as a “groundwater

revolution” (Shah, 2010).

In particular, the fastest growth in groundwater irrigation has occurred through private sector

led, decentralised and rainfed smallholder farmer dominated adoption of tubewells in the

economic liberalisation era since the 1990s, what this thesis terms the Liberalised Green

Revolution. Groundwater irrigation has been regarded as a crucial technology for improving

crop yields, economic growth and rural poverty reduction for rainfed farmers outside river

command areas (Narayanamoorthy, 2006; 2015). The region of Telangana in the south Indian

state of Andhra Pradesh, the focus of this chapter, was home to centuries of smallholder

subsistence farming, lacking irrigation infrastructure and characterised by harsh climate, erratic

Page 141: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

141

monsoons, and poor soils (Prasad, 2015). In the 1990s, the newly appointed Chief Minister of

Andhra Pradesh sought to cut back public sector spending, streamline the state’s finances,

including in agriculture, and integrate smallholder farmers into markets for agricultural

commodities via tubewells (Vakulabharanam, 2004).

Cutbacks in public sector credit and irrigation projects and the promotion of private sector

activity in the 1990s (Sahay, 2010) unleashed the competition between thousands of irrigation

firms to maximise irrigation adoption. This brought down prices of tubewells from $10,000 in

1978 to $1,000 in 1999 (Freed and Freed, 2002; Gine et al, 2008). Supported by widely

available informal credit that helped finance groundwater, it allowed smallholder farmers to

realise their dream of growing rice for the household (Alary, 1999). As characterised in Chapter

2 however, the Liberalised Green Revolution proceeded in pockets of liberalisation amidst

continued state intervention (Shah and Harriss-White, 2011). The state government in the

Telangana case study was a prime example of this as even after liberalisation, electricity

subsidies and high minimum support prices for rice continued to appease the groundwater voter

base, incentivising groundwater irrigation adoption to take off further (Taylor, 2013a; Vasavi,

2019; 2020).

Tubewell irrigation in Telangana increased 20x in area from 60,000 ha in 1992 to 1.2 million

hectares by 2018 (DES India, 2019a, b), with small and marginal farmers (<2 ha land) owning

81% of all wells in Telangana (MoWR, 2017). Groundwater growth was also evident in the

explosion in pump set ownership in Telangana from 122,000 in 1972 to 1.76 million in 2011,

an increase of 14x in four decades (Reddy, 2020a). Smallholder rainfed farmers adopted a

double cropped system of rainfed Bt cotton in the monsoon and groundwater irrigated rice in

the dry season (Bhavani et al, 2017). Groundwater expansion was also a realisation of the

Telangana government’s political ambitions to transform the state from an agricultural

backwater to rice bowl of India (News Minute, 2020). This culminated in the state becoming

the biggest dry season rice grower in India in 2020, covering 4 million ha and producing 10

million tonnes (Live Mint, 2020).

In the fieldwork village of Kacharam, most smallholder farmers were rainfed prior to

groundwater irrigation, much like the broader trend in Telangana (Pingle, 2011). Political

economy changes in the 1990s brought tubewells, informal credit and rural electrification

expansion in the village to kick start irrigation adoption. By 2019, 69 out of 105 farming

households (65%) adopted tube well irrigation. Tubewells came to Kacharam in the village in

Page 142: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

142

conjunction with Bt cotton in the early 2000s. Yet, despite proponents arguing for irrigation to

accelerate Bt cotton yields (Sharma et al, 2018), government policy encouraged farmers to

grow rice with tubewells. Meanwhile, irrigation firms prioritised profitability via sales of

irrigation equipment rather than advising tubewells and Bt cotton to be used together. In a

liberalised environment, they served as salesperson and extension advisors for their

technologies in the absence of the government. This left Bt cotton to be grown rainfed, and

tubewells to irrigate household rice in the dry season, leading to indebtedness from both

technologies in a semi-arid and low and erratic monsoon environment of Kacharam, forcing

farmers to rely on non-farm income to make ends meet.

Tubewell adoption in Telangana and Kacharam occurred in a severely socio-ecologically

constrained environment for agricultural livelihoods. The increasing variability of the monsoon

in recent years exacerbated low yields for rainfed Bt cotton as shown in Chapter 4. With regards

to groundwater, Telangana is mostly underlain by hard rock aquifers, characterised by a

shallow storage, poor infiltration capacity of its laterite soils from rainfall and high density of

tubewells (Jacoby, 2017). To support groundwater expansion, successive Chief Ministers since

1977 (Sishodia et al, 2016) subsidised electricity for farmers, becoming the first state in India

to do so, to appease farmers in Telangana for the historic neglect of the region in irrigation

expansion and river water allocation (Government of India, 2010). After Telangana’s

independence from Andhra Pradesh as a new state in 2014, this was improved upon by the TRS

government since 2018 by expanding free 24x7 electricity for groundwater, the first in India

(Rao, 2018a). This rapidly increased adoption in Telangana but depleted aquifers due to the

zero-marginal cost of extraction of groundwater.

Overall, tubewells failed for most households investing in them in Kacharam. In 2018, the

household survey year, only 10 out of 69 (14%) tubewell irrigated households across all

classes, castes and genders had sufficient groundwater to grow rice successfully in the dry

season. Moreover, 89% of all 215 wells drilled in the village since 2000 failed, leaving only 24

working, a wider pattern also seen in villages elsewhere in Telangana (Rao, 2020). Well

failures became increasingly common due to erratic monsoon rainfall patterns and deepening

of water tables in the village, with farmers increasing their well depths from an average of 81m

in the early 2000s to depths of up to 120m in 2018, well beyond the productive range of hard

rock aquifers in the state (CGWB Telangana, 2017). This race to the bottom for finite

groundwater depleted aquifers quickly after monsoon as the density of tubewells in the village

Page 143: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

143

increased and free electricity incentivised farmers to run submersible pumps for multiple hours

per day in the search for water (Surendra et al, 2014; Jacoby, 2017).

As with Bt cotton in Chapter 4, tubewells had high fixed costs. When coupled with persistent

failures in an adverse agroecological and aquifer environment, this resulted in farmer

indebtedness. Indebtedness from cumulative tubewell failures over time in Kacharam made

tubewells the most common debt source for farmers at $2,207 per farmer. Installing a tube well

cost up to $1,462 and an additional $439 to $585 for each new well drilled. On average a farmer

in Kacharam made $2,043 annually before all expenses, so tubewells cost 70% of household

income in Kacharam. The price of failure and cumulative debt from moneylenders at 36%

interest increased economic desperation for farmers, trapping them into debt relations with

creditors like with commercial crops (Vasavi, 2020). Rainfed farmers attempted to grow rice

for the household as a symbolism for success to emulate rice growing farmers in the previous

generation. Yet back then, well densities were low, monsoons were more reliable and only 10

irrigated households existed. Now, due to the density of tubewells in Kacharam increasing 7x

relative to 2000, and declining monsoon rainfall, aquifers were depleted quickly and unable to

grow dry season rice.

The aspiration to grow rice in the dry season with tubewells in Kacharam despite

agroecological conditions was also encouraged by private irrigation firms. Due to the

deregulated tubewell economy and absent government, private irrigation firms acted as both

extension advisors and salesperson, like Bt cotton in Chapter 4. Tubewell firms encouraged

drilling at any cost and leaving farmers to irrigate dry season rice for the household versus Bt

cotton, their cash crop. This left their only cash crop to face low yields and harvest failure under

erratic monsoons. These paradoxical set of conditions are also reflected in Telangana, where

only 15% of Bt cotton is irrigated, and in Nalgonda district the figure is less than 1% (DES

Telangana, 2016; DES India, 2019a, b). This exacerbated risks for both Bt cotton and rice for

the household in Kacharam. Tubewells failed in the dry season due to insufficient groundwater

and zero sum well drilling and high densities of tubewells in the village. Furthermore, as

farmers did not use tubewells for Bt cotton, harvest failures from declining monsoons also

occurred frequently. The debts from Bt cotton and tubewells interlocked, burdening farmers

and forcing a reliance on non-farm incomes.

Page 144: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

144

Unlike in Chapter 4 where Bt cotton was adopted for its high market price, installing tubewells

for household dry season rice had no return on investment. In the Liberalised Green Revolution,

the input dealer, creditor, and irrigation firm all worked in siloes to maximise their own sales,

rather than to increase farmer welfare. From the governments side, irrigation ministers and the

Chief Minister KC Rao encouraged the rapid expansion of tubewells and rice (Live Mint,

2020). On the other hand, groundwater departments were understaffed and had limited

jurisdiction to provide suitable irrigation extension advice to farmers (Pahuja et al, 2010).

At the local level, the rapid expansion of tubewells was encouraged by irrigation firms who

were ever present in nearby towns to Kacharam, providing informal credit to finance the

technology. Farmers, like with Bt cotton in Chapter 4, to take drilling advice from tubewell

firms with no other alternative. Firms acted as both salesperson and irrigation extension

advisors. The culmination of the tubewell political economy in Telangana and Kacharam is

that farmers have become indebted to tubewells and Bt cotton, both unsuitable technologies in

the first place for smallholder intensification in a semi-arid landscape. Losing faith in tubewell

profitability, farmers are anxious to reinvest any further. They now rely more non-farm

incomes to make a living and are encouraging their children to do the same.

The rest of this chapter will be laid out as follows. First, I go detail into how tubewells emerged

in Telangana and Kacharam and the precedent of the Liberalised Green Revolution leading up

to this. Second, I look at the farming logic used with tubewell irrigation and the environmental

backdrop as to why tubewells have not succeeded in increasing economic growth in Kacharam

and Telangana. Third, I examine the role of private irrigation companies acting as extension

providers, and the debt and risk implications from tubewell adoption and use. Finally, I

conclude the chapter by dissecting the consequences of tubewell irrigation on future farming

livelihoods in Kacharam and beyond.

5.2 Tubewell adoption in the Liberalised Green Revolution in Telangana

As late as 1991, public sector tank and canal irrigation dominated the irrigation landscape in

Telangana, as tubewells only covered approximately 4% of the net irrigated area (DES

Telangana, 2016). The extent of surface irrigation technologies however were limited to

geographical boundaries near dams, excluding much of Telangana’s farmers (MoWR, 2017).

Dug well irrigation was the only other option for farmers outside of command areas. Powered

by oil/diesel/electric engines, dug wells extracted water in situ from underground aquifers

through drilling into the bedrock and pumping the water to the surface to irrigate a field

Page 145: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

145

(Vasavi, 2020). Dug wells however were rudimentary technologies, only able to irrigate 2 ha

and drill at 15m depth (MoWR, 2017). Furthermore, their high fixed costs limited adoption to

only the richest classes of farmers (A7, academic, 1/8/18). This was confirmed in surveys by

Deb et al (2002) in Mahbubnagar district, who find that in the early 1990s, only a handful of

the richest farmers could afford dug wells in the village and irrigate rice.

Figure 33- Dried Up Dug Well in Kacharam

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

This changed in the 1990s because of the Liberalised Green Revolution. The private sectors

share in gross capital formation in agriculture increased from 49% in 1981 to 78% in 2000, as

liberalisation shifted investment in agriculture from public to private (Aggarwal, 2008). The

state government reduced the budgetary allocation to public irrigation from 12% in 1990s to

5% in the 2000s, in order to reduce the public expenditure burden and tighten fiscal spending

(Sahay, 2010). At the same time, the encouragement of market development in irrigation saw

the entry of small-scale entrepreneurs setting up irrigation and drilling firms (Birkenholtz,

2007). Growing demand for groundwater came mainly from smallholder farmers moving to

Page 146: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

146

commercial agriculture, driven by rising household expenditure and a desire to improve profits

from commercial agriculture as shown in Chapter 4.

A key groundwater technological innovation introduced in 1996 by the Indian pump

manufacturer Texmo was the submersible pump, which powered the tubewell (Taro, 2020).

Submersible pumps were an electric pump technology installed underground and able to pump

water at 20x to 30x the depths of dug wells, extracting water from deep water tables during bad

monsoons (D60, tubewell company, 15/07/19). Attached to PVC tubes, the name tubewell was

given to this overall irrigation system, superseding dugwells as a technology. The most

powerful tubewells could discharge 200-300cm3 per day, 3x the capacity of dugwells and

capable of irrigating 10-15 ha compared to 1-2 ha for dug wells (MoWR, 2017). Private market

competition among irrigation firms and drilling firms in Telangana reduced the cost of

groundwater irrigation to $1,000 (Alary, 1999), a 10x decrease in price compared to the late

1970s (Freed and Freed, 2002). Therefore, tubewells supplanted dug wells not only

technologically but also in affordability.

Figure 34 - Tubewell Irrigation System in Kacharam

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 147: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

147

Figure 35 - Submersible Pump for a Tubewell

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Tubewells also entered as a new technology due to the technological exhaustion of dug wells.

Previously, the low density and high cost of dug wells meant farmers could access the

groundwater from a shallow depth for irrigating rice (Deb et al, 2002). Over time however, as

groundwater adoption rapidly increased in Telangana in the 1990s, it also increased the density

of wells drawing upon the same aquifer. Combined with the government’s subsidised

electricity scheme, it depleted dug wells completely, requiring tubewells to drill deeper. In

addition, the erratic monsoons and low storage capacity of hard rock aquifers in Telangana

meant aquifer recharge often was outstripped by the rate of extraction of groundwater due to

high tubewell density (Jacoby, 2017). As a tubewell firm D68 described in a nearby town to

Kacharam:

“They used to drill [15] to [20]m…now wells dried up and people drilled deeper beyond

[20]m in the search for water…. now even smallholder farmers drill before rich farmers

drilled for [tubewells]…farmers [drill] up to [156m].” (D68, tubewell drilling firm,

15/7/19)

The final step of the emergence of tubewells was the concomitant rise of informal credit

provision in Telangana during the Liberalised Green Revolution period. The 1990s saw a

slowdown of public sector credit disbursal in Andhra Pradesh, with the share of smallholder

farmers in total bank credit dispersals dropping from an already low 22% in 1991 to 7% in

Page 148: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

148

2001 (Pradhan, 2013), relative to their share of informal credit being at 87% (Agarwal, 2008).

This was despite the share of smallholder farmers of all holdings increasing from 43% to 82%

between 1980 and 2000 (DES Telangana, 2016).

Moneylending historically always existed as the norm in Telangana in the village setting

(Venkateshwarlu, 2002). Liberalisation in the 1990s broadened the availability and entry of

new caste entrants, as changing village structures and urbanisation saw traditional

moneylending castes leave villages to cities (Parthasarathy, 2013) (see Figure 13 for a caste

diagram of Telangana). The liberalisation of the credit sector allowed greater opportunities for

new private moneylenders from lower OBC castes in villages and urbanising towns to disburse

credit in high demand from smallholders for new tubewell and cotton technologies

(Vakulabharanam and Motiram, 2014). Despite paying higher interest rates, smallholder

farmers accepted the risk due to the easy access, flexible repayment terms and low collateral

of informal credit, as shown in Chapter 4. This equally crucial but exploitative role of

moneylenders in the Liberalised Green Revolution was explained by interviewee A4, an

agricultural economist:

“But where are they getting the investment for the [tubewells]? The cash needs of the

farmers are small and in lower intervals whereas the banking sector is unable to cater

to such kind of needs. [The]…moneylender supports them in a time of need so…of

course it was a high interest [loan] which would involve exploiting also… but we

should not throw out the baby with the bathwater as the alternative is nobody.” (A4,

academic, 23/8/18)

The liberalisation of the credit sector allowed greater opportunities for new private

moneylenders in Telangana to take advantage of the burgeoning demand for tubewells. The

untapped market was the millions of subsistence rainfed smallholder farmers who aspired to

adopt tubewell irrigation to grow rice for the household (Alary, 1999).

Declining prices of tubewells, marketing by irrigation firms and increased availability of

informal credit provision in rural Telangana in the 1990s opened up tubewell adoption to

smallholder farmers. Figures 36 and 37 below show the growth in tubewell irrigation at both

the Telangana and Nalgonda level. In Telangana, tubewells contributed to <5% of the net

irrigated area at 100,000 ha as late as the 1990s, when dug well irrigation dominated at almost

43% (DES Andhra Pradesh, 2006). Tubewells quickly took off in the 1990s however,

accelerating further in the 2000s and reaching nearly 1.2 million hectares in 2018, making up

Page 149: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

149

50% of the total net irrigated area (DES India, 2019a, b). In Nalgonda, tubewells mirrored the

state-wide trend, increasing from less than 2,000 ha to over 190,000 ha by 2018, or 59% of the

net irrigated area (ibid).

Figure 36 - Telangana Irrigation Area by Source 1955-2018

Source: DES Andhra Pradesh (2006); DES Telangana (2016); DES India (2019a, b)

Figure 37 - Nalgonda Irrigation Area by Source 1955-2018

Source: DES Andhra Pradesh (2006); DES Telangana (2016); DES India (2019a, b)

0

50000

100000

150000

200000

250000

195

5-5

6

195

7-5

8

195

9-6

0

1961-6

2

196

3-6

4

196

5-6

6

1967-6

8

196

9-7

0

197

1-7

2

197

3-7

4

197

5-7

6

197

7-7

8

197

9-8

0

198

1-8

2

198

3-8

4

198

5-8

6

198

7-8

8

198

9-9

0

199

1-9

2

199

3-9

4

199

5-9

6

199

7-9

8

199

9-0

0

200

1-0

2

200

3-0

4

200

5-0

6

200

7-0

8

200

9-1

0

2011-1

2

201

3-1

4

201

5-1

6

2017-1

8

Hec

tare

s

Year

Tanks Project Canals

Tube Wells Dug Wells

Other Sources

0

200000

400000

600000

800000

1000000

1200000

1400000

195

5-5

6

195

7-5

8

195

9-6

0

196

1-6

2

1963-6

4

196

5-6

6

1967-6

8

196

9-7

0

197

1-7

2

197

3-7

4

197

5-7

6

197

7-7

8

197

9-8

0

198

1-8

2

198

3-8

4

198

5-8

6

198

7-8

8

198

9-9

0

199

1-9

2

199

3-9

4

199

5-9

6

199

7-9

8

199

9-0

0

200

1-0

2

200

3-0

4

200

5-0

6

200

7-0

8

2009-1

0

201

1-1

2

201

3-1

4

201

5-1

6

201

7-1

8

Hec

tare

s

Year

Tanks Project Canals Tube Wells

Dug Wells Other Sources

Page 150: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

150

While tubewells increased, other types of irrigation in Telangana and Nalgonda decreased or

stagnated in this period, meaning that tubewell irrigation singlehandedly contributed to a total

increase in net irrigated area from 30% in the 1990s to almost 50% by 2018 (DES India, 2019a,

b). Another indicator of tubewell growth is the increase in pump sets ownership in Telangana

and Nalgonda. In Telangana, pump sets increased from 122,000 in 1972 to 1.76 million in

2011, an increase of 14x. In Nalgonda, pump sets increased 14x from 18,000 in 1972 to 256,000

in 2011 (Reddy, 2020a). In addition, almost 80% of tubewells in Telangana were used as the

sole irrigation type outside of canal command areas, meaning that most farmers adopting them

were previously rainfed or only had access to groundwater irrigation (MoWR, 2017). Finally,

81% of all the tubewells in Telangana in 2014 were owned and operated by smallholder farmers

owning <2ha, confirming them as the dominant drivers of tubewell growth (ibid). The next

section shows the process of tubewell adoption in Kacharam.

5.2.1 The entry of tubewell irrigation in Kacharam

Prior to tubewells, Kacharam was largely a rainfed village, with farmers growing sorghum,

millets, or castor in the monsoon. Kacharam was more than 50km away from the nearest canal

command area, the Nagarjuna Sagar dam, hence was excluded from surface irrigation. For the

10 families that could afford irrigation, private dug wells were used to irrigate rice for

household consumption in the dry season. By the end of the 1990s, many dug wells in

Kacharam dried out due to deepening water tables because of erratic monsoons and increase in

tubewell density (Shashikala, 2015). Farmer D67, an elderly ST farmer cultivating 1.5 ha,

described the transition her family made to tubewells owing to the exhaustion of dug wells:

“We used to have a [dug] well system….then there was no water in the well. We didn’t

have the energy [to restore it] plus everyone was installing [tubewells] at the time we

saw each other and installed it [to grow rice].” (D67, farmer, 25/6/19)

Seeing other farmers successfully growing rice with tubewells, the incentive to adopt the latter

was also created following her dug well drying up, as she had the means to finance it with

informal credit. The final step to bring tubewells into Kacharam was rural electrification.

Kacharam saw a delay in tubewell adoption relative to Telangana as the village was not

electrified fully until 1999/2000 (D1, farmer, 27/6/19). Electricity is essential for tubewells as

92% of tubewells in Telangana run on electric submersible pumps (MoWR, 2017). With the

entry of tubewell irrigation, emulating the dug well irrigated rice growing households of

previous generations was finally possible.

Page 151: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

151

By 2019, tubewells were adopted by 69 out of 105 (66%) of farming households, from 0

households in 2000. The end goal of the tubewell irrigation was to grow rice, bringing food

security and a cultural symbolism of material success. As Alary (1999: p1402-1404) explains

for Mahabubnagar district in Telangana:

“From the time it is possible, the farmers resort to rice cultivation… not only does rice

constitute the staple diet in all meals during the day, it becomes symbolic also of a

certain economic status. In the non-irrigated zone, presence or absence of a well

conditions choice of crops. The moment a farmer can afford a well, he takes up rice

cultivation.”

As Fishman et al (2011) explain, the pursuit of tubewell irrigation for rice consumption in

Telangana was also a way to emulate and compete with the canal irrigated regions of coastal

Andhra Pradesh that benefited from a Green Revolution in rice in the 1960s. Using tubewells

to overcome Telangana’s difficult agroecological soil, climate and rainfall conditions,

Telangana was able to compete with coastal Andhra in rice production. In recent years, the free

24/7 electricity scheme passed by the Telangana government after independence from Andhra

Pradesh further encouraged farmers to attempt rice cultivation in the dry season with tubewells

(Rao, 2018a). This was also a statement for the Chief Minister of Telangana KC Rao for the

state to overcome its historic marginalisation in agriculture within Andhra Pradesh and

compete in rice production. This reached its culmination in 2020, as the Live Mint (2020: p1)

reported:

“Thanks to…the 24x7 electricity supply, India’s youngest state, once described as the

most backward and parched, is on the way to emerge as the new rice bowl of India.

With record cultivation of paddy on nearly [4m ha] during the ongoing [dry] season,

the state expects a yield of more than [10m tonnes], the highest for the season since the

creation of the state six years ago. Agriculture Minister S Niranjan Reddy believes that

the state will emerge as the rice bowl of India in three years.”

The aspirations of farmers in Kacharam to grow irrigated rice for the household was made

possible with the rapid expansion of tubewells since the 1990s. Supported by private irrigation

firms, informal credit, and the larger incentives and political goals of the Telangana

government, tubewells were therefore both a micro and macro scale desire within Kacharam

and Telangana. Through tubewell irrigation, Telangana was an example of what Sultana (2013:

p343) calls “technonatures”, the process by which water technologies reflect political aims.

Page 152: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

152

The growth of tubewell irrigation to 69 out of 105 households for dry season rice consumption

in Kacharam matched the overall trends at both the Nalgonda district level and Telangana level,

as Figures 38 and 39 show below. Dry season rice increased in absolute terms from 1998-2019

in both Telangana and Nalgonda. In Telangana, the percentage share of dry season rice

increased from 375,000 ha (29%) in 1999 to a peak of almost 1 million ha (52%) of total rice

area in 2016 (DES India, 2019a, b). In Nalgonda, dry season rice area increased from 63,000

ha in 1999 (26%) of total rice area to 232,000 ha (58%) in 2017 (ibid). Given that tubewells

were the only irrigation type to increase in area in this period as shown earlier in Figure 37,

this means that most of the dry season rice was driven by the increased adoption in tubewells.

Figure 38 - Telangana Dry Season Rice Area 1998-2019

Source: DES India (2019a, b)

0

500000

1000000

1500000

2000000

2500000

Hec

tare

s

Year

Dry Season Rice Area Telangana

Total Rice Area Telangana

Page 153: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

153

Figure 39 - Nalgonda Dry Season Rice Area 1998-2019

Source: DES India (2019a, b)

This section has shown that tubewell adoption fundamentally reshaped Kacharam and

Telangana. The culmination of a superior technology via submersible pumps, private market

competition and price reduction by irrigation firms, energy subsidies and increased availability

of credit made it possible for millions of smallholder rainfed farmers to adopt tubewells.

Tubewells outstripped all other irrigation types in Telangana, single handedly increasing the

net irrigated area from the 1990s onwards. It also contributed to the phenomenon of dry season

rice growth. In Kacharam, initially, only 10 households out of 105 could afford irrigation with

dugwells, but in the 2019, 69 out of 105 farmers adopted tubewell irrigation, fulfilling their

desire to grow rice for the household. The culture of dry season rice was also a factor of farmers

wanting to emulate dug well farmers in the previous generation. At a wider policy level, the

Telangana government through successive subsidy schemes promoted the adoption of

tubewells and rice cultivation in the dry season to make the state a rice growing powerhouse in

India.

The next section discusses the long-term implications and outcomes for tubewell adopting

households in Kacharam.

0

50000

100000

150000

200000

250000

300000

350000

400000

450000

500000

Hec

tare

s

Year

Dry Season Rice Nalgonda

Total Rice Nalgonda

Page 154: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

154

5.2.2 The political economy of tubewell failure in Kacharam and Telangana

This section argues that the Liberalised Green Revolution was tremendously successful in

pushing tubewell adoption in Kacharam. Yet, agroecological conditions and aquifer

characteristics combined with high debt driven tubewell investments created tubewell failure

in Kacharam. The key reason of failure was the increased tubewell densities that propagated

“competitive well deepening” (Shah, 2010). Upon installing tubewells, farmers in Kacharam

initially enjoyed high yields rice for the household. Within five years however, tubewells failed

persistently for farmers across all castes, classes, and genders, with only 10 households (14%)

in 2019 having enough water in the tubewell to grow rice successfully until harvest. In total,

215 tubewells were drilled since 2000 but only 24 worked as of 2019, an 89% failure rate.

Tubewells also became the most common source of debt for farmers in Kacharam, with 29%

of farmers citing it as their biggest debt at an average of $2,207. Bringing no economic returns,

however, it forced farmers to abandon the technology and seek incomes from non-farm

livelihoods to repay their debts.

Farmers irrigated rice, a household food crop, over Bt cotton, the main cash crop for 100% of

the 105 farming households in Kacharam. This left Bt cotton prone to the monsoon and harvest

failures as shown in Chapter 4. Cotton and tubewell irrigation were the two flagship Liberalised

Green Revolution technologies but were used seperately. This paradoxical irrigation choice

was also the norm in Telangana and Nalgonda district, as only 15% and 1% of Bt cotton area

in 2019 was irrigated respectively (DES Telangana, 2016; DES India, 2019a, b).

In addition to this, the adoption of tubewells in Kacharam and Telangana occurred in a harsh

environment for agrarian livelihoods, characterised by variable monsoons, low average

rainfall, low infiltration capacity soil and high evapotranspiration and runoff rates. Nalgonda

district has a low average monsoon rainfall of 474mm, the lowest district average in Telangana

(DES Andhra Pradesh, 2006; CGWB Telangana, 2019). In addition, 85% of Telangana is

underlain by hard rock aquifers (CGWB Telangana, 2019). Hard rock aquifers have low storage

capacity and porosity, with groundwater unevenly spread between interstitial cracks in the rock

(Hora et al, 2019). Almost 67% of groundwater recharge comes from the monsoon in hard rock

aquifers (Asoka et al, 2018), but as Chapter 4 showed, monsoons became more variable in

recent years, driving droughts and harvest failures. Compounding the problem was the fact that

less than 4-10% of rainfall in the monsoon reached the aquifer due to the poor laterite red soil

Page 155: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

155

infiltration capacity, with the rest being lost to surface runoff and evapotranspiration (Kumar

et al, 2011).

The dense rock substrata and low storage capacity also made it risky and expensive to drill

into, often requiring multiple drill attempts for the farmer to find water in a narrow band of

porous rock (Marechal, 2010). The cost of tubewells in Kacharam were up to $1,462 for the

first installation and a further $485-$539 for each drill attempt (D60, tubewell firm, 15/7/19),

making up more than 70% of the annual income of farmers in Kacharam. This figure is similar

elsewhere in Telangana too (Sishodia et al, 2017). In addition, the deeper the well was drilled,

the more expensive it became. Finally, the tubewells were almost entirely financed by informal

credit in Kacharam, where farmers paid up to 36% interest per year on top of the tubewell cost.

As Bt cotton, the main cash crop, was left rainfed in the face of a declining monsoon over time,

there was little recourse to repay the moneylender for either tubewell or Bt cotton debts.

In Kacharam, the rapid adoption of tubewell irrigation rapidly increased the density of

tubewells all drawing from the same aquifer source in the village, with each farmer drilling on

average of 93m and as deep as 130m. The total number of wells drilled in Kacharam since 2000

were 215, spread across 69 households. Combined with the factors above, it meant groundwater

reserves were quickly depleted before they could recharge from the monsoon (Jacoby, 2017).

Table 7 shows how tubewell irrigation failed across all categories of class, caste and gender of

the households that adopted it. By July 2019, the success rate for a tubewell was 11% to 33%

across all categories, roughly translating to 7-9 out of every 10 tubewells in Kacharam failing.

Table 7 - Tubewell Outcomes in Kacharam

Category

Total

Farming

Households

Irrigated

Households

Working

Irrigated

(%)

Failed

Irrigated

(%)

Total

Drill

Attempts

Success

Rate

(%)

All Farmers 105 69 24 (35) 45 (65) 215 11

OBC 74 49 16 (33) 33 (66) 129 12

SC 23 14 6 (43) 8 (57) 57 11

ST 8 6 2 (33) 4 (67) 29 7

Widow 11 2 1 (50) 1 (50) 3 33

Non-Widow 94 67 23 (34) 44 (66) 212 11

Marginal (<1 ha) 33 17 1 (6) 16 (94) 39 3

Small (1-2 ha) 56 40 18 (45) 22 (55) 119 15

Medium (>2-5ha) 16 12 5 (42) 7 (58) 57 9

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 156: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

156

Rainfall in semi-arid Kacharam was always unstable and low in quantity, reliant on the erratic

monsoon. Yet as Chapter 4 showed, even these conditions worsened over time. The

intensification of tubewells in Kacharam therefore only made an already bad situation worse,

depleting aquifers faster than they could be recharged under the monsoon. Telangana tried to

replicate the success of rice cultivation as coastal Andhra Pradesh enjoyed in the 1960s, but

without the geographic suitability or advantage to benefit from the technologies in a sustainable

manner (Government of India, 2010). In fact, as far back as the 1960s, an economic survey

report deemed Telangana unsuitable for widespread groundwater irrigation due to its

hydrogeology (Rao, 2014).

The low storage and poor recharge capability of laterite soils exacerbated the demand on the

aquifer from tubewell densities increasing in the village (Ahmed et al, 2008). More farmers

drilling wells and extracting water from the same aquifer increased competition amongst the

farmers. In a survey of 144 villages in Andhra Pradesh and Telangana, Jacoby (2017: p13-14)

found:

“[Tubewell] clustering leads to well interference. In Andhra Pradesh, pumps are run

continuously throughout the dry season for the hours during which electricity is

available. When a pair of nearby submersible pumps run in tandem, the combined

drawdown of the local water table is greater, and the combined discharge of the pumps

correspondingly much less…a cluster of [tubewells] in short, creates a localised

depression of the water table, which is increasing in [tubewell] density.”

Relative to the era of dug wells in the village previously where 10 dug wells were spread across

105 households and 120 ha of cropping area, the tubewell era saw 69 households adopting and

drilling 215 powerful submersible pump powered wells (MoWR, 2017). The 7x increase in

density of wells in the village drove tubewell failures, leaving them unable to grow rice or

repay tubewell investments.

Page 157: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

157

The nexus of environmental and social factors deepened farmers’ economic problems rather

than solve them. Farmer D3, an OBC middle aged female owning 1.2 ha land, invested in four

failed tubewells with her husband, spending over $2,000 in pump, drilling, pipe, and

installation costs, and deepening her wells from 40m to 50m, but to no avail:

“[The dug well] worked quite well we planted rice. This was 15 to 20 years

ago….[After drilling for the new tubewell] we grew rice for one year that was food for

the household… the [tubewell] dried up over time our fields dried up and so did our

yields. The neighbours couldn’t help me out as they don’t have water either…we are

living in bad times sir we have no money.” (D3, farmer, 1/7/19)

Relative to the pre-tubewell era where the low number of groundwater users could access water

for rice, the increase in density with the finite groundwater source made rice irrigation at scale

infeasible in Kacharam. This is further underlined by Anupoju and Kambhammetu (2020), who

describe that water requirements for rice alone in India are more than 50% of the total annual

groundwater supply available. This outlines the infeasibility of farmers to grow rice, especially

in the dry season where there is no rainfall to recharge aquifers. Moreover, as Sidhu et al (2020:

p24-25) note, free electricity incentivises farmers to pump as much as possible:

“Farmers paying flat charges face no marginal cost of pumping groundwater (Scott &

Shah, 2004). As a result, flat-tariffed regions have witnessed rapid groundwater

depletion and wasteful power consumption in agriculture. Rice crop needs to be

irrigated approximately 20 times over a season, so some farmers err on the side of

caution and keep their pumps running continuously during the sowing days to keep

fields inundated.”

Therein, rice cultivation in Kacharam was never a feasibility due to hydrogeology and the water

demands from the crop. A secondary factor adding to the problem of well density was the

declining monsoon rainfall, as shown in Chapter 4. In a village level sample survey in

Kacharam, rainfall was consistently cited as the biggest problem facing farmers by 100% of

105 household respondents in Kacharam. Under erratic monsoons, the combination of lower

rainfall and more farmers attempting to draw on the limited groundwater lowered the water

table, drying out tubewells and incurring heavy losses for the farmers from Bt cotton too.

Furthermore, tubewells in Kacharam were the singular source of irrigation used in the village.

Similarly, a Telangana-wide irrigation census found that 80% of tubewells were installed

outside of canal command areas and were the sole source of irrigation for farmers. This meant

Page 158: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

158

there were no other supplemental sources of irrigation to recharge groundwater tables (Pingle,

2011; MoWR, 2017). Farmer B19, an elderly ST farmer, drilled 12 times for tubewells, but all

of them dried up. Compared to his parent’s generation where they could grow seven food crops

for the household under rainfed conditions, now neither rainfed nor irrigating crops worked:

“We drilled 12 borewells and had a debt of [$3,000] …[there is] no water…where is

[our parent’s] time and where is ours. They grew things well whatever they planted it

grew fully. Now it rains for one month and [then] does not. It falls a little bit then dries

up. The field of rice dries up because there is no water in the [tubewell].” (B19, farmer,

2/4/19)

The phenomenon of increasing well failures and tubewell densities in semi-arid and hard rock

areas was also observed elsewhere in Telangana, confirming findings in Kacharam. For

example, Taylor (2013a) reported how in Medak district, 244 out of 250 wells failed in 2009

due to the lowering of the groundwater table. Similarly, in Nalgonda district, one village

Musapally drilled 6,000 borewells over several years, investing $1.2 million, but 85% of the

wells failed over time (ibid).

