Top Banner
THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA [email protected] Abstract. The purely forward-looking New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) is presented as the new consensus on inflation theory. Yet this canonical NKPC is now challenged by a hybrid NKPC (HNKPC) that incorporates a backward-looking component. Standard empirical estimations remain inconclusive on this controversy, with conflicting results that favour either the NKPC, or the HNKPC, depending on the econometric approach. This article explores the debate about the empirical estimation of the HNKPC by using a different method: a meta-analysis technique. I collect 891 estimations, which come from 79 papers. I find a significant backward-looking component in the HNKPC (about one third), although the forward- looking share is significantly dominant (about two thirds). This macroeconomic result is also seen at the microeconomic level, in which firms’ surveys indicate about one third of prices are formed on a backward-looking basis. The implications of this result for the conduct of the inflation targeting regime are examined. Keywords. New Keynesian Phillips Curve; Meta-analysis; Inflation persistence; Inflation targeting JEL Classification: C42; C82 ; E31; E32 ; E52
32

THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA [email protected] Abstract.

May 25, 2020

Download

Documents

dariahiddleston
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE:

A META-ANALYSIS

Emmanuel Carré

University of Bordeaux – GREThA

[email protected]

Abstract. The purely forward-looking New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) is presented as the

new consensus on inflation theory. Yet this canonical NKPC is now challenged by a hybrid NKPC

(HNKPC) that incorporates a backward-looking component. Standard empirical estimations remain

inconclusive on this controversy, with conflicting results that favour either the NKPC, or the

HNKPC, depending on the econometric approach.

This article explores the debate about the empirical estimation of the HNKPC by using a different

method: a meta-analysis technique. I collect 891 estimations, which come from 79 papers. I find a

significant backward-looking component in the HNKPC (about one third), although the forward-

looking share is significantly dominant (about two thirds). This macroeconomic result is also seen at

the microeconomic level, in which firms’ surveys indicate about one third of prices are formed on a

backward-looking basis. The implications of this result for the conduct of the inflation targeting

regime are examined.

Keywords. New Keynesian Phillips Curve; Meta-analysis; Inflation persistence; Inflation targeting

JEL Classification: C42; C82 ; E31; E32 ; E52

Page 2: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

2

1. Introduction

The New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) originated in the New Keynesian theory of price

stickiness cum rational expectations hypothesis (Calvo, 1983). This results in a purely

forward-looking formula as the baseline or ‘canonical’ NKPC. These New Keynesian rigidity

hypotheses are supposed to constitute robust theoretical microfoundations and lead the NKPC

to surpass the old Phillips curve or its expectations augmented or accelerationist versions that

had the disadvantage of emerging from empirical results. It is generally considered that the

analysis of the NKPC began with Roberts (1995). Nowadays some academics suggest that the

NKPC has become ‘the closest thing there is to a standard specification’ (McCallum, 1997,

p.357). Indeed, the NKPC is the core inflation equation of the simple New Keynesian model

of the inflation targeting regime, and this New Keynesian ‘science’ of optimal monetary

policy pretend to lead the academic field: ‘Deviate from this, and you are not a member of the

In Crowd’ (Goodhart, 2006, p.1). The NKPC shows so clearly that it is the short term

inflation equation of both New Keynesian and New Classical, forming one of the main pillars

of the NNS (New Neo-classical Synthesis)1 that nowadays is the standard underlying

structural model of the inflation targeting regime.

Nevertheless, beyond the veil of polite academic consensus, the NKPC has been undermined

by a series of lasting and intractable controversies in both theory and practice. It has led

McCallum (2007, p.1) to change his mind about the Calvo-NKPC: ‘There are reasons,

however, to be somewhat dissatisfied with this state of affairs’. The Calvo price equation is a

‘heroic’ hypothesis, with a highly unrealistic time-dependent lottery as theory of firms’

pricing rule, with a fix probability to change price at each period. The Calvo pricing is

nowadays controversial, and competes with state-dependent price theory, or sticky

information theory of price rigidity. Moreover the Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium2

models (DSGE) using the Calvo pricing equation struggles to match stylised facts, and

Page 3: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

3

generally add a non realistic degree of price duration to reproduce the reality. Hence,

microfoundations are not necessary based on empirical grounds.

Therefore, the purely forward-looking NKPC seems unable to reproduce the inflation

dynamics observed in data: the hump-shaped response of inflation to a shock, with a gradual

and delayed response to the shock. Contrary to its initial ambitions, the NKPC does not seem,

in the empirical point of view, a better option than the old models of the Phillips Curve. In the

New Keynesian perspective, this empirical failure is a severe drawback, as realism is a key

foundation of this school. In particular, inflation persistence is regarded by New Keynesians

as a basic stylised fact that the model should be able to reproduce (Taylor, 1999). These

theoretical and empirical limits to the NKPC mean that it cannot be used in practice as a

robust theory of inflation by central bankers under an inflation targeting regime.

Due to these limits, the purely forward-looking NKPC is increasingly challenged by a hybrid

NKPC (HNKPC). This includes a backward-looking component to deal with the empirical

question of inflation persistence, and more generally intends to reconcile the theory of

inflation with empirical inflation dynamics. This inclusion of lagged inflation tends to

suggest, however, that there are reasons to doubt the rational expectations hypothesis for

modelling inflation. One thus returns, to a certain extent, to the previous accelerationist

Phillips Curve which relied on adaptive expectations.

Since the beginning with Irving Fisher and next with Phillips in 1958, the Phillips’ type

equation has been an empirical issue. It is for this reason that this paper focuses on the

empirical aspect of the NKPC. The analysis aims to investigate the empirical degree of

forward-lookingness of the NKPC, in order to provide evidence as to the validity of the

canonical purely forward-looking NKPC.

Yet, there is a controversy about the optimal econometric methodology used to measure the

respective forward-looking and backward-looking components of the NKPC. Indeed,

Page 4: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

4

different econometric methods of estimation give conflicting results: the NKPC could be

empirically either mainly forward or backward-looking. In the face of this intractable

controversy on the empirical form of the NKPC, a meta-analysis is employed to reduce the

methodological dilemma. This method is intensively used in medical and social science, and

recently became common in economics, both among academics and central banks (Card and

Krueger, 1995 ; Knell and Stix, 2003 ; Nijkamp and Poot, 2004 ; De Grauwe and Costa Sorti,

2004 ; Rose and Stanley, 2005). This technique is applied to a sample of 891 empirical

estimations of the HNKPC, sourced from 79 articles.

The first section analyses the prospects for the NKPC, and next the different problems.

The second section is dedicated to the empirical analysis, using a meta-analysis method, of

the degree of forward/backward lookingness of the HNKPC. Finally, section three draws the

implications of the results for the conduct of monetary policy, and more generally for the

conduct of the inflation targeting regime.

2. The NKPC: claims and criticisms

2.1 The alleged superiority of the NKPC

2.1.1 Microfoundations and rational expectations: a robust structural

equation

Traditional Phillips curves were empirical. Even the Phelps (1967) or Friedman (1968)

expectations augmented Phillips curves were used as empirical equations, calibrated to match

the data. Expectations were mainly adaptive: a backward looking autoregressive process. The

lack of solid microfoundations was a non-issue because reproducing facts was the Keynesian

macroeconometric priority. This accelerationist Phillips curve respected the natural rate

hypothesis defended by New Classicals.

Page 5: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

5

Due to the rational expectations revolution, microfoundations have become the core

requirement of the macroeconomics agenda. New Keynesians claim to satisfy this standard by

integrating their price rigidity hypothesis into the rational expectations scheme via, for

example, the Calvo (1983) pricing equation. With this pricing equation, New Keynesians

pretend to offer solid microfoundations for the Phillips Curve. This means that the NKPC is

different in the sense that it possesses rational expectations hypothesis microfoundations: it is

a theoretical curve, instead of the old empirical Phillips curves. Thus, in contrast to the

empirical Phillips curve, the NKPC is supposed to respect the natural rate hypothesis, and,

being a structural equation, to be immune to the Lucas critique (1976). As emphasised by

Gagnon and Khan (2001, p.1), ‘The main advantage of the NKPC over the traditional Phillips

curve is that the former has theoretical foundation and, therefore, a clear structural

interpretation, whereas the latter is a reduced-form relationship’3. In light of the new

macroeconometric standards, this enables New Keynesian to claim that the NKPC is superior

to previous curves.

The NKPC is the core supply equation of the three equations New Keynesian model (NKPC,

IS, Taylor rule), which is now textbook optimal monetary policy analysis4. It is also the basic

firms’ price theory and supply theory of larger mainstream models: the DSGE models.

Moreover, because it is embedded in the rational expectations and microfoundations

paradigm, the NKPC is also accepted by New Classicals. This explains why the NKPC is one

of the core equations of the new consensus in macroeconomics, the NNS.