Furthermore, in a longitudinal village study of two villages in Mahbubnagar district between

1989 and 2013, farmers also described reduced rainfall in the monsoon and rising tubewell

densities (Rao and Bhattarai, 2014). In addition, they found that previous dug well and tank

irrigation systems for rice dried out completely, with the success rate of drilling wells only at

20-25%. By 2013, groundwater depletion rendered farmers unable to extract water even with

more powerful pumps and by drilling over 150m (ibid). In Kacharam, tubewells saw a rapid

adoption rate with 69 out of 105 farming households adopting tubewells within 20 years of its

introduction, drilling 215 wells in total. However, tubewells did not improve farmer outcomes

in the long term, with 89% of all tubewells drilled having failed. In the rare cases tubewells did

work, they were used for growing rice, a household food crop and not for Bt cotton, their main

cash crop, so the farmer was unable to repay either informal debt in tubewells or Bt cotton.

To answer why this has taken place, the next section investigates the role of private irrigation

firms as salesperson and extension advisor in pushing tubewells to rainfed farmers in a semi-

arid Telangana. Simultaneously, the state government, with their populist policies and absence

in providing irrigation extension advice, exacerbated failures from tubewells, increasing debts

and pushing farmers off the farm to cover losses from failed Liberalised Green Revolution

technologies.

Page 159: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

159

5.2.3 Intermediaries and governments as key drivers of tubewell failure

A major component of tubewell growth in the Liberalised Green Revolution in Telangana were

private irrigation firms that sold the technology and helped spread its adoption. The explosion

of competing private firms in the 1990s in Telangana fostered innovation by introducing more

powerful submersible pumps and lowering tubewell prices through market competition. Yet

private irrigation firms were largely unregulated, which also created predatory behaviour. In a

competitive environment where tubewells were taking off and millions of rainfed farmers were

adopting this technology, private firms maximised tubewell adoption at any cost to any farmer

to purchase a tubewell via accessing informal credit. Moreover, tubewell companies had no

scientific background, but farmers relied on their authority for tubewell extension advice. In

this unregulated tubewell political economy, the absence of government departments in

regulating or advising on irrigation management gave farmers no alternative for extension

advice. This section provides original research into the nature of private irrigation firms in the

tubewell economy. It is a topic that has remained underexplored in the literature in India except

for Birkenholtz (2007) in Rajasthan.

Private irrigation firms played a dual role as extension advisor and salesperson, creating a

conflict of interest much like input dealers with Bt cotton in Chapter 4. This partially helps

explain the paradox of why farmers do not irrigate Bt cotton and instead irrigate dry season

rice in Kacharam, aggravating risk and debt problems in an extreme agroecological and

hydrogeological environment. Extension advice from tubewell firms to keep drilling more and

deeper wells after well failure kept farmers drilling in desperation for groundwater, even when

this was beyond the aquifer depth that hydrologists in Telangana recommended. A plethora of

moneylenders financing this endeavour also kept farmers drilling.

At the same time in the Liberalised Green Revolution, the Telangana government on the one

hand was absent in providing suitable cropping pattern and irrigation management extension

advice for tubewells, leaving a situation of Bt cotton to be rainfed and tubewells left to irrigate

rice. On the other hand, the Telangana government made tubewell failure worse through

encouragement of rainfed Bt cotton and dry season rice (Live Mint, 2020). Although in recent

years the government has expanded canal and tank irrigation schemes (Verma and Shah, 2019),

groundwater dependence is still dominant in Telangana.

Page 160: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

160

Erratic monsoons, persistent well failures, climbing debts and immiserating Bt cotton losses in

Kacharam have driven farmers into crisis through the Liberalised Green Revolution. The

burden of risk and financial exhaustion of repeated tubewell failures have now made farmers

reticent to drill any further as they are not confident in the technology to deliver. Failures from

both technologies have also meant farming livelihoods are no longer sustainable in Kacharam.

Instead of irrigation and high value crops boosting economic growth and enabling the structural

transformation of the economy out of agriculture (Van Der Ploeg, 2014), farmers have been

forced out of agriculture because of agricultural intensification. This final section therefore

answers how and why tubewell irrigation has failed, and what lies ahead for the farmers in

Kacharam.

5.2.4 The role of private firms and governments in tubewell failure in Kacharam

A crucial aspect of aquifer depletion across all categories of farmers in Kacharam and

Telangana was the zero-sum drilling environment between farmers. This increased tubewell

densities and depleted aquifers in a water stressed and climatically adverse environment.

Importantly however, the tubewell political economy also had a key role in exacerbating

tubewell failure. The rapid growth through the 1990s of tubewells from 4% to 50% of the net

irrigated area in Telangana by 2019 (DES Telangana, 2016; DES India, 2019a, b) was in part

due to the Telangana government’s role in encouraging tubewell expansion through energy

subsidies. Yet, at the same time, groundwater department hydrogeologists were understaffed

and underfunded, playing a limited role in suggesting ameliorative policies for irrigation

management compared to irrigation ministers who promoted tubewell expansion (Pahuja et al,

2010). This left farmers to rely on private irrigation providers who were readily available and

contactable by phone and in shops in nearby towns for advice on well depth, installation and

well drilling.

Competition amongst private irrigation firms prioritised maximising profits via encouraging

farmers to drill numerous wells, rather than to irrigate Bt cotton or using more efficient

technologies such as drip irrigation (Sharma et al, 2018), both of which are shown to increase

Bt cotton yields and incomes (Shah, 2011). These predatory forces in the Liberalised Green

Revolution were consequential, as tubewells were adopted by mostly poor farmers in the most

marginal growing and aquifer environments. The vested interest in these private irrigation

providers in keeping business flowing meant farmers were encouraged to drill again or deepen

wells after each failure.

Page 161: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

161

Due to informal credit availability farmers doubled down on tubewell drilling despite multiple

failures. Each well failure compounded the debt of the farmers, and with farmers’ decision to

irrigate rice and leave Bt cotton rainfed, it meant no way to pay the debt back. The initial cost

of a tubewell was up to $1,462, with additional wells costing $439 to $585 versus an average

farmer’s total household income of $2,043 in Kacharam. Farmers bore the brunt of costs from

tubewell failure to the benefit of private irrigation firms, plunging their farming livelihoods

into further economic crisis on top of Bt cotton cultivation problems in rainfed conditions as

Chapter 4 showed. In a survey conducted with 72 farming households in Kacharam, tubewells

were the most common source of debt per household at 29% of the sampled households, an

average debt of $2,207. In addition, debts from inputs for Bt cotton came to $2,238, meaning

debts from Liberalised Green Revolution technologies made up 47% of debts in Kacharam.

This is shown in Figure 40 below. Adopting the technologies in unsuitable agroecological and

aquifer conditions plus using the technologies separately mutually reinforced indebtedness

from both.

Figure 40 - Main Debt Sources in Kacharam

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 162: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

162

Moreover, the figure of $2,207 for tubewell debt was only the average across farmers in

Kacharam. Farmer D57, an elderly ST farmer, drilled 12 tubewells with no success over the

course of five years, losing over $5,000:

“I drilled 12 [times] for wells…one works if the monsoon is good but that too doesn’t

work now…. each [tubewell] cost [$438]….in total 6 failed at the beginning the others

worked a few years…. [I started drilling] 5 to 6 years ago then I kept drilling and it has

come to 12…[the rice] was just for the household. The debts were not touched.” (D57,

farmer, 11/7/19)

The desperation not finding any water spurred him to drill over a five to six year period, taking

out informal loans each time to cover the costs of drilling but to no avail. Private irrigation

firms played a key role in perpetuating this trend of drilling multiple times for tubewells, as

their business came from demand for their services. Regardless of wells failing repeatedly,

private irrigation firms benefited each time the farmer drilled. In fact, it was more profitable

for farmers wells to fail for the irrigation firm, as it meant repeat business, compared to a

working tubewell. This made drilling for tubewells in an adverse semi-arid and hard rock

aquifer environment more profitable for irrigation firms. Yet, when asked about their role in

encouraging farmers to drill without consideration to the sunk costs and wasted cropping

patterns, interviewee D68, an owner of a tubewell firm, answered:

“We just drill where they point out. If it fails or not that is not down to us…” (D68,

tubewell drilling firm, 15/7/19)

This implied that the desire to drill for tubewells came entirely from the farmer. If farmers

called for their services, they could not refuse, and as they drill where the farmer asks, they are

not responsible for what happens next. However, tubewell firms were found from numerous

interviews in Kacharam and Telangana to actively pursue farmers in the search for repeat

customers, calling to advertise their services to rainfed farmers and farmers with failed wells.

This is confirmed by an interviewee A1, an agricultural economist, who observed:

“…[T]his is all private markets…this [drilling] fellow will contact local people [in the]

village so the village will have a contact person that person will arrange the market.”

(A1, agricultural economist, 30/7/18)

Page 163: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

163

The circular reasoning offered by the irrigation firm that the demand came solely from farmers

belies interviews with farmers and academics who felt that farmers were chased up and targeted

by private firms to buy their services. In nearby towns to Kacharam, I observed tubewell shops

and drilling machines were everywhere, ready to be deployed. Tubewell companies were a

constant presence, as I counted 10 shops within a 3km radius in a town near Devarakonda.

Even as farmers’ crops and tubewells fail and dry out due to erratic monsoons and zero-sum

drilling, tubewell companies have continued to receive demand for wells as they take advantage

of the farmers’ desperation to keep coming back to them, only to fall deeper into debts. Unlike

with Bt cotton moreover where it had a market price, tubewells were a sunk cost without a

return.

Figure 41 - A Tubewell Drilling Rig in Mallepally, a Nearby Town to Kacharam

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 164: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

164

Figure 42 - Tubewell Shops in Towns Near Kacharam

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Figure 43 - Tubewell Shops in Towns Near Kacharam 2

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 165: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

165

Tubewell firms have also widened their business portfolios in recent years. In view of multiple

drilling attempts becoming cost prohibitive for farmers, tubewell companies also offered

farmers to deepen their existing wells. This mirrored input firms with Bt cotton promoting

different seed varieties and input combinations with farmers year on year, gearing each part of

their extension advisor and salesperson position towards maximising revenues and opening

new income streams (Aga, 2018; 2019). Deepening wells cost $219 to $292 per well; a cheaper

option compared to drilling new wells for $439 to $585. Farmer D41, a SC female widow with

1 ha land could not afford to drill new wells on the farm, failing with multiple attempts. So,

deepening the well was a cheaper option:

“We had one [working tubewell] but it doesn’t work anymore. That [well] dried up too.

Even if it rains it will not come back now, they said there was no more water left in

there after we deepened it again. [So] we spent another [$292] we deepened it another

3m.” (D41, farmer, 4/7/19)

Deepening wells, it turns out, is another sales avenue for private firms, but to no help for the

farmer, as well deepening is still prone to failure, costing $292, as the tubewell densities remain

high. Table 8 shows the increasing well depths in Kacharam, with the expectation from farmers

that the deeper you drill the better chance you will find water amidst deepening groundwater

tables. It shows that original drill depths ranged from 75m to 99m when first installed in the

early 2000s and increased for every category of farm household to between 80m and 107m in

2019.

Table 8 - Tubewell Deepening

Category Irrigated

Households

Tubewell

Original Depth

(m)

Tubewell Current

Depth (m)

All Farmers 69 81 86

OBC 49 75 80

SC 14 93 99

ST 6 99 107

Widow 2 84 84

Non-Widow 67 81 86

Marginal (<1 ha) 17 78 80

Small (1-2) 40 79 84

Medium (>2-5 ha) 12 93 99

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Page 166: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

166

In interviews with tubewell drillers, they once again pointed to the erratic monsoon as the

necessity for farmers to deepen their wells, and hence the increasing demand for tubewell

deepening. In one interview with a farmer, they revealed that private irrigation firms

recommended him to deepen his wells even though they dried up 5 years ago (D7 farmer,

interview, 1/7/19). Therefore, tubewell drillers push farmers to deepen their wells as an

additional revenue stream on top of drilling services. The trend of deepening wells was also

evident in other parts of Telangana. In work by Surendra et al (2014) in Mahbubnagar district,

farmers drilled progressively deeper wells between 2000 and 2014, increasing the depths of

wells from 30m to 116m in this time.

Figure 44 - A Price List for Tubewells by Depth

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Moreover, this advice to drill deeper for higher chance of groundwater access contradicts how

hard rock aquifers are understood by hydrologists. In hard rock aquifers, water is found in pores

between the rock spaces of an aquifer, so is highly localised and variable in depth (Bassi et al,

2008). As Fishman et al (2011) explain in their survey of villages in Telangana, farmers may

strike water at a much lower depth than other farmers, but this is a function of luck, of hitting

water at a particular depth, not of how deep wells are.

Page 167: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

167

Marechal (2010: p289) describes how drilling deeper with existing wells is akin to gambling:

“Once started, it is difficult to decide to stop drilling if the well is dry because the driller

thinks that expected water-bearing structure could be a few meters away. This is similar

to the compulsive gambler who needs, after losing, to gamble again to recover his

losses…[Yet] this escalation of commitment for drilling deeper and deeper may be

encouraged by drilling companies as the potential money gains are increased.”

Indeed, hydrogeological surveys by the CGWB in Telangana found that most of the available

groundwater in Nalgonda district was present in between 40m-80m depths (CGWB Telangana,

2017). In Kacharam, the minimum depth drilled was 75m, almost as high as the maximum

recommended depth by the CGWB at 80m. Furthermore, in a Telangana irrigation census in

2014, 27% of all tubewells were found to be over 70m, meaning this belief of drilling deeper

to find water is pervasive beyond Kacharam (MoWR, 2017). The reality, as Jacoby (2017)

explains, is that for every 10m increase in well depth, drilling costs increase by 6% and pump

costs by 9%, due to the greater time and energy expended to drill. This indicates that the

unregulated nature of tubewell drilling in Kacharam is a profitable business model for the

tubewell firm at the detriment of farmer welfare and absence of the government in the tubewell

political economy.

The density of deep tubewells in Telangana is also shown below by Rajan et al (2020: p277)

in Figure 45, who find that at an all-India level, Telangana has some of the highest densities of

tubewells drilled over 70m, mirroring the trends in Kacharam of drilling firms encouraging

well drilling beyond the recommended depths by the CGWB expected to yield water.

Page 168: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

168

Figure 45 - Deep Tubewell Density Map of India

Source: Rajan et al (2020: p277)

During fieldwork, I found the CGWB was absent for farmers to contact if they needed advice.

Located in Nalgonda city, almost 60km from Kacharam, 80% of the 65 farmers interviewed in

Kacharam had never heard of the CGWB nor did they feel they could contact them when they

needed to. In addition, the Telangana state government assigns just one hydrogeologist per

district, a total of 31 hydrogeologists for the 2.4 million wells drilled in Telangana. Giving a

deeper insight into groundwater departments in Andhra Pradesh, Pahuja et al (2010: p50-51)

summarise:

“Even in states such as Andhra Pradesh and Maharashtra, which boast the best

groundwater departments in the country, staffing strength and profiles are grossly

inadequate compared to what is needed. Groundwater organizations are generally

located at a relatively low level in the state hierarchy, often in the departments whose

interest is focused on one of the main water uses, for example irrigation or water supply.

The structure, functioning, and staffing of groundwater agencies conform primarily to

the long-outdated mandate of surveying and developing the groundwater resource, and

are not oriented to paying any attention to the users and the socioeconomic dimensions

of groundwater use.”

Page 169: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

169

Irrigation firms monopolised extension services for tubewells in the scenario of absent

governments. The interests of the tubewell firms were driven by a vested interest to sell more

pumps and drill more wells and provide advice that was antithetical to official hydrogeological

guidance. Regardless of success or failure, the demand for their services continues unabated

despite the 89% failure rate of all tubewells in Kacharam. Concurrently, however, while being

absent in regulation or extension services, the Telangana government also continues long-

standing efforts to appease farming voting blocs through energy subsidies and encourage

tubewell expansion.

Costing the Telangana government $541 million in covering costs of the scheme in 2018-19,

the budget estimate for electricity subsidies in 2020-21 has doubled to $1 billion (Telangana

Today, 2020). Rajan et al (2020) find that the deepest tubewells and most overexploited

aquifers in India are in nine states, of which Telangana is one, where the electricity is the

cheapest for the farmer via subsidies. Moreover, they find that within the nine worst

groundwater depleted states, 27 districts are the most overexploited, which includes Nalgonda

and every other district in Telangana. Figure 46 below by Rajan et al (2020: p268) shows that

Telangana has the cheapest electricity costs per unit for groundwater in India in green at $0-5

along with the rest of the nine other groundwater depleted states in India.

Page 170: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

170

Figure 46 - Groundwater Electricity Costs by State in India

Source: Rajan et al (2020: p268)

India wide, electricity subsidies have also increased in real terms from $4 billion to $10 billion

between 2000 and 2016 (OECD, 2018), most prominent in the states that also face severe

groundwater exploitation problems (Sidhu et al, 2020). On the ground consequences in villages

like Kacharam is testament to this, the long-term well failure and immiseration of farmer

livelihoods, which has increased indebtedness and exacerbated the adverse adoption of both

tubewells and Bt cotton.

Factors such as climate change in Telangana are set to decrease monsoon rainfall by 5-10%

between 2030 and 2060 (Reddy et al, 2014c), which is significant because rainfall makes up

67% of the recharge of aquifers in India (Asoka et al, 2018). Perversely however, the Green

House Gas (GHG) emissions from electricity for tubewells in India contributes to 11% of total

GHG emissions in India alone.

Page 171: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

171

This presents a perverse feedback loop where subsidies increase electricity consumption,

increasing GHGs, which increases rainfall variability in the monsoon and reduces both the total

quantity of rainfall in the season as well as groundwater recharge. This means that electricity

subsidies will potentially reinforce the depletion of tubewells and rainfed Bt cotton outcomes

in the future too if the current system persists. India is on track to face potentially irreversible

groundwater depletion by 2025 of 60% of its aquifers if current groundwater extraction rates

continue (Rajan et al, 2020), underlining the impending problems of climate change and its

role in worsening Bt cotton and tubewell outcomes in the fragile economic, climatic, and

hydrogeological landscape as Telangana. Interviewee A2, an academic, summarised the nexus

of policy making and adverse environmental outcomes for farmers in the Liberalised Green

Revolution era:

“…We do not live in a system where farmers can be told what to grow and what not to

grow we live in a system where…policies make sure that incentives are almost always

perverse and almost sort of push farmers towards choices that are bad for them, bad for

water, bad for food, bad for the environment…the answer is not in terms of fancy

policies but the politics of who benefits and who loses.” (A2, academic, 1/8/18)

Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation were both introduced at similar times in Kacharam but the

profit maximising siloes of irrigation firms, input dealers and moneylenders increased their

revenue streams rather than the sustainability or profitability of the investment for the farmer.

Irrigating a high-water intensive household food crop such as rice in the dry season also

exacerbated the exploitation of groundwater in the least appropriate way for farmers in

Kacharam, while leaving them with no way to repay their investments on Bt cotton in leaving

it rainfed. This was not only the case in Kacharam, but Telangana and Nalgonda district more

widely too, as shown by Figure 47 and 48 below. For Telangana, cotton irrigated area covered

between 10-15% of the total cotton area between 1998-2018. For Nalgonda, it was <1%, with

the blue cotton area not even visible on the graph (DES India, 2018; 2019a, b).

Page 172: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

172

Figure 47 - Cotton Irrigated Area Telangana 1998-2018

Source: DES Telangana (2016); DES India (2018; 2019a, b)

Figure 48 - Cotton Irrigated Area Nalgonda 1998-2018

Source: DES India (2018; 2019a, b)

0

500000

1000000

1500000

2000000

2500000

Hec

tare

s

Year

Cotton Irrigated Area Total Cotton Area

0

50000

100000

150000

200000

250000

300000

350000

400000

Hec

tare

s

Year

Nalgonda Cotton Irrigated Area Nalgonda Cotton Area

Page 173: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

173

Rainfed Bt cotton is the norm across India too, with less than 33% of Bt cotton irrigated in

total, but with significant variability. Some states such as Gujarat, Haryana, Punjab, and

Rajasthan irrigate cotton at higher rates and have higher yields than Telangana (Shah, 2011;

Plewis, 2019; Todhunter, 2020). Therefore, the fact that Telangana relies on rainfed cotton has

negatively impacted on productivity. Out of 11 cotton growing states in India, Telangana has

the 3rd largest area and production, but comes 10th in yields (DES Telangana, 2016). In

Kacharam, like most of Telangana, the dominance of the private sector in extension advice has

denied farmers from using more profitable irrigation patterns, as farmers drilled tubewells to

failure for their least efficient use, to grow rice in the dry season. In an agronomic study across

Nalgonda and Warangal district in Telangana, Dev and Rao (2007) found in 2004-5 that

irrigated Bt cotton produced 35% greater yields than non-irrigated Bt cotton. In addition,

Glover (2010b) finds that during initial field trials of Bt cotton in India in the early 2000s, yield

growth comparisons compared irrigated Bt cotton with irrigated non-Bt cotton. This means the

optimal conditions from which Bt cotton’s superiority was marketed were in irrigated

conditions, unlike most of Bt cotton grown in India today (Rawal and Swaminathan, 2011;

Gutierrez et al, 2020).

Amidst an imperfect set of alternative cropping choices to sustain economic livelihoods for

smallholder farmers, one way forward could be to drip irrigate Bt cotton. This has shown to

increase Bt cotton yields by 114% relative to flood irrigation, while saving 50%-60% of the

water and 45% of the costs (Narayanamoorthy, 2008). The reasoning behind irrigating cotton

is explained by Sharma et al (2018: p144-145):

“Rain fed cotton requires a minimum rainfall of 500 mm, with favourable distribution

for good cotton yields which generally is not available and leads to crop failures or very

low yields. Cotton requires four to six irrigations, depending upon soil type and

seasonal rainfall… The crop must not be allowed to suffer water stress during flowering

and fruiting stage, otherwise a lot of shedding of flowers and bolls will take place

resulting in low cotton yield.”

As Chapter 4 has shown, the lack of reliable monsoon rainfall has driven farmers into debt

traps from persistent harvest failures in Bt cotton. As there is so much expense and debt riding

on Bt cotton, farmers in Kacharam with drip irrigation could have seen an improved outcome.

Considering the dual failures and debts from tubewells and Bt cotton, a mixture of fear,

apprehension and resigned fatalism drained farmers of any confidence in tubewells working

Page 174: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

174

again. This was a realisation that came after years of misery. For many farmers, tubewells have

yielded disastrous outcomes: high failure rates, high debts, failed rice crops and failed Bt

cotton. Faced with the second successive poor monsoon in 2019 at the end of fieldwork and

cumulative years of tubewell problems, a consensus emerged from 60 out of the 65 farmers

interviewed in Kacharam of losing faith in tubewells as a technology. For farmer D12, a middle

aged OBC farmer with three children to support, years of successive failures from tubewells

depleted him of his hope and finances:

“It will cost another [$1462] and who knows whether it will work or not I have a doubt

about it. There is not good rainfall I do not have the confidence I have a fear of it failing

and falling into further debt. If we take out a loan then we will have to pay interest and

will have nothing to show for it with a failed borewell.” (D12, farmer, 2/7/19)

This was also reflected in a demand shortfall for private irrigation firms in recent years, as

revealed by an exchange with interviewee D60, an irrigation firm, who felt that farmers have

become apprehensive with further tubewell investments:

“[Tubewell] demand has reduced for the last 3 years. Farmers have drilled for a few

years but they are now tired of drilling drilling drilling they are fed up. They don’t want

to drill for [tubewells]….we are facing losses” (D60, irrigation firm, 11/7/19).

At a time when Bt cotton and tubewells have rendered farming livelihoods unviable in the long

term, farmers are increasingly pivoting towards non-farm incomes to make a living. Tubewell

irrigation was a widely adopted Liberalised Green Revolution technology in Kacharam but in

an unsuitable climate and topography. The unregulated tubewell market brought the technology

to millions of poor farmers in Telangana via easy credit and private irrigation firms, and

politically expedient free electricity schemes from the Telangana government to grow dry

season rice. Nonetheless, in the long term, it led to the exhaustion of farming livelihoods and

few economic or food security returns to show for it. Rather, it has spurred a crisis in farming

that has forced farmers off the farm to scrape together a living. It has been the antithesis of the

universal, linear technology led transformation in agriculture that agricultural modernisation

proponents propagated in the most dramatic fashion (Vasavi, 2019; 2020).

Page 175: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

175

5.3 Conclusion

The answer to this chapter’s research question: “How has tubewell irrigation changed the

political economy of agriculture in Telangana?” is quite clear. Erratic monsoons and poor

storage, recharge and yields of hard rock aquifers in Telangana made for an adverse ecological

setting to introduce tubewells. Factors such as populist public policy, competitive tubewell

drilling, unsuitable crop irrigation choices, increasing debts and reliance on irrigation firms for

extension advice has plunged farmers into crisis through tubewell irrigation. The drill failure

rates and unproductive use of tubewells make it a debt laden technology with only 10 out of 69

households successfully able to grow rice in the dry season, while their Bt cotton cash crop

was left to fail under erratic monsoons. Overall, tubewells delivered failure rates of 89% for

the 215 wells drilled since the adoption of tubewells took place 20 years ago, becoming the

most common source of debt for farmers at over $2,000. In fact, debts from both Bt cotton and

tubewells contributed to 47% of all outstanding debt in Kacharam, as they were used seperately

so there was little chance to recoup their investments.

The unregulated tubewell market and free electricity scheme from the Telangana government

enabled the widespread adoption of tubewells but also perpetuated the continual drilling of

wells for farmers. In addition, the lack of government involvement in regulation or use of

tubewells meant that private irrigation firms were relied upon to provide extension support to

the farmers. As private irrigation firms were also the salesperson of the tubewell, they

privileged repeat business from farmers over sustainable use, encouraging multiple drill

attempts for each farmer. This made it more profitable for the tubewell firm for the farmer to

fail than find a successful tubewell. Facing repeated failure over 10 years and only intermittent

successes, farmers have largely abandoned tubewells, failed by its promises of prosperity.

Chapter 6 explores the future consequences for agricultural livelihoods in Kacharam after the

Liberalised Green Revolution. It links concurrent Bt cotton and tubewell adoption to distress

induced transitions to non-farm livelihoods to make up for their lost gambles in agriculture.

Moreover, it demonstrates the intergenerational exit from agriculture for educated rural youth

out of witnessing their parents’ failures from the Liberalised Green Revolution. Nonetheless,

due to the informal, menial, and insecure nature of non-farm jobs in India, incomes from all

generations of rural households have been neither stable or remunerative enough to meet debts

and rising household expenditures. Hence, a life outside farming in itself provides new

problems of insecurity.

Page 176: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

176

Chapter 6 – What are the implications of the Liberalised Green Revolution

for future agricultural livelihoods in Telangana?

6.1 Introduction

Chapter 5 examined smallholder tubewell adoption in Telangana and Kacharam and its

implications for agricultural livelihoods. Most farmers practised rainfed agriculture prior to

tubewells, living outside of canal command areas and priced out of available dugwells. After

liberalisation in the 1990s, public sector cutbacks saw governments incentivised private

irrigation firms to market, compete and expand groundwater irrigation adoption to rainfed

smallholders via new, advanced tubewell technologies. Like Bt cotton, tubewells were a key

Liberalised Green Revolution technology. Farmers adopted irrigation to grow rice, financing

investments with widely accessible informal credit and lower tubewell prices from market

competition. Irrigation adoption also took off via state government electricity subsidies, as part

of their vision to make Telangana a rice bowl of India. Despite initial gains from rice

cultivation, tubewell expansion occurred in a highly unsuitable aquifer, climate and political

economy setting. Electricity subsidies and irrigation firms incentivised ceaseless investments

in wells and drove up well densities to the point of widespread aquifer depletion in Kacharam

and Telangana. 89% of all 215 wells drilled in Kacharam failed since 2000, pushing farmers

into debt traps and non-farm livelihoods to survive. This chapter answers the research question:

“What are the implications of the Liberalised Green Revolution for future agricultural

livelihoods in Telangana?”. I will divide the chapter into four sections.

This first section explores smallholder outcomes from the Liberalised Green Revolution,

creating deagrarianisation and structural change in the rural economy towards non-farm

livelihoods. Following the Liberalised Green Revolution model shown in Chapter 2, the four

factors of environment, credit/debt relations, market intermediaries and governments

facilitated rapid technology driven intensification to integrate smallholder farmers in marginal

settings into markets but caused adverse long term outcomes. As demonstrated in Chapters 4

and 5, Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation adoption in Telangana and Kacharam increased the

capital expenditures, risk and indebtedness for adopting farmers without sustained yields or

profitability over the long term, due to the unsuitability of the climate, soils and groundwater.

Page 177: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

177

In Kacharam in 2018, this resulted in non-farm incomes making up between 39% to 70% of all

household income across all caste, class, and gender categories. Non-farm incomes are defined

as rural economic activities that do not directly come from crop and livestock production and

includes agricultural wage labour, non-agricultural wage labour, non-agricultural self-

employment and remittances and transfers (Lanjouw et al, 2013; Reddy et al, 2014). Facing

rising debt obligations from agriculture and household expenditures, farmers were forced to

abandon agriculture as a primary income and rely on a variety of non-farm incomes to make a

living.

Hence, this trajectory is contrary to the structural transformation pathway from agriculture to

non-farm livelihoods (De Janvry, 2010). This normative assumption claims that agricultural

technology adoption increases yields, profits, and economic growth. Farmers with higher

incomes drive demand and investments into non-farm non-agricultural goods and services

(Bergius et al, 2018). Subsequently, farmers exit agriculture by diversifying into the non-farm

sector and urbanisation that enables a structural transformation from agriculture to service and

manufacturing sectors dominated economy (Reddy et al, 2014b). Instead, in Telangana and

Kacharam, non-farm livelihoods were sought out from a position of desperation resulting in

deagrarianisation from adverse outcomes from commercial farming.

Non-farm livelihoods have become integral for rural households in Telangana, as only 52% of

rural households in 2013 relied on agriculture as their main income (Reddy, 2014). Agriculture

continues to employ 55% of Telangana’s workforce, but the sector’s contribution to GDP has

declined from 16.3% in 2011 to 12.9% in 2020 (DES, 2020), no longer remunerative for many

farmers (Jakimow, 2014; Stone and Flachs, 2015). Finally, between 1991-2012, Datt et al

(2020) show that non-farm incomes from service and manufacturing sectors were responsible

for 91% of total poverty reduction in India, compared to only 9% for agriculture, despite 43%

of the country’s workforce relying on agriculture (DES India, 2018). This underlines the lack

of returns from agriculture despite commercialisation in the Liberalised Green Revolution since

the 1990s.

Second, the chapter focuses on the intergenerational dynamics of non-farm transitions, where

rural youth desire for social mobility and to exit agriculture. The key to this has been improved

educational outcomes and witnessing their parents’ long-term outcomes from agricultural

commercialisation. In Telangana, enrolment in colleges and universities between 2005-12

increased from 15% to 35% (Kannibiran et al, 2017). In Kacharam, 85% of household heads

Page 178: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

178

had no formal education, compared to over 50% of 15-29-year-olds in the village having a 10th

grade education or higher, including 31-degree graduates. Wanting also for their children to

leave the farm and not suffer the same hardships as them, farmers invested in their children’s

education to help them attain salaried work outside the village. Opinion surveys carried out in

Kacharam confirmed an average of 67% of farming households heads across class, caste and

gender desired for their children to not practise agriculture for a living.

Third, this chapter investigates the non-farm labour market in India dominated by low paid and

insecure jobs, and the consequences for rural households in Telangana and Kacharam. The shift

in Kacharam to non-farm incomes has done little to address rising debt obligations from

Liberalised Green Revolution technologies and household expenditures. For the average

household across all classes, castes, and genders in Kacharam in 2018, net incomes were

-$1,550, indicating expenditure and debts to be vastly greater than farm and non-farm income.

Older farmers worked in agricultural or construction labour and a government work guarantee

scheme called MNREGA, earning an average of $3-7 per day and finding work only for 10-15

days per month in the dry season. This corroborates with all India rural wages of $3-5 per day,

just higher than the international poverty line of $1.90 (New Indian Express, 2020b).

For younger educated generations in Kacharam, only 40% of degree graduates in Kacharam

had jobs, working as rickshaw/car drivers and shop assistants, earning as little as $5 per day

and relegated to menial work or dropping out of the labour market altogether. In Telangana,

the rural youth unemployment is 25%, the fifth worst in India (Newsclick, 2018). In India,

since 2005, only 7% of all jobs created were in the formal sector (Srivastava et al, 2020).

Finally, the chapter explores the implications of inadequate agricultural and non-farm incomes

in Kacharam. This has pushed farmers into what I term a “risk indebtedness treadmill”,

strategies where farmers engage in short term cash earning opportunities to repay debts, but in

the process create further indebtedness and undermine their asset base. For instance,

reinvesting in Bt cotton, loan stacking and selling land. The chapter concludes by assessing the

prospects of future rural livelihoods in Kacharam and Telangana considering the economic

distress both from the Liberalised Green Revolution and non-farm livelihoods.

Page 179: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

179

6.2 Distress driven farm to non-farm transitions in Telangana and Kacharam

India is a primarily agrarian country with 70% of the population living in rural areas and 43%

of the workforce in agriculture as a primary occupation (DES India, 2018). However, due to

unremunerative returns from agriculture, non-farm incomes are increasingly playing a more

prominent role. In Telangana, representative state-wide surveys showed that 57% of rural

households relied primarily on non-farm incomes (NFHS, 2016). At an India level, Chand et

al (2017) found that the non-farm sector contributed to 65% of rural household incomes within

agricultural households.

Table 9 below shows that in Kacharam, 39% to 70% of total household income came from

non-farm livelihoods. Even though most households self-identify as farming households, the

most important income is actually non-farm sources.

Table 9 - Non-farm Incomes

Household Category Count Household

Income ($)

Non-Farm

Income ($)

Non-Farm

Income % Of

Household

Income

All Farmers 105 1948 996 51

OBC 74 1819 757 42

SC 23 2541 1741 69

ST 8 1443 1011 70

Widow 11 2391 1516 63

Non-Widow 94 1897 934 49

Marginal (<1 ha) 33 1820 1229 68

Small (1-2 ha) 56 1905 905 48

Medium (>2-5 ha) 16 2101 825 39

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

In the model of structural transformation within developing countries, agricultural

intensification was predicted to increase productivity and economic growth (Van Der Ploeg,

2014). Higher farm incomes were then expected to drive consumption demand and

reinvestment in other sectors of the economy. Eventually, the linkages with non-farm sector

led to urbanisation and industrialisation, and new job opportunities outside of farming pulled

people out of agriculture into non-farm work (Carlson, 2018). This is what Reddy et al (2014b)

call a demand pull or growth led rural non-farm transition.

Page 180: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

180

In Kacharam and Telangana, on the other hand, an adverse form of structural transformation

of farmer livelihoods occurred, what Singh and Bhogal (2016: p285) term as a:

“distress induced transformation, based on crisis-driven factors such as falling

productivity, increasing costs and decreasing returns, unemployment and

underemployment and indebtedness. These push factors force the agricultural

workforce towards non-farm activities.”