2.1.2 The importance of forward-looking expectations

The NKPC that derives from the Calvo pricing is purely forward-looking, in contrast with the

old Phillips curve equations that were based on lagged values: ‘Another important way that

the new Phillips curve differs from the old is that it is fully forward-looking’ (Gali and

Gertler, 2007, p.33); it is of the form:

Page 6: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

6

tttt xE απβπ += +1 (1)

π: inflation ; x: output gap ; E: expectation operator.

The inflation expectations formation process Etπt+1 consists in future expectations at t+1

formed in the current period t. It is in contrast with the Lucas supply curve where inflation

expectations for the present period were formed at the previous period t-1 (Et-1πt). This

difference is crucial because it means that current value of inflation depends on the future

expected value of inflation. As a consequence, if agents’ future inflation expectations are

controlled, current inflation is also controlled. It opens the door to the ‘expectations

management’ that consists, for the central bank, of the intention to turn agents’ expectations

into a forward-looking phenomenon that conforms to the theory of expectations presented in

the NKPC (Woodford, 2003).

2.1.3 A reasonable empirical fit

The NKPC is the short to medium term inflation theory of the inflation targeting regime. New

Keynesians claim that the baseline Calvo-NKPC has demonstrated strong empirical

performances in reproducing the inflation data, and provides ‘a reasonably good description

of inflation dynamics’ (Gali and Gertler, 1999, p.219)5.

Thus the NKPC should be employed by central banks in their large scale models to produce

inflation forecasts and so be at the centre of the decision-making process of the inflation

targeting regime.

2.2 Some limits to the NKPC6

The baseline NKPC suffers from both theoretical and empirical limitations, and has now

become controversial. The literature sheds light on the surprising theoretical fragility of the

Page 7: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

7

Calvo scheme: a time-dependent pricing equation in which firms change their price according

to a Poisson Process. This is an ad hoc process, and a ‘lottery’ that does not satisfy New

Keynesians themselves – although analytically convenient, it is a poor theory of price change.

Microfoundations can turn to be ad hoc when not realistic. That is why some New Keynesians

propose a sticky information Phillips curve as an alternative to the NKPC (Mankiw and Reis,

2002). Even some New Classicals prefer state-dependent pricing equations (Dostey and King,

2005). On top of that, some New Classicals affirm that the NKPC does not respect the natural

rate hypothesis7.

2.2.1 The empirical failure of the NKPC in matching inflation persistence

The Calvo pricing is mainly scrutinised on the empirical field. Indeed, the NKPC is unable to

reproduce the empirical inflation dynamics8: ‘we argue in this paper that various recent

macroeconomic models based on sound microeconomic foundations fare poorly when

confronted to the data’ (Estrella and Fuhrer, 2002, p.1026). In particular, the NKPC does not

have the ability to reproduce inflation persistence: the hump shaped response of inflation to

shocks, that is to say a gradual and delayed response9. This is a basic stylized fact of New

Keynesian economics10, and, from the beginning, has been a constant problem for the

NKPC11: ‘prevailing specifications fail to match the facts of actual macroeconomic

experience - in particular, the fact that both nominal and real variables respond sluggishly but

substantially to monetary shocks’ (McCallum, 1998, p.357). This problem of lack of inflation

persistence of the NKPC continues during its development, and is now commonplace in

literature: ‘the pure NKPC lacks sufficient inertia to adequately explain the path of actual

inflation’ (Barkbu et al., 2005, p.4). Very recently, this was acknowledged by the authors of

the NKPC themselves: ‘The macroeconomic variables within the baseline model appear to

display greater persistence in practice than the basic framework can capture’ (Gali and

Gertler, 2007, p.42).

Page 8: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

8

The purely forward-looking NKPC describes inflation as a ‘jump’ variable, and not a

persistent variable12. In order to reproduce inflation persistence, DSGE models incorporate

large price durations that are at odds with empirical surveys.

2.2.2 Towards a hybrid NKPC (HNKPC)

This statement of a NKPC ‘flying in the face of facts’ has raised the necessity to restore a

backward-looking mechanism in the NKPC to improve its empirical fit, and in particular its

ability to properly reproduce inflation persistence13. This was achieved by introducing a

source of ‘intrinsic persistence’14 with lagged inflation as an additional explanatory variable.

The canonical NKPC became a ‘hybrid’ NKPC (HNKPC) that includes both a forward-

looking share (βf) and a backward-looking share (βb), forming the equation (2):

ttbttft xE απβπβπ ++= −+ 11 (2)

The HNKPC is a compromise between robust microfoundations and empirical fit - an

ambition to reconcile the ‘science’ and ‘art’ of the inflation dynamics15. The condition βf + βb

= 1 is often imposed on the NKPC to satisfy the natural rate hypothesis and to respond to

critiques of the NKPC formulated by Sims and McCallum. Generally, in the literature, this

type of HNKPC is modelled by a difference, that is β, (1- β), adopting the formulation:

ttttt xE απβπβπ +−+= −+ 11 )1( (3)

Backward-lookingness is introduced via indexation of firms’ prices on past inflation. This

backward indexation seems to be confirmed by microeconomic surveys of firms, which

Page 9: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

9

demonstrate that about 30% or one third of firms’ prices are indexed on past inflation, a result

in favour of the HNKPC16.

The rise of the HNKPC is a critique of the scheme NKPC cum rational expectations

hypothesis since lagged inflation can be seen as a departure from full rationality17.

Despite these theoretical and empirical weaknesses, the controversy NKPC versus HNKPC is

still alive. This is because New Keynesian theoreticians continue to claim that the purely

forward-looking NKPC is a robust and realistic theory of inflation dynamics. In order to

contribute to this debate, a meta-analysis of the empirical estimates of the HNKPC is

undertaken below.

3. Empirical tests of the HNKPC: a meta-analysis.

To my knowledge the meta-analysis has not yet been applied to the NKPC, although it seems

an appropriate technique to alleviate the controversy over its empirical estimate. This meta-

analysis aims to evaluate the NKPC versus the HNKPC by testing the empirical validity of

the NKPC: does βb = 0 ?

Nevertheless, the meta-analysis should be applied with care. Firstly, it is necessary to

determine if the empirical estimates of the HNKPC is a topic suitable for the application of

the meta-analysis method. Secondly, one must construct a robust database, based on rigorous

criteria. In the following paragraphs we explain the criteria of exclusion and inclusion of

estimates in the database.

3.1 Why a meta-analysis?

The meta-analysis is ‘a body of statistical methods that have been found useful in reviewing

and evaluating empirical research results’ (Stanley, 2001, p.131). This definition of meta-

analysis18 indicates that this method is appropriate for the study because empirical estimations

of the HNKPC are collected and because the degree of backward-lookingness (βb) in the

Page 10: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

10

HNKPC is an empirical question. From the beginning the form of the Phillips curve has been

an empirical matter.

The main reason for this methodological choice is that there is an intractable controversy on

the robust econometric method to test the HNKPC. The traditional method to estimate the

HNKPC is the generalised method of moment (GMM), used in the pioneer articles of Gali

and Gertler (1999), and of Gali et al. (2001). This method, in particular, has been criticised

for its bias (overestimating βf), and its weak identification problem19. This is why some

authors – such as Fuhrer (1997) or Lindé (2005)20 - prefer a full information maximum

likelihood method (FIML). More recently, DSGE models employ Bayesian estimation.

Accordingly, there is an intractable controversy on the econometric technique to evaluate

empirically the HNKPC: ‘the debate on the appropriate technique to use when estimating

Phillips curve remains open’ (Barkbu et al., 2005, p.6)21. These three methods lead to

conflicting estimations: the NKPC could be empirically either mainly forward or backward-

looking. There are three competing views regarding the empirical form of the NKPC, or three

conflicting results:

a) βf = 1, βb = 0. According to the mainstream, the NKPC should be purely forward-looking,

that is βf = 1 and βb = 0. Effectively, they claim that the backward-looking share is

different from 0, but is small enough to be neglected: ‘the structural estimates suggest that

this fraction, while statistically significant, is not quantitatively important’ (Gali and

Gertler, 1999, p.219)22.

On the contrary, the HNKPC’s view considers that βb > 0. Among these advocates of the

hybrid view, there are two main schools:

b) βf > βb. One school is a simple watering down of the mainstream view by adding an

inflation persistence component to the canonical NKPC, but the HNKPC remains mainly

forward-looking, so they claim that βf > βb.

Page 11: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

11

c) βf < βb. The other school considers that the HNKPC is predominantly backward-looking23.

This view is relatively similar to the traditional accelerationist Phillips curve.

Hence, depending on the method, the value of βb can vary considerably: ‘Empirical estimates

of the hybrid model have yielded conflicting results and interpretations’ (Jondeau and Le

Bihan, 2005, p.522). The meta-analysis is a useful technique to analyse this sort of problem:

‘meta-analysis has become the accepted practice for evaluating the current flood of

conflicting evidence’ (Stanley, 2001, p.132).

The meta-analysis consists in combining a set of different techniques for evaluating empirical

results of several studies. Consequently, this aggregation of estimates from different

econometric methods (GMM, FIML) is not a weakness, but a condition of valid meta-

analysis.