Due to persistent harvest and well failures in the Liberalised Green Revolution shown in

Chapters 4 and 5, the move to non-farm incomes was a response to their plight on their farm

and pressing need to repay debts from agriculture and household expenses. Non-farm incomes

subsidised the losses from agricultural commercialisation. This thesis makes a theoretical

distinction as to the type of farmers that exit agriculture. For agricultural modernisation

theorists, subsistence agriculture is regarded as an insufficient livelihood for maximising

economic growth, envisaging their exit out of agriculture and into wage labour or integration

into markets to increase their incomes (Li, 2009). Moreover, in the agrarian political economy

literature, scholars (Bernstein, 2010; Hebinck, 2018; Bennike et al, 2020) show how

subsistence farming in a market economy becomes increasingly unremunerative relative to the

economic demands on the household, requiring them to engage in different non farm activities

to make ends meet. This is evidenced at an India level, as Rahman and Mishra (2019) calculate

that 25% of smallholder farmers in India would fall below the poverty line if they did not earn

non-farm incomes.

However, in this thesis, I argue that adverse agricultural commercialisation is the causal driver

of the structural shift to non-farm livelihoods in Kacharam. This contrasts with subsistence

farming or agricultural intensification causing the exit from agriculture. The introduction of

high capital intensive and debt backed Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation occurred in a harsh

agroecological and aquifer environment and by intermediaries and governments in the

Liberalised Green Revolution. Yet, accumulating loans from farm losses and rising household

expenditure meant that interest repayments of 24% to 36% on informal credit increased,

pushing farmers to non-farm livelihoods out of no other choice. Farmer B19 in Kacharam, an

elderly ST farmer with 1 ha, felt agriculture was not remunerative for the past decade in the

village despite investing in 12 tubewells, which all failed and left him debts of $5,000. He felt

the same about Bt cotton despite growing it for 15 years. He said exasperatedly:

Page 181: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

181

“No nothing is left from farming. We get more money from working in the rice mill

and agricultural labour we don’t have any income from farming…we cannot meet the

costs of the household from just farming is why we go for agricultural labour. There

are no opportunities the fields have dried up [there is] no water.” (B19, farmer, 2/4/19)

The political economy of the capital, risk and debt backed Bt cotton and tubewell technologies

intersected with worsening aquifer and climate conditions over the last two decades, causing

an agrarian crisis. The bet on Bt cotton had devastating consequences for 85% of Kacharam’s

farmers who grew it as a monocrop and 66% of the village that adopted tubewells as the

expected profitability increasingly did not arrive.

This section has laid out the dynamics of the transition from farm to non-farm in Kacharam.

The fallout of the Liberalised Green Revolution in Kacharam have prompted unintended

deagrarianisation. The next section explores the intergenerational dynamics of non-farm

livelihoods for rural youth in Kacharam.

6.2.1 Rural youth and farming in Telangana and Kacharam

Education attainment in Kacharam and Telangana has been one of the most important

incentives for rural youth to leave farming behind, unwilling to endure the penury their parents

faced in the Liberalised Green Revolution. Youth within farming households, classified as ages

15-29, are much better educated than their parents’, part of a rural generation attaining

education for the first time in India (Jakimow, 2014). In Kacharam, 85% of household heads

have no formal education, compared to 53% of 15-29 year olds attaining a 10th grade education

or higher, with 23% of them degree educated. Gender wise, this corresponded to 54% of female

youth with a 10th grade education or higher, whereas for male youth the number was 72%. In

Telangana, the percentage of rural youth in tertiary education also increased from 30% to 36%

between 2011-20 (Kannibiran et al, 2017; DES Telangana, 2020). The percentages of rural

male and female youth engaging in agriculture in Telangana stood at 18% and 9% in 2004-5,

and decreased to 11% and 6% by 2011-12 (Kannibiran et al, 2017). In place of agriculture,

opportunities in the transport sector, salaried administration jobs and construction saw the

biggest increases in employment (ibid).

For the older farmers, helping their parents with farming from a young age made it an inherited

livelihood and asset, taking over their parents once they passed. Education was not a priority

for the current generation of farmers, as their own parents lacked the awareness, finances and

opportunity to educate them. For this generation, farming was a way of life they inherited from

Page 182: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

182

their parents. This is reflected by the fact that 85% of all farmer households have no formal

education. Similarly, in village surveys in 1975 in Mahbubnagar district in Telangana, Deb et

al (2014) found that households on average only had 3 years of schooling for males and 1 year

for females. This increased to 7 years for males and 5 years for females by 2011-12 respectively

(ibid). In helping out their parents on the farm from a young age, farming became a livelihood

they inherited as they took over the land from their parents. For the new generation of rural

youth in Kacharam, the practise and experience of farming at a young age was replaced by

education, as they were encouraged by their parents to not follow the farming trajectory.

For rural youth today, farming from childhood was replaced by education, as they were

encouraged by their parents not to farm. Farmers educated their children, and their children

were motivated to leave the farm and not fall into the same immiserating conditions of the

Liberalised Green Revolution as their parents did. This is confirmed in village wide opinion

surveys where I asked the question: “Would you like your child to practise agriculture as a

primary livelihood in the future?”. The responses to the question are laid out below in Table

10. Across every category, an average of 74% of farmers did not want their children to farm.

Table 10 - Farming Futures Survey

Household Category Count Farming Future

Children Yes (%)

Farming Future

Children No (%)

All Farmers 105 26 74

OBC 74 28 72

SC 23 26 74

ST 8 25 75

Widow 11 55 45

Non-Widow 94 22 78

Marginal (<1 ha) 33 12 88

Small (1-2 ha) 56 32 64

Medium (>2-5 ha) 16 31 69

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Table 10 showed that across all categories except widows, farmers wanted their children to not

go into agriculture. Widow’s responses can be explained by the fact that most of the widows

were females. In a highly patriarchal system such as India’s daughters are usually married off

into another village and sons stay behind to take care of the land. For widowed women the need

for their sons to take over is more important than for other types of households, simply because

of the need for extra labour on the farm and support for their mother in their old age.

Interviewee C57 was a middle aged OBC woman with 2.5 ha of land and made $147 profit in

Page 183: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

183

2018 from cotton. Fortunately, her son had an undergraduate degree, knew how to farm and

also worked in a fertiliser shop on a part time basis while writing exams for government jobs.

Referring to the help she received from her son, C57 commented:

“I am saved due to the land otherwise I would have been in an unimaginable

situation….my son’s income is the primary income for the household other than

farming”. (C57, farmer, 10/6/19)

For most farmers, they wanted their children to pursue better paid jobs with their educational

opportunities, bringing material and social advancement for the household (Jakobsen, 2019).

As Jakimow (2014) describes from her fieldwork in Telangana, education represented

progression in social status and dignity for the household imbued through their children,

compared to the grinding work and poverty they endured. For older generations, the definition

of a good life was for their children was to not go through hard labour in the fields which they

regarded as undignified, but instead work inside under a fan and at a desk, earning a monthly

salary (Jakimow, 2012).

Decisions to send their children to private school therefore are not taken lightly and require

recurring payments of fees. The purposeful decision to invest in children’s education, costing

up to $500 annually or 25% of annual household incomes, also came with the understanding

that their children would never learn how to farm. Farmers believed that if they educated their

children fully, they could escape the farm and secure a well-paying job. In some instances

among rural youth however they chose not to be educated out of dislike for school in their

childhood so dropped out. Later into adulthood they went into farming with no other option for

a livelihood (D7 Farmer, interview, 1/7/19). Farmer’s wanting their children to go into

agriculture therefore was as a last resort only if they had no education and no other options to

pursue.

Moreover, if older farmers were struggling to successfully grow Bt cotton despite farming since

childhood, there was no chance of their children surviving as farmers in Liberalised Green

Revolution. This is especially true considering the worsening climatic extremes and rainfall

variability farmers have experienced in Kacharam which has made farming risky. Therefore, it

was a better choice for farmers to not farm at all, as even if they did, they would not be able to

cope with the stresses and technical skills in farming. Farmer D30, a middle aged OBC woman,

raised her daughter on her own from infancy when her husband abandoned the family and

remarried. Owning less than 1 ha of land and struggling to make ends meet, it was clear to her

Page 184: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

184

that her daughter should live a better life than what she went through. Nor would she be able

to cope with farming in the unpredictable agroecological setting and high capital intensive

crops in Kacharam:

“No I want her to study I don’t want her to do farming oh no…because now we

ourselves are struggling to survive on the farm without any education so if she is more

intelligent becomes educated she can survive she can escape all of this…now the

children are studying what do they know about farming how will they cope with the

difficulty? If they get a job then their life will be set.” (D30, farmer, 26/6/19)

Farmers put their children through education at any cost to secure well paid non-farm jobs.

This aspiration was matched by their children, who watched their parents suffer through

repeated problems with agricultural commercialisation. The emphasis for younger generations

of farming households was to access greater occupational and income mobility through

education that their parents never enjoyed. For elder farming household heads, they accepted

the trade-off that their children would never know how to farm if they went to school, as even

they themselves struggled to make a meaningful livelihood out of farming in the Liberalised

Green Revolution. It meant accepting that this current generation of older farming households

may be the last generation of full-time farmers in the village.

This section has shown that non-farm livelihoods are not only a practical necessity but an

aspirational desire for their children to leave farming for good through education. The next

section however, reveals that non-farm incomes have not kept up with the rising indebtedness

and costs of living at the household level. The average household in Kacharam made -$1550

in the fieldwork year 2018, highlighting the gap between expenditure and income. These have

prompted them to engage in risky short term cash earning strategies I term “risk indebtedness

treadmills”. A key reason of why farmers have resorted to this is the prevalence of low paid,

menial non-farm jobs in India as the main employment option, even for their educated children.

Hence, the bet on their children’s education has not come to fruition, leaving rural households

mired in economic uncertainty.

Page 185: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

185

6.2.2 Contending with precarious non-farm employment in Kacharam and Telangana

Non-farm livelihoods in Telangana brought much needed income support for farmers who bore

the brunt of the agrarian crisis from the Liberalised Green Revolution. Non-farm livelihoods

provided work in the dry season for farmers in Telangana plus a permanent livelihood for the

younger educated generation. However, despite all non-farm household incomes across

generations, 100% of the 65 farmers interviewed felt that non-farm incomes were still

insufficient to simultaneously cover their interest repayments, household expenditure and farm

debts.

Older generations largely worked in low skilled agricultural labour, MNREGA and

construction labour, earning $3 to $7 per day. Adding up all labour days came to 298 days per

year per household, compared to 480 available workdays outside the farming season from June

to September for a husband-and-wife farmer. In total, this earned farmers on average $1075

per household in Kacharam. Farmers could only find non-farm work for 62% of the labour

days available in the dry season.

Labour however is highly gendered and segmented in rural areas, referred to as social

reproduction, which Katz (2001: p709) defines as:

“social practices through which people reproduce themselves on a daily and

generational basis and through which social relations and the material basis of

capitalism are renewed.”

For Levien et al (2018), these social practices include unpaid domestic work, child rearing and

lower pay and more precarious work in agricultural labour and construction work for women

relative to men, exemplifying differentiation in at all areas from within the household to labour

markets. Across all females in Kacharam aged over 18, farming was the primary occupation

for 58% of them and agricultural labour for 28%. Likewise for all males over 18 in Kacharam,

only 6% listed their primary occupation as agricultural labour and 61% for agriculture.

Agricultural labour is highly gendered with regards to the work done on the farm. Agricultural

labour is mostly conducted by women in the village, due to the gendered division of labour

demand. Labour intensive work such as hand weeding and picking cotton is done primarily by

women, owing to their lower agricultural wages at $2-3 per day and lack of desire for men to

do such a difficult task. Moreover, Venkateshwarlu and Da Corta (2001) report from Andhra

Pradesh that women were regarded by labour organisers as being easier to discipline and more

Page 186: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

186

willing to work in the cotton harvest season. In comparison, men do activities such as spraying

pesticides, tilling the land with tractors, weeding it with oxen, and spreading seeds. These tasks

require fewer people to carry it out and are less labour intensive so can be done in a shorter

period compared to women’s agricultural labour work. This explains why out of all the

agricultural labour in the village in Kacharam, women make up 60% to 70% of total days

worked. Men are paid $4 to $12 per day, the lowest paid work is for manual labour tasks and

the highest earners driving tractors or working oxen to till the land before a farmer plants the

seeds. In discussions with female household members, it was acknowledged that women are

in more demand for agricultural labour in cotton growing areas as cotton harvesting was the

most labour intensive and most important part of the cotton season (B6 farmer, 24/6/19).

A further aspect of gender differentiation is also in present in construction labour. Women are

mainly confined to the lowest skilled aspects of construction labour, such as lifting and

transporting cement bricks around the site. For this, they are paid $4 to $5 per day. In

comparison, men are paid $6 to $8 for equivalent work. Furthermore, men are able to access

more skilled construction labour roles such as masons, who on average earn $10 to $12 per day

from construction, supervising the lower skilled workers and working on more technical

aspects of construction. For the majority of women and men in the village, daily wage labour

is the most common available work, comprising of mostly unskilled, low paid and laborious

work. Within these daily wage labour positions however, women are paid less for equivalent

work and due to the gendered division of labour are unable to move up to more skilled roles in

both construction and agricultural labour. Their low pay is partly offset by the greater demand

for agricultural labour for women, especially during harvest season in picking rice or cotton.

For the educated rural youth in Kacharam, non-farm work as shop attendants or drivers in

nearby towns and cities earned better wages than their parents, at $5-10 per day. However,

even with rural youth incomes, households in Kacharam were still unable to meet their annual

expenses such as food, education, and medical care. A key reason for this household financial

situation has been the unfulfilled potential of educated rural youth in India in accessing salaried

jobs in towns and cities. This is a symptom of the inability of the labour market in India to

create adequate skilled jobs to meet the growing numbers of educated youth in India (Mehra,

2019).

Page 187: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

187

India has ideal demographic and educational conditions for an economic growth take off. The

median age in India is 29 compared to China’s 37 (Kaul, 2019), meaning that the working age

population vastly outnumbers the dependent elderly population, referred to as the demographic

golden age. Much of this young workforce is also educated and seeking work. The absolute

numbers of the 15-29 year olds in education have increased from 56.8 million in 2004-5 to 127

million in 2017-18, much faster than the population growth rate (Mehrotra and Parida, 2019).

India has experienced 5-8% annual economic growth rates since liberalisation in 1991

(Srivastava et al, 2020), but growth has not come with required increases in formal skilled jobs

either in the public or private sector. Out of the 61 million jobs created since 1991, 92% have

been informal jobs, characterised by low wages and little social protection or pensions (India

Spend, 2019). The main non-farm sector in rural areas has been construction, which grew at

17% per year from 9.4 million in 1999 to 54.3 million in 2017-18, making it the second biggest

employer in rural areas after agriculture (Dhanagare, 2016; Mehrotra and Parida, 2019).

Between 2005 and 2018 only 4.6 million formal jobs were created, 7% of the total (Srivastava

et al, 2020). This meant that 14% of 15-29 year olds in rural India in 2017 fell under the

working poverty rate of earning less than $1.90 per day (Reddy, 2020). This echoes Kacharam,

whereby both farmers and their children engage in low paid daily wage labour in construction

and in the transport sector. Though rural youth are better educated, they could not access the

social mobility both they and their parents expected, driving them into despair (Jakimow, 2016;

Aga, 2019).

The 2010s in India has been termed as the “lost decade” (Kaul, 2019), partly due to the financial

crisis causing an economic growth slowdown, rising youth unemployment and slow job

creation relative to demand (Pastore, 2018). Between 2012 and 2018, the construction and

service sectors only created 4.5 million jobs per year compared to 17.5 million job entrants into

the labour market annually (Jose Thomas, 2020). In this period moreover, 90.4% of all new

non-agricultural jobs were taken by men aged 30-59, leaving out youth and women (ibid). This

is partially because some educated youth are choosing to drop out from the labour market

altogether than enter low skilled jobs available (Reddy, 2020a).

The economic malaise has also exacerbated gender differentiation in the labour market. For

rural women in India, social relations at the household level and the labour market resign them

to the bottom of the social hierarchy, especially if they are already low class and low caste.

Lerche and Shah (2018) categorise their position in India’s economy as a form of conjugated

Page 188: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

188

oppression, as they not only face exploitation in agriculture and as wage labourers, but their

social reproduction of labour in the household is also devalued. Within a capitalist system, rural

women face a burden of gender and caste exploitation, but under a framework of class relations

(ibid). This translates to their livelihood opportunities in agriculture and non-agriculture,

relegated to the lowest paid, most laborious tasks while also expending reproductive labour at

the household level. This has been no different in the stagnation era in the 2010s. Owing to a

lack of economic opportunities in the labour market, Thomas (2020) notes that approximately

29m women withdrew from India’s workforce altogether a de-feminisation of the labour

market. In the working age category of 15-59, total employment for women declined from 43%

in 2005 to 23% in 2018, with the majority of women now classified as reproductive labour

(ibid).

In sectors like construction, women have historically been restricted to unskilled manual labour

through a gendered division of labour. Sanghera (2019) explains that in times of economic

contraction, women are the first to be let go, with men in skilled positions retaining their jobs

as supervisors and masons. Educational inequalities and labour market discrimination with

maternity leave have also diminished women’s chances in the more skilled labour markets too,

being left with limited options that avail their qualifications. This explains the disappearance

of rural women especially from India’s labour market during this stagnation. Not only are they

unable to gain access to the new non-farm jobs relative to men, but are discriminated at the

workplace through a gendered division of labour and have lower educational completion rates

than men. Faced with limited options to improve occupational and social mobility in a capitalist

and patriarchal system, women have exited the workforce altogether (Rao, 2018b).

For example, patriarchal and class relations affect entry into a labour market by poor women

through historic social norms of women’s access to education, discrimination at the work place,

and women’s role as child carers that limit promotions, equal pay and full time work

opportunities, and a gendered division of labour (Rao, 2018b). Making it easier to enter a labour

market in this case therefore does nothing to change social relations in women’s favour so they

benefit from it, as markets are built within a patriarchy (Katz, 2001). Market incorporation is

built upon local and context specific socio-cultural categories that adversely impact poverty

and inequality, rather than reduce them.

Low paid work in non-farm sectors has also been especially bleak for the educated rural youth

who expected better job prospects. In response to the lack of available and desirable non-farm

Page 189: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

189

jobs, between 2005 and 2018, the number of educated youth in NEET status in India (not in

employment, education or training) increased from 69.5 million to 100.2 million (Mehrotra and

Parida, 2019). In Telangana and Andhra Pradesh, the corresponding figure over this period

increased from 4.2 million to 5.8 million (ibid). This had important gender dynamics however.

Disaggregating further, Kannibiran et al (2017) found that in Telangana, the share of rural

female youth engaging in domestic and household work as their principal status increased from

18% to 28%, compared to only 4% for rural males. For women overall, the share of women in

unpaid work also increased from 35% to 39% between 2004-5 and 2011-12 in Telangana. In

India, 38% of the rural female population aged 15-24 are in the NEET category, compared to

only 12% for rural males in the same age group. When it comes to graduates moreover, 29%

of rural males and 38% of rural females are in this category, signifying a high drop out rate

from the labour market and under/unemployment.

A large portion of educated youth therefore are not only underemployed or unemployed but

are no longer looking for work, out of the options available to them. Youth unemployment

outpaced population growth between 2005 and 2018, increasing from 8.9 million to 25.1

million in this period (Mehrotra and Parida, 2019). In Andhra Pradesh and Telangana, the

situation has been even worse than the Indian average, as youth unemployment rose from 3%

in 2004-5 to 27.4% in 2018-19 versus the all-India average of 17.8% (The Print, 2020).

In Kacharam, only 15 out of 31-degree graduates in the village had jobs. Out of the 15, 6 were

car or rickshaw drivers, which are low daily wage jobs. The remaining worked in input or

grocery stores as attendants, earning up to $9 per day, much lower than what they expected in

the formal government or private sector jobs. Even within educated rural youth however,

employment was highly gendered. Amongst 68 female youth in the village, 54% had a 10th

grade education or higher, of whom 17 had degrees. However, only 3 out of 17 had jobs as

shopkeepers, teachers or in the private sector, with the rest unemployed or engaging in

housework. The exception in employment for rural females were for SC households, For SCs,

educational quotas in the public sector have helped the younger generations to become

educated for free and access better jobs than their parents. SC youth in the village are also

eligible for government jobs such as teachers, which has brought benefits especially to SC

women, as farmer D38 described, an SC farmer with two children who were both educated for

free via caste based quotas in education. From this, his daughter was also able to access quotas

in the labour market to become a public school teacher:

Page 190: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

190

“My daughter is also educated and now she is teaching at a English medium school…I

got my due with her. (D38, farmer, 3/7/19)

Due to caste based reservations in the labour market and education, the highest earning

occupation in the village are two SC female teachers, who earn on average $2777 per year

much higher than average earnings for non-farm livelihoods overall at $990 in the village. For

the rest of the educated female youth however, degrees have not come with employment.

In comparison, for the 72 male youth, 68% had a 10th grade education or higher, and 22 with

degrees. Amongst the degree educated youth, only 8 had jobs, of which 5 worked as drivers

and 3 in shops. Hence, despite the high level of unemployment amongst rural youth in

Kacharam, degree educated females have a higher unemployment rate, which demonstrates

that gains in education for women has not borne out in better labour market outcomes, which

is emblematic of wider trends at the Telangana or India level.

The story of educated youth in Kacharam has often been to persist in a menial job that is

unfulfilling, while they apply for better positions elsewhere in the private or public sector.

Farmer C37, an SC widow with two young degree educated sons, last made a profit from Bt

cotton three years ago. The loss of her husband a decade ago, plus her underemployed sons left

her lamenting why, despite doing everything right, she was not seeing the gains from her efforts

to educating them:

“Back then my husband was still alive it was good…we [now] feel like there is no

difference between us planting cotton or not in terms of welfare…The elder [son] is

educated but is struggling to find a job so he does odd jobs here and there…What can

[our extended family] do [to help us] they are in the same situation as us.” (C37, farmer,

19/6/19)

Over 50% of the degree educated rural youth in the village were either desperately seeking

work or in the worst case giving up on looking altogether, passing their time in the village

playing cards, cricket or watching Youtube videos on their mobiles. Internally, youth

joblessness not only diminished their own aspirations in living a better life and securing a well-

paid job, but their parents’ too (Aga, 2019). This difficulty in finding jobs and of the labour

market for the younger generation had a direct impact on household finances. Farmers relied

on getting their educated children into a decent government or private sector job that provides

a monthly income. In Kacharam however, many farmers find their children working in menial

and unfulfilling jobs despite degrees, unable to get a foothold in the labour market. While this

Page 191: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

191

situation persists, farming households’ economic pressures remain, with too many financial

liabilities to repay and too little income coming in.

A major financial obligation was the interest repayments farmers had to make annually to

moneylenders and input dealers on their debts. These were primarily from farming but also

marriages, weddings, medical expenses or from buying TVs, mobile phones, or motorbikes on

credit (Louis, 2015; Jakobsen, 2019). As revealed in Chapters 4 and 5, debt burdens for farmers

from Liberalised Green Revolution and the rising cost of living was backed by informal credit

in Kacharam (C5, farmer, 11/6/19). Informal lenders were preferred by farmers over formal

sources for their flexibility in repayment terms. Farmers took out loans from informal creditors

as they were only required to repay annual interest in exchange for new loans. In comparison,

banks required farmers to pay the full principle plus interest to renew loans. In exchange for

easy credit terms however, farmers were obliged to pay higher annual interest repayments of

24% to 36%, sometimes up to 60% in emergencies (Taylor, 2013b).

Average household debts in Kacharam were $3,500 across all castes, classes, and genders,

meaning just annual interest payments alone were between $840 to $1,260, which was 40% to

60% of total household income annually of ~$2100. Table 11 below shows the total household

income, expenditures, and net incomes for farming households in Kacharam. Every category

of household in Kacharam faced average net losses of $1124 to $1550 for the year 2018. The

culmination of interest repayments, household expenses and farm losses in the Liberalised

Green Revolution drove farmers to a grave financial situation.

Table 11 - Net Household Incomes in Kacharam

Source: Ambarish Karamchedu (2019)

Household

Category

Count Total

Household

Income ($)

Total

Household

Expenses +

24%

Interest

Repayment

($)

Total

Household

Expenses +

36%

Interest

Repayment

($)

Net Income

after 24%

Interest

Repayment

($)

Net Income

after 36%

Interest

Repayment

($)

All Farmers 105 2093 3217 3643 -1124 -1550

OBC 74 1924 3182 3634 -1258 -1710

SC 23 2707 3249 3633 -543 -926

ST 8 1828 3792 4250 -1964 -2422

Widow 11 2571 2225 2568 346 3

Non-Widow 94 1945 3361 3810 -1416 -1865

Marginal (<1 ha) 33 1946 2501 2924 -555 -978

Small (1-2 ha) 56 2171 3322 3708 -1152 -1537

Medium (>2-5 ha) 16 2122 4469 5110 -2347 -2988

Page 192: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

192

All but one category of farming households had vastly higher expenditure compared to their

incomes. Table 11 furthermore looked at the best-case scenario and worst-case scenario for

households, comparing 24% and 36% annual interest repayments added onto household

expenditure. Even with the best-case scenario of 24% interest, households on average made a

loss of $1124 across all categories, after all household expenditures. For the worst-case

scenario of a 36% annual interest rate repayment, the net losses for farmers worsened to $1550.

Liberalised Green Revolution technologies added on top of rising household costs and interest

repayments on debt. Both farmer C47 and his wife worked in agricultural labour to make ends

meet and with two young children to support, due to losses of $1346 from Bt cotton in 2018.

Overall, counting net incomes even before his debt repayments, his household lost $2145,

leaving him in despair:

“We go between farming and agricultural labour to find work…we planted twice, and

we didn’t even recoup costs of one round of seeds and inputs…agricultural labour we

don’t get much either…farming, inputs, building an extension on the house, buying

sheep we have so many expenses so we are in debt…we are [only] paying the interest.”

(C47, farmer, 7/6/19)

Farmers’ main debts came from Bt cotton and tubewells, followed by one-off life events such

as medical emergencies and marriage. Debts from Bt cotton and tubewells were the single

highest debt source for 47% of farming households in Kacharam, at an average debt of $2200.

This rise in indebtedness and expenses relative to household incomes was also evident

elsewhere in Telangana. In Deb et al (2014)’s study in two villages in Mahabubnagar district,

they found that between 1989 and 2011, debts increased almost 6x in real terms, with an

average of 65% of loans coming from informal credit sources. Debts came from farm

investments in Bt cotton and tubewells as well as increases in ownership of motorbikes, fridges,

mobile phones, and TVs. In this time frame, per capita incomes only increased by 5x in one of

the villages, meaning consumption expenditure and farm investments were rising faster than

incomes (ibid). Finally, Telangana wide figures revealed that the 89% of agricultural

households were indebted in 2013, compared to 57% at the India level (NSSO, 2013a).

Between 2002 and 2013, debts across all class categories increased by an average of 14x in

real terms for farming households in Telangana (Reddy, 2014). As a result of their mounting

indebtedness and inability to repay, farmers in Kacharam engaged in risky cash earning

strategies that I call “risk indebtedness treadmills” to keep on top of their repayments. I explore

these strategies in the next section.

Page 193: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

193

6.2.3 Risk indebtedness treadmills

Pressed from low incomes from farm and non-farm work and debt repayments, farmers

resorted to several strategies to dig themselves out of their economic situation. Farmers must

repay the interest on their loans annually to renew loans for the next year, so prioritise that

from whatever income they earn. Farmers have resorted to several cash earning strategies as a

last-ditch effort, what I call “risk indebtedness treadmills”. These are distress inducing income

strategies that involve generating short term cash but at the cost of long term immiseration.

Risk indebtedness treadmills meet short term cash needs for farmers. These occur as a response

to the fact that farmers have no real easy solutions to escape their financial obligation but need

cash in the short term to stave off the worst-case scenario of defaulting on their debts and

having their land seized from them. Farmer C3, a young OBC farmer, worked in agricultural

labour with his wife but all incomes in 2018 from farm and non-farm came to $347, versus

household expenses of $720. This made it impossible to repay his debts in the short or the long

term, but the minimum he needed to pay was the interest each year:

“They add the interest repayments onto the next year they don’t cause a fuss but add a

cumulative repayment term. If we do not pay the interest they complain. We paid it this

year.” (C3, farmer, 7/6/19)

With no prospect of paying off the principle, farmers can still take out new loans with the

moneylender if they keep on top of the interest payments. Keeping good faith with their

moneylenders was so they could continue to take out new loans to finance their rising cost of

living and economic obligations. This strategy of prioritising interest repayments kept them

afloat for another year as the moneylender continued to issue new loans. These loans were then

used to pay for the next most pressing financial payments they need to make, be it education,

a medical emergency or farm investments. Additionally, farmers stacked loans from different

sources to repay their existing interest repayments, further perpetuating their indebtedness (C3,

farmer, 7/6/19). Using smaller loans e.g. from microcredit, farmers would use these to pay off

larger informal interest repayments annually. This matches fieldwork in Telangana by

Ramprasad (2019), who reported similar strategies of loan stacking between formal and

informal sources. This, however, formed a risk indebtedness treadmill, as taking out new loans

increased the overall debt and therefore also the interest payments, worsening the household

finances in the long term and keeping them within tighter debt relations.

Page 194: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

194

The second strategy for farmers was to double down on their Bt cotton investments for the

coming year. Despite the problems of indebtedness and harvest failures with Bt cotton shown

in Chapter 4 the hope remained that they would strike lucky one time and it will solve their

problems. After all they went through, the hope remained that its profitability would come to

fruition one day. This is like the sunk cost fallacy of drilling tubewells deeper and expecting it

to yield groundwater, as shown in Chapter 5 (Marechal, 2010). So, the choice to keep growing

Bt cotton could ruin them and increase their risk and debt loads and interest repayments in

future years but a good harvest could also bring a golden income. This calculus of risk however

often pushed towards a loss, due to the lack of suitability of Bt cotton for Telangana with

climate extremes and erratic rainfall. This makes the decision to continue growing Bt cotton a

strategy that perpetuates a risk indebtedness treadmill.

In Mahbubnagar district in Telangana, Jakimow (2014) also found repeated gambles from

farmers in borrowing further loans to grow Bt cotton. She explained that the chance of one

bountiful harvest from Bt cotton was worth years of failure to farmers, despite mounting

evidence that it did not bring the promised returns (ibid). This also matches Bt cotton

cultivation in Burkina Faso, where scholars revealed that it was the biggest economic risk and

debt for households but the only crop with a high enough market price to meet household costs

(Luna, 2019). Similarly, in Kacharam, though a Bt cotton golden harvest did not arrive in recent

years, the prospect that it may still one day come was enough to sustain farmers in reinvesting,

backed by informal credit lines to renew their loans each year.

The final short-term cash strategy was for farmers to sell their assets such as land and livestock.

This was done for meeting agricultural investments for planting before the monsoon but also

one-off expenses such as medical emergencies or marriage. Selling land was the last resort out

of all options however as farmers held a deep cultural identity with their land, something they

inherited and chose to pass onto their children (D7, farmer, 2/7/19). Yet, left with no choice

and mounting debts, farmers have been selling pieces of land to pay for expenses. Equally, in

the case of Bt cotton debts in Burkina Faso, Gray and Dowd-Uribe (2013) report how low Bt

cotton yields in rainfed conditions forced farmers to sell off assets to meet debt repayments. In

Kacharam, since 2017, I found that 15 households sold a portion of their land and 8 households

sold their livestock. In fact, land sales were the highest sources of non-farm income in

household surveys in 2018 in Kacharam at $2300. This reflects the fact that non-productive

activities are the highest earning non-farm incomes in Kacharam, showing activities like wage

Page 195: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

195

labour and shop work to be relatively low paid. In times of stress however, the instant need for

cash required drastic measures for farmers to sell land. Farmer C30 was one such example, a

middle-aged SC farmer who had to deal with her daughter having pregnancy complications,

breaking her own leg and her other daughter’s marriage in a space of a few weeks:

“We had a lot of health problems to deal with. We had [$2923] to [$4385] of debts that

way. [Due to] hospital expenses…we sold an acre for my daughter’s wedding then 15

days later I fell down and broke my leg. It cost [$2923] [but] then within a year my

daughter became sick.” (C30, farmer, 18/6/19)

For this household, consecutive emergencies required land to be sold. Land, however, is often

also the most valuable asset a farmer holds, both in terms of monetary value and its cultural

significance. Selling land is a strategy that perpetuates a risk indebtedness treadmill as the more

land that a farmer sells, the smaller their asset base for collateral for future loans. The distress

strategy solved the immediate short-term cash emergency but reduced the landholding size in

the long run. This is especially risky as the average landholding in Kacharam is already low at

1.2 ha.

Based on nationally representative household surveys, land contributed to 71.3% of total assets

of rural households in Telangana and 72.6% at the all-India level (NSSO, 2013d, e). Selling

land was not an option except in emergencies when no more loans can be taken out and all

other risk indebtedness treadmill options had been exhausted. Selling land moreover would be

a one-off scenario after which they no longer have the asset after their last chunk of land is

sold. Nonetheless, the growing trend in Kacharam has been to engage in this distress tactic that

shrunk their assets, future ability to borrow, erased their cultural attachment to land and left

them with a smaller land parcel to farm on.

Burdened by debts from Bt cotton and tubewell investments that did not pay off and rising

household costs, farmers in Kacharam resorted to earning non-farm incomes, as well as

investing in their children’s education to help them secure salaried jobs and leave farming. Yet,

as a function of a jobs crisis in India, non-farm incomes have largely been low paid and

insecure, forcing farmers to resort to the three “risk indebtedness treadmill” tactics mentioned

to keep the household afloat, but in the process undermining their asset base and debt relations.

This demonstrates that there are no easy answers in this transition from the farm to the non-

farm and the future of agriculture in Kacharam.

Page 196: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

196

6.3 Conclusion

To respond to their economic burden from Liberalised Green Revolution, farmers in Kacharam

and Telangana have transitioned into relying on non-farm incomes for survival. Non-farm

incomes make up the biggest share in household incomes for farmers, and so have been an

important coping strategy for dealing with unremunerative agricultural incomes. However,

available non-farm livelihood options in Kacharam were largely limited to daily wage labour

roles characterised by low pay, insecure contracts, and insufficient supply of labour days.

Despite the transition to non-farm livelihoods, household incomes are simply inadequate for

meeting farmers’ expenditures from farming, household consumption and debt repayments.

The biggest bet for farmers was to educate their children. Education was paramount for

farmers’ children, a ticket to a better, more secure life away from the problems they faced in

farming. Unfortunately, the last decade in India has seen a big rise in young, educated job

seekers relative to the jobs created in the non-farm sector in number and quality. Kacharam’s

youth are therefore inhibited by the broader political economy of the labour market in the

country. Left with little choice in the non-farm sector, many youths in Kacharam have retreated

from the job market altogether or persist in menial jobs, while they wait to catch a lucky break.

This has important implications for households as farmers’ reliance on their educated children

to get them out of their economic problems has not paid off, and they are faced with

increasingly desperate set of distress inducing options to cope.