Moreover, given the discussion on the robust method to test the NKPC, the meta-analysis

offers less controversial results than a single article or estimation technique considered in

isolation. This is an advantage in an intractable controversy, such as the empirical estimation

of the HNKPC.

Furthermore, the meta-analysis permits the combination, integration and comparison of

disparate estimates coming from various techniques, thus allowing for a global comparative

assessment of estimates, facilitating a comprehensive survey of the literature.

Finally, the meta-analysis seems appropriate due to the growing volume of literature on the

empirical NKPC. Due to the large number of studies on this issue, a narrative survey of this

research would have produced a very long article, and synthesis would only have been

manageable with difficulty. The meta-analysis seems the appropriate technique to review the

wealth of literature, as it is a quantitative survey, which preserves a synthetic view of the

current state of the literature.

Page 12: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

12

3.2 The meta-analysis technique

The meta-analysis rests upon rigorous criteria for selecting the relevant estimates to be

included, and are presented below.

3.2.1 Data and selection procedures

Only estimations for the HNKPC, and not for the NKPC, are selected. Because the NKPC

does not allow for backward-looking elements, the purpose of investigating the basic

hypothesis of the canonical NKPC cannot be fulfilled: βf = 1 and βb = 0.

The selection of estimations available in the literature has been made according to the two

criterions of coverage and precision24.

In terms of coverage, the papers chosen cover the period from 1995 and 2007, as the literature

on the NKPC began with Roberts in 1995.

As to precision - that is to say if estimations are representative of the literature – articles on

EconLit are consulted, as is usual in meta-analysis25. Journal articles as well as working

papers at Repec-Ideas and central banks’ web sites are used. Journal articles cannot be judged

a complete enough resource, as the NKPC is a recent literature, meaning that many working

papers on the subject are still unpublished due to the normal publication delays. Journal

articles would have limit the number of available estimations. Moreover, it is generally

considered in the meta-analysis literature that unpublished papers should be incorporated

because the number of estimations is a way to avoid the possible bias in a particular

methodology26. The biases are present in the estimation of the NKPC, implying that the

inclusion of working papers to enlarge the number of estimates is essential. The idea of the

meta-analysis is to collect as many estimates as possible27. Furthermore, the criterion of

‘precision’ also consists of retaining only closed-economy estimations of the NKPC, and

excluding estimates of the NKPC with money as an explanatory variable. Statistically non

Page 13: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

13

significant estimates are also included. All these estimates are combinable because they test

the same equation: the HNKPC.

The issue of ‘publication bias’ is a constant preoccupation in the construction of meta-

analysis databases (Stanley, 2008). Three standard solutions, proposed in the literature, are

employed to tackle this problem. The first is the inclusion of a significant number of working

papers, and not only published articles (Stanley, 2005, p.310). The second is to incorporate

non significant results. The third is to consider a large sample because this can be expected to

reduce the bias (Stanley, 2005, p.321). To judge the importance of the sample, the sample

sizes of various articles in economics using meta-analysis are shown in table 1 (see appendix).

Having considered these factors, the meta-analysis collects 891 comparable estimates of the

NKPC from 79 papers28. The same weight is put on each of these estimates29.

As it is suggested in the literature the NKPC is the inflation theory of the inflation

targeting regime, the focus is on countries that have adopted this regime – such as Australia,

Canada, New-Zealand, Sweden and the United-Kingdom. The estimations collected from

these five countries for the two coefficients βf and βb, of the HNKPC (equation 2), respectively

the forward and backward-looking components.

Due to the debate regarding the necessity for the HNKPC to respect the natural rate

hypothesis, an initial robustness check is undertaken by only selecting the estimations that

fulfil the condition βf + βb = 1. Then a second robustness check of the results of inflation

targeting countries is conducted by collecting estimations of the USA and the Euro Zone as

examples of non inflation targeting countries. Finally a meta-analysis for all the countries -

targeters and non targeters – is done.

3.3 Results and descriptive statistics

This study is interested in the debate NKPC versus HNKPC: that is to say the validity of the

views a), b) and c) presented above. The results of the meta-analysis are reported in the scatter

Page 14: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

14

graphs (figures 1 to 14). Each scatter plot in lozenge form represents a collected estimation.

The x axis shows the forward-looking share of the HNKPC (βf), while the y axis indicates the

backward-looking share (βb). The scatter plot in pink (square form) is the mean of the

estimates, while that in yellow (triangular form) is the median.