These set of constraints in non-farm livelihoods and desperation from limited alternative

sources of income prompted farmers to employ short term cash earning strategies that I called

a “risk indebtedness treadmill”, used to repay interest on loans and secure informal credit lines

for another year. Three examples of these include selling parts of their land, stacking loans and

continuing to reinvest in Bt cotton. While they placated temporary cash flow needs for the

household, they also undermined their economic base further, creating more indebtedness in

the long run. The transition from the farm to the non-farm was touted as the solution for

Kacharam and India’s failing agricultural fortunes. Yet, it brought its own problems and had

few answers to help farmers and their children lead a better life as they hoped it would. Instead,

they persist and survive ever more desperately from an uncertain and unyielding future both in

farming and outside of it.

Page 197: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

197

Chapter 7 - Discussion

7.1 Introduction

The previous analysis chapters 4, 5 and 6 answered each of the three research questions of the

thesis on agrarian change and the Liberalised Green Revolution:

1) What are the consequences of Bt cotton farming in the Liberalised Green

Revolution in Telangana?

2) How has tubewell irrigation changed the political economy of agriculture in

Telangana?

3) What are the implications of the Liberalised Green Revolution for the future of

agricultural livelihoods in Telangana?

This discussion chapter situates the findings of the thesis within the broader literature covered

in Chapter 2, both the Liberalised Green Revolution framework and literature on Bt cotton and

tubewell irrigation in India. In doing so, the chapter relates the findings from the thesis to the

Indian context and similar developing country marginal settings. Plus, I engage with theoretical

debates on agricultural commercialisation in agroecologically fragile smallholder settings.

Based on the findings from the fieldwork in Kacharam, this chapter finds that the Liberalised

Green Revolution through informal credit, government subsidies and market intermediaries

enabled smallholder integration into commodity agriculture through the adoption of Bt cotton

and tubewell irrigation. Yet, long-term farm incomes and indebtedness from technology

adoption in marginal areas forced them to leave agriculture for economic survival as an

unintentional side effect of agricultural commercialisation.

In an original finding, I theorised the Liberalised Green Revolution, providing an explanatory

process of how and why potentially adverse agricultural commercialisation can take place in

marginal settings, pointing to the intersection of four factors of environment, credit/debt,

market intermediaries and governments. I located market intermediaries of input dealers,

moneylenders, and irrigation firms as the drivers of technology adoption and agrarian change

in marginal settings. In Kacharam I found that the interlinkages of these four factors tentatively

explained the adverse Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation smallholder adoption and the distress

driven non-farm livelihood transitions it creates.

Page 198: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

198

This chapter will first revisit the Liberalised Green Revolution in context of the thesis findings,

then insert the original findings within the four key causes of environmental conditions,

credit/debt relations, market intermediaries and governments in partially explaining farming

outcomes. In doing so, I will engage with theoretical and empirical debates in the literature on

technology and agrarian change in India that I build on or disagree with. The chapter will then

conclude.

7.2 Revisiting and justifying the Liberalised Green Revolution

In Chapter 2 of the thesis, I proposed that since the 1980s, development donors, country

governments and IFIs have been attempting to replicate the Green Revolution model of

agricultural development in dryland smallholder regions in developing countries through

private sector led economic liberalisation (McMichael, 2009; Moseley et al, 2017). I chose to

define economic liberalisation as:

“new political, economic, and social arrangements within society that emphasize

market relations, re-tasking the role of the state, and individual responsibility…the

extension of competitive markets into all areas of life, including the economy, politics,

and society.” (Springer, 2016: p2)

I termed this private sector agricultural development epoch the “Liberalised Green

Revolution”. It retained similar goals to the Green Revolution of agricultural intensification

through the application of inputs, high yielding seed technologies and pesticides, but took place

in a different political economy, climatic and farmer context. The key differentiating factor was

that agricultural commercialisation this time was being attempted in agroecologically marginal

and economically poor areas in developing countries, involving rainfed subsistence farmers, a

short growing season of up to 120 days, low productivity soils, variable rainfall and worsening

climatic conditions of floods and droughts (Pender, 2007). These areas were largely ignored in

the initial Green Revolution due to the difficulty in replicating yields found in more favourable

areas through technological intensification (Byerlee et al, 2005; Pingali, 2012). Nonetheless,

these areas are globally significant, accounting for over 40% of the global surface area and

supporting 1.8 billion people (Li et al, 2020).

Page 199: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

199

Economic crises in the 1980s in developing countries initially created conditions for economic

liberalisation terms set by the World Bank, IMF and country governments but continue as the

agricultural policy norm today (Kashwan et al, 2019). For instance, efforts in the last decadeto

bring an agribusiness-led GM biotechnology “African Green Revolution” (Bergius and

Busteth, 2019).

Therein, I argued that the Liberalised Green Revolution involved agricultural

commercialisation in smallholder and marginal agroecological areas where the private sector

took the lead in credit, irrigation, inputs, seeds, and extension services, bringing a decentralised,

privatised and marketised agricultural intensification (Oya, 2010; 2011). It drew upon

modernisation theory of the 1960s and 1970s, the idea that technological improvements in

inputs, high yielding seeds and irrigation improved agricultural growth and farmer incomes.

These technologies moreover according to Birner and Resnick (2010) were scale neutral,

meaning they worked regardless of the size of landholding. In the Liberalised Green

Revolution, the lead role of intermediaries and agribusiness was to increase the availability and

reduce the cost of technologies through market competition and subsequently improve incomes

from high prices for commercial crops, high yielding seeds and irrigation (Byerlee et al, 2008;

Zhou, 2010; Venkateshwar and Bandopadhyay, 2016). This would transform the agricultural

sector and lead to the structural transformation of the economy through rising agricultural

growth and eventual industrialisation (Van der Ploeg, 2014; Bergius et al, 2018).

In critiquing the above characterisation of technology-led agrarian change, I proposed the

framework of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in Chapter 2 to formulate the causal

mechanism of why agricultural commercialisation in agroecologically marginal areas in

particular political economy contexts may not improve farmers livelihoods in the long run. The

above theoretical proposition drew upon insights from agrarian political economy and political

ecology scholars who argued that uneven and detrimental outcomes from technology adoption

under agrarian change can occur due to a lack of consideration of the embedded social,

economic and agroecological context, and differentiated access and outcomes mediated by

caste, class, or gender (Gerber, 2013, 2014; Schnurr, 2019; Myers et al, 2020).

Page 200: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

200

I delineated four key factors to causally understand the process of market integration of

smallholders. First was the characteristics of soils, climate, and water in marginal

agroecological areas (Rao, 2008). Second, the credit/debt relations that farmers entered with

creditors to finance agricultural investments (Ramprasad, 2019). Third, I examined the role of

market intermediaries in credit, technology, and extension services as replacement of

governments in driving agricultural commercialisation in a liberalised setting (Aga, 2019).

Finally, was the role of governments in facilitating market integration in agriculture via both

scaling back public sector provision of inputs, credit and irrigation in welfare and subsidy

supports (Harriss-White, 2020).

Political ecology and agrarian political economy scholars have looked at these four factors in

different combinations in analysing adverse agricultural liberalisation in developing countries

(Taylor, 2011; Green, 2019; Natarajan et al, 2019) but this thesis argues that the conjugated

axes along which they interact is important, as well as emphasising market intermediaries at

the centre of the process of agricultural liberalisation and technology adoption (Jan and Harriss-

White, 2019).

The reasons for selecting the intersection of the four factors in the Liberalised Green

Revolution framework were as follows. Political ecology scholars have found that agricultural

intensification in marginal areas can be adverse as the soil, water and climatic conditions are

unconducive to prolonged intensification (Watts, 1983).

Second, I observed that credit was key to financing agricultural investments for cash poor

smallholders in developing countries. The common process through which this occurred are

interlocked factor markets, where farmers buy investments on informal credit to finance

technology and in exchange, sell their produce at a fixed price back to the intermediary (Jaleta

et al, 2009). However, in marginal settings, political ecology scholars have termed the process

of “reproductive squeeze” to describe how the more farmers proceed with agricultural

intensification, the more they increase environmental degradation and are kept within debt

relations to intermediaries over time due to unrealised incomes from crop investments (Gerber,

2013; Green, 2019; Vasquez, 2020). In a context of rising household expenses under economic

liberalisation for smallholders, they also entered market relations at the household level for

education, health, and consumption too (Luna, 2019). To afford these, farmers continued to

grow commodity crops as the only economically viable option relative to subsistence crops.

Page 201: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

201

Third, I argued that market intermediaries under economic liberalisation in developing

countries replaced the government in credit, technology, and extension services due to public

sector cutbacks as the important propagator of agricultural commercialisation (Bergius et al,

2019). Following a profit ethos, each intermediary served to increase provision of credit, inputs

or irrigation and provide extension advice to facilitate farmer adoption (Glover, 2007; Aga,

2019). In this way, intermediaries promoted agricultural technologies to smallholder farmers

in difficult growing environments, but often yields never matched the investments in inputs,

leaving farmers unable to repay cumulative interest repayments (Schnurr, 2012). This

reinforced a “reproductive squeeze”, forcing farmers to sell assets to cope or double down on

commodity crop cultivation in hope that the high market price pays off (Gray and Dowd-Uribe,

2013).

Finally, governments under economic liberalisation acted as facilitators of markets as part of

an economic development agenda to increase economic growth. In developing country

contexts, governments played contradictory roles of stepping back to enable market

intermediaries to function in deregulated markets, but also stepping forward to enact welfare

policies to appease voter groups. This amounted to what Sanyal (2008) called “welfare

governmentality”, which was to enact palliative welfare policies to stem crises in agriculture

while keeping the rubric of commodification as the normative goal. Examples such as cash

transfer programmes, electricity and fertiliser subsidies and disbursal of formal credit alongside

agricultural commercialisation are examples of these in developing countries (Demirguc-Kunt

et al, 2018; Natarajan et al, 2019; Norberg, 2020).

Putting these four together, I explained that technology adoption in particular marginal

environments could result in negative long term outcomes for smallholder farmers in yields

and indebtedness, requiring them to engage in non-farm livelihoods to cope with

unremunerative agricultural livelihoods. This is a theoretical distinction from agricultural

modernisation theorists modelling linear increases in agricultural productivity once market

conditions and agricultural technologies are adopted, causing structural transformation and

economic growth as the economy shifts from agrarian to industrialisation (Byerlee et al, 2005;

De Janvry, 2010). Also, I expand on agrarian political economy scholars’ characterisation of

“deagrarianisation” as the process where subsistence farmers are forced to abandon agriculture

from being unable to meet rising household expenses, making them rely on non-farm incomes

to support themselves (Bernstein, 2010; Ellis, 2010; Bryceson, 2019). Instead, I argue that after

subsistence farmers adopt cash crops to become commercial farmers, the long-term outcomes

Page 202: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

202

from unsuitable technology adoption can in some instances drive up indebtedness, and lower

relative incomes compared to cultivation costs, forcing a reliance on non-farm livelihoods.

The following sections highlight the key findings from the thesis, situating them within the

theoretical and empirical literature in order to answer the research questions posed in Chapter

1 of the thesis.

7.3 Technology adoption, agricultural commercialisation, and long-term farming

outcomes

The thesis explored the Liberalised Green Revolution in India through the case studies of Bt

cotton and tubewell irrigation adoption in Telangana, both high capital and input intensive

private sector technologies that took off in the 1990s and 2000s for their high market price and

ability to increase crop yields (Rao, 2008; Flachs, 2019). After the country liberalised its

economy, these were adopted rapidly in often difficult semi-arid and hard rock aquifer

conditions by smallholder farmers. The key reason I argued was the proliferation of private

sector credit, irrigation and input firms that promoted technologies to farmers, along with

governments that facilitated market adoption (Vakulabharanam, 2004; Vasavi, 2019; 2020).

In the case of Telangana, Chapter 4 and Chapter 5 found support to some of the arguments

made by agricultural liberalisation’s proponents of private sector led agricultural

commercialisation. The Liberalised Green Revolution was successful in rapidly increasing

technology adoption amongst smallholder farmers through decentralised market competition.

In particular, the increase in availability of flexible, informal credit to finance Bt cotton and

tubewell investments helped adoption (Parthasarathy, 2013; Vakulabharanam and Motiram,

2014). Compared to the original Green Revolution which targeted specific classes of farmers

with favourable loans and subsidies (Lerche, 2011), private market competition expanded the

access to agricultural technologies to smallholder farmers in the most marginal of areas in

Telangana (Stone and Flachs, 2018).

In Chapter 4, I showed that cotton area in Telangana increased rapidly with the introduction of

Bt cotton in 2002. Between 1955 and 2002, cotton area only increased by 5x from ~100,000

ha to 500,000 ha, but from 2002 to 2019, Bt cotton increased the crop area to almost 2 million

ha, a 4x increase in under 20 years, driven mostly by the 85% of Telangana’s population of

smallholders (DES Andhra Pradesh, 2006; DES Telangana, 2016; DES India, 2019a, b). This

made Bt cotton the single biggest crop by area in Telangana at 33% of the cropping area (ibid).

Page 203: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

203

In Kacharam, a largely subsistence village in 2000, Chapter 4 showed that Bt cotton adoption

was adopted by 100% of the 105 farming households in the village in two decades since its

entry, financed entirely by informal credit. Additionally, the switch to commercial crops by

smallholders in Kacharam to Bt cotton in Chapter 4 fetched 5-6x the market price of

subsistence crops such as sorghum and millets at $58-$73, matching figures by Dhanagare

(2016) in the literature.

In initial years, yields from Bt cotton in Kacharam were higher than the cost of cultivation,

bringing profits and welfare spill overs such as greater consumption of durable goods than with

subsistence farming (Kathage and Qaim, 2012). Beyond the Indian context, we also find in

South Africa and Burkina Faso that favourable credit terms and interlocked factor markets

rapidly increased smallholder adoption and incomes of Bt cotton in semi-arid areas initial

years. In South Africa, Schnurr (2012) finds that adoption increased from 7% to 90% between

2000-2002, whereas in Burkina Faso, smallholder Bt cotton adoption increased to 70%

between 2008-13 and increased household profit by 51% from 2008 to 2011 relative to local

cotton varieties (Dowd-Uribe and Schnurr, 2016).

Similarly, with tubewell irrigation, the Liberalised Green Revolution saw prices decline from

the equivalent of $10,000 for rudimentary tubewells in 1978 in India that could only extract

water up to 50m (Freed and Freed, 2002), to costing $800-$1500 in 2019 for superior

submersible pump tubewells that could extract water from up to 150m depth (MoWR, 2017).

In Kacharam, groundwater was only adopted by 10 farmers in the village previously due to its

price, but Chapter 5 showed that the expansion of credit and private irrigation firms increased

adoption to 69 out of 105 (65%) households, enabling farmers to grow rice for the household.

This is supported in wider literature by Reddy (2020a) in Telangana who showed that tubewell

pump ownership increased by 14x between 1975 and 2011 and at an India level that

groundwater produces $8 billion a year in GDP for agriculture through improved yields (Shah,

2010). Similarly, in dryland Jordan in the 1980s and 1990s, groundwater irrigation of high

value crops increased profits for smallholder farmers rapidly (Al Naber and Molle, 2017). In

this regard, agricultural liberalisation’s proponents were correct in predicting private market

competition increasing technology availability, access, reduced costs and improving incomes

via higher productivity and high market prices for commercial crops (Byerlee et al, 2008).

Page 204: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

204

However, Chapter 4 and 5 showed that economic liberalisation of the agricultural sector in

Telangana in the Liberalised Green Revolution did not produce long-term improvements in

yields or farmer incomes. This was primarily due to the context in which technological

intensification took place (Schnurr, 2017). In Kacharam, Chapter 4 showed that although Bt

cotton was adopted by 100% of farmers, yields and profitability collapsed within five years of

adoption, with 65% of all farmers in Kacharam making a loss from it in 2018. This agrees with

longitudinal studies by Kranthi and Stone (2020), over a similar period, who also reveal that

Bt cotton yields in Telangana and India overall stagnated since 2007. Chapter 4 therefore

refutes the claims made using panel studies between 2003-8 by Qaim et al (2009) that Bt cotton

increased yields, as the thesis takes a longer timeframe to study Bt cotton adoption. Similarly,

outside of India, Bt cotton in South Africa declined in yields by 90% between 1999 and 2011

and in Burkina Faso yields in the long-term improved only by 13% between 2009 and 2015,

despite an increase in cultivation costs by 65% (Schnurr, 2012; Luna and Dowd-Uribe, 2020;

Luna, 2020). This also resonated with Chapter 5, which found that despite 69 households

adopting tubewells, only 14% successfully irrigated crops through to harvest. Overall, 89% of

all 215 wells drilled in the village have failed in two decades. This is corroborated by other

studies in Telangana by Jacoby (2017) of 70-80% failure rates of tubewells drilled over time.

As a result of Bt cotton and tubewell adoption, Chapter 6 found that Bt cotton and tubewell

debts together made up the highest source of debt for 47% of farmers in Kacharam at $2200.

In the long run, the thesis found that Bt cotton and tubewells increased indebtedness from high

capital investments without the adequate return from farm incomes, making farmers rely on

non-farm incomes to survive. Therein, Chapter 6 refuted agricultural modernisation theorists

(Birner and Resnick, 2010) that technology adoption would kick start agricultural growth and

enable the structural transformation of an economy from the farm to the non-farm. In agreement

with Singh and Bhogal (2016)’s term of “distress induced transformation”, agricultural

intensification did not accelerate growth or the structural transformation from farm to the non-

farm. The shift in Kacharam instead occurred in as farmers were forced to rely on non-farm

incomes due to the persistence of Bt cotton harvest losses and aquifer depletion under semi-

arid agroecological settings and worsening monsoons and groundwater levels. This drove them

away from commercial agriculture out of distress.

Page 205: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

205

7.3.1 Explaining agrarian change in the Liberalised Green Revolution in India

Chapter 4 of the thesis argued that the agroecological setting of cotton adoption that was a main

factor voiced by farmers in Bt cotton outcomes, resulting in losses for 65% of all households

across class, caste, and gender of households. Semi-arid areas dominate Telangana’s

agricultural landscape, characterised by poor fertility, storage capacity red soils, unreliable

monsoons, frequent droughts, and high rates of evapotranspiration from rainfall (Gine et al,

2008). Investing in an input and capital-intensive crop such as Bt cotton increased per acre

costs by 10x relative to non-Bt cotton in India (Dhanagare, 2016). This was risky for

smallholder farmers to adopt as it was beholden to climate variability.

Chapter 4 found that declining monsoons over time caused Bt cotton losses for all groups,

overcoming social differentiation by class, caste, or gender. This agreed with studies in

Telangana by Dev and Rao (2007) between 2003-7, who also found cross cutting Bt cotton

problems in rainfed areas. More widely, the problems of rainfed Bt cotton are evident in all

India Bt cotton yield data, which show that rainfed Bt cotton states such as Telangana and

Maharashtra have the lowest yields in India (DES India, 2018). Looking beyond India, low Bt

cotton yields in Burkina Faso and South Africa due to rainfall variability were also key factors

in explaining increasing debts for smallholder farmers from losses in farm investments

(Schnurr, 2012; Gray and Dowd-Uribe, 2013). In a rainfed environment, farmers planted Bt

cotton immediately after the onset of the monsoon, to maximise the chances of rainfall across

the four-month growing season across the monsoon until September (Sharma et al, 2018).

However, monsoons in semi-arid areas were erratic in timing, quantity and consistency,

meaning that even if monsoons were delayed or reduced in a part of the harvest season of Bt

cotton, the crop would dry up.

Worsening monsoons experienced by farmers in Kacharam was also backed by longitudinal

monsoon data at Nalgonda district and Telangana levels showing a negative trendline in total

monsoon rainfall from 1950-2019 (DES Andhra Pradesh, 2006; DES Telangana, 2016; DES

Telangana, 2020). In addition, ethnographic work by Rao et al (2014) in two villages in

Mahbubnagar district in Telangana also found that farmer’s perceived monsoons to be arriving

later and having higher drought frequency between 2002-13, like the findings from Kacharam.

At an India level, rainfall variability is projected to lower Bt cotton production by 15 to 25%

by 2050, indicating that Bt cotton in rainfed growing environments is unsuitable for agricultural

intensification, especially given the high input costs (OECD, 2018).

Page 206: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

206

Nonetheless, the outcomes for Bt cotton was not only a function of the environment, but

political economy conditions too. As shown in Chapter 5, an original finding was that one of

the reasons why Bt cotton was rainfed was due to the siloed and profit maximising private input

dealers and tubewell irrigation firms. In a deregulated private market economy within the

Liberalised Green Revolution, private credit, seeds, inputs, and irrigation firms all sought to

maximise their own profits without complementarity, as farmers adopted tubewells and Bt

cotton but left the latter rainfed. This contrasted with the original Green Revolution as Byres

(1981) argues where inputs, seeds, credit, and extension services were all applied as a sum of

their parts to increase yields and production.

Although 65% of the village installed tubewells, Chapter 5 showed that farmers irrigated rice,

a household food crop, rather than Bt cotton, their main cash crop. In a political economy

context of agricultural liberalisation, the withdrawal of the public sector in extension services

left input and irrigation firms to provide extension advice to farmers on Bt cotton and tubewells.

Bt cotton firms advised farmers to keep reinvesting in the crop when it failed, due to erratic

rainfall. They suggested reinvesting with a different seed variety or combination of pesticides

and inputs, when the problem was growing Bt cotton in rainfed conditions in an unsuitable

semi-arid climate such as Telangana. This mirrors Aga’s (2018) findings of input firms pushing

different fertilisers and pesticides as solutions to problems while not addressing the structural

problems behind low yields.

Equally, Chapter 5 showed that tubewell irrigation firms also sought to maximise tubewell

sales, without advising farmers to irrigate Bt cotton, the main cash crop which faced persistent

yield problems in rainfed conditions. Chapter 5 deepened understanding of the rationale for

why Bt cotton was largely unirrigated in India. The Telangana government actively sought the

cropping pattern of rainfed Bt cotton and tubewell irrigated rice in the dry season, helping it

become the biggest dry season rice grower in India in 2020 (Tribune India, 2020). This is

despite water consumption for rice alone making up 50% of total groundwater available in

India annually (Anupoju and Kambhammettu, 2020), and incentivising it in a semi-arid state

such as Telangana.

Page 207: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

207

This rationale of rainfed Bt cotton was also reflected in Nalgonda and Telangana where only

0-5% and 10-15% of cotton was irrigated respectively (DES Telangana, 2016; DES India,

2019a, b). This agrees with work by Sharma et (2018) who find that on average only 37% of

the total Bt cotton area is irrigated, leaving India with one of the lowest Bt cotton yields globally

(Gutierrez et al, 2020). As Glover (2010b) argues, Bt cotton’s proponents cited studies of

superior yields, but these results were premised on growing it in irrigated conditions. As we

have shown in Chapters 4 and 5, Bt cotton is left rainfed due to the political economy

environment of profit maximising private sector firms and the absence of the government in

regulating or acting as an alternative arbiter of extension advice. This means despite the high

market price most farmers cannot achieve profits due to growing it in rainfed and semi-arid

conditions.

The cropping and irrigation patterns in Kacharam had a quartet of intersecting effects in the

Liberalised Green Revolution, leading to Bt cotton, rice and tubewell failures and increased

indebtedness for farmers. Tubewell firms pushed tubewells to farmers in a hard rock

environment, combined with semi-arid climatic conditions. Drilling into hard rock aquifers is

unpredictable as groundwater availability varies by area and depth, so aquifers can take

multiple attempts to locate a working groundwater source, costing $400-$500 each time

(Blakeslee et al, 2020). Finally, aquifer storage is also shallow in hard rock aquifers, meaning

they can be depleted quickly if extraction exceeds recharge from monsoon rainfall (Sishodia et

al, 2016).

Chapter 5 showed that as the number of farmers installing tubewells increased in the village, it

drove up tubewell densities at the advice of tubewell firms. Farmers competed for scarce

groundwater in the shallow storage hard rock aquifers, which depleted at a faster rate than were

recharged. Well density increases in Kacharam lowered the groundwater table to such an extent

that aquifers became depleted, and the more wells farmers drilled the less water was available

for everyone. As each well failed, tubewell firms pushed farmers to drill deeper and for more

wells as a solution. In the process, it made it more profitable for them if a well failed as it kept

a repeat customer coming back.

Page 208: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

208

By the time fieldwork ended in Kacharam in July 2019, only 24 wells were working out of 215

drilled overall in the village since 2000, a failure rate of 89%. This is worse than studies into

hard rock aquifers in semi-arid Telangana by Jacoby (2017), who found well failure rates of

75%. Previously, it was possible to irrigate rice in the village as the densities were lower but

now the competitive drilling for groundwater in a worsening monsoon made farmers unable to

do so. This was also coupled with laterite soils in Kacharam which had a low infiltration and

storage capacity so rather than the monsoon recharging aquifers most of the rainfall evaporated.

Looking beyond the Indian context, unsustainable groundwater extraction for water intensive

olive cash crops in semi-arid Jordan since the 1980s was supported by electricity subsidies and

government policies to expand irrigated agriculture in arid conditions. This caused widespread

well failure, pushing extraction rates to between 179% and 242% beyond safe limits (Al Naber

and Molle, 2017).

Tubewell adoption maximised sales for private firms but increased well failures and left

farmers unable to grow both rice and Bt cotton. Moreover, Chapter 5 showed depletion was

distributed across class, caste and gender of the household heads, meaning that richer farmers

could afford to drill more wells, but they were equally affected by the semi-arid climate, hard

rock aquifers and increasing tubewell densities. This finding is original and a contrast to class

and caste differentiation in outcomes found in the literature by Birkenholtz (2009) in Rajasthan,

where lower caste farmers had fewer working tubewells as they could not afford to drill more

wells.

A key consequence of Bt cotton and tubewell outcomes in Chapters 4 and 5 was that it

worsened farmer indebtedness on high interest informal credit. Informal credit was preferred

to formal credit as the collateral requirements were minimal, crucial for smallholder farmers

with landholdings of <1 ha. Furthermore, whereas banks and microcredit required loans to be

paid back in full before issuing new ones, moneylenders would issue new loans without the

principle being repaid, as long as farmers repaid the interest annually. This preference of

farmers for informal credit is also shown by Ramprasad (2019) in Telangana who reports that

corruption, delays in credit disbursal and inflexible terms prevents farmers from using formal

credit even if they have access to it. Yet, informal credit came with a high interest rate of 24%

to 36% annually in exchange for flexible credit terms.

Page 209: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

209

In an original finding, I showed in Chapters 4 and 5 that the choice of farmers to irrigate rice,

versus Bt cotton meant there was no way to get higher yields and benefit from the high market

price from Bt cotton or repay debts from crop or irrigation investments. Farmers kept

reinvesting in Bt cotton and tubewells at the advice of private firms, but using the technologies

separately worsened indebtedness for them. This contrasts with studies in Telangana by Taylor

(2013a) who found that farmers adopted tubewells for irrigated agriculture but environmental

conditions intensified harvest losses and trapped them in a cycle of debt. In Kacharam on the

other hand, the logic of leaving Bt cotton rainfed and rice irrigated left farmers worse off on

both fronts.

If a harvest resulted in losses for farmers, they had to repay the interest and extend loans for

another year or find other means to repay input loans, e.g. selling assets. However, farmers

were compelled to keep growing Bt cotton out of desperation to recoup their losses, once again

risking further harvest failure. In fact, Telangana has one of the highest indebtedness rates in

India as well as cultivation costs per acre, partly due to to Bt cotton being the highest cropped

area of all crops in the state (NSSOa, 2013; Reddy, 2014; DES India, 2018). A similar pattern

was also found with Bt cotton adoption in rainfed Burkina Faso and South Africa, where

increasing debts from poor yields amidst erratic rainfall forced farmers to sell assets or reinvest

in Bt cotton again, as it was the only crop with a high enough market price to repay debts and

household expenses (Schnurr, 2012; Gray and Dowd-Uribe, 2013; Luna, 2019).

This was relative to the Green Revolution, where governments in India issued favourable low-

cost loans and subsidies to large holder farmers in fertile areas to grow high yielding crops and

install groundwater irrigation (Subramanian, 2015). In a bad harvest, the subsidies and loans

offered would ameliorate the losses (Stone, 2019). In the Liberalised Green Revolution,

smallholder farmers invested in agricultural technologies at full market prices in a semi-arid

environment and with high-risk, high-interest informal credit, so a harvest loss or aquifer

failure was felt far more severely. This has been extensively found in the Telangana context

by Ramprasad (2017), who explains that smallholder farmers are often trapped in cycles of

debt to moneylenders and input dealers through commercial crop cultivation.

Page 210: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

210

Chapter 4 and 5 found that governments in the Liberalised Green Revolution were at once

absent in extension services for crops and irrigation, in regulating market intermediaries or

water/electricity use for groundwater, but interventionist in energy subsidies for groundwater

and expanding formal credit. The former vastly outweighed the latter in worsening smallholder

outcomes in marginal areas.

In Chapter 4, the absence of governments in inputs, irrigation or extension services left farmers

in Kacharam to rely on input and irrigation firms for buying their products and taking extension

advice. Aga (2018) notes the same conflict of interest problem in Maharashtra with the profit

maximising synergistic roles of input dealers as creditor, salesperson, and extension advisor.

This increased the revenue streams for input firms, while increasing indebtedness for farmers

as agricultural intensification continued in climatically extreme environment. These findings

contrast with proponents of interlocked markets, who argue that they are a win-win situation

for both farmers and intermediaries (Swain, 2000). In Kacharam, market intermediaries spread

technologies to unsuitable environments, so yields were never realised, and farmers were

unable to repay their investment costs (Taylor, 2013b). In addition, the availability of input

firms at all times by phone or in person relative to government extension officers made farmers

depend on intermediaries. In the nearby town of Devarakonda for example, there was only one

extension agent for the whole sub-district level, compared to 15 input dealers in the town. This

ever-present availability of Bt cotton input dealers was also evident in Warangal district in

Telangana in studies by Stone and Flachs (2018).

For tubewells, Chapter 5 showed that the absence of the government in monitoring or pricing

electricity or water use was due to the transaction and political costs of regulating tubewells.

Chapter 5 revealed that in Nalgonda district only one or two hydrogeologists were responsible

for much of the groundwater monitoring. This was confirmed by Mukherji and Shah (2005) in

Gujarat and by Pahuja et al (2010) in Andhra Pradesh. They found that hydrogeology

departments were largely understaffed, had limited jurisdiction and were confined to

measurement and scientific testing of wells, rather than to provide irrigation extension advice

directly to farmers (ibid).

Page 211: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

211

Like with Bt cotton, irrigation extension advice in Kacharam was provided by private irrigation

firms that also sold farmers their tubewells, presenting a conflict of interest. This finding is

novel, as private irrigation firms in India have not been studied in the literature yet except by

Birkenholtz (2007) and Vasavi (2020). When wells failed, farmers went to private irrigation

firms who encouraged them to deepen their wells or drill new ones. They received the fixed

cost of the well from the farmer whether the well worked or not. The understanding that

groundwater could be found by drilling deeper also went against the hydrogeological science

of hard rock aquifers which showed that water in aquifers was only found in localised fractures

in the rock of up to 15-80m depths (CGWB Telangana, 2017).

The advice to deepen wells to strike water therefore only increased drilling costs and debts and

did not yield water. Chapter 5 showed that the key lubricant of this chaotic system was the flow

of credit enabled by local moneylenders, who benefited from a parasitic relationship with

farmers of extracting interest. In the context of smallholder coffee farming in Colombia,

Vasquez (2020) demonstrates in a similar manner how agricultural commercialisation failures

have kept farmers in debt relations with creditors. Despite frequent Bt cotton low yields and

aquifer depletion, farmers could keep loading up the debt to cover their expenditure, keeping

afloat year on year by paying the interest on their loans to moneylenders, but in an unviable

position where they cannot afford to repay.

While the government was absent in regulation or monitoring of tubewells, it was at the same

time ever present in electricity subsidies. In 2014, 92% of the 2m tubewells in Telangana were

powered by electricity (MoWR, 2017), supported by electricity subsidies. For groundwater

users in Kacharam, this had the effect of placing a zero-marginal cost of pumping groundwater

in a water stressed environment, as farmers maximised water extraction for their crops

whenever water was available, driving up well densities, depletion and indebtedness, making

farmers rely on non-farm incomes to make ends meet like in findings in Karnataka by Blakeslee

et al (2020).

Page 212: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

212

Environmental, credit/debt relations, market intermediaries and governments left smallholders

in semi-arid Kacharam with stagnating incomes, and high debts from lost Bt cotton and

tubewell investments. Chapter 6 found therefore that farmers in Kacharam stopped relying on

farming as their primary income and pursued non-farm livelihoods as a distress led response

to unrealised incomes from commercialisation. Rather than the agricultural modernisation

theory of agricultural intensification driving structural transformation of the economy towards

industrialisation (Da Corta and Venkateshwarlu, 1999), the thesis revealed that the transition

from farm to the non-farm was sought out of crisis from agriculture.

Chapter 6 showed that non-farm incomes make up 39-70% of household incomes in Kacharam,

the most important source of income. This echoed trends at an India level as Chand et al (2017)

found that up to 65% of household incomes for farming households came outside of agriculture,

as agriculture is no longer remunerative. In Telangana, this is shown by the fact that agriculture

in Telangana is the primary employer at 55% of the workforce, but the gross value added

(GVA) contribution is less than 13% in 2020 (DES Telangana, 2020). However, the thesis

refutes agrarian political economy scholars who argue that subsistence farmers are the primary

class of farmers exiting agriculture under economic liberalisation (McMichael, 2009; Li, 2009).

Instead, I argue that many smallholder farmers who entered agricultural commercialisation in

semi-arid India are leaving agriculture because of the financial insecurity from commercial

farming.

Seeking a solution in the non-farm sector, Chapter 6 showed that elder generations of farming

households indebted themselves by investing in their children’s education for a salaried job

and not face the difficulties in the Liberalised Green Revolution that they faced. Reflecting

this, almost 53% of youth in Kacharam aged 15-29 were educated to at least a 10th grade

education, in comparison to only 5% in their parents’ generation. Chapter 6 showed both older

and younger generations aspired towards non-farm livelihoods, with parents actively

preventing their children from farming to focus on their education. This was also because they

knew their children could never cope with the economic risks or skills needed for commodity

farming (Jakimow, 2016).

Page 213: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

213

However, in an original finding, Chapter 6 found in Kacharam that not only were agricultural

livelihoods insufficient, but non-farm incomes too. In agreement with Agarwal and Agrawal

(2017), Chapter 6 showed that non-farm opportunities in Kacharam was a distress led choice

by farmers out of limited options, despite non-farm work being low paid. Farmers earned $3-7

per day from work such as agricultural and construction labour. This finding is in line with

authors such as Rahman and Mishra (2019) who argue that much of India’s growth post-

liberalisation, non-farm growth has been immiserating. However, Chapter 6 claimed that even

the younger generation worked in menial work, such as autorickshaw drivers, input shop

assistants and car drivers. These jobs paid more than their parents, but were regarded as

undesirable by the younger generation, so rural youth often were unemployed or dropped out

of the labour market altogether. In Kacharam, over 50% of degree graduates were unemployed,

much greater than the Indian rural youth unemployment level of 17% in 2018 (Mehrotra and

Parida, 2019).

Chapter 6 showed that neither farm nor non-farm incomes were enough to meet farmers’ debt

and interest repayments from agriculture or household expenditure from medical expenses and

education. Annual interest repayments from Bt cotton and tubewell debts alone were $660 on

average, 31% of the entire annual household income for farmers in 2018 of ~$2100. Overall,

in the survey year 2018, household expenditures and interest repayments on debt from all

sources were $3415, compared to incomes of ~$2100, so households in Kacharam made a loss

of $1,337 in 2018. This is matched by state level figures in Telangana where 89% of farming

households are indebted, the second worst in India, and where debts have increased by 13x in

real terms between 2002 and 2013 for rural households (Reddy, 2014).

To deal with indebtedness problems, Chapter 6 revealed that farmers engaged in a number of

distress inducing activities to repay informal moneylenders, what I called “risk indebtedness

treadmills”. Farmers prioritised clearing their interest repayment to moneylenders annually as

the minimum for moneylenders to renew their loans for another year. Renewing loans meant

they could meet household expenditure in case of further harvest losses. For the moneylender,

they preferred for farmers to be in debt and interest repayments flowing rather than have them

default on loans or seize assets. This is something also found in work by Gerber (2013) with

palm oil cultivation in Indonesia. In Chapter 6, I expand on this parasitic relationship between

debt and interest to show a “risk indebtedness treadmill”, where farmers took drastic steps year

to year to just to meet the minimum interest repayment, without even touching their principal

amounts.

Page 214: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

214

Farmers for example took microcredit loans to repay interest for larger moneylender loans.

This paid off their short-term interest repayment but increased the overall debt burden. Distress

inducing debt strategies like these have also been found in work by Ramprasad (2019) in

Telangana. Additional strategies found in Chapter 6 included doubling down on Bt cotton

investments, with farmers having few other options to earn quick cash. This is also evident in

Gray and Dowd-Uribe’s (2013) work in Burkina Faso, of farmers in semi-arid areas doubling

down on Bt cotton in the face of indebtedness. Even though Bt cotton showed persistent

problems, a mixture of moneylenders keeping farmers afloat by renewing loans for further

input investments and the desperation for farmers to try their luck kept farmers coming back to

Bt cotton for the elusive golden harvest that would one day repay all debts and expenses. This

preponderance of farmers to keep taking risks despite fleeting rewards has also been evidenced

in Andhra Pradesh and Telangana in work by Maertens et al (2014).

The last option for farmers in Kacharam was to sell part of their land. Land was their biggest

asset, holding deep cultural and economic value for farmers despite their fortunes from

agriculture (Harriss and Jeyaranjan, 2014). In rural Telangana, land made up 71.3% of total

assets (NSSO, 2013d, e). Therefore, in medical emergencies or marriage, farmers sold parts of

their land to meet these expenses. This on the one hand brought cash but also reduced their

future landholding size, eroding their most valuable asset and collateral for future loans, as well

as Bt cotton incomes from smaller landholdings. The desperate strategies farmers engaged in

to survive represented the fallout of the Liberalised Green Revolution in the long term, added

on top of non-farm marginality, leaving dual problems for households in Kacharam to deal

with.

Page 215: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

215

7.4 Limitations

Despite the thesis making original contributions to the literature, the research was limited in a

few ways. First, the thesis focused on one village, Kacharam, and on one year of recall data in

2018. Hence, the experiences of Bt cotton, tubewell irrigation and non-farm livelihoods could

have been temporally or spatially specific to Kacharam. However, I remedied the limitation by

conducting interviews with farmers comparing farming outcomes from when they first adopted

Bt cotton, as well as five year and one year recall years in comparison to the survey year 2018.

In addition, the thesis found corroborating evidence in similar agroecological and

hydrogeological village settings in Telangana as well as other parts of India and other

developing countries within the Liberalised Green Revolution. This confirmed the findings

beyond the village setting in India.

Second, the thesis did not interview government agricultural extension officers, moneylenders,

or hydrogeologists in the fieldwork. In the case of the government officials, it was emblematic

of the absence of the government in agriculture in the Liberalised Green Revolution, as there

was just one extension officer and two hydrogeologists for the whole sub district block and

Nalgonda district, respectively. I was unable to meet or contact them by phone, compared to

input dealers who were widely available and willing to be interviewed. In the case of

moneylenders, informal lending was often done off the books, so moneylenders were not

willing to be recorded or interviewed in person. Instead, I gained extensive information from

farmers themselves of how the informal credit system worked.

Regarding youth unemployment and non-farm aspirations, I primarily interviewed household

heads and not explicitly the younger villagers. Although I gained many insights into what older

generations of farmers thought of their children’s future livelihoods and the challenges facing

them, getting insights from the younger generations themselves was missing. However,

numerous informal discussions with my research assistants, both degree graduates, and other

youth in the village during the fieldwork, provided many perspectives on agriculture and their

non-farm prospects. Moreover, younger generations of the households sat in during many

interviews and household surveys I conducted and added to the insights of their parents when

we discussed the intergenerational shifts in livelihoods outside of agriculture. These informal

discussions were recorded in notes, as part of my daily reflections from fieldwork and in audio

recordings if they sat in on interviews. Therefore, while they were not quoted in the thesis, they

did substantially inform the writing and the arguments made.

Page 216: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

216

7.5 Conclusion

This chapter has situated the findings of the thesis within the broader theory and empirical

context of the literature on agricultural modernisation and smallholder outcomes in marginal

areas. Engaging with the Liberalised Green Revolution theoretical framework in Chapter 2, the

thesis found that the agricultural commercialisation with Bt cotton and tubewells was unviable

in the long term, as shown by Chapters 4, 5 and 6. The thesis findings agreed about the private

sector increasing adoption and lowering technology prices. Yet, agricultural liberalisation

failed to improve farmer incomes over the long term or spark a productivity led structural

change in the economy in rural India.

The thesis found that four key theoretically and empirically interrelated factors in adverse

environmental conditions, intermediaries, market facilitating governments and high interest

and risk credit/debt relations combined to cause negative Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation

intensification. This agreed with political ecology and agrarian political economy scholars who

argued that the social and economic context in which agricultural technologies were adopted

were as important as the technologies themselves. The Liberalised Green Revolution in

Kacharam over the long-term increased indebtedness via Bt cotton and tubewell technologies,

forcing sales of assets in risk indebtedness treadmills and deagrarianisation. This discussion

chapter therefore showed that the theoretical and empirical findings from the thesis on the

Liberalised Green Revolution contested, expanded upon, and filled gaps in the literature. The

concluding chapter of the thesis, Chapter 8, will explore the implications of the thesis for

policy, research and political economy in India.

Page 217: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

217

Chapter 8 – Conclusion

8.1 Introduction

This conclusion chapter is broken into four sections. First, the chapter provides a brief summary

of the thesis. Furthermore, I compare and contrast the thesis findings with similar longitudinal

village studies carried out elsewhere in India to situate the research in Kacharam within broader

smallholder rainfed settings. I also postulate some tentative applications of the research beyond

India. Next, I discuss the policy implications of the thesis’ findings pertinent to the state of

Telangana and India more widely. Following this, I lay out the political economy implications

of the findings within the Telangana and Indian context. Finally, I provide policy

recommendations and highlight what work can be done in other parts of India and beyond to

extend and confirm the research findings from Kacharam for further research.

8.2 Thesis summary

The thesis found that Bt cotton and tubewell irrigation failed to increase incomes in a sustained

manner in the long term in Kacharam and Telangana in a semi-arid and hard rock aquifer

environment, leading to rising indebtedness, diminishing returns from agriculture and the

transition to non-farm livelihoods to survive. Although seeing initial gains, the input and capital

intensive Bt cotton was grown in rainfed conditions that witnessed more erratic and declining

monsoons over time, causing frequent harvest failures and increasing indebtedness for farmers

in the long run across castes, classes and genders. Similarly, the capital intensive tubewell was

adopted in unsuitable hard rock aquifer settings. Initial gains from rice cultivation came in the

first few years but increasing tubewell densities in the villages exacerbated groundwater

decline in the village, causing frequent tubewell failures in the long run. The failure of the

Liberalised Green Revolution forced farmers to seek non-farm livelihoods to survive.

However, the thesis found that structural problems in the labour market in India meant non-

farm livelihood opportunities were low paid and insecure, insufficient to meet debt obligations

and household expenses. This forced farmers into “risk indebtedness treadmills”, where they

engaged in short term cash strategies to sustain debt repayments and renew loans to finance

household expenses. This included doubling down on Bt cotton, selling land or stacking loans

from microcredit and bank loans to repay informal creditors.

Page 218: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

218

The thesis found that market intermediaries were key in promoting Bt cotton to marginal areas,

providing credit, inputs, seeds and extension to farmers, financing inputs and seeds on credit

in interlocked factor markets and buying the harvest from farmers. In an unregulated Bt cotton

market however, they failed to advise farmers to irrigate Bt cotton, posing different seeds and

input solutions instead when farmers faced harvest losses, seeking to maximise input sales and

keep farmers within debt relations. Similarly, with tubewells, irrigation firms failed to advise

farmers to irrigate cotton, leaving farmers to imitate early adopters in the village and grow rice,

a household crop. This left Bt cotton, the main cash crop to be prone to erratic rainfall, bringing

reduced yields or harvest failures, while investments for tubewells were left unpaid by growing

household food crops. Debts from both technologies increased with repeated technology

failures, forcing farmers to seek cash from non-farm livelihoods to make up for losses.

Finally, the government was absent in regulating Bt cotton markets, facilitating market activity

from intermediaries. In tubewells, the Telangana government promoted tubewells for growing

rice in the village as part of their development vision to be the rice bowl of India via energy

subsidies. They were absent in irrigation extension advice however, leaving irrigation firms to

advise farmers to repeatedly drill in the face of well failures to maximise their own sales. The

thesis found that the social and economic context within which agricultural technology

adoption took place was a crucial factor in determining the success of the Liberalised Green

Revolution in Telangana. The mutually intersecting factors of agroecological conditions,

credit/debt relations and the roles of market intermediaries and governments, failed to increase

yields and incomes of smallholder farmer adopters in the long term in marginal settings, leading

to technology failure and unintentional adverse deagrarianisation, thereby critiquing the

assumption of market integration increasing agricultural growth and skilled non-farm

transitions.

Page 219: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

219

8.3 Comparing and contrasting the thesis findings within India and beyond

To compare and contrast the outcomes from Kacharam, I drew upon work by the Foundation

of Agrarian Studies (FAS), who have been conducting longitudinal village surveys on agrarian

change across numerous agroecological regions in India since 2005 as part of their “Project on

Agrarian Relations in India” (FAS, 2021). This allows comparisons of Bt cotton cultivating

villages with Kacharam across time and geography in India to see for differentiation in

outcomes, given Kacharam’s negative Bt cotton outcomes across classes, castes and gender

across a number of measures.

In initial years in two villages Kanzara and Warwat Khanderao in Vidharba region in

Maharashtra, Swaminathan and Rawal (2011) found Bt cotton net incomes to be 97% higher

than local cotton varieties at roughly $425 per hectare in 2007, despite the higher input costs.

However, only 10% of the total gross cropped area was monocropped by Bt cotton, that too

dominated by larger landholders who could afford the cultivation costs. For most smallholder

farmers in the villages, they found that intercropped Bt cotton in rainfed conditions had similar

returns to improved varieties of non-Bt cotton technologies, hence the economics in the long

run were not clear cut. In comparison to Kacharam, there was a clear class differentiation with

who grew Bt cotton as a monocrop, as in Vidharba it was dominated by large landholders, with

smallholder farmers intercropping Bt cotton with food crops to diversify their spatial and

temporal risk of drought. This indicates Kacharam’s farmers willingness to take the risk to

grow Bt cotton as a monocrop, but this has turned adverse without the returns in recent years.

Moreover, the initial gains from Bt cotton in this study also match Kacharam’s experience of

farmers enjoying much higher net incomes that incumbent crop choices.

In line with findings from Kacharam, Ramkumar and Raut (2011), also showed that 143 labour

days were required for Bt cotton per year, disaggregated into 105 for females and 38 for males.

Relative to non-Bt cotton, Bt cotton required more labour intensive tasks to harvest it, which

was centred on gendered labour. Women worked more on Bt cotton due to higher yields relative

to non-Bt cotton, so required more days of picking and hand weeding in the harvest season.

Men mostly engaged in ploughing, oxen weeding, spraying seeds, pesticides and

transportation, but each of these tasks are short in duration and are only required 1-2 times per

season.

Page 220: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

220

However, these FAS papers were released in 2011 so did not cover the longitudinal time frame

that I investigated in my thesis. In later work though, they revealed stagnation or abandonment

of Bt cotton for other crops due to the tailing off net incomes from the crop relative to rising

input costs.

In Buldhana, a rainfed, smallholder, Bt cotton growing district in Maharashtra, Swaminathan

and Baksi (2017) found that 76% of smallholder farmers intercropped Bt cotton with sorghum

and millets. This was to ensure both cash crop cultivation and food security. In comparison,

only 55% of large farmers in Buldhana intercropped with food crops, and in other regions of

Maharashtra, Bt cotton was grown as a monocrop, but only by larger farmers (Swaminathan

and Rawal, 2011; ibid). In the overall sample by FAS however, Bt cotton was the only rainfed

cash crop grown in their study. Relative to Kacharam therefore, we see important continuities

and divergences. The phenomenon of growing Bt cotton in rainfed conditions seems to hold

across other states in India outside of Telangana, which carries with it the risk of drought and

harvest failure shown in the thesis in Kacharam. However, in research by FAS in Maharashtra

at least, the practise of intercropping by smallholder farmers diversifies risk and food security

better than in Kacharam, with only larger farmers willing to grow Bt cotton as a cash crop

given their better collateral and risk absorption capacity.

In another study by Ramakumar et al (2017), they conducted longitudinal village studies

between 2006-2014 in two districts in the Vidharba region in Maharashtra. In one village in

Dongargaon, they found that Bt cotton yields increased rapidly from 195kg/ha to 356kg/ha

between 2001-2014, matching the increases in Kacharam and Telangana. This led to a

declining cropping area for sorghum, as Bt cotton covered 41% of the village in 2007, chosen

for its high productivity and market prices. However, by 2014, Bt cropping area declined to

6%, replaced by soybean and pigeon pea. In another village Savali, Bt cotton was replaced by

maize and soybean. The biggest reason for the abandonment of Bt cotton were the rising

cultivation prices in inputs and labour, relative to the market price and high credit repayment

costs from informal creditors (ibid).

Like in Kacharam, frequent yield shocks created economic losses and risks for farmers they

could not bear given the unremunerative market prices. Pesticide, seed, fertiliser and labour

costs per acre all increased from 2006 to 2014 faster than the market price, in an environment

of inadequate rainfall in the region. Finally, farmers chose maize and soybean for their shorter

3-month crop cycles and ability to intercrop with household food crops unlike Bt cotton which

Page 221: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

221

could only be cropped with pigeon pea due to its longer growing season. Whereas farmers in

Kacharam persisted with Bt cotton despite similar problems exhibited as in Maharashtra,

Ramakumar et al (2017) found that farmers quickly switched to an intercropped system of

growing short season maize and soybean for cash with food crops such as sorghum and pigeon

pea. The reasons for leaving Bt cotton were similar to Kacharam, in the high cultivation costs

relative to returns in the long run, under an environment of erratic rainfall and high credit costs.

This confirms the problems faced by farmers in Kacharam in this thesis.

The theoretical and empirical findings from the thesis also have tentative implications for wider

settings beyond India. With Bt cotton, the long-term indebtedness, declining yields, and

adverse outcomes from adoption as shown in India have also been evident in some similar

smallholder semi-arid contexts in South Africa and Burkina Faso. Political ecologists have

demonstrated the rapid adoption and abandonment of Bt cotton in Burkina Faso from 2008-16,

where rising debts, low yields in rainfed settings caused farmers to stop growing Bt cotton, as

well as a countrywide ban (Dowd-Uribe and Schnurr, 2016). Similarly, Schnurr (2012) finds

in South Africa that Bt cotton saw initial yield increases in semi-arid smallholder settings since

its inception in the early 2000s, but by 2011, low yields and rising indebtedness caused farmers

to abandon the crop. Nonetheless, GM crops continue to be presented as a food security and

agricultural modernisation solution for the African continent as part of an “African Green

Revolution”, (Moseley et al, 2017; Schnurr, 2019) spreading to a further four countries since

South Africa and Burkina Faso, with Mozambique and Kenya at late stages of GM cassava and

maize approvals (ISAAA, 2019). Overall, GM crops are already being planted across 24

developing countries, with pending regulatory approvals pushing the figure closer to 70 (ibid).

Furthermore, Sub-Saharan Africa is also being targeted as the new untapped rainfed

smallholder area to expand groundwater intensification, with 40% of the continent classified

as dryland and rainfall volatility common across the continent (Cobbing and Hillier, 2019).

World groundwater consumption for agriculture has tripled since the 1960s, contributing to

43% of irrigation consumption (Siebert et al, 2010; Wada et al, 2012). Given the sheer size and

scale of marginal farming areas globally, where 1.5 billion people live and covering 40% of

the global land area, the prospect of agricultural intensification by policymakers in these areas

has been regarded as tantamount to a blank canvas to transform, especially with drought

resistant GM crop strains and expanding irrigation (Sharma et al, 2014; Lall et al, 2020).

Page 222: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

222

Like with India however, the cycle of environmental decline, rising indebtedness, failure of

technology adoption and potential distress induced non-farm transitions risks repeating itself,

as the model of agricultural intensification in the 21st century continues to ignore the fragility

of resource base and the affordability of such crops for environments. With climate change set

to worsen droughts, floods and rainfall variability in marginal agrarian settings globally (Li et

al, 2020), this presents a risky scenario for farmers to become integrated into markets and take

on similar economic and environmental risks as Bt cotton and tubewell adopting farmers did

in India. For instance, scholars such as Natarajan et al (2019) have proposed a “climate

precarity approach” using the example of Cambodia to describe the mutual effects of increasing

climate risks and rising debts from agricultural technology adoption failures that drive farmers

into debt bondage in non-farm livelihoods to recoup losses.

8.4 Policy implications for Telangana and India

Despite the plethora of environmental and economic risks that have evidently trapped certain

smallholders within adverse agricultural commercialisation in Telangana, the ideological

fixation with private sector technologies such as Bt cotton for economic growth persists. Policy

makers at the Telangana and India level continue to push Bt cotton as a flagship technology to

replicate with other crops. The Telangana Chief Minister KC Rao for example in 2020 began

plans to link welfare eligibility for cash transfers with the increased acreage of Bt cotton in the

state, as part of a new “Regulated Crop Policy” (New Indian Express, 2020a: p1), stating in an

article:

“Chief Minister K Chandrasekhar Rao on Thursday said those farmers who cultivate

crop as per the direction of the Telangana government would get the full Ryuthu

Bandhu [cash transfer scheme]. The Chief Minister said the intention of the government

is for farmers to cultivate crops which are in demand and get attractive prices for their

yield. “The farmers will not face losses if they grow crops as per the suggestions given

by the state government” he said. Rao said that [Bt] cotton should be cultivated in

[2.8m] hectares in both [monsoon] and [dry] seasons together, [up from 2.1m hectares

currently].”

The emphasis on Bt cotton and GM crops more widely has also been part of the agricultural

policy agenda of the Indian government. This is shown by their premier thinktank, the NITI

Ayog, celebrating Bt cotton’s purported success and stressing the need for further GM crop

approvals to ensure economic growth (NITI Ayog, 2015).

Page 223: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

223

This is evident for example in the flagship agricultural policy programme of the current BJP

government from 2018, titled “Doubling Farmers Income”. This aims to increase the real

annual incomes of farmers from $1,555 in 2016 to $3,100 in 2023 (Gulati et al, 2020). The

primary vehicle used by the government to achieve this is to deregulate agricultural markets

and trade, emphasise the expansion of Bt cotton and other biotechnology crops, gain

investments from FDI and increase the role of the private sector in agricultural output markets

(Chand, 2019).

With regards to irrigation, despite the risks presented by groundwater intensification in semi-

arid and hard rock areas, policy continuities persist at the Telangana level and beyond to

promote the cultivation of unviable water intensive crops such as dry season rice via tubewells.

For instance, Telangana became the biggest dry season rice grower in India in 2020 at 10m

tonnes (News Minute, 2020), largely due to the expansion of their 24x7 free electricity scheme

for groundwater. This is even though rice cultivation alone accounts for 50% of total

groundwater withdrawal in India per year, let alone other water intensive cash crops such as

sugarcane (Anupoju and Kambhammetu, 2020).

This perverse policy serves as both a development vision for the Chief Minister KC Rao to

demonstrate Telangana’s technological superiority and as a political vote winner amongst the

tubewell farmer base. The budget for electricity subsidies has doubled from $541m in 2018-19

to $1bn in 2020-21 for Telangana (Telangana Today, 2020), due to the burgeoning demand

from the 2.3m tubewells which are only set to increase in the future, reinforcing the nexus of

electricity subsidies at the cost of long term economic and aquifer sustainability. Although

recent efforts have been made in Telangana to increase canal irrigation coverage and restore

reservoirs and tank irrigation for conjunctive use with tubewells, these are undermined by the

fact that electricity policy continues in the state (Verma and Shah, 2019; Tribune India, 2020).

At the India level too, electricity subsidies have more than tripled from $3.5bn in 2000 to

$10.5bn in 2020 (OECD, 2018), indicating the political saliency to introduce these schemes in

several states in India beyond Telangana. Furthermore, in the 9 most heavily subsidised

tubewell states in India where electricity costs are <$5 per MWh, aquifer overexploitation and

density of deep tubewells per square km is the highest in India, including in Telangana (Rajan

et al, 2020). At this rate of groundwater depletion and tubewell expansion aided by subsidies,

India is currently predicted to permanently dry out 60% of current aquifer capacity by 2025

(ibid). This is not to mention the effects of climate change, which are set to reduce monsoon

Page 224: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

224

recharge of aquifers through increasingly erratic distribution and quantity of rainfall (Ferrant

et al, 2014).

For both Bt cotton and tubewells therefore the doubling down of technology adoption in

Telangana and India seems to continue as a dominant policy strategy. This reflects the

enmeshing of political and market ideals in the Liberalised Green Revolution no matter the

costs. Political and ideological ends by state and central governments supersede the mounting

micro-level longitudinal evidence of the long term adverse effects of decontextualized

agricultural commercialisation in dryland areas in India as shown in this thesis (Vasavi, 2019).

8.5 Political economy implications for Telangana and India

The outcomes from the Liberalised Green Revolution have unfortunately not had much of a

bearing with regards to the political economy of agriculture nor political responses by farmers

in Telangana. The nationwide farmer protests in India since 2020 have come in reply to the

passing of laws in relation to eventual abolishment of government regulated markets for

agricultural harvests, which purportedly give farmers the chance to sell their crops to private

market players such as corporations (Deccan Chronicle, 2020). The policy trajectory suggests

a further epoch of agricultural liberalisation in India, potentially ending current policies for

crops such as the minimum support price for rice and wheat (Himanshu, 2020). Unfortunately,

with regards to Kacharam, Bt cotton is a crop where markets have already been liberalised

since their introduction in 2002.

As shown in Chapters 2 and 4, Bt cotton is largely controlled by the private sector, with inputs,

credit, extension advice and output markets the remit of market intermediaries, outside of

government regulation and subsidies. This system in Kacharam as evidently shown in the thesis

has not borne fruitful results over the long term for smallholder farmers in dryland areas. Hence

the ongoing protests in India have little to do with the predicament facing farmers growing Bt

cotton. If anything, the experiments with a fully liberalised Bt cotton market in Kacharam

serves as a cautionary tale of the power relations that will accrue with the private sector

intermediaries at the local level if liberalisation reforms proceed in other parts of India and

other crops.

Page 225: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

225

Despite the prevailing trends of commercialisation in agriculture however, there are

alternatives emerging to the incumbent model of farming. Policy and practise on alternatives

to industrial farming in dryland areas has coalesced around the system of “sustainable

intensification”, which involve increase yields while also improving socio-ecological

conditions of the environment. These cover a broad spectrum of activities, including:

“crop varietal improvements, new rotations, water conservation, the system of crop

intensification (SCI), integrated pest management (IPM), agroforestry, conservation

agriculture (CA), crop diversification (e.g. rotations, intercropping, water harvesting)

and the intensification of small patches” (Bharucha et al, 2020: p3-4).

An evaluation of sustainable intensification across 20 countries has already suggested

improvements in crop yields, but limitations remain in making the system remunerative for the

cash needs for dryland smallholders (ibid). In India, early evidence of a major long-term vision

transition plan from commercial farming to more agroecologically suitable farming is found in

the Zero Budget Natural Farming (ZBNF) movement, pioneered by a farmer, Subash Palekar

in Maharashtra in the 2000s (Koner and Laha, 2020). Supported in speeches by the Finance

Minister Nirmala Sitharaman and Prime Minister Narendra Modi (Bharucha et al, 2020), ZBNF

at least in terms of discourse has been gaining traction in India in recent years. The key goal

behind this method of farming is to limit reliance on external chemical fertilisers, pesticides

and seeds through organic and naturally occurring plant and animal sources such as animal

manure, urine, anti-bacterial tree and plant species. It is composed of four steps, each geared

to reduce input costs and maintain productivity of crops:

1) increase the soil productivity by increasing microbial activity and organic matter

2) treat seedlings for protection against bacterial and fungal disease

3) mulching to increase organic matter and nutrients in soil

4) aerate soil for air and water (Gupta et al, 2020)

The emphasis of ZBNF is to implement farming practices to diversify risk by intercropping,

reduce input costs and improve soil fertility. ZBNF practices have benefited many farmers in

India since the 2000s, with the neighbouring state of Andhra Pradesh in 2018, the first in India

to implement ZBNF methods at a statewide level. The plan was to target 6m farmers and 8m

hectares with ZBNF farming by 2024 under their agricultural policy “Climate Resilient Zero

Budget Natural Farming” (Koner and Laha, 2020). The programme has been supported by the

UNEP, World Bank, and international NGOs to help farmers with regards to financing,

Page 226: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

226

extension advice and logistical support, including a $14m donation by the Azim Premji

Foundation (Bharucha et al, 2020). By 2019, 13% or 204,000 ha had been converted to ZBNF

methods, planted by 523,000 farmers in 3015 villages (Smith et al, 2020).

In a study surveying the ZBNF cropping system in Andhra Pradesh, Bharucha et al (2020)

reveal that net incomes for rainfed cotton were INR 50,000 per ha for ZBNF compared to INR

30,000 per ha for non-ZBNF. Across rice, maize, cotton groundnut and millets in both rainfed

and irrigated conditions, they found that overall, yields increased by 17%, cost of cultivation

decreased by 23% and net incomes increased by 50% in ZBNF settings relative to non-ZBNF

(ibid). The main benefit has been the reduced cost of chemical fertiliser and pesticides in the

ZBNF programme, which reduced cultivation costs, positively affecting net incomes even if

yields were not much higher than in industrial farming. Finally, in their survey of ZBNF

farmers in Andhra Pradesh, Gupta et al (2020) note that ZBNF initiatives have been taken up

by farmers with on average higher education, with only 20% of the ZBNF cohort having no

education compared to 42% for the non-ZBNF group. They also found that the ZBNF cohort

were younger on average, better represented by women and lower castes than non-ZBNF, plus

58% of them already relied on non-farm income sources, compared to 49% for non-ZBNF

(ibid).

For Kacharam, this suggests a promising set of results for crops such as Bt cotton and millets,

with gains being evident in both rainfed environments as well as irrigated scenarios. Key to its

success in Andhra Pradesh however is the institutional infrastructure created by the Andhra

Pradesh government in setting up training programmes, NGO partnerships and self-help groups

and centralised funding by the state government (Veluguri et al, 2021). These have had a long

legacy in Andhra Pradesh in previous sustainable agricultural programmes in the state since

2004 in their Community Managed Sustainable Agriculture scheme (Ramanjaneyulu and Rao,

2008), which was designated within the Department of Rural Development. Building on these

arrangements therefore has been key to scaling up of ZBNF in Andhra Pradesh, so presents a

unique blueprint for success in this particular context, which may not be replicable in

Telangana (ibid).

Page 227: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

227

Similarly, in initial studies in rice cultivation in Purulia village in West Bengal in 2020, Koner

and Laha (2020) found that ZBNF farmers saw decreased yields per hectare of 20% relative to

intensive farmers in the control sample, but income per hectare increased by $21, due to the

savings in input costs. This region of Bengal featured shallow soil capacity, low rainfall and

low water retention of the soil. However, the authors did note that ZBNF was sponsored by the

government through natural pesticides and fertiliser supplies, hence inputs were subsidised

only after support from governments versus purchasing chemical inputs on credit in input

markets. This protected farmers from input costs, price fluctuation and indebtedness by being

subsidised by the government (ibid). This brings into question the financial sustainability of

this scheme in Kacharam given the lack of government policy to support farmers this way, as

the market for Bt cotton is entirely reliant on the private sector, and the Telangana government

has encouraged intensive cultivation through markets in recent years (DES Telangana, 2020),

but indicates that an alternative vision is possible in agriculture with the right political support.

8.6 Policy recommendations

A number of policy recommendations can be drawn out from the thesis. The critical finding

was the consideration of agroecological and hydrogeological factors for optimal cropping

patterns. The thesis showed that Bt cotton grown in rainfed conditions in is too risky and prone

to harvest failure, especially when considering Bt cotton is such an input and capital-intensive

crop. Farmers however, chose a rainfed crop such as Bt cotton for its relative market price

compared to other rainfed crops. The thesis therefore recommends policy makers to incentivise

farmers to switch away from Bt cotton. This can be to rainfed crops that can improve household

food security, as well as diversifying cropping patterns of rainfed crops suitable to the climate

and soils of Telangana. Scientists at ICRISAT for example have developed improved peanut,

chickpea and millet varieties that are drought and pest resistant (Kumar et al, 2014). These can

be important not only for household food security but fodder too for livestock.

Efforts in recent years by NGOs and policymakers have attempted to reintegrate drought

resistant food crop varieties such as millets into smallholder semi-arid and rainfed Indian farms.

Millets were traditionally grown as a food crop in rainfed areas for their low input costs and

drought resistant properties, forming an important source of food security for subsistence

households (Louis, 2015). Increasingly in previous decades however, as economic demands on

households have increased, millet cultivation in rainfed areas has declined in favour of cash

crops such as Bt cotton to meet expenses, as seen in Chapter 4 in Kacharam and in FAS’s work

Page 228: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

228

in Maharashtra (Swaminathan and Baksi, 2017). In Telangana for instance, it dropped from

60% of the gross cropped area in the 1960s to 2% in 2017 (Reddy et al, 2017). In their research

in drought prone Ananthapur district in Andhra Pradesh, Fischer et al (2016) found that millets

were seen as culturally inferior foods and crops relative to rice, due to their low market prices,

taste, labour intensive processing and cultural association with historical poverty and low

status. However, they also found that extension support from NGOs on the nutritional

properties of millets, their use as fodder and short growing season incentivised farmers to

intercrop millets with groundnut, their cash crop, as millets was a fallback crop in drought

years. The supply of fodder also made farmers more likely to rely on livestock as a source of

income on the farm for milk, rather than as a further investment to make.

Fischer et al (2016) also report how recent resurgence of millets in urban India as a “superfood”

presents a new market niche to target in supermarkets in major cities in India such as Mumbai,

Hyderabad and Bangalore (ibid). Farmers can take advantage of the rising demand for healthy

eating in urban middle classes in India as a growing target market for millets. To overcome

market volatility, villages such as Kacharam can benefit from the state government setting a

minimum support price for millets in drought years and improve marketing and extension

channels to reach urban centres. By either selling them to government markets or urban food

value chains it can be a partial solution to shift away from Bt cotton. This would create an

output market for a crop suited to rainfed and semi-arid Telangana, plus give farmers an

economic incentive to plant drought resistant crops (ibid).

Furthermore, rather than the current “Regulated Crop Policy” in Telangana to increase Bt

cotton production, the Telangana government can instead link their Ryuthu Bandhu cash

transfer programme to growing agroecologically suited crops such as millets, which would not

only provide food security, fodder and diversify agro-climatic and economic risk, it would also

meet farmers need for cash for household expenses. The political trajectory within Telangana

however at present continues in the vein of promoting input intensive cash crop agriculture

however, as indicated by their plans to increase Bt cotton production and tubewell use for dry

season rice despite the environmental and economic problems shown in Kacharam.

Page 229: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

229

Perhaps the most difficult aspect is to change the incentives for input dealers as they benefit so

much from the Bt cotton market currently. One way to do this could be to scale up the extension

services and NGO support for farmers from the public sector, creating a viable alternative

source for seeds, inputs and extension support. The combination of the rainfed crop conditional

cash transfer scheme and the increase in support prices can also create the demand for input

dealers to start supplying the varieties themselves, if they sense a profit opportunity. This will

require a long-term strategy however with strong decentralised powers, skill training and

budgetary support at the district level in Telangana. This is due to the power that intermediaries

have currently and the chaotic nature of Bt cotton seed markets.

In the scenario of farmers continuing to grow Bt cotton, policy makers should consider

diversifying cropping patterns alongside Bt cotton in the dry season with rainfed food crops

mentioned above. This is instead of the current practice of growing rice in the dry season, which

is also unsuitable for the aquifer environment and climate of Telangana. Moreover, with this

shift, farmers can use precision irrigation such as drip for Bt cotton in the monsoon. This would

improve yields and allow a more stable water supply for Bt cotton than in rainfed conditions.

The culture and habit of irrigating rice however may take time to change farmer behaviour.

This would require a set of tools like increased extension supports, site visits, show farmers

and field demonstrations from NGOs and agricultural officers of drip irrigation and Bt cotton.

Using drip irrigation from groundwater can also reduce the overexploitation and demand on

the current aquifer systems. Finally, using improved varieties of cotton as Siddiqui (2020)

suggests can further increase yields and reduce water consumption. Open pollinated seed

varieties can be planted in higher densities and have a shorter growing season than Bt cotton

seeds in India currently. These open pollinated varieties are the preferred cotton strain in most

of the productive cotton producers in the world, so India can emulate the same path.

In terms of tubewell irrigation, several policy prescriptions, technological interventions and

community management have been tried at various stages of India’s groundwater history in

order to curb the worst effects of groundwater exploitation. From the technological perspective,

drip irrigation has been the most popular alternative posed. Drip irrigation is still based on

groundwater supply, but the flow is more control and precise to the roots of the crop, saving

up to 60% of water consumption per hectare (Narayanamoorthy, 2006). Recognising

groundwater irrigation’s poverty reduction role, Sishodia et al (2017) posit that introducing

drip irrigation to Andhra Pradesh’s groundwater users can cost $6bn, but will save water in the

long run, and make more efficient use of water in semi-arid and hard rock constrained

Page 230: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

230

environments. Subsidies and conditional cash transfers can encourage farmer adoption of drip

irrigation.

However, criticisms of drip irrigation point out that stacking another technological fix onto

farmers is meaningless without changing the cropping patterns or behaviour of resource users.