Figures 1 to 8 relates to inflation targeting countries. Figures 1 to 5 are case studies of the five

countries (cited above) under inflation targeting regimes. Figure 6 is the aggregation of all the

estimations of these inflation targeting countries. Figure 7 represents the same estimation as

Figure 6 but has a selection of estimations that satisfy the natural rate hypothesis, and thus are

compatible with equation (3). This choice has been made in response to the criticisms of the

NKPC by Sims and McCallum, on the basis that it does not fulfil the natural rate hypothesis.

For this reason, only the estimations that satisfied the restriction βf + βb = 1 are retained. This

explains why the estimation points are on the same line. Finally, in figure 8, only the post

1990 estimations - i.e. not just after the birth of the inflation targeting regime - are retained.

Figure 8 also deals with the question of estimations that do not correspond to the inflation

targeting time period.

The visual impression of the graphs for inflation targeting countries is one where the

backward-looking component does not appear to be zero. Similarly, inflation targeters seem

to differ substantially regarding the ratio forward:backward-looking components of the

HNKPC, and so struggle to lead exactly the same type of inflation targeting, because they are

not confronted with identical inflation dynamics. Additionally, Figure 8 indicates that the

adoption of inflation targeting does not eliminate the backward-looking fraction of the

HNKPC. Nevertheless, given the low number of observations, this should be received with

caution.

Page 15: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

15

Figure 1: AustraliaN = 9 observations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Estimates Mean Mediane

Figure 2: Canada N = 51 estimations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Figure 3: New-ZealandN = 9 estimations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Figure 4: Sweden N = 12 estimations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Figure 5: United-Kingdom N = 41 estimations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Figure 6 : All inflation targeting countries N = 122 estimations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Source: author

Page 16: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

16

Figure 7: All inflation targeters; natural rate condition; N = 89 observations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t Figure 8: All inflation targeters; estimations

post 1990; N = 22 observations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Source: author

Figures 9 to 14 investigate the robustness of previous results. Figures 9 to 12 compare them

with the results of two non inflation targeting countries: USA and the Euro Zone; while

Figures 13 and 14 realise the aggregation of estimations of targeting and non targeting

countries. Some estimations points for the US are at odds with the baseline NKPC, as they

lack a forward-looking component or present a negative coefficient. Visually, these

robustness checks tend to confirm that the coefficient on the backward-looking share is

different from zero. They also confirm, especially with US and, to a lesser degree, with the

Euro Zone, that the domination of the forward-looking component over the backward-looking

is not as obvious as view a) claims. In summary, prima facie, the view b) seems the most

likely candidate for representing the empirical HNKPC.

Figure 9: USAN = 677 estimations

-0,75-0,50-0,250,000,250,500,751,001,251,501,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Figure 10: USA ; natural rate condition N = 615 observations

-0,75-0,50-0,250,000,250,500,751,001,251,501,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Page 17: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

17

Figure 11: Euro Zone N = 89 observations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

tFigure 12: Euro Zone; natural rate hypothesis

condition; N = 84 estimations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Figure 13: All countries N = 891 estimations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Figure 14: All countries; natural rate hypothesis condition; N = 787 estimations

-0,75-0,5

-0,250

0,250,5

0,751

1,251,5

1,75

-0,5 -0,3 0 0,25 0,5 0,75 1 1,25 1,5 1,75

Forward coefficient

Bac

kwar

d co

effi

cien

t

Source: author

Figures 15 to 23 present statistics in the form of histograms and box plots. Tables 2 to 5 are

descriptive statistics30. These figures and tables show that the bias in the distribution goes

both forward and backward, so that there is apparently no systematic bias. Estimations are

generally not symmetrically distributed: the mean differs from the median. Nevertheless, a

simple t-test indicates that for βf and βb, the mean and the median are not significantly

different.

Figure 15: All inflation targeting countries

00,10,20,30,40,5

-1 -0,5 0 0,5 1 1,5 2Forward-looking share (βf)

Freq

uenc

y

Figure 16: Box plot (βf)

-1-0,5

00,5

11,5

2

Forw

ard

shar

e

Source: author

Table 2 Minimum 0.00

Maximum 1.45

Median 0.68

Mean 0.64

Variance 0.07

Standard deviation 0.27

Skewness (Pearson) 0.02

Page 18: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

18

Figure 17: All inflation targeting countries

00,10,20,30,40,5

-1 -0,5 0 0,5 1 1,5 2Backward-looking share (βb)

Freq

uenc

y

Figure 18 : Box plot (βb)

-1-0,5

00,5

11,5

2

Bac

kwar

d sh

are

Figure 19 : All countries

00,10,20,30,40,5

-1 -0,5 0 0,5 1 1,5 2Forward-looking share (βf)