Fieldwork in Morocco by Molle and Tanouti (2017) found that drip irrigation caused farmers

to expand irrigated area and changing to more water intensive crops, leading to higher water

use than before. The perception of water saving was outweighed by the increase in irrigated

area and cropping patterns, increasing the overall use. Other scholars point out that drip

irrigation obfuscates the social relations of its use and practical distributional issues such as

affordability and access (Venot et al, 2014). Therefore, drip irrigation if not implemented

properly falls into the same trap as tubewells, a technological fix to a decontextualised setting.

Another localised policy measure has been to introduce community management schemes for

groundwater, consisting of either sharing and pooling of wells for group use, informational and

awareness campaigns and game theory for groundwater governance. One such example in

Andhra Pradesh was the Andhra Pradesh Farmer Groundwater Management Scheme led by the

World Bank in the 2000s (Taylor, 2013). This was an NGO led, community driven approach

advocated for pooling groundwater resources, educated farmers on groundwater depletion and

trained them to monitor groundwater levels, with the end goal for farmers to self-regulate on a

voluntary basis through choosing less water intensive crops (ibid).

Collective management of groundwater at a village level is a step in the right direction, but can

only work in given settings. For example, Taylor (2013) notes, community management may

work in a harmonious fashion in times of ample rainfall but in drought periods, farmer

desperation for incomes and fear of harvest losses may induce them to overexploit

groundwater. The lack of alternatives and individual self-interest of avoiding hunger is a

priority at the individual level. Moreover, he raises questions over its sustainability if NGOs

withdrew from the scheme, leaving it in hands of the village hierarchy (ibid). Asymmetric

power relations of class, caste and gender may reconfigure who has to save water and who

doesn’t in the scheme, therefore community management may only be enforced for the poorest

and those with least power, relative to the dominant power group (ibid).

Page 231: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

231

Work by Meinzen-Dick et al (2018) has tried to address this using game theory in groundwater

governance in Andhra Pradesh. Her fieldwork involved encouraging groundwater recharge by

farmers through managing their demand. Information sharing and awareness of the effect of

crop choice, rather than rainfall on groundwater development was discussed with farmers.

Experimental games where farmers learned in real time how changes in crop choice affect

water tables help improve farmer understanding at the individual and community level. For

collective decision making in reducing water use however, she noted that community cohesion,

trust, social structure and individual profit incentives of choosing alternative crops were crucial

(ibid).

Therefore, community management can work in the right settings, but the fundamental issue is

not of farmer intelligence or awareness, but their incentives. Farmers have few economically

viable alternatives to the current cropping patterns of cash crops, as subsistence and low market

price crops require time and additional sources of income to offset their problems. Farmers

make decisions in a constrained environment of opportunities and threats, highly price

conscious, and with each choice they choose prone to distress and failure due to their lack of

risk bearing capacity, especially in water stressed, semi-arid and hard rock aquifer regions

(Blakeslee et al, 2020).

Next, ways to reduce evapotranspiration and runoff of rainwater can also be beneficial for

tubewells. The Telangana government has already unveiled a scheme called Mission Kakatiya,

which aims to repair and restore 1m hectares of rainwater harvesting and reservoir tanks for

use in conjunction with groundwater by 2020 (Verma and Shah, 2019). Tanks can improve the

storage of rainwater and help raise groundwater tables. In areas like Kacharam where tanks are

not present, building such water storage mechanisms can help alleviate the tubewell failures.

Practices such as furrow irrigation, borewell recharge schemes and encouraging shared

tubewell use for farming families with neighbouring plots of land can all improve conditions

for tubewell irrigation.

The lack of information and awareness of such methods is the problem in villages like

Kacharam, and so the right mix of incentives, public policy initiatives and better practises of

groundwater management can encourage a behaviour shift to a judicious use of the existing

groundwater systems already in place in Kacharam. Finally, at the public policy level, schemes

such as the 24x7 free electricity scheme need to be reversed, which may be politically very

difficult but possible. Some evidence from Rao (2018a) in Telangana suggests that not all

Page 232: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

232

farmers think the scheme is beneficial and even necessary, so perhaps through social

movements and farmer led coalitions the political consensus could change to remove the

subsidy and reinvest it in other areas to recharge aquifers.

Finally, for non-farm livelihoods, unfortunately not many recommendations for policy can be

made easily. The structural economic and labour market problems in India will only become

exacerbated in the advent of COVID-19 (Miyamura, 2021). However, the policy suggestions

listed above to improve agricultural and irrigation outcomes can reduce the debt burden for

households in Kacharam and Telangana. In terms of non-farm livelihoods, a greater role for

local district level vocational training, apprenticeships and employment skills training for youth

can be an alternative to traditional education. This can be a mix of partnerships with local firms,

NGOs and government support. Therein, it can prevent educated rural youth from adding to

the growing pool of jobseekers in the labour market and fill demand for other livelihood options

outside the office based private or public sector jobs.

Rural educated youth can also enter farming, but do it in a completely different manner to their

parents. They can take advantage of their digital literacy and learn methods of farming from

Youtube and other online and mobile app-based platforms. These can be used for example to

change cropping patterns to high value agriculture crops such as horticulture or vegetables and

fruits. Government and NGOs can play a role in awareness training and financial start up

support for rural youth to take advantage of technologies and their education to practise farming

in an agroecologically and profitable way. This will also have positive implications for rural

households to change their cropping patterns. Ultimately however, changing the culture of rural

non-farm aspirations is a difficult task, and the demand remains strong for salaried and office-

based positions in the government or private sector. The non-farm economy will require an

overall increase in economic growth and job creation growth by investment and trade policy in

both private and public sector for the current situation in Kacharam to improve.

Page 233: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

233

8.7 Areas for future research

The thesis has provided insights into the political economy of the Liberalised Green Revolution

in Telangana. Future research, however, can take the work done in this thesis can validate and

explore it in different directions. For example, comparative ethnographic work can investigate

Bt cotton in rainfed and irrigated settings in developing countries, looking in both semi-arid

and hard rock areas as well as more favourable environments. This would provide insights into

the role that irrigation plays in outcomes for Bt cotton across the similar and different

agroecological settings, and whether initiatives such as drip irrigation can improve outcomes.

By exploring Bt cotton in different agroclimatic regions it would also give insights as to the

relative contribution of political economy factors to Bt cotton outcomes, as the different

settings would still be broadly part of the Liberalised Green Revolution and so private sector

firms would still dominate.

In a similar vein, future studies can also look at regions within India and other countries where

farmers have transitioned away from input and capital-intensive cropping patterns like Bt

cotton to more climatically suited and agroecology type cropping patterns. This way, an

ethnographic account can provide details as to the changes the transition has brought to farmers

in the long term in terms of debt, household incomes and food security. It can also show

whether it is economically and practically viable alternative for farmers in marginal settings

versus typical commodity crop cultivation in a time of rising household expenditure and

indebtedness at the household level.

Page 234: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

234

References

Aalbers, M.B., 2013. Neoliberalism is dead… long live neoliberalism!. International Journal

of Urban and Regional Research, 37(3), pp.1083-1090.

Aayog, N.I.T.I., 2015. Raising agricultural productivity and making farming remunerative for

farmers. An Occasional Paper National Institution for Transforming India (NITI) Aayog,

Government of India. 16 December 2015. pp.1-46.

Adve, N., 2019. Impacts of Global Warming in India: Narratives from Below. In India in a

Warming World . Oxford University Press. pp.64-78.

Aga, A., 2018. Merchants of knowledge: Petty retail and differentiation without consolidation

among farmers in Maharashtra, India. Journal of Agrarian Change, 18(3), pp.658-676.

Aga, A., 2019. The marketing of corporate agrichemicals in Western India: theorizing graded

informality. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 46(7), pp.1458-1476.

Agarwal, B. and Agrawal, A., 2017. Do farmers really like farming? Indian farmers in

transition. Oxford Development Studies, 45(4), pp.460-478.

Aggarwal, R.M., 2008. Resource-Poor Farmers in South India: On the Margins or Frontiers of

Globalization? In Globalization and the Poor in Asia. Palgrave Macmillan UK. pp.196-220.

Aggarwal, P., Roy, J., Pathak, H., Kumar, S.N., Venkateswarlu, B., Ghosh, A. and Ghosh, D.,

2020. Indian Agriculture Towards 2030. Pathways for Enhancing Farmers’ Income, Nutritional

Security and Sustainable Food Systems. Thematic Session: Climate Change And Risk

Management Discussion Paper: Managing Climatic Risks in Agriculture. pp.1-19.

Ahaibwe, G., Mbowa, S. and Lwanga, M.M., 2013. Youth engagement in agriculture in

Uganda: Challenges and prospects. Economic Policy Research Centre. pp.1-48.

Ahmed, S., Jayakumar, R. and Salih, A. eds., 2008. Groundwater dynamics in hard rock

aquifers: sustainable management and optimal monitoring network design. Springer Science &

Business Media.

Akram‐Lodhi, A.H., 1998. The agrarian question, past and present. The Journal of Peasant

Studies, 25(4), pp.134-149.

Akram‐Lodhi, A.H., 2008. (Re) imagining agrarian relations? The World Development Report

2008: agriculture for development. Development and Change, 39(6), pp.1145-1161.

Page 235: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

235

Akram-Lodhi, A.H. and Kay, C., 2010b. Surveying the agrarian question (part 2): current

debates and beyond. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 37(2), pp.255-284.

Akram-Lodhi, H. 2018. What is Critical Agrarian Studies?. Available:

http://roape.net/2018/03/28/what-is-critical-agrarian-studies/. Last accessed 12/1/21.

Alagh, Y. 2018. Planning the Agricultural Vision. Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics

73(1). pp.1–16.

Alary, V., 1999. Rice Cultivation in Telangana: Comparative Study in Irrigated and Non-

Irrigated Zones. Economic and Political Weekly, pp.1402-1404.

Al Naber, M. and Molle, F., 2017. Controlling groundwater over abstraction: state policies vs

local practices in the Jordan highlands. Water policy, 19(4), pp.692-708.

Anupoju, V. and Kambhammettu, B.V.N.P., 2020. Role of deficit irrigation strategies on ET

partition and crop water productivity of rice in semi-arid tropics of south India. Irrigation

Science, 38(4), pp.415-430.

Aronson, J. 1995. A Pragmatic View of Thematic Analysis. The Qualitative Report, 2(1), pp.1-

3. Retrieved from http://nsuworks.nova.edu/tqr/vol2/iss1/3

Asfaw, S., Shiferaw, B., Simtowe, F. and Lipper, L., 2012. Impact of modern agricultural

technologies on smallholder welfare: Evidence from Tanzania and Ethiopia. Food

policy, 37(3), pp.283-295.

Asoka, A., Wada, Y., Fishman, R. and Mishra, V., 2018. Strong linkage between precipitation

intensity and monsoon season groundwater recharge in India. Geophysical Research

Letters, 45(11), pp.5536-5544.

Attride-Stirling, J., 2001. Thematic networks: an analytic tool for qualitative research.

Qualitative research, 1(3), pp.385-405.

Azam, M., Chin, A. and Prakash, N., 2013. The returns to English-language skills in

India. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 61(2), pp.335-367.

Bandyopadhyay, D., 2001. Andhra Pradesh: Looking beyond" Vision 2020". Economic and

Political Weekly, pp.900-903.

Banerjee, A.V. and Duflo, E., 2019. Good economics for hard times: Better answers to our

biggest problems. Penguin UK.

Page 236: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

236

Bassi, N., Vijayshankar, P.S. and Kumar, M.D., 2008. Wells and ill-fare: Impacts of well

failures on cultivators in hard rock areas of Madhya Pradesh. Managing water in the face of

growing scarcity, inequity and declining returns: Exploring fresh approaches. pp.318-330.

Baxter, P. and Jack, S., 2008. Qualitative case study methodology: Study design and

implementation for novice researchers. The qualitative report, 13(4), pp.544-559.

Benbabaali, D., 2016. From the peasant armed struggle to the Telangana State: changes and

continuities in a South Indian region’s uprisings. Contemporary South Asia, 24(2), pp.184-196.

Bennike, R.B., Rasmussen, M.B. and Nielsen, K.B., 2020. Agrarian crossroads: rural

aspirations and capitalist transformation. Canadian Journal of Development Studies, 41(1),

pp.40-160.

Bergius, M., Benjaminsen, T.A. and Widgren, M., 2018. Green economy, Scandinavian

investments and agricultural modernization in Tanzania. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 45(4),

pp.825-852.

Bergius, M. and Buseth, J.T., 2019. Towards a green modernization development discourse:

the new green revolution in Africa. Journal of Political Ecology, 26(1), pp.57-83.

Bernstein, H., 1996. Agrarian questions then and now. The Journal of peasant studies, 24(1-2),

pp.22-59.

Bernstein, H., 2004. ‘Changing before our very eyes’: Agrarian questions and the politics of

land in capitalism today. Journal of Agrarian Change, 4(1‐2), pp.190-225.

Bernstein, H., 2006. Is there an agrarian question in the 21st century?. Canadian Journal of

Development Studies/Revue canadienne d'études du développement, 27(4), pp.449-460.

Bernstein, H., 2010. Class dynamics of agrarian change (Vol. 1). Kumarian Press.

Bernstein, H., 2014. Food sovereignty via the ‘peasant way’: a sceptical view. The Journal of

peasant studies, 41(6), pp.1031–1063.

Bezu, S. and Holden, S., 2014. Are rural youth in Ethiopia abandoning agriculture?. World

Development, 64, pp.259-272.

Bhalla, G.S. and Singh, G., 2009. Economic liberalisation and Indian agriculture: a statewise

analysis. Economic and Political Weekly, pp.34-44.

Page 237: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

237

Bharucha, Z.P., 2019. This is what Nature has become: Tracing climate and water narratives

in India’s rainfed drylands. Geoforum, 101, pp.285-293.

Bharucha, P.Z., Attwood, S., Badiger, S., Balamatti, A., Bawden, R., Bentley, J.W., Chander,

M., Davies, L., Dixon, H., Dixon, J. and D’Souza, M., 2020. The Top 100 questions for the

sustainable intensification of agriculture in India’s rainfed drylands. International Journal of

Agricultural Sustainability, pp.1-22.

Bharucha, Z.P., Mitjans, S.B. and Pretty, J., 2020. Towards redesign at scale through zero

budget natural farming in Andhra Pradesh, India. International Journal of Agricultural

Sustainability, 18(1), pp.1-20.

Bhuyan, S. and Pray, C., 2019. Role of interest groups in technology policy: a case study of

policies on agricultural biotechnology in India. Indian Journal of Economics and

Development, 7(9). pp.1-17.

Birkenholtz, T.L., 2007. The politics of groundwater scarcity: technology, institutions, and

governance in Rajasthani irrigation. Doctoral dissertation, The Ohio State University.

Birkenholz T.L,. 2009. Groundwater governmentality: hegemony and technologies of

resistance in Rajasthan’s (India) groundwater governance. The Geographical Journal 175(1).

pp.208–220.

Birner, R. and Resnick, D., 2010. The political economy of policies for smallholder

agriculture. World Development, 38(10), pp.1442-1452.

Blakeslee, D., Fishman, R. and Srinivasan, V., 2020. Way Down in the Hole: Adaptation to

Long-Term Water Loss in Rural India. American Economic Review, 110(1), pp.200-224.

Boudreaux, D.J., 2014. The Essential Hayek. Fraser Institute.

Bowles, E., 2003. Andhra Pradesh, India, as a Case Study in Perspectives on

GMO's. Cumberland Law Review., 34(3), pp.413-426.

Bownas, R., 2016. Lost in Transnationalism? GMOs in India and the Eclipse of Equitable

Development Discourse. Journal of South Asian Development, 11(1), pp.67-87.

Breman, J., 1994. Wage hunters and gatherers: search for work in the urban and rural economy

of South Gujarat. Oxford University Press.

Page 238: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

238

Breman, J., 2009. The great transformation in the setting of Asia. Public lecture to accept

honorary doctorate (The Hague: International Institute of Social Studies). pp.3-30.

Bryceson, D.F., 2019. Gender and generational patterns of African deagrarianization: Evolving

labour and land allocation in smallholder peasant household farming, 1980–2015. World

Development, 113, pp.60-72.

Byerlee, D. and Morris, M., 1993. Research for marginal environments: Are we

underinvested?. Food Policy, 18(5), pp.381-393.

Byerlee, D., De Janvry, A., Sadoulet, E., Townsend, R. and Klytchnikova, I., 2008. World

development report 2008: agriculture for development (No. 41455). The World Bank. pp.1-

390.

Byerlee, D., Diao, X. and Jackson, C.P., 2005. Agriculture, rural development, and pro-poor

growth: Country experiences in the post-reform era. Agriculture & Rural Development

Department., World Bank.

Byres, T.J. 1981. The new technology, class formation and class action in the Indian

countryside. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 8(4), pp.405-454.

Byres, T., 1991. The agrarian question and differing forms of capitalist agrarian transition: an

essay with reference to Asia. Rural transformation in Asia., pp.3-76.

Byres, T.J., 1995. Political economy, the agrarian question and the comparative method. The

Journal of Peasant Studies, 22(4), pp.561-580.

Byres, T.J., 2009. The landlord class, peasant differentiation, class struggle and the transition

to capitalism: England, France and Prussia compared. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 36(1),

pp.33-54.

Byres, T.J., 2016. In pursuit of capitalist agrarian transition. Journal of Agrarian Change, 16(3),

pp.432-451.

Carlson, C., 2018. Rethinking the agrarian question: Agriculture and underdevelopment in the

Global South. Journal of Agrarian Change, 18(4), pp.703-721.

Central Groundwater Board Andhra Pradesh. 2013. Groundwater Brochure Nalgonda District,

Andhra Pradesh. Hyderabad: Ministry Of Water Resources, Government Of India. pp.1-59.

Page 239: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

239

Central Groundwater Board Telangana. 2017. Groundwater Year Book 2016-17 Telangana

State. Hyderabad: Ministry Of Water Resources, River Development and Ganga Rejuvenation,

Government Of India. pp.1-99.

Central Groundwater Board Telangana. 2019. Groundwater Year Book 2018-19 Telangana

State. Hyderabad: Ministry Of Jal Shakti, Department of Water Resources, River Development

and Ganga Rejuvenation, Government Of India. pp.1-103.

Chambers, R., 1984. Beyond the Green Revolution: a selective essay. Understanding Green

Revolutions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp.362-379.

Chand, R., 2017. Doubling Farmers Income: Rationale, Strategy, Prospects and Action Plan

NITI Policy Paper No 1/2017, NITI Aayog, New Delhi, Government of India.

Chand, R., 2019. Innovative policy interventions for transformation of farm

sector. Agricultural Economics Research Review, 32(347-2019-3210), pp.1-10.

Chand, R., Srivastava, S.K. and Singh, J., 2017. Changing structure of rural economy of India

implications for employment and growth. Discussion Paper, NITI Aayog, Delhi. pp.1-30.

Chang, H.J., 2009. Rethinking public policy in agriculture: lessons from history, distant and

recent. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 36(3), pp.477-515.

Chaudhuri, A., 2019. The kernel of doubt: agricultural biotechnology, braided temporalities,

and agrarian environments in India. Doctoral dissertation, Massachusetts Institute of

Technology.

Chronicle, D. 2020. Many more come in support of protesting farmers in Telangana. Available:

https://www.deccanchronicle.com/nation/politics/301220/many-more-come-in-support-of-

protesting-farmers-in-telangana.html. Last accessed 5/1/21.

Cobbing, J. and Hiller, B., 2019. Waking a sleeping giant: Realizing the potential of

groundwater in Sub-Saharan Africa. World Development, 122, pp.597-613.

Creswell, J.W., 2007. Five qualitative approaches to inquiry. Qualitative inquiry and research

design: Choosing among five approaches, 2, pp.53-80.

Cuthbert, M.O., Gleeson, T., Moosdorf, N., Befus, K.M., Schneider, A., Hartmann, J. and

Lehner, B., 2019. Global patterns and dynamics of climate–groundwater interactions. Nature

Climate Change, 9(2), pp.137-141.

Page 240: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

240

Da Corta, L. and Venkateshwarlu, D., 1999. Unfree relations and the feminisation of

agricultural labour in Andhra Pradesh, 1970–95. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 26(2-3),

pp.71-139.

Damodaran, H., 2008. Kammas, Reddys, and Rajus. In India’s New Capitalists. Palgrave

Macmillan, London. pp.92-137.

Dar, W.D., 2011. Dryland agriculture in semi-arid tropics: Constraints and

opportunities. Indian Journal of Dryland Agricultural Research and Development, 26(1), pp.1-

7.

Datt, G., Ravallion, M. and Murgai, R., 2020. Poverty and growth in India over six

decades. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 102(1), pp.4-27.

Dawson, J., 2010. Thick description. Encyclopedia of case study research, 2, pp.942-944.

De Janvry, A., 2010. Agriculture for development: new paradigm and options for

success. Agricultural Economics, 41(1), pp.17-36.

Deb, U.K., Nageswara Rao, G.D., Rao, Y.M. and Slater, R., 2002. Diversification and

livelihood options: A study of two villages in Andhra Pradesh, India 1975–2001. Working

Paper 178, London: Overseas Development Institute.

Deb U, Bantilan C and Anupama GV. 2014a. Drivers of change: dynamics of rural livelihoods

and poverty in SAT India, Research Bulletin No. 26, ICRISAT. pp.1-53.

Deb, U., Nagaraj, N., Kumar, R., Bhattarai, M., Padmaja, R., Parthasarathy Rao, P. and

Bantilan, C., 2014b. Dynamics of rural labor markets in India: Implications for inclusive

development strategy. ICRISAT Policy Brief, 27, pp.1-12.

Demirguc-Kunt, A. and Klapper, L., 2012. Measuring financial inclusion: The global findex

database. The World Bank.

Demirguc-Kunt, A.., Klapper, L., Singer, D., Ansar, S. and Hess, J., 2018. The Global Findex

Database 2017: Measuring Financial Inclusion and the Fintech Revolution. Washington, DC:

World Bank. doi: 10.1596.

Dev, S.M. and Rao, N.C., 2007. Socioeconomic impact of Bt cotton. Hyderabad, India: Centre

for Economic and Social Studies. CESS Monographs 3. pp.1-107.

Page 241: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

241

Dhanagare, D.N., 2016. Declining credibility of the neoliberal state and agrarian crisis in India:

some observations. In Critical Perspectives on Agrarian Transition Routledge India. pp.166-

191.

Directorate of Economics and Statistics Andhra Pradesh. 2006. Compendium of Area and Land

Use Statistics Of Andhra Pradesh 1955-2005. Hyderabad: Government of Andhra Pradesh.

pp.1-361.

Directorate of Economics and Statistics India. 2018. Agricultural Statistics At A Glance 2018.

Department of Agriculture, Cooperation and Farmers Welfare., Ministry of Agriculture and

Farmers Welfare, Government of India.

Directorate of Economics and Statistics, India. 2019a. District Wise Land Use Statistics.

Special Data Dissemination Standard Division, Ministry of Agriculture and Farmers Welfare,

Govt. Of India.

Directorate of Economics and Statistics, India. 2019b. District Wise Crop Production Statistics.

Special Data Dissemination Standard Division, Ministry of Agriculture and Farmers Welfare,

Govt. Of India.

Directorate of Economics and Statistics Telangana. 2016. Agricultural Statistics At A Glance

2015-16. Directorate of Economics and Statistics Planning Department, Government Of

Telangana, Hyderabad, 500 004.

Directorate of Economics and Statistics Telangana. 2019. District Administrative Map.

Available: https://nalgonda.telangana.gov.in/map-of-district/. Last accessed 10/12/20.

Directorate of Economics and Statistics Telangana. 2020. Socio Economic Outlook 2020.

Planning Department, Government of Telangana, Hyderabad, 500 004.

Dorward, A., Kydd, J., Morrison, J. and Urey, I., 2004. A policy agenda for pro-poor

agricultural growth. World development, 32(1), pp.73-89.

Dowd-Uribe, B. and Schnurr, M.A., 2016. Briefing: Burkina Faso's reversal on genetically

modified cotton and the implications for Africa. African Affairs, 115(458), pp.161-172.

Dowd-Uribe, B., 2017. GMOs and poverty: Definitions, methods and the silver bullet paradox.

Canadian Journal of Development Studies/Revue canadienne d'études du développement,

38(1), pp.129-138.

Page 242: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

242

Du Toit, A., 2009. Adverse incorporation and agrarian policy in South Africa, Or, How not to

connect the rural poor to growth.

Dubash, N.K., 2002. Tubewell capitalism: groundwater development and agrarian change in

Gujarat. Oxford University Press.

Dutta, S., 2012. Green revolution revisited: the contemporary agrarian situation in Punjab,

India. Social Change, 42(2), pp.229-247.

Easterly, W., 2005. What did structural adjustment adjust?: The association of policies and

growth with repeated IMF and World Bank adjustment loans. Journal of development

economics, 76(1), pp.1-22.

Ekers, M. and Prudham, S., 2018. The socioecological fix: Fixed capital, metabolism, and

hegemony. Annals of the American Association of Geographers, 108(1), pp.17-34.

Ellis, F., 2010. Strategic dimensions of rural poverty reduction in sub-Saharan Africa. The

comparative political economy of development: Africa and South Asia, pp.47-63.

Evenson, R., and D. Gollin. 2003. "The green revolution: An end-of-century perspective.

International conference on impacts of agricultural research and development: Why has impact

assessment research not made more of a difference?." International Conference on Impacts of

Agricultural Research and Development. 4-7 Feb 2002. San José (Costa Rica). pp.1-31.

Fairbairn, M., Fox, J., Isakson, S.R., Levien, M., Peluso, N., Razavi, S., Scoones, I. and

Sivaramakrishnan, K., 2014. Introduction: New directions in agrarian political economy. The

Journal of Peasant Studies, 41(5), pp.653-666.

Fan, S., Gulati, A. and Thorat, S., 2008. Investment, subsidies, and pro‐poor growth in rural

India. Agricultural Economics, 39(2), pp.163-170.

FAS. 2021. The Foundation for Agrarian Studies. Available: https://fas.org.in/. Last accessed

27th May 2021.

Ferrant, S., Caballero, Y., Perrin, J., Gascoin, S., Dewandel, B., Aulong, S., Dazin, F., Ahmed,

S. and Maréchal, J.C., 2014. Projected impacts of climate change on farmers' extraction of

groundwater from crystalline aquifers in South India. Nature Scientific Reports, 4 (3697), pp.1-

10.

Page 243: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

243

Fischer, K., Ekener-Petersen, E., Rydhmer, L. and Björnberg, K.E., 2015. Social impacts of

GM crops in agriculture: A systematic literature review. Sustainability, 7(7), pp.8598-8620.

Fischer, H.W., Reddy, N.N. and Rao, M.S., 2016. Can more drought resistant crops promote

more climate secure agriculture? Prospects and challenges of millet cultivation in Ananthapur,

Andhra Pradesh. World Development Perspectives, 2, pp.5-10.

Fishman, R.M., Siegfried, T., Raj, P., Modi, V. and Lall, U., 2011. Over‐extraction from

shallow bedrock versus deep alluvial aquifers: Reliability versus sustainability considerations

for India's groundwater irrigation. Water Resources Research, 47(6). pp. 1-15.

Flachs, A., 2016. Cultivating knowledge: The production and adaptation of knowledge on

organic and GM cotton farms in Telangana, India. PhD Thesis. University Of Washington St-

Louis.

Flachs, A., 2019. Cultivating Knowledge: Biotechnology, Sustainability, and the Human Cost

of Cotton Capitalism in India. University of Arizona Press.

Flachs, A., 2020. Political ecology and the industrial food system. Physiology & Behavior, 220

(2020). pp.1-6.

Foster, A.D. and Rosenzweig, M.R., 2004. Agricultural productivity growth, rural economic

diversity, and economic reforms: India, 1970–2000. Economic Development and Cultural

Change, 52(3), pp.509-542.

Gerber, J.F., 2013. The hidden consequences of credit: an illustration from rural Indonesia.

Development and Change, 44(4), pp.839-860.

Gerber, J.F., 2014. The role of rural indebtedness in the evolution of capitalism. Journal of

Peasant Studies, 41(5), pp.729-747.

Ghosh, S. and Meer, A., 2020. Extended urbanisation and the agrarian question: Convergences,

divergences and openings. Urban Studies, p.0042098020943758.

Giné, X., Townsend, R.M. and Vickery, J., 2008. Rational Expectations?: Evidence from

Planting Decisions in Semi-arid India. Bureau for Research and Economic Analysis of

Development.

Gleeson, T., Befus, K.M., Jasechko, S., Luijendijk, E. and Cardenas, M.B., 2016. The global

volume and distribution of modern groundwater. Nature Geoscience, 9(2), pp.161-164.

Page 244: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

244

Glover, D., 2007. Farmer participation in private sector agricultural extension. IDS

Bulletin, 38(5), pp.61-73.

Glover, D., 2010a. The corporate shaping of GM crops as a technology for the poor. The

Journal of Peasant Studies, 37(1), pp.67-90.

Glover, D., 2010b. Is Bt Cotton a Pro‐Poor Technology? A Review and Critique of the

Empirical Record. Journal of agrarian change, 10(4), pp.482-509.

Glover, D., Venot, J.-P., Maat, H. 2017. On the movement of agricultural technologies:

Packaging, unpacking and situated reconfiguration, in: Sumberg, J. (ed.), Agronomy for

Development: The politics of knowledge in agricultural research. Routledge, London, UK,

Chapter 2, pp. 14-30.

Glover, D., Sumberg, J., Ton, G., Andersson, J. and Badstue, L., 2019. Rethinking

technological change in smallholder agriculture. Outlook on Agriculture, 48(3), pp.169-180.

Google Maps. 2019. Kacharam. Available:

https://www.google.com/maps/place/16%C2%B039'29.3%22N+78%C2%B053'27.9%22E/@

16.6600919,78.8872953,1191m/data=!3m1!1e3!4m5!3m4!1s0x0:0x0!8m2!3d16.65813!4d78

.89108. Last accessed 10/12/20.

Government of India. 2010. Report of the Committee for Consultations on the Situation of

Andhra Pradesh. Chairperson, Justice Sri Krishna. New Delhi: Ministry of Home Affairs,

Government of India. Retrieved from http://mha.nic.in/

Gray, L. and Dowd-Uribe, B., 2013. A political ecology of socio-economic differentiation:

Debt, inputs and liberalization reforms in southwestern Burkina Faso. Journal of Peasant

Studies, 40(4), pp.683-702.

Green, W.N., 2019. Landscapes of Debt: A Political Ecology of Microfinance and Land Titling

Programs in Cambodia. The University of Wisconsin-Madison.

Green, W.N., 2020. Financial landscapes of agrarian change in Cambodia. Geoforum. In Press.

pp.1-9.

Gruère, G. and Sengupta, D., 2011. Bt cotton and farmer suicides in India: An evidence-based

assessment. The Journal of Development Studies, 47(2), pp.316-337.

Page 245: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

245

Grzanka, P.R., Mann, E.S. and Elliott, S., 2016. The neoliberalism wars, or notes on the

persistence of neoliberalism. Sexuality Research and Social Policy, 13(4), pp.297-307.

Guba, E.G. and Lincoln, Y.S., 1994. Competing paradigms in qualitative research. Handbook

of qualitative research, 2(163-194), pp.105-117.

Guérin, I., Roesch, M., Venkatasubramanian, G. and D'espallier, B., 2012. Credit from whom

and for what? The diversity of borrowing sources and uses in rural southern India. Journal of

International Development, 24, pp.122-137.

Guérin, I., D'Espallier, B. and Venkatasubramanian, G., 2013. Debt in rural South India:

Fragmentation, social regulation and discrimination. The Journal of Development Studies,

49(9), pp.1155-1171.

Gulati, A,. Juneja, R. 2019. Agricultural credit system in India: Evolution, effectiveness and

innovations, ZEF Working Paper Series, No. 184, University of Bonn, Center for Development

Research (ZEF), Bonn. pp.1-57.

Gulati, A., Kapur, D. and Bouton, M.M., 2020. Reforming Indian agriculture. Economic &

Political Weekly, 55(11), pp.35-42.

Guntukula, R., 2020. Assessing the impact of climate change on Indian agriculture: Evidence

from major crop yields. Journal of Public Affairs, 20(1), pp.1-7.

Gupta, N., Tripati, S. and Dholakia, H.H., 2020. Can zero budget natural farming save input

costs and fertiliser subsidies. Report. The Council on Energy, Environment and Water, pp.1-

52.

Gutierrez, A.P., 2018. Hybrid Bt cotton: a stranglehold on subsistence farmers in India. Current

Science, 115(12), pp.2206-2210.

Gutierrez, A.P., Herren, H.R. and Kenmore, P.E., 2020. The Failure of GMO Cotton In India.

www.resilience.org. pp.1-18.

Gutierrez, A.P., Ponti, L., Kranthi, K.R., Baumgärtner, J., Kenmore, P.E., Gilioli, G., Boggia,

A., Cure, J.R. and Rodríguez, D., 2020. Bio-economics of Indian hybrid Bt cotton and farmer

suicides. Environmental Sciences Europe, 32(1), pp.1-15.

Haggblade, S., Hazell, P. and Reardon, T., 2010. The rural non-farm economy: Prospects for

growth and poverty reduction. World development, 38(10), pp.1429-1441.

Page 246: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

246

Harriss, J. and Jeyaranjan, J., 2014. Rural Tamil Nadu in the Liberalisation Era: What Do We

Learn from Village Studies. Institute of South Asian Studies. pp.1-25.

Harriss, J., 2011. Civil society and politics: An anthropological perspective. A Companion to

the Anthropology of India, pp.389-406.

Harriss-White, B. and Harriss, J., 2007. Green Revolution and After: The 'North Arcot Papers'

and Long-term Studies of the Political Economy of Rural Development in South India. Oxford.

QEH Working Paper Series 146. pp.1-27.

Harriss-White, B. and Janakarajan, S., 1997. From green revolution to rural industrial

revolution in South India. Economic and Political Weekly, pp.1469-1477.

Harriss-White, B. and Garikipati, S., 2008. India's semi-arid rural economy: livelihoods,

seasonal migration and gender. The European Journal of Development Research, 20(4),

pp.547-548.

Harriss-White, B. 2012. Capitalism and the Common Man. Peasants and Petty Production in

Africa and South Asia. Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 1(2), pp.109–60.

Harriss-White, B., 2013. Debt, credit and contractual synchrony in a South Indian market

town. Microfinance, Debt and Over Indebtedness: Juggling with Money, pp.103-24.

Harriss-White, B., 2018. Awkward classes and India's development. Review of Political

Economy, 30(3), pp.355-376.

Harriss-White, B., 2020. The Green Revolution and Poverty in Northern Tamil Nadu: a Brief

Synthesis of Village-Level Research in the Last Half-Century. STEPS Working Paper 115.

pp.1-54.

Harwood, J., 2019. Was the Green Revolution intended to maximise food

production?. International Journal of Agricultural Sustainability, 17(4), pp.312-325.

Hebinck, P., 2018. De-/re-agrarianisation: Global perspectives. Journal of Rural Studies, 61,

pp.227-235.