Freq

uenc

y

Figure 20: Box plot (βf)

-1-0,5

00,5

11,5

2Fo

rwar

d sh

are

Figure 21: All countries

00,10,20,30,40,5

-1 -0,5 0 0,5 1 1,5 2Backward-looking share (βb)

Freq

uenc

y

Figure 22: Box plot (βb)

-1-0,5

00,5

11,5

2

Bac

kwar

d sh

are

Source: author

In Table 6, a t-test31 is undertaken to see if on average βf = 1, as suggested by

advocates of the baseline NKPC (view a). This hypothesis is not valid, with the exception of

Sweden. However because of the limited number of estimations for this country, the t-test

result, in line with standard theory should be viewed with caution. In order to investigate the

doctrine of the baseline NKPC (view a), a further t-test is carried out to see if on average βb =

0. The results are not significant, except, once again, for Sweden, where the same reservations

as previously prevail. A further t-test is used to examine if, as defended by view b), the mean

of the forward-looking fraction is more important than the mean backward-looking share.

This hypothesis is valid, with the exception of New-Zealand. This result – like that for

Sweden – is problematic, due to the limited number of estimations.

Table 3 Minimum -0.56

Maximum 1.46

Median 0,27

Mean 0.26

Variance 0.07

Standard deviation 0.26

Skewness (Pearson) 0.22

Table 4 Minimum -0.25

Maximum 1.54

Median 0.60

Mean 0.56

Variance 0.05

Standard deviation 0.22

Skewness (Pearson) -0.29

Table 5 Minimum -0.56

Maximum 1.46

Median 0.38

Mean 0.40

Variance 0.05

Standard deviation 0.23

Skewness (Pearson) 0.13

Page 19: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

19

Table 6. Results of the meta-analysis.

Forward share (βf)

Mean Median

Backward share (βb)

Mean Median

Mean βf =1

(t -test)

Mean βb = 0 (t -test)

Mean βf > Mean βb (t -test)

Australia 0.55 0.52 0.44 0,47 -8.36 8.59 1.53* Canada 0.58 0.65 0.29 0,29 -11.88 7.33 5.37*** New-Zealand 0.57 0.56 0.43 0,44 -5.80 5.80 1.27 Sweden 1.02 0.99 -0.02 0,002 0.27*** -0.27*** 8.23*** United Kingdom 0.57 0.60 0.43 0,39 -10.3. 8.03 8.42*** All inflation targeting countries 0.64 0.68 0.27 0,28 -14.57 10.93 10.73*** All inflation targeting countries ; natural rate hypothesis 0.69 0.69 0.29 0,29 -12.34 11.96 11.41*** All inflation targeting countries, estimations post 1990 0.57 0.54 0.44 0,46 -11.01 11.16 2.35** USA 0.54 0.59 0.44 0,40 -54.46 52.40 8.34*** USA ; natural rate hypothesis 0.54 0.58 0.46 0,40 -56.17 54.69 7.04*** Euro area 0.64 0.67 0.33 0,32 -22.14 21.74 14.45*** Euro area ; natural rate hypothesis 0.65 0.67 0.34 0,32 -26.05 23.72 16.46*** All countries 0.57 0.60 0.41 0,38 -57.53 52.68 14.78*** All countries; natural rate hypothesis 0.57 0.60 0.43 0,39 -58.13 56.36 13.53***

*, ** and *** indicate the level of signification respectively at 10%, 5% and 1%.

The meta-analysis indicates a large variation of the mean of βf and βb between countries

(columns 2 and 4). At one extreme, Sweden presents similar results to the mainstream view a)

of a purely forward-looking NKPC. At the other extreme, the US seems to indicate that the

NKPC is fifty-fifty, so nearly a perfect HNKPC.

The conclusion of the meta-analysis is that view b) seems to be dominant: the NKPC

is hybrid, but mainly forward-looking. We see that for all inflation targeting and all countries,

the mean is respectively βb = 0.27 and 0.41; so the repartition of βf and βb is approximately

two-third:one third.

This agrees with microeconomic surveys of firms in which the proportion of firms’ prices

based on backward-looking inflation is also about one third. This appears to be a macro-level

confirmation of micro-level results. The meta-analysis shows weak evidence for the

mainstream view a) of a purely forward-looking NKPC.

Although indicative, these results must be received with caution, and cannot claim to

provide a definitive answer to the question of the form of the HNKPC. Their lack of

conformity with the mainstream view of the NKPC necessitate, to ensure good practice, an

examination of potential implications for the conduct of inflation targeting strategy.

Page 20: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

20

4. Implications for the conduct of monetary policy and the

inflation targeting regime

4.1 The role of expectations: limits to expectations management

According to the baseline NKPC, inflation is mainly an expectations phenomenon: if the

central bank controls future inflation expectations, it controls the present value of inflation.

This explains why the expectations channel of transmission is central to monetary policy:

‘markets do the job’ instead of the central bank. It is also why the ‘expectations management’

is so crucial in the modern view of optimal monetary policy under the inflation targeting

regime: the expectations management is the root of monetary policy efficiency. According to

the ‘Divine Coincidence’ (Blanchard and Gali, 2007), the stabilisation of inflation coincide

with the stabilisation of the output gap. This implies that the expectations management

consists in anchoring inflation expectations to the medium term inflation target. Once

anchored to the future, agents do not react to past or present values of inflation, and therefore

do not react to the current shock. The expectations management is the New Keynesian version

of the old ‘credibility bonus’ of the credibility literature of the 1980s32.

Nevertheless, this expectation management strategy is less efficient if the inflation process

follows a HNKPC, as agents continue to take into account past values of inflation. Inflation is

no longer a purely forward-looking phenomenon. It implies that the central bank cannot fully

rely on agents to do the job: it has to act, and not only to talk. With a HNKPC,

communication is not enough, and action has to be taken.

4.2 NKPC, inflation targeting and the reaction to shocks

For the standard NKPC, inflation is the jump variable, and there is no inflation persistence.

This means that next to an inflationary shock there is an immediate response of inflation to

Page 21: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

21

the new information. This shock is temporary, and only exists in the short-term. Disinflation

is quick, so that the inflation-output trade-off is weak, or inexistent: the fully credible

disinflation can be a ‘free lunch’33. A maxima, the NKPC suggests a disinflationary boom

(Ball, 1994) that does not seem realistic. A minima, the disinflation is quick and the sacrifice

ratio weak. The result is that the trade-off and the shock are very likely to disappear in the

medium term: that is to say the time horizon of the inflation target. Inflation targeters can

focus only on inflation. Above all, the canonical NKPC implies that the central bank can

practice a benign neglect regarding the first round effect of the shock because it is very

unlikely to face a second round. The shock does not affect inflation expectations, and thus

offers protection from a prices-wages spiral. As a consequence, the first round effect of the

shock can be accommodated, leading to a more flexible type of inflation targeting.

On the contrary, the HNKPC suggests that the shock is more permanent: the short term effect

can also exist in the longer term. The disinflation occurs over ad longer period, and the trade-

off is less favourable. The lower rate of disinflation suggests that the second round effect of

the shock is more likely to lead the central bank to be more aggressive and to act sooner

against the shock34. The central bank has to be aggressive soon after the shock because the

HNKPC suggests that it would be a costly and slow process to bring inflation back to the

target after a shock: inflation is no longer a ‘jump’ variable, but, in part, a sluggish variable.

4.3 The form of the NKPC and central bank credibility.

If the central bank under inflation targeting is to be fully credible, inflation expectations

should be anchored to the medium term inflation target: inflation expectations should be

purely forward-looking. Agents should not be concerned about the present inflation shock, but

focus on the future inflation forecasts if, in the medium term, inflation is on target. In the

HNKPC this would be βf = 1.

Page 22: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

22

The meta-analysis analysis is thus a rough indicator of the degree of central bank credibility.

Since βb >0 in the meta-analysis, there is a rough indication that credibility is imperfect. If

credibility is imperfect, it implies that the central bank does not fully benefit from the

credibility bonus that emerges from the absence of immediate reactions of agents to the

inflation shock. Therefore the central bank does not benefit from a time lag to offset the

shock, because agents do not totally look beyond the shock. Once more, this lack of

credibility implies that the central bank has to act sooner and more aggressively to avoid the

risk of a second round effect.

4.4 An evolution towards a stricter type of inflation targeting?

The two previous points were oriented towards a more aggressive inflation targeting strategy

in short term response to the shock. They indicate a shorter optimal horizon for monetary

policy, so that more weight should be put on inflation in the central bank loss function,

corresponding to a more conservative Rogoff’s central banker. Does it mean that a HNKPC

calls for the end of a flexible and the return to a more ‘strict’ type of inflation targeting?

The answer could be negative for two reasons. The first is that a baseline NKPC calls for the

central bank to accommodate the first round of the inflation shock, and to induce a deflation if

a second round happens. In contrast, with a HNKPC, it seems more appropriate to respond

sooner and more gradually to the