Heckathorn, D.D., 2011. Comment: Snowball versus respondent-driven sampling. Sociological

methodology, 41(1), pp.355-366.

Page 247: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

247

Herring, R.J., 2008. Whose numbers count? Probing discrepant evidence on transgenic cotton

in the Warangal district of India. International Journal of Multiple Research Approaches, 2(2),

pp.145-159.

Herring, R.J. and Rao, N.C., 2012. On the ‘Failure of Bt Cotton’. Economic & Political

Weekly, 47(18), pp.45-54.

Herring, R. and Paarlberg, R., 2016. The political economy of biotechnology. Annual Review

of Resource Economics, 8, pp.397-416.

Himanshu, J. and Jha, P., P., Rodgers, G.(2016). The changing village in India: Insights from

longitudinal research.

Himanshu. 2019. India's Farm Crisis: Decades Old and With Deep Roots. Available:

https://www.theindiaforum.in/article/farm-crisis-runs-deep-higher-msps-and-cash-handouts-

are-not-enough. Last accessed 19th September 2019.

Himanshu. 2020. Lessons from Bihar’s abolition of its APMC system for farmers, Mint, 24th

September. Available at: https://www.livemint.com/opinion/columns/lessons-from-bihar-s-

abolition-of-its-apmc-system-for-farmers-11600962615201.html. Accessed: 10 May 2021.

Hoogesteger, J. and Wester, P., 2015. Intensive groundwater use and (in) equity: Processes and

governance challenges. Environmental science & policy, 51, pp.117-124.

Hoogesteger, J.V., 2018. The Ostrich Politics of Groundwater Development and Neoliberal

Regulation in Mexico. Water Alternatives, 11(3), pp.552-571.

Hora, T., Srinivasan, V. and Basu, N.B., 2019. The groundwater recovery paradox in South

India. Geophysical Research Letters, 46(16), pp.9602-9611.

Indian Planning Commission, 2008. Eleventh Five Year Plan 2007-12. Volume-III.

Agriculture, Rural Development, Industry, Services and Physical Infrastructure. pp.1-537.

Indiaspend. 2019. Climate Change, Farm Crisis, Unemployment: 2019 In 5 Charts. Available:

https://www.indiaspend.com/climate-change-farm-crisis-unemployment-2019-in-5-charts/.

Last accessed 3rd April 2020.

ISAAA., 2017. Global status of commercialized biotech/GM crops in 2017: Biotech crop

adoption surges as economic benefits accumulate in 22 years. Manila, Philippines:

International Service for the Acquisition of Agri-biotech Applications.

Page 248: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

248

ISAAA. 2019. ISAAA in 2019: Accomplishment Report. Brief 55: Global Status of

Commercialized Biotech/GM Crops: 2019. Manila, Philippines: International Service for the

Acquisition of Agri-biotech Applications (ISAAA). pp.1-40.

Jacoby, H.G., 2017. “Well-fare” Economics of Groundwater in South Asia. The World Bank

Research Observer, 32(1), pp.1-20.

Jakimow, T., 2012. Serious games in livelihood analysis: Reflections from the case of

agricultural wage labourers in Andhra Pradesh. Journal of Development Studies, 48(9),

pp.1274-1287.

Jakimow, T., 2014. Gambling on Livelihoods. Asian Journal of Social Science, 42(3-4),

pp.409-434.

Jakimow, T., 2016. Clinging to hope through education: The consequences of hope for rural

laborers in Telangana, India. Ethos, 44(1), pp.11-31.

Jakobsen, J., 2018. Neoliberalising the food regime ‘amongst its others’: the right to food and

the state in India. The Journal of Peasant Studies, pp.1-21.

Jakobsen, J., 2019. The maize frontier in rural South India: Exploring the everyday dynamics

of the contemporary food regime. Journal of Agrarian Change, 2019(0), pp.1-26.

Jakobsen, J. and Nielsen, K.B., 2019. Compounding aspirations: grounding hegemonic

processes in India's rural transformations. Canadian Journal of Development Studies/Revue

canadienne d'études du développement, pp.1-17.

Jaleta, M., Gebremedhin, B. and Hoekstra, D., 2009. Smallholder commercialization:

Processes, determinants and impact. Discussion Paper No.18.. International Livestock

Research Institute. pp.1-55

Jan, M.A. and Harriss-White, B., 2012. The Three Roles of Agricultural Markets: A Review

of Ideas about Agricultural Commodity Markets in India. Economic and Political Weekly,

pp.39-52.

Jan, M.A. and Harriss-White, B., 2019. Petty Production and India’s Development. In Karl

Marx’s Life, Ideas, and Influences Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. pp. 345-367.

Jodhka, S.S., 2014. Emergent ruralities: Revisiting village life and agrarian change in

Haryana. Economic and Political Weekly, 49(26), pp.5-17.

Page 249: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

249

Jose Thomas, J. 2020. Creating jobs for young India. Available:

https://www.thehindu.com/opinion/op-ed/creating-jobs-for-young-india/article29559283.ece.

Last accessed 2nd April 2020.

Kannibiran, K,. Jeyaranjan, J. Swaminathan, P. 2017. Telangana Social Development Report

2017. Hyderabad: Council for Social Development Available:

https://www.telangana.gov.in/downloads/reports. Last accessed 2nd April 2020.

Kannan, K.P., 2020. Structural Transformation and the Agrarian Question in the Indian

Economy. In Development Challenges of India After Twenty Five Years of Economic

Reforms. Springer, Singapore. pp. 305-329.

Kannan, E. and Sundaram, S., 2011. Analysis of trends in India's Agricultural Growth. Institute

for Social and Economic Change.

Karimi, P., Qureshi, A.S., Bahramloo, R. and Molden, D., 2012. Reducing carbon emissions

through improved irrigation and groundwater management: A case study from

Iran. Agricultural water management, 108, pp.52-60.

Kashwan, P., MacLean, L.M. and García-López, G.A., 2019. Rethinking power and institutions

in the shadows of neoliberalism:(An introduction to a special issue of World

Development). World Development, 120, pp.133-146.

Kathage, J. and Qaim, M., 2012. Economic impacts and impact dynamics of Bt (Bacillus

thuringiensis) cotton in India. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 109(29),

pp.11652-11656.

Katz, C., 2001. Vagabond capitalism and the necessity of social reproduction. Antipode, 33(4),

pp.709-728.

Kaul, A. 2019. Demographic dream is collapsing rapidly. Available:

https://www.livemint.com/news/india/demographic-dream-is-collapsing-rapidly-

11576505253176.html. Last accessed 2nd April 2020.

Kingdon, G.G., 2020. The private schooling phenomenon in India: A review. The Journal of

Development Studies, pp.1-23.

Kloppenburg, J.R., 2005. First the seed: The political economy of plant biotechnology. Univ

of Wisconsin Press.

Page 250: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

250

Koner, N. and Laha, A., 2020. Economics of Zero Budget Natural Farming in Purulia District

of West Bengal: Is It Economically Viable?. Studies In Agricultural Economics, 122(1), pp.22-

28.

Kouser, S. and Qaim, M., 2013. Valuing financial, health, and environmental benefits of Bt

cotton in Pakistan. Agricultural Economics, 44(3), pp.323-335.

Kranthi, K.R. and Stone, G.D., 2020. Long-term impacts of Bt cotton in India. Nature

Plants, 6(3), pp.188-196.

Kuchimanchi, B.R., Nazareth, D., Bendapudi, R., Awasthi, S. and D’Souza, M., 2019.

Assessing differential vulnerability of communities in the agrarian context in two districts of

Maharashtra, India. Climate and Development, 11(10), pp.918-929.

Kukanur, V. S., Singh, T. V. K., Kranthi, K. R. & Andow, D. A. 2018. Cry1Ac resistance allele

frequency in feld populations of Helicoverpa armigera (Hubner) collected in Telangana and

Andhra Pradesh, India. Crop Prot. 107, pp.34–40

Kumar, M.D., Sivamohan, M.V.K., Niranjan, V. and Bassi, N., 2011. Groundwater

management in Andhra Pradesh: time to address real issues. Institute for Resource Analysis

and Policy, Hyderabad. pp.1-27.

Kumar, A., 2017. Agrarian questions: Old and new. Review of Agrarian Studies, 7(2369-2020-

2019).

Kumar, S., Murthy, D., Gumma, M.K., Khan, P., Khatri-Chhetri, A., Aggarwal, P.K., Murthy,

C.S.R., Chakravarthy, K. and Whitbread, A.M., 2018. Towards climate-smart agricultural

policies and investments in Telangana. CGIAR Info Note, pp.1-4.

Kumar, S., Craufurd, P., Haileslassie, A., Ramilan, T., Rathore, A. and Whitbread, A., 2019.

Farm typology analysis and technology assessment: An application in an arid region of South

Asia. Land Use Policy, 88(104149). pp.1-14.

Lall, U., Josset, L. and Russo, T., 2020. A snapshot of the world's groundwater

challenges. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 45. pp.171-194.

Lanjouw, P., Murgai, R. and Stern, N., 2013. Non-farm diversification, poverty, economic

mobility and income inequality: A case study in village India. Policy Research Working Paper

6451. The World Bank.

Page 251: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

251

Lerche, J., 2011. Agrarian crisis and agrarian questions in India. Journal of Agrarian

Change, 11(1), pp.104-118.

Lerche, J., 2013. The agrarian question in neoliberal India: Agrarian transition

bypassed?. Journal of Agrarian Change, 13(3), pp.382-404.

Lerche, J. 2015. Regional Patterns of Agrarian Accumulation in India. Chapter 3 in Indian

Capitalism in Development, edited by B. Harriss-White and J. Heyer. London: Routledge.

pp. 46-55.

Lerche, J. and Shah, A., 2018. Conjugated oppression within contemporary capitalism: class,

caste, tribe and agrarian change in India. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 45(5-6), pp.927-949.

Levien, M., Watts, M. and Hairong, Y., 2018. Agrarian Marxism. The Journal Of Peasant

Studies, 45(5-6), pp.853-883.

Li, G.X., Xu, B.C., Yin, L.N., Wang, S.W., Zhang, S.Q., Shan, L., Kwak, S.S., Ke, Q. and

Deng, X.P., 2020. Dryland agricultural environment and sustainable productivity. Plant

Biotechnology Reports, 14(2), pp.169-176.

Live Mint. 2020. Rare good news amid Covid-19 crisis: Telangana witnesses bumper paddy

harvest. Available: https://www.livemint.com/news/india/rare-good-news-amid-covid-19-

crisis-telangana-witnesses-bumper-paddy-harvest-11587295986844.html. Last accessed

10/12/20.

Lopez, R., 2002. The economics of agriculture in developing countries: the role of the

environment. Handbook of agricultural economics, 2, pp.1213-1247.

Louis, E., 2015. “We Plant Only Cotton to Maximize Our Earnings”: The Paradox of Food

Sovereignty in Rural Telangana, India. The Professional Geographer, 67(4), pp.586-594.

Luna, J.K. and Dowd-Uribe, B., 2020. Knowledge politics and the Bt cotton success narrative

in Burkina Faso. World Development, 136, pp.1-12.

Luna, J.K., 2019. ‘Pesticides are our children now’: cultural change and the technological

treadmill in the Burkina Faso cotton sector. Agriculture and Human Values, pp.1-14.

Luna, J.K., 2020. Peasant essentialism in GMO debates: Bt cotton in Burkina Faso. Journal of

Agrarian Change, 20(4), pp.579-597.

Page 252: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

252

Maertens, A., Chari, A.V. and Just, D.R., 2013. Why farmers sometimes love risks: evidence

from India. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 62(2), pp.239-274.

Maertens, A., 2017. Who cares what others think (or do)? Social learning and social pressures

in cotton farming in India. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 99(4), pp.988-1007.

Maréchal, J.C., 2010. Editor′ s message: the sunk cost fallacy of deep drilling. Hydrogeology

Journal, 18(2), pp.287-289.

McMichael, P., 2009. Banking on agriculture: a review of the World Development Report

2008. Journal of Agrarian Change, 9(2), pp.235-246.

Mehra, P., 2019. The Lost Decade (2008-18): How India's Growth Story Devolved into Growth

Without a Story. Penguin Random House India Private Limited.

Mehrotra, S. and Parida, J.K., 2019. India’s employment crisis: rising education levels and

falling non-agricultural job growth. Centre For Sustainable Employment Working Paper 2019-

04, Azim Premji University. pp.1-22.

Meinzen-Dick, R., Janssen, M.A., Kandikuppa, S., Chaturvedi, R., Rao, K. and Theis, S., 2018.

Playing games to save water: Collective action games for groundwater management in Andhra

Pradesh, India. World Development, 107, pp.40-53.

Mellor, J.W., 1976. New economics of growth. Cornell University Press.

Menon, M., Uzramma, 2017. A Frayed History: The Journey of Cotton in India. Oxford

University Press.

Michler, J.D., 2020. Agriculture in the process of development: A micro-perspective. World

Development, 129, pp.1-17.

Ministry Of Water Resources, 2017. Report of 5th Minor Irrigation Schemes. Government of

India, New Delhi. pp.1-419.

Mishra, V., Thirumalai, K., Singh, D. and Aadhar, S., 2020. Future exacerbation of hot and dry

summer monsoon extremes in India. Climate and Atmospheric Science, 3(1), pp.1-9.

Miyamura, S., 2021. Turbulence ahead: labour and struggles in times of the Covid-19 pandemic

in India. Canadian Journal of Development Studies/Revue canadienne d'études du

développement, pp.1-13.

Page 253: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

253

Mohamed, A.M.O. and Paleologos, E.K., 2017. Fundamentals of geoenvironmental

engineering: understanding soil, water, and pollutant interaction and transport. Butterworth-

Heinemann.

Mohammad, R. 2001. 'Insiders' and/or 'outsiders' : positionality, theory and praxis. In:

Qualitative Methodologies for Geographers. Arnold, London,. ISBN 9780340742266. pp. 101-

117.

Mohan, T.D., 2015. Labour tying arrangements: an enduring aspect of agrarian capitalism in

India. Doctoral dissertation, The London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE).

Molle, F. and Tanouti, O., 2017. Squaring the circle: Agricultural intensification vs. water

conservation in Morocco. Agricultural Water Management, 192, pp.170-179.

Mollinga, P.P., 2008. Water, politics and development: Framing a political sociology of water

resources management.Water alternatives, 1(1), pp.7-23.

Mooij, J., 2007. Hype, skill and class: the politics of reform in Andhra Pradesh,

India. Commonwealth & Comparative Politics,45(1), pp.34-56.

Moseley, W., Schnurr, M. and Bezner Kerr, R., 2015. Interrogating the technocratic

(neoliberal) agenda for agricultural development and hunger alleviation in Africa. African

Geographical Review, 34(1), pp.1-7.

Moseley, W.G., 2017. A risky solution for the wrong problem: why GMOs won't feed the

hungry of the world. Geographical Review, 107(4), pp.578-583.

Moseley, W.G., Schnurr, M.A. and Bezner-Kerr, R. eds., 2017. Africa’s green revolution:

Critical perspectives on new agricultural technologies and systems. Routledge.

Mosse, D., 2007. Power and the durability of poverty: a critical exploration of the links between

culture, marginality and chronic poverty. Chronic Poverty Research Centre Working Paper,

(107). pp.1-60.

Mukherjee, A., 2018. Groundwater of Hard Rock Aquifers of India. In Groundwater of South

Asia. Springer, Singapore. pp.61-85.

Mukherjee, A.N. and Kuroda, Y., 2003. Productivity growth in Indian agriculture: is there

evidence of convergence across states?. Agricultural Economics, 29(1), pp.43-53.

Page 254: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

254

Mukherji, A. and Shah, T., 2005. Groundwater socio-ecology and governance: a review of

institutions and policies in selected countries. Hydrogeology Journal, 13(1), pp.328-345.

Murgai, R., Ali, M. and Byerlee, D., 2001. Productivity growth and sustainability in post–

Green Revolution agriculture: the case of the Indian and Pakistan Punjabs. The World Bank

Research Observer, 16(2), pp.199-218.

Murray Li, T., 2009. Exit from agriculture: a step forward or a step backward for the rural

poor?. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 36(3), pp.629-636.

Musabanganji, E., Karangwa, A. and Lebailly, P., 2016. Intensification of smallholder

agriculture in Rwanda: scenarios and challenges towards a sustainable transformation. Invited

paper presented at the 5th International Conference of the African Association of Agricultural

Economists, September 23-26, 2016, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia. pp.1-18.

Myers, R. and Hansen, C.P., 2020. Revisiting a theory of access: a review. Society & Natural

Resources, 33(2), pp.146-166.

Nagaraj, K., Sainath, P., Rukmani, R. and Gopinath, R., 2014. Farmers’ Suicides in India:

Magnitudes, Trends, and Spatial Patterns, 1997-2012. Journal, 4(2), pp.53-83.

Narayanamoorthy, A. and Kalamkar, S.S., 2006. Is BT cotton cultivation economically viable

for Indian farmers? An empirical analysis. Economic and Political Weekly, pp.2716-2724.

Narayanamoorthy, A., 2006. Potential for drip and sprinkler irrigation in India. Draft prepared

for the IWMI-CPWF project on ‘Strategic Analysis of National River Linking Project of India.

Narayanamoorthy, A., 2008. Drip Irrigation and Rainfed Crop Cultivation Nexus: The Case of

Cotton Crop. Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 63(3), pp.1-15.

Narayanamoorthy, A., 2015. Groundwater depletion and water extraction cost: some evidence

from South India. International Journal of Water Resources Development, 31(4), pp.604-617.

Natarajan, N., Brickell, K. and Parsons, L., 2019. Climate change adaptation and precarity

across the rural–urban divide in Cambodia: Towards a ‘climate precarity’approach.

Environment and Planning E: Nature and Space, 2(4), pp.899-921.

National Family Health Survey. 2016. NFHS-4, 2015-16: India. Mumbai: International

Institute for Population Sciences.

Page 255: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

255

National Sample Survey Organisation. 1992. Land and Livestock Holdings Survey NSS 48th

Round Report 407. India: Department Of Statistics, Ministry of Planning and Programme

Implementation, Government of India. pp.1-212.

National Sample Survey Organisation. 2013a. Income, Expenditure, Productive Assets and

Indebtedness of Agricultural Households In India, NSS 70th Round, Ministry of Statistics and

Programme Implementation, New Delhi.

National Sample Survey Organisation. 2013b. Key Indicators of Debt and Investment in India.

NSS 70th Round, Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation, New Delhi.

National Sample Survey Organisation. 2013c. Some Aspects of Farming in India. NSS 70th

Round, Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation, New Delhi.

National Sample Survey Organisation. 2013d. Some Characteristics Of Agricultural

Households In India 2013. NSS 70th Round, Ministry of Statistics and Programme

Implementation, New Delhi.

National Sample Survey Organisation. 2013e. Household Assets and Liabilities, NSS 70th

Round, Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation, New Delhi.

National Sample Survey Organisation. 2014. Key Indicators of Situation of Agricultural

Households in India, NSS 70th Round, MoSPI, New Delhi, December.

New Indian Express. 2020a. Telangana govt working on ‘comprehensive’ agricultural

policy. Available:https://www.newindianexpress.com/states/telangana/2020/may/24/kcr-

creating-win win-situation-for-farmers-of-telangana-2147248.html. Last accessed 10/12/20.

New Indian Express 2020b. Nearly 70 per cent informal sector employees have no job contract:

Survey. Available:https://www.newindianexpress.com/thesundaystandard/2020/jun/14/nearly

-70-per-cent-informal-sector-employees-have-no-job-contract-survey-2156257.html.

Last accessed 10/12/20.

News Minute. 2020. As paddy cultivation hits new high in Telangana, procurement delays

haunt KCR govt. Available: https://www.thenewsminute.com/article/paddy-cultivation-hits-

new-high-telangana-procurement-delays-haunt-kcr-govt-123909. Last accessed 10/12/20.

Newsclick. 2018. Telangana Polls: TRS Set to Face Ire of Unemployed Youth. Available:

https://www.newsclick.in/telangana-polls-trs-set-face-ire-unemployed-youth. Last accessed

10/12/20.

Page 256: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

256

Nilotpal, K., 2011. Egoism, anomie and masculinity: suicide in rural South India (Andhra

Pradesh). Doctoral dissertation, The London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE).

Norberg, M.B., 2020. Regulative Shifts Paving the Way for Agrarian Change. In The Political

Economy of Agrarian Change in Latin America (pp. 165-208). Palgrave Macmillan, Cham.

OECD. 2018. Agricultural Policies in India, OECD Food and Agricultural Reviews, OECD

Publishing, Paris. https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264302334-en. pp.1-296.

Olsen, W., 1993. Competition and power in rural markets: a case study from Andhra Pradesh.

ids bulletin, 24(3), pp.83-89.

Oya, C., 2010. Agro-pessimism, capitalism and agrarian change. The political economy of

Africa, pp.85-110.

Oya, C., 2011. Agriculture in the World Bank: Blighted harvest persists. In: Bayliss, Kate and

Fine, Ben and Van Waeyenberge, Elisa, (eds.), The Political Economy of Development. The

World Bank, Neoliberalism and Development Research. London: Pluto Press, pp. 146-187.

Pahuja, S., Tovey, C., Foster, S. and Garduno, H., 2010. Deep wells and prudence: towards

pragmatic action for addressing groundwater overexploitation in India. Washington, DC:

World Bank.

Pal, D., 2015, January. Linking credit with other markets: a review of the issues in rural

economies. In Forum for Development Studies. 42(1). pp. 159-178.

Panagariya, A., 2004, December. India’s trade reform. In India Policy Forum Volume 1,

Brookings Institution Press. pp. 1-57.

Parayil, G., 2003. Mapping technological trajectories of the Green Revolution and the Gene

Revolution from modernization to globalization. Research policy, 32(6), pp.971-990.

Parthasarathy, D., 2013,. The Eccentricity of Global—Regional Linkages: Provincial Capital

and Divergent Urban Growth Patterns in Coastal Andhra. In International Conference on

Regional Towns and Migration: Interrogating Transnationalism and Development in South

Asia, University of Amsterdam.

Pastore, F., 2018. Why is youth unemployment so high and different across countries?. IZA

World of Labor.

Patel, R., 2013. The Long Green Revolution. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 40(1), pp.1–63.

Page 257: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

257

Pattenden, J., 2018. The politics of classes of labour: fragmentation, reproduction zones and

collective action in Karnataka, India. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 45(5-6), pp.1039-1059.

Pender, J.L., 2007. Agricultural technology choices for poor farmers in less-favored areas of

South and East Asia (No. 589-2016-39793). pp.1-196.

Pingali, P.L., 2012. Green Revolution: Impacts, limits, and the path ahead. Proceedings of the

National Academy of Sciences, 109(31), pp.12302-12308.

Pingle, G., 2011. Irrigation in Telangana: the rise and fall of tanks. Economic and Political

Weekly, pp.123-130.

Plewis, I., 2019. Adopting hybrid Bt cotton: using interrupted time-series analysis to assess its

effects on farmers in Northern India. Review of Agrarian Studies, 9 (2), pp.5-23.

Posani, B., 2009. Farmer suicides and the political economy of agrarian distress in India.

Development Studies Institute Working Paper Series, (09-95).

Poulton, C., Kydd, J. and Dorward, A., 2006. Overcoming market constraints on pro‐poor

agricultural growth in Sub‐Saharan Africa. Development policy review, 24(3), pp.243-277.

Pradhan, N., 2013. Persistence of Informal Credit in Rural India: Evidence from ‘All-India

Debt and Investment Survey’ and Beyond (No. 80381). University Library of Munich,

Germany.

Prasad, N.P., 2015. Agrarian class and caste relations in ‘United’Andhra Pradesh, 1956–

2014. Economic and Political Weekly, 1(16), pp.77-83.

Qaim, M., Subramanian, A. and Sadashivappa, P., 2009. Commercialized GM crops and

yield. Nature Biotechnology, 27(9), pp.803-804.

Rahman, A. and Mishra, S., 2019. Does non-farm income affect food security? Evidence from

India. The Journal of Development Studies, pp.1-20.

Rajan, A., Ghosh, K. and Shah, A., 2020. Carbon footprint of India’s groundwater

irrigation. Carbon Management, 11(3), pp.265-280.

Ramachandran, V.K., 2011. The state of agrarian relations in India today. The Marxist, 27(1-

2), pp.51-89.

Page 258: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

258

Ramakumar, R., 2009, March. Indian Agriculture Under Economic Reforms: A Preliminary

Review. In International conference on “The Crisis of Neo-liberalism in India: Challenges and

Alternatives” Organised by Tata Institute of Social Sciences (TISS), Mumbai and International

Development Economics Associates (IDEAs). pp. 13-15.

Ramakumar, R. and Raut, K., 2011. Agricultural Employment in a Vidarbha Village: Results

from a Resurvey. Review of Agrarian Studies, 1(1). pp.63-100.

Ramakumar, R., Raut, K. and Kamble, T., 2017. Moving Out of Cotton: Notes from a

Longitudinal Survey in Two Vidarbha Villages. Review of Agrarian Studies, 7(1). pp.107-132.

Ramamurthy, P., 2011. Rearticulating caste: the global cottonseed commodity chain and the

paradox of smallholder capitalism in south India. Environment and planning A, 43(5), pp.1035-

1056.

Ramani, S.V. and Thutupalli, A., 2015. Emergence of controversy in technology transitions:

Green Revolution and Bt cotton in India. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 100,

pp.198-212.

Ramanjaneyulu, G.V. and Rao, V.R., 2008. Sustaining Agriculture-Based Livelihoods:

Experiences with non-pesticidal management in Andhra Pradesh. Development, 51(4), pp.541-

546.

Ramprasad, V., 2017. Institutions and social-ecological synergies in Indian agriculture.

Doctoral dissertation, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.

Ramprasad, V., 2019. Debt and vulnerability: indebtedness, institutions and smallholder

agriculture in South India. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 46(6), pp.1286-1307.

Rao, K.P.C., 2008. Changes in dry land agriculture in the semi-arid tropics of India, 1975–

2004. The European Journal of Development Research, 20(4), pp.562-578.

Rao, C. H. 2014. The New Telangana State. A Perspective for Inclusive and Sustainable

Development. Economic and Political Weekly 49(9), pp.10–13.

Rao, A.S. 2018a. Telangana starts free, 24-hour power supply to farmers. Available:

https://www.hindustantimes.com/india-news/telangana-starts-free-24-hour-power-supply-to-

farmers/story-jdQCZIRh1oEzkObm9cC3UN.html. Last accessed 9th October 2018.

Page 259: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

259

Rao, S., 2018b. Gender and class relations in rural India. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 45(5-

6), pp.950-968.

Rawal, V. and Swaminathan, M., 2011. Income inequality and caste in village India. Review

of Agrarian Studies, 1(2), pp.108-33.

Reddy, D.N., 2006. Economic reforms, agrarian crisis and rural distress. Prof. B. Janaradhan

Rao Memorial Lecture, Department of Public Administration and Human Resource

Management Kakatiya University Warangal, Andhra Pradesh.

Reddy, A.A., 2011. Sources of Agricultural Growth in Andhra Pradesh, India: Scope for Small

Farmer Participation. The Indian Economic Journal, 59(3), pp.87-108.

Reddy, D. N. 2014. Farmers’ Indebtedness and Agricultural Credit Situation in Andhra

Pradesh. Centre For Social Development Working Paper, Hyderabad. 1 (1), pp.1-29.

Reddy, A.A., Reddy, G.P., Rani, C.R., Reddy, A.N. and Bantilan, M.C.S., 2014a. Regional

disparities in rural and agricultural development in undivided Andhra Pradesh, India. ICRISAT

Working Paper Series No 47. pp.1-57.

Reddy, D.N., Reddy, A.A., Nagaraj, N. and Bantilan, C., 2014b. Rural non-farm employment

and rural transformation in India. ICRISAT Research Programmes Markets Institutions and

Policies, Working Paper Series, (57), pp.1-28.

Reddy, K.S., Kumar, M., Maruthi, V., Umesha, B., Vijayalaxmi and Rao, C.N., 2014. Climate

change analysis in southern Telangana region, Andhra Pradesh using LARS-WG

model. Current Science, 107(1), pp.54-62.

Reddy, A.A., Raju, S.S. and Bose, A. 2019. Farmers’ Income, Indebtedness and Agrarian

Distress in India.. The Microfinance Review. 12(1). pp.19-38.

Reddy, A., 2020a. Agrarian Change in Telangana: A Discussion on Policy Options. Economic

Affairs, 65(2), pp.137-150.

Reddy, A. A. 2020b. Youth employment and Guarantee Programme. Available:

https://telanganatoday.com/youth-employment-and-guarantee-programme. Last accessed

10/12/20.

Ribot, J.C. and Peluso, N.L., 2003. A theory of access. Rural sociology, 68(2), pp.153-181.

Page 260: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

260

Rigg, J., Salamanca, A. and Parnwell, M., 2012. Joining the dots of agrarian change in Asia: A

25 year view from Thailand. World Development, 40(7), pp.1469-1481.

Rigg, J., Phongsiri, M., Promphakping, B., Salamanca, A. and Sripun, M., 2019. Who will tend

the farm? Interrogating the ageing Asian farmer. The Journal of Peasant Studies, pp.1-20.

Roy, T., 2007. A delayed revolution: environment and agrarian change in India. Oxford

Review of Economic Policy, 23(2), pp.239-250.

Ruben, R. and Pender, J., 2004. Rural diversity and heterogeneity in less-favoured areas: the

quest for policy targeting. Food policy, 29(4), pp.303-320.

Sahay, G.R., 2010. Globalization, Liberalization and Agrarian Distress: A Study of Suicides

among Farmers in India. Paper for 6th Global Labour University Conference, Berlin. pp.1-41.

Sanghera, T. 2019. When Rural Jobs Disappear, Women Are The First To Lose Out. Available:

https://www.indiaspend.com/when-rural-jobs-disappear-women-are-the-first-to-lose-out/.

Last accessed 3rd April 2020.

Sanyal, K. (2008). Rethinking capitalist development: Primitive accumulation,

governmentality and post-colonial capitalism. New Delhi: Routledge.

Schnurr, M.A., 2012. Inventing Makhathini: Creating a prototype for the dissemination of

genetically modified crops into Africa. Geoforum, 43(4), pp.784-792.

Schnurr, M.A., 2015. GMO 2.0: Genetically modified crops and the push for Africa’s green

revolution. Canadian Food Studies/La Revue canadienne des études sur l'alimentation, 2(2),

pp.201-208.

Schnurr, M.A., 2017a. Can genetically modified crops help the poor? Incomplete answers to a

flawed question. Canadian Journal of Development Studies/Revue canadienne d'études du

développement , 38(1). pp.125-128.

Schnurr, M.A., 2017b. GMOs and poverty: yield gaps, differentiated impacts and the search

for alternative questions. Canadian Journal of Development Studies/Revue canadienne

d'études du développement, 38(1), pp.149-157.

Schnurr, M.A., 2019. Africa's gene revolution: genetically modified crops and the future of

African agriculture. McGill-Queen's Press-MQUP.

Page 261: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

261

Schultz, T.W., 1964. Economic growth from traditional agriculture. Agricultural Sciences for

Developing Nations, pp.185-205.

Scoones, I., 2006. Science, agriculture and the politics of policy: The case of biotechnology in

India. Orient Blackswan.

Scoones, I., 2008. Mobilizing against GM crops in India, south Africa and brazil. Journal of

agrarian change, 8(2‐3), pp.315-344.

Scott, C.A. and Shah, T., 2004. Groundwater overdraft reduction through agricultural energy

policy: insights from India and Mexico. International Journal of Water Resources

Development, 20(2), pp.149-164.

Scott, C.A. and Sharma, B., 2009. Energy supply and the expansion of groundwater irrigation

in the Indus‐Ganges Basin. International Journal of River Basin Management, 7(2), pp.119-

124.

Sekhri, S., 2011. Public provision and protection of natural resources: Groundwater irrigation

in rural India. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 3(4), pp.29-55.

Servet, J.M. and Saiag, H., 2013. Household over-indebtedness in northern and southern

countries: a macro-perspective. Chapter 1 in Guérin, I., Morvant-Roux, S. and Villarreal, M.

eds., Microfinance, debt and over-indebtedness: juggling with money. Routledge. pp.24-46.

Shah, A. and Harriss-White, B., 2011. Resurrecting scholarship on agrarian transformations.

Economic and Political Weekly, pp.13-18.

Shah, E., 2005. Local and global elites join hands: Development and diffusion of Bt cotton

technology in Gujarat. Economic and Political Weekly, pp.4629-4639.

Shah, E., 2008. What makes crop biotechnology find its roots? The technological culture of Bt

cotton in Gujarat, India.The European Journal of Development Research, 20(3), pp.432-447.

Shah, E., 2011. Social Responses to Crop Biotechnology: Bt Cotton Cultivation in Gujarat,

India. In Engineering Earth. Springer, Dordrecht. pp. 217-233.

Shah, E., 2012. ‘A life wasted making dust’: affective histories of dearth, death, debt and

farmers' suicides in India.The Journal of Peasant Studies, 39(5), pp.1159-1179.

Shah, M,. Rao., R. & Shankar, P.S.V. 2007. Rural credit in 20th century India: overview of

history and perspectives, Economic & Political Weekly, 42(15), pp.1351–1365.

Page 262: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

262

Shah, T., Singh, O.P. and Mukherji, A., 2006. Some aspects of South Asia's groundwater

irrigation economy: analyses from a survey in India, Pakistan, Nepal Terai and Bangladesh.

Hydrogeology Journal, 14(3), pp.286-309.

Shah, T., 2009. India’s ground water irrigation economy: The challenge of balancing

livelihoods and environment. Quarterly Journal of Central Ground Water Board, pp.21-37.

Shah, T., 2010. Taming the anarchy: Groundwater governance in South Asia. Routledge.

Shah, T., 2012. Community response to aquifer development: distinct patterns in India's

alluvial and hard rock aquifer areas. Irrigation and Drainage, 61, pp.14-25.

Shah, T., Giordano, M. and Mukherji, A., 2012. Political economy of the energy-groundwater

nexus in India: exploring issues and assessing policy options. Hydrogeology Journal, 20(5),

pp.995-1006.

Sharma, B.R., Gulati, A., Mohan, G., Manchanda, S., Ray, I. and Amarasinghe, U., 2018.

Water productivity mapping of major Indian crops. NABARD and ICRIER Report, pp.1-212.

Sharma, K.K., Dumbala, S.R. and Bhatnagar-Mathur, P., 2014. Biotech approaches for crop

improvement in the semi-arid tropics. In Plant Biotechnology Springer, Cham. pp. 193-207.

Shashikala, A.V. 2015. Geographical Study Impact Of Climate Change On Agricultural

Productivity In Andhra Pradesh . Hyderabad: University Grants Commission New Delhi. pp.1-

227.

Siddiqui, I. 2020. The flawed spin to India’s cotton story. Available:

https://www.thehindu.com/opinion/lead/the-flawed-spin-to-indias-cotton-

story/article30627778.ece. Last accessed 28th April 2020.

Sidhu, B.S., Kandlikar, M. and Ramankutty, N., 2020. Power tariffs for groundwater irrigation

in India: A comparative analysis of the environmental, equity, and economic tradeoffs. World

Development, 128(2020), pp.1-13.

Siegfried, T., Sobolowski, S., Raj, P., Fishman, R., Vasquez, V., Narula, K., Lall, U. and Modi,

V., 2010. Modeling irrigated area to increase water, energy, and food security in semiarid India.

Weather, Climate, and Society, 2(4), pp.255-270.

Page 263: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

263

Singh, C., Rahman, A., Srinivas, A. and Bazaz, A., 2018. Risks and responses in rural India:

Implications for local climate change adaptation action. Climate Risk Management, 21, pp.52-

68.

Singh, S. and Bhogal, S., 2016. Punjab’s Small Peasantry. Critical Perspectives on Agrarian

Transition: India in the global debate, pp.276-293.

Sinha, S., 2020. The politics of markets: Farmer–trader relations under neoliberalism in Punjab,

India. Journal of Agrarian Change, 20(2), pp.255-269.

Sishodia, R.P., Shukla, S., Graham, W.D., Wani, S.P. and Garg, K.K., 2016. Bi-decadal

groundwater level trends in a semi-arid south indian region: Declines, causes and management.

Journal of Hydrology: Regional Studies, 8, pp.43-58.

Sishodia, R.P., Shukla, S., Graham, W.D., Wani, S.P., Jones, J.W. and Heaney, J., 2017.

Current and future groundwater withdrawals: Effects, management and energy policy options

for a semi-arid Indian watershed. Advances in Water Resources, 110 (2017), pp.459-475.

Skelton, T., 2001. Cross-cultural research: issues of power, positionality and ‘race’. Qualitative

methodologies for geographers: Issues and debates, pp.87-100.

Smale, M., 2017. GMOs and poverty: the relationship between improved seeds and rural

transformations. Canadian Journal of Development Studies/Revue canadienne d'études du

développement, 38(1), pp.139-148.

Smilovic, M., Gleeson, T. and Siebert, S., 2015. The limits of increasing food production with

irrigation in India. Food Security, 7(4), pp.835-856.

Smith, J., Yeluripati, J., Smith, P. and Nayak, D.R., 2020. Potential yield challenges to scale-

up of zero budget natural farming. Nature sustainability, 3(3), pp.247-252.

Spielman, D.J., Kolady, D.E., Cavalieri, A. and Rao, N.C., 2014. The seed and agricultural

biotechnology industries in India: An analysis of industry structure, competition, and policy

options. Food Policy, 45, pp.88-100.

Springer, S., Birch, K. and MacLeavy, J. eds., 2016. Handbook of neoliberalism. Routledge.

Srinivasulu, K. 2002. Caste, Class and Social Articulation in Andhra Pradesh: Mapping

Differential Regional Trajectories. Working Paper 179. London: Overseas Development

Institute. pp.1-72.

Page 264: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

264

Srinivasalu, K., 2015. Agrarian Crisis and Farmers’ Suicides: Reflecting on The Green

Revolution Model. CMDR Monograph Series, (75). pp.1-17.

Srivastava, R., Padhi, B. and Ranjan, R., 2020. Structural Change and Increasing Precarity of

Employment in India. In Development Challenges of India After Twenty Five Years of

Economic Reforms. Springer, Singapore. pp. 133-156.

Stewart, B.A., 2016. Dryland farming. Reference Module in Food Science. pp.1-10.

Stone, G.D., Brush, S., Busch, L., Cleveland, D.A., Dove, M.R., Herring, R.J., Joly, P.B.,

Mosse, D., Scoones, I., Shah, E. and Tripp, R., 2007. Agricultural deskilling and the spread of

genetically modified cotton in Warangal. Current anthropology, 48(1), pp.67-103.

Stone, G.D., 2011. Field versus farm in Warangal: Bt cotton, higher yields, and larger

questions. World Development, 39(3), pp.387-398.

Stone, G.D., 2012. Constructing Facts: By Cotton Narratives in India. Economic and Political

Weekly, pp.62-70.

Stone, G.D., Flachs, A. and Diepenbrock, C., 2014. Rhythms of the herd: Long term dynamics

in seed choice by Indian farmers. Technology in Society, 36, pp.26-38.

Stone, G.D. and Flachs, A., 2015. Seeking sustainability for smallholders: Bt cotton in India.

Analyses: Africa’s Future, pp.119-127.

Stone, G.D. and Flachs, A., 2018. The ox fall down: path-breaking and technology treadmills

in Indian cotton agriculture. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 45(7), pp.1272-1296.

Stone, G.D., 2019. Commentary: New histories of the Indian Green Revolution. The

Geographical Journal, 185(2), pp.243-250.

Subramanian, K., 2015. Revisiting the Green Revolution: Irrigation and food production in

twentieth-century India (Doctoral dissertation, King's College London).

Sultana, F., 2013. Water, technology, and development: transformations of development

technonatures in changing waterscapes. Environment and Planning D: Society and

Space, 31(2), pp.337-353.

Surendra A, Rao N and Bhattarai M. 2014b. Social Safety Net Programs in Selected Villages

of Andhra Pradesh. Description: SaciWATER working paper 02/2014. Documentation. South

Asia Consortium for Interdisciplinary Water Resources Studies. Hyderabad. pp.1-48.

Page 265: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

265

Surendra, V., The Moneylender as Middleman: Formal Credit Supply and Informal Loans in

Rural India. Job Market Paper. pp.1-68.

Suresh, A., Ramasundaram, P., Samuel, J. and Wankhade, S., 2013. Impact of technology and

policy on growth and instability of agricultural production: the case of cotton in India. Indian

Journal of Agricultural Sciences, 83(8), pp.939-48.

Suri, K.C., 2002. Democratic process and electoral politics in Andhra Pradesh, India. London:

Overseas Development Institute. pp.1-95.

Swain, M., 2000. Agricultural development and interlocked factor markets. Indian Journal of

Agricultural Economics, 55(3), pp.308-316.

Swaminathan, M. and Baksi, S. eds., 2017. How Do Small Farmers Fare?: Evidence from

Village Studies in India. Tulika Books.

Swaminathan, M. and Rawal, V., 2011. Are there benefits from the cultivation of Bt cotton? A

comment based on data from a Vidarbha village. Review of Agrarian Studies, 1(1). pp.101-

124.

Swyngedouw, E., 2009. The political economy and political ecology of the hydro‐social

cycle. Journal of contemporary water research & education, 142(1), pp.56-60.

Taro Pumps. 2020. A Timeline of Texmo Industries' History. Available:

https://www.taropumps.com/about-us/history. Last accessed 10/2/21.

Taylor, M., 2011. ‘Freedom from poverty is not for free’: rural development and the

microfinance crisis in Andhra Pradesh, India. Journal of Agrarian Change, 11(4), pp.484-504.

Taylor, M., 2012. The Antinomies of ‘Financial Inclusion’: Debt, Distress and the Workings

of Indian Microfinance. Journal of Agrarian Change, 12(4), pp.601-610.

Taylor, M., 2013a. Liquid Debts: credit, groundwater and the social ecology of agrarian distress

in Andhra Pradesh, India. Third World Quarterly, 34(4), pp.691-709.

Taylor, M., 2013b. Climate change, relational vulnerability and human security: rethinking

sustainable adaptation in agrarian environments. Climate and Development, 5(4), pp.318-327.

Taylor, M. and Bhasme, S., 2020. Between deficit rains and surplus populations: The political

ecology of a climate-resilient village in South India. Geoforum. pp.1-10.

Page 266: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

266

Telangana Today. 2020. Affordable electricity is a right. Available:

https://telanganatoday.com/affordable-electricity-is-a-right. Last accessed 10/2/21.

The Hans India. 2020. Making farmer the king: KCR ushers in new agricultural

policy. Available: https://www.thehansindia.com/telangana/making-farmer-the-king-kcr-

ushers-in-new-agriculture-policy-623280. Last accessed 10/12/20.

The Print. 2020. Bihar Rajasthan amongst states with steep rise in unemployed in 2018-19

youth hit hardest. Available: https://theprint.in/economy/bihar-rajasthan-among-states-with-

steep-rise-in-unemployment-in-2018-19-youth-hardest-hit/442713/. Last accessed 10/12/20.

Timmer, C.P., 2002. Agriculture and economic development. Handbook of agricultural

economics, 2, pp.1487-1546.

Times of India. 2019. Central govt’s 10% quota move to benefit 21% of Telangana's

Population. Available: https://timesofindia.indiatimes.com/city/hyderabad/central-govts-10-

quota-move-to-benefit-21-of-telanganas-population/articleshow/67454890.cms. Last accessed

10/12/20.

Tiwary, R. and Sabatier, J.L., 2009. Anthropological perspectives on groundwater irrigation:

ethnographic evidence from a village in Bist Doab, Punjab. Groundwater Governance in the

Indo-Gangetic and Yellow River Basins, Chapter 12, pp.221-229.

Todhunter, C. 2020. Dependency, Distress and No Durable Agronomic Benefits: The Story of

Bt Cotton in India. Available: https://www.counterpunch.org/2020/03/16/dependency-

distress-and-no-durable-agronomic-benefits-the-story-of-bt-cotton-in-india/. Last accessed

28th April 2020.

Todmal, R.S., 2019. Droughts and agriculture in the semi-arid region of Maharashtra, western

India. Weather, Climate, and Society, 11(4), pp.741-754.

Tribune India. 2020. Telangana emerges as ‘rice bowl’ of India. Available:

https://www.tribuneindia.com/news/nation/telangana-emerges-as-rice-bowl-of-india-99570.

Last accessed 10/12/20.

Tripp, R., 2001. Agricultural technology policies for rural development. Development Policy

Review, 19(4), pp.479-489.

Vaditya, V., 2017. Economic Liberalisation and Farmers’ Suicides in Andhra Pradesh (1995–

2014). South Asia Research, 37(2), pp.194-212.

Page 267: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

267

Vakulabharanam, V., 2004. Immiserizing growth: globalization and agrarian change in

Telangana, south India between 1985 and 2000. PhD thesis submitted to the Economics

Department of University of Massachusetts Amherst.

Vakulabharanam, V., 2005. Growth and distress in a South Indian peasant economy during the

era of economic liberalisation. Journal of Development Studies, 41(6), pp.971-997.

Vakulabharanam, V., and S. Motiram. 2014.“The Dissolution of 'United'Andhra Pradesh:

Insights from Growth and Distribution Process, 1956–2010.” Economic and Political Weekly

49 (21) pp.59–70.

Van der Ploeg, J.D., 2014. Peasant-driven agricultural growth and food sovereignty. Journal of

Peasant Studies, 41(6), pp.999-1030.

Vasavi, A.R., 2009. Suicides and the making of India's agrarian distress. South African Review

of Sociology, 40(1), pp.94-108.

Vasavi, A.R., 2014. Debt and its social entrapments. Women's Studies Quarterly, 42(1/2),

pp.23-37.

Vasavi, A.R., 2019. The Displaced Threshing Yard: Involutions of the Rural. Review of

Development and Change, 24(1), pp.31-54.

Vasavi, A.R., 2020. The tiger and the tube well: malevolence in rural India. Critical Asian

Studies, pp.1-17.

Vásquez, L.A., 2020. If you don't owe, you don't own: debt, discipline and growth in rural

Colombia. Journal of Rural Studies, 78, pp.271-281.

Veluguri, D., Bump, J.B., Venkateshmurthy, N.S., Mohan, S., Pulugurtha, K.T. and Jaacks,

L.M., 2021. Political analysis of the adoption of the Zero-Budget natural farming program in

Andhra Pradesh, India. Agroecology and Sustainable Food Systems, pp.1-24.

Venkateshwarlu, D. and Da Corta, L., 2001. Transformations in the age and gender of unfree

workers on hybrid cotton seed farms in Andhra Pradesh. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 28(3),

pp.1-36.

Venkateswar, S. and Bandyopadhyay, S. eds., 2016. Globalisation and the Challenges of

Development in Contemporary India. Springer.

Page 268: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

268

Venot, J.P., Zwarteveen, M., Kuper, M., Boesveld, H., Bossenbroek, L., Kooij, S.V.D.,

Wanvoeke, J., Benouniche, M., Errahj, M., Fraiture, C.D. and Verma, S., 2014. Beyond the

promises of technology: A review of the discourses and actors who make drip

irrigation. Irrigation and drainage, 63(2), pp.186-194.

Verma, S. and Shah, M., 2019. Drought-proofing through groundwater recharge: lessons from

Chief Ministers’ initiatives in four Indian states. IWMI.

Vijayabaskar, M., 2017. The Agrarian question amidst populist welfare-interpreting Tamil

Nadu's emerging rural economy. Economic and Political Weekly, 52(46). pp.67-72.

Wada, Y., Van Beek, L.P.H. and Bierkens, M.F., 2012. Nonsustainable groundwater sustaining

irrigation: A global assessment. Water Resources Research, 48(6). pp.1-18.

Watson, S., 2013. The limits of self help: policy and political economy in rural Andhra Pradesh.

Doctoral dissertation, University of Manchester.

Watts, M., 1983. Hazards and crises: A political economy of drought and famine in Northern

Nigeria. Antipode, 15(1), pp.24-34.

Wield, D., Chataway, J. and Bolo, M., 2010. Issues in the political economy of agricultural

biotechnology. Journal of Agrarian Change, 10(3), pp.342-366.

Wikipedia. 2021. Map of Telangana. Available:

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Telangana#/media/File:IN-TG.svg. Last accessed 10/2/21.

Zhou, Y., 2010. Smallholder agriculture, sustainability and the Syngenta Foundation. Syngenta

Foundation for Sustainable Agriculture, pp.1-15.

Page 269: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

269

Appendix

Appendix 1 – List of interviewees

No. Interview

Code

Profession Caste Class Gender Date Location

1 A1 Academic N/A N/A M 30/7/18 Hyderabad

2 A2 Academic N/A N/A M 1/8/18 Hyderabad

3 A3 NGO N/A N/A M 30/7/18 Hyderabad

4 A4 Academic N/A N/A F 23/8/18 Hyderabad

5 A5 Academic N/A N/A M 23/8/18 Hyderabad

6 A6 Academic N/A N/A M 23/8/18 Hyderabad

7 A7 Academic N/A N/A M 23/8/18 Hyderabad

8 A8 NGO N/A N/A M 30/7/18 Hyderabad

9 B1 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 29/4/19 Kacharam

10 B2 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 2/5/19 Kacharam

11 B3 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 1/5/19 Kacharam

12 B4 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 2/5/19 Kacharam

13 B5 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 29/4/19 Kacharam

14 B6 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 24/6/19 Kacharam

15 B7 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 2/5/19 Kacharam

16 B8 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 29/4/19 Kacharam

17 B9 Farmer SC Smallholder F 30/4/19 Kacharam

18 B10 Farmer SC Smallholder M 30/4/19 Kacharam

19 B11 Farmer SC Smallholder F 30/4/19 Kacharam

20 B12 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 1/5/19 Kacharam

21 B13 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 17/4/19 Kacharam

22 B14 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 1/5/19 Kacharam

23 B15 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 5/4/19 Kacharam

24 B16 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 19/4/19 Kacharam

25 B17 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 12/4/19 Kacharam

26 B18 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 1/4/19 Kacharam

27 B19 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 2/4/19 Kacharam

28 B20 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 4/4/19 Kacharam

29 B21 Farmer SC Smallholder M 22/4/19 Kacharam

30 C1 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 7/6/19 Kacharam

31 C2 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 12/6/19 Kacharam

32 C3 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 7/6/19 Kacharam

33 C4 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 5/6/19 Kacharam

34 C5 Farmer OBC Medium F 11/6/19 Kacharam

35 C6 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 10/6/19 Kacharam

36 C7 Farmer OBC Medium F 10/6/19 Kacharam

37 C8 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 7/6/19 Kacharam

38 C9 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 13/6/19 Kacharam

39 C10 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 12/6/19 Kacharam

40 C11 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 13/6/19 Kacharam

41 C12 Farmer SC Smallholder M 17/6/19 Kacharam

42 C13 Farmer SC Smallholder M 17/6/19 Kacharam

43 C14 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 6/6/19 Kacharam

Page 270: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

270

No. Interview

Code

Profession Caste Class Gender Date Location

44 C15 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 10/6/19 Kacharam

45 C16 Farmer OBC Medium F 14/6/19 Kacharam

46 C17 Farmer ST Smallholder F 4/6/19 Kacharam

47 C18 Farmer SC Smallholder F 20/6/19 Kacharam

48 C19 Farmer SC Smallholder M 20/6/19 Kacharam

49 C20 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 12/6/19 Kacharam

50 C21 Input

Dealer

N/A N/A M 4/6/19 Devarakonda

51 C22 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 18/6/19 Kacharam

52 C23 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 18/6/19 Kacharam

53 C24 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 13/6/19 Kacharam

54 C25 Farmer OBC Medium F 21/6/19 Kacharam

55 C26 Shop

Owner

Muslim N/A M 17/6/19 Kacharam

56 C27 Farmer ST Smallholder M 19/6/19 Kacharam

57 C28 Farmer SC Smallholder M 21/6/19 Kacharam

58 C29 Farmer SC Smallholder F 21/6/19 Kacharam

59 C30 Farmer SC Smallholder F 18/6/19 Kacharam

60 C31 Farmer SC Smallholder M 18/6/19 Kacharam

61 C32 Farmer SC Smallholder F 6/6/19 Kacharam

62 C33 Farmer SC Smallholder M 6/6/19 Kacharam

63 C34 Farmer SC Smallholder M 19/6/19 Kacharam

64 C35 Farmer SC Smallholder M 24/6/19 Kacharam

65 C36 Farmer SC Smallholder M 21/6/19 Kacharam

66 C37 Farmer SC Smallholder F 19/6/19 Kacharam

67 C38 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 17/6/19 Kacharam

68 C39 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 12/6/19 Kacharam

69 C40 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 4/6/19 Kacharam

70 C41 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 24/6/19 Kacharam

71 C42 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 4/6/19 Kacharam

72 C43 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 12/6/19 Kacharam

73 C44 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 5/6/19 Kacharam

74 C45 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 21/6/19 Kacharam

75 C46 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 11/6/19 Kacharam

76 C47 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 7/6/19 Kacharam

77 C48 Farmer OBC Medium F 11/6/19 Kacharam

78 C49 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 13/6/19 Kacharam

79 C50 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 6/6/19 Kacharam

80 C51 Farmer ST Smallholder M 4/6/19 Kacharam

81 C52 Mason Muslim N/A F 24/6/19 Kacharam

82 C53 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 5/6/19 Kacharam

83 C54 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 5/6/19 Kacharam

84 C55 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 24/6/19 Kacharam

85 C56 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 11/6/19 Kacharam

86 C57 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 10/6/19 Kacharam

87 C58 Farmer ST Smallholder F 25/6/19 Kacharam

Page 271: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

271

No. Interview

Code

Profession Caste Class Gender Date Location

88 C59 Farmer ST Smallholder M 25/6/19 Kacharam

89 C60 Input

Dealer

N/A N/A M 4/6/19 Devarakonda

90 C61 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 28/6/19 Kacharam

91 D1 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 27/6/19 Kacharam

92 D2 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 28/6/19 Kacharam

93 D3 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 1/7/19 Kacharam

94 D4 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 8/7/19 Kacharam

95 D5 Farmer OBC Medium M 9/7/19 Kacharam

96 D6 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 28/6/19 Kacharam

97 D7 Farmer OBC Medium M 1/7/19 Kacharam

98 D8 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 28/6/19 Kacharam

99 D9 Water

Witcher

OBC Smallholder M 11/7/19 Kacharam

100 D10 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 2/7/19 Kacharam

101 D11 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 2/7/19 Kacharam

102 D12 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 2/7/19 Kacharam

103 D13 Farmer OBC Medium F 9/7/19 Kacharam

104 D14 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 27/6/19 Kacharam

105 D15 Farmer SC Smallholder M 3/7/19 Kacharam

106 D16 Farmer SC Smallholder M 9/7/19 Kacharam

107 D17 Farmer SC Smallholder F 3/7/19 Kacharam

108 D18 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 26/6/19 Kacharam

109 D19 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 27/6/19 Kacharam

110 D20 Farmer OBC Medium F 27/6/19 Kacharam

111 D21 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 27/6/19 Kacharam

112 D22 Farmer SC Smallholder F 10/7/19 Kacharam

113 D23 Farmer SC Smallholder M 4/7/19 Kacharam

114 D24 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 28/6/19 Kacharam

115 D25 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 5/7/19 Kacharam

116 D26 Irrigation

Firm

N/A N/A M 15/7/19 Mallepally

117 D27 Farmer SC Smallholder F 10/7/19 Kacharam

118 D28 Farmer OBC Medium F 26/6/19 Kacharam

119 D29 Shop

Owner

Muslim N/A M 10/7/19 Kacharam

120 D30 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 26/6/19 Kacharam

121 D31 Farmer SC Smallholder M 10/7/19 Kacharam

122 D32 Farmer SC Smallholder F 11/7/19 Kacharam

123 D33 Farmer SC Smallholder M 4/7/19 Kacharam

124 D34 Farmer SC Smallholder M 10/7/19 Kacharam

125 D35 Farmer SC Smallholder F 3/7/19 Kacharam

126 D36 Farmer SC Smallholder M 5/7/19 Kacharam

127 D37 Farmer SC Smallholder F 4/7/19 Kacharam

128 D38 Farmer SC Smallholder M 3/7/19 Kacharam

129 D39 Farmer SC Smallholder F 10/7/19 Kacharam

Page 272: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

272

No. Interview

Code

Profession Caste Class Gender Date Location

130 D40 Farmer SC Smallholder F 10/7/19 Kacharam

131 D41 Farmer SC Smallholder F 4/7/19 Kacharam

132 D42 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 1/7/19 Kacharam

133 D43 Irrigation

Firm

N/A N/A M 15/7/19 Mallepally

134 D44 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 9/7/19 Kacharam

135 D45 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 8/7/19 Kacharam

136 D46 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 8/7/19 Kacharam

137 D47 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 8/7/19 Kacharam

138 D48 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 2/7/19 Kacharam

139 D49 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 8/7/19 Kacharam

140 D50 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 4/7/19 Kacharam

141 D51 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 5/7/19 Kacharam

142 D52 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 1/7/19 Kacharam

143 D53 Farmer OBC Medium F 26/6/19 Kacharam

144 D54 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 2/7/19 Kacharam

145 D55 Water

Witcher

OBC Smallholder M 11/7/19 Kacharam

146 D56 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 3/7/19 Kacharam

147 D57 Farmer ST Smallholder M 11/7/19 Kacharam

148 D58 Mason Muslim Smallholder M 5/7/19 Kacharam

149 D59 Irrigation

Firm

N/A N/A M 15/7/19 Mallepally

150 D60 Irrigation

Firm

N/A N/A M 15/7/19 Mallepally

151 D61 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 12/7/19 Kacharam

152 D62 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 12/7/19 Kacharam

153 D63 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 12/7/19 Kacharam

154 D64 Farmer OBC Smallholder M 5/7/19 Kacharam

155 D65 Farmer OBC Smallholder F 9/7/19 Kacharam

156 D66 Farmer ST Smallholder F 25/6/19 Kacharam

157 D67 Farmer ST Smallholder M 11/7/19 Kacharam

158 D68 Farmer ST Smallholder F 25/6/19

158 D69 Irrigation

Firm

N/A N/A M 15/7/19 Mallepally

Page 273: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

273

Appendix 2 – Interview coding example

Page 274: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

274

Appendix 3 – Interview questions

Page 275: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

275

Page 276: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

276

Page 277: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

277

Page 278: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

278

Page 279: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

279

Page 280: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

280

Page 281: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

281

Page 282: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

282

Page 283: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

283

Page 284: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

284

Page 285: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

285

Page 286: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

286

Page 287: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

287

Page 288: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

288

Page 289: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

289

Page 290: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

290

Page 291: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

291

Page 292: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

292

Page 293: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

293

Page 294: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

294

Tubewell companies

Name?

Mee peru?

Age?

Mee Vayasu?

Caste?

Mee Kulamu?

Landholding?

Meeku enni acrealu unnai?

Is this your main occupation?

Idhi mee okate vruti aa leka vere panlu kuda chestara?

What other occupations do you engage in?

Inka emi panlu chestaru?

When was this company set up?

Ee company epudu modalu chesinaru?

When was tubewell irrigation first adopted in Nalgonda/Telangana?

Borelu epudu ochhinai ee prantham lo? Telangana lo?

By whom? Why?

Evaru modalu pettinaru? Enduku?

When was tubewell irrigation first adopted widely?

Etlanti raitulu mundu borlu pettukunnaru?

Why?

Enduku?

Why/how has tubewell irrigation adoption increased in the past few decades in Nalgonda/Telangana?

Etlantivi marpulu occhinai gottapi bavulo pettadam?

How is tubewell irrigation adoption differentiated amongst your customers by:

Caste?

Konni kulamulu ekva pettukuntara thatvi borlu?

Landholding size?

Pedda bhoomi raitulu ekva pettukuntara borlu?

Gender?

Mogadulu adivalu ekwa pettukuntara?

Could you explain how tubewell irrigation works?

Gottapi baavu ela panjestundi? Meeru chappagaltara?

Who is involved in the irrigation installation?

Page 295: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

295

Gotappi baavu pettadanki evaru evaru untaru? Emi emi stagelu untai?

What are the different types of tubewell irrigation systems?

Etlantivi gottapi bavulu unntai? Enni feetlu pothai? Current aa diesel aa?

What are the different components needed for tubewell irrigation?

Emi emi parts avusaram gottapi bavvululo

What are the total average costs of installing tubewell irrigation?

Kharchulu entha antha kalpi oka system kosam? Feetlu patti?

Re-drilling?

Oka vela fail ai malli pettalante entha kharchu authundi?

Are sales in tubewell irrigation systems increasing/decreasing over last year? Five years? Ten years?

Mee company lo gottapi bavulu dwara labham ekva ostunadhe poina samvatsaram ninchi? Emi marpulu jarginayi

meeru mundu company pettinapudu nunchi?

What are the main crops used with tubewell irrigation?

Ev evi pantalaki vadutharu gotappi baavu thoti?

Page 296: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

296

Drilling rig operators

Name?

Mee peru?

Age?

Mee Vayasu?

Caste?

Mee Kulamu?

Landholding?

Meeku enni acrealu unnai?

Is this your main occupation?

Idhi mee okate vruti aa leka vere panlu kuda chestara?

What other occupations do you engage in?

Inka emi panlu chestaru?

When was this company set up?

Ee company epudu modalu chesinaru?

When was tubewell irrigation first adopted in Nalgonda/Telangana?

Borelu epudu ochhinai ee prantham lo? Telangana lo?

By whom? Why?

Evaru modalu pettinaru? Enduku?

When was tubewell irrigation first adopted widely?

Etlanti raitulu mundu borlu pettukunnaru?

Why?

Enduku?

Why/how has tubewell irrigation adoption increased in the past few decades in Nalgonda/Telangana?

Etlantivi marpulu occhinai gottapi bavulo pettadam?

How is tubewell irrigation adoption differentiated amongst your customers by:

Caste?

Konni kulamulu ekva pettukuntara thatvi borlu?

Landholding size?

Pedda bhoomi raitulu ekva pettukuntara borlu?

Gender?

Mogadulu adivalu ekwa pettukuntara?

Could you explain how tubewell irrigation works?

Gottapi baavu ela panjestundi? Meeru chappagaltara?

Who is involved in the irrigation installation?

Gotappi baavu pettadanki evaru evaru untaru? Emi emi stagelu untai?

Page 297: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

297

What are the different types of tubewell irrigation systems?

Etlantivi gottapi bavulu unntai? Enni feetlu pothai? Current aa diesel aa?

What are the different components needed for tubewell irrigation?

Emi emi parts avusaram gottapi bavvululo

What are the total average costs of installing tubewell irrigation?

Kharchulu entha antha kalpi oka system kosam? Feetlu patti?

Re-drilling?

Oka vela fail ai malli pettalante entha kharchu authundi?

Are sales in tubewell irrigation drilling increasing/decreasing over last year? Five years? Ten years?

Mee company lo gottapi bavulu dwara labham ekva ostunadhe poina samvatsaram ninchi? Emi marpulu jarginayi

meeru mundu company pettinapudu nunchi?

What are the main crops used with tubewell irrigation?

Ev evi pantalaki vadutharu gotappi baavu thoti?

How much do you charge for hire of your drilling rig?

Entha kharchu cheyale mee drill ki rent cheyalante?

Per day?

Roju ki?

Per square foot?

Feet vatti?

What is the average depth you drill for farmers?

Averagega enni feetlu drill chestaru raitulaki?

What is the highest depth you have drilled for a farmer?

Annitikante ekva feetlu entha thovvinaru oka raitu ki?

Etlanti raitu unde?

Peru? Bhoomi? Etlanti pantalaki?

How much did this cost?

Entha kharchu aindi?

Where is the highest demand coming from for the business?

Etlanti raitula nunchi ostunadi labham meeku ee business ki?

Why?

Enduku?

Domestic Water Use?

Meeru taguneelaku kuda thovvutara?

Page 298: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

298

Appendix 4 – Household survey questions

Page 299: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

299

Page 300: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

300

Page 301: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

301

Page 302: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

302

Page 303: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

303

Page 304: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

304

Page 305: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

305

Page 306: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

306

Page 307: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

307

Page 308: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

308

Page 309: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

309

Page 310: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

310

Page 311: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

311

Page 312: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

312

Page 313: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

313

Page 314: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

314

Page 315: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

315

Page 316: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

316

Page 317: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

317

Page 318: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

318

Page 319: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

319

Page 320: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

320

Page 321: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

321

Appendix 5 – Consent form English

Consent form

(Also available in printed or verbal Telugu format)

Research Project Title: Dried Up Livelihoods: The Political Economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in

India

Name of Researcher: Ambarish Karamchedu

Thank you for your interest in taking part in this research.

If you have any questions arising from the information sheet or explanation already given to you, please ask the

researcher before you to decide whether to join in. You will be given a copy of this consent form to keep and refer

to at any time. The original copy will be retained for the research team and will be scanned and shredded, with

the scanned copy being encrypted. Information used is subject to you giving your permission with this consent

form. If you are happy to participate please complete and sign the consent form below.

Please tick:

( ) I confirm that I have read the attached information sheet (Version 2.0, Date 28/11/2018) for the above

study and have had the opportunity to consider the information and ask questions and had these answered

satisfactorily.

( ) I understand that my participation in the study is voluntary and that I am free to withdraw at any time

without giving a reason and without detriment to myself. I understand that it will not be possible to remove my

data from the project once it has been anonymised and forms part of the data set. I agree to take part on this basis

( ) I agree to the interviews being audio / video recorded.

( ) I consent to being audio recorded and notes being written as part of the project (Leave blank if you do

not consent)

( ) I agree that pictures of my face may be used in publications

( ) I agree that any data collected may be published in anonymous form in academic books, reports or

journals

( ) I agree that the researchers/researchers at other institutions may contact me in future about other research

projects.

( ) I understand that the anonymised data can be used by research team members (translators, research

assistants).

( ) I agree that the researchers may retain my contact details in order to provide me with a summary of the

findings for this study.

Page 322: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

322

( ) I understand that there may be instances where during the course of the interview information is revealed

which means that the researchers will be obliged to break confidentiality and this has been explained in more

detail in the information sheet.

( ) I agree to take part in this study

Data Protection

The personal information we collect and use to conduct this research will be processed in accordance with

data protection law as explained in the Participant Information Sheet and the Privacy Notice for Research

Participants.

________________________ ________________________

Name of Participant Signature Date

________________________ ________________________

Name of the person taking consent Signature Date

Page 323: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

323

Appendix 6 – Consent form Telugu

సమమ త ఫరం

(పరంటడ లద వరబ ల తలుగు ఫరమ టల కూడ లభసతంద)

పరశధన పరజకట శరక: కనసగంపు, మరపు , లద "సంకషభం"? తలంగణల వయ వసయ మరపు యకక రమజకయ

ఆరధక వయ వసథ

పరధశధకుడ పరప: AMBARISH KARAMCHEDU

ఈ పరధశధనల పలగనడనక మ ఆసక తక ధనయ వదలు.

మకు ఇపు టక ఇచచ న సమచరం షట లద వవరణ నండ ఏవన పపశన లు ఉంట, దయచస మరప సన ఇన

చయల లద నర ణయంచ మందు పరధశధకుడన అడగండ. మరప ఎపుు డన ఉంచడనక మరధయు సూచచంచడనక ఈ

సమ త ఫరమ యకక కపన ఇసతరప. ఉపయగంచచన సమచరం ఈ సమ త ఫరమతత మరప మ అనమతన

ఇవవ డనక కటటుబడ ఉంటటంద.

దయచస టక చయండ:

( ) పన పరకక నన పపజక ు కసం సమచర షటన నన చదవన మరధయు అరథం చసకునన నన నన నరమరధంచన

మరధయు పరధశధకుడు న సంతృరతక ఏ పపశన లకు సమధనం ఇసతనన నన నన నరమరధసతనన న.

( ) న పలగనడం సవ చఛ ందమన నన అరథం చసకునన న మరధయు ఏ సమయంల అయన పపజక ు నండ

ఉపసంహరధంచుకవడం నకు ఉచచతం, కరణం లకుండ మరధయు ఏ పరయ వసనలు లకుండన.

( ) నన అందంచ సమచరం కంపయయ టరల మరధయు నటటబ క రధకరడ చయబడందన నన అరథం చసకునన న

( ) ఆడయ రధకరపగ ఉండటనక మరధయు పపజకుుల భగంగ పవసన గమనకలన నన అంగకరధసతనన న (మరప

సమ తంచకపత ఖళగ వదలవయండ)

( ) ఈ పపజక ు చచనన మరధయు సనన కరప రతులకు తలంగణల వయ వసయ మరపు న పరధశలసతంద మరధయు UK

లన మంచసురడ వశవ వదయ లయం నండ అంబరష కరంచూడు యకక PhD పపజక ు కసం పరధశధన పపదశలల

పగమల ఎంరకల చర లన కలగ ఉంటటంద.

( ) డట రధకరప చటుం 1998 లన నబంధనలకు అనగుణంగ ఏ నమతదు చయబడన సమచరం ఖచచ తంగ

రహసయ ంగ నరవ హంచబడుతుందన నన అరథం చసకునన న. ననన గురధతంచ సమచరం బహరంగంగ

అందుబటటలక వసతంద.

( ) న గురధతంపున మరపవషంచడం దవ రమ పవయడం దవ రమ నరమథ రధసతంద అన నన అరథం చసకునన న.

Page 324: The political economy of the “Liberalised Green Revolution” in ...

324

( ) అనమక డటన పరధశధన బృందం సభయయ లు (అనవదకులు, పరధశధన సహయకులు) ఉపయగంచవచ న

నన అరథం చసకునన న.

(దయచస ఒక పటటను టకట చయండ :)

( ) న ఇంటరవవ య నండ వలకతసన / వలకతసన పపచురణకు నన అంగకరధసతనన న

( ) న ఇంటరవవ య నండ వలకతసన / వలకతసన పపచురణకు నన ఇషుం లదు

( ) డసరట ుషన రసరడ పపజక ు ల పలగనడనక న అనమతన మంజూరప చసతనన న

భగసవ మ పరప:

సంతకం: తద:

పరధశధకుల పరప:

సంతకం: తద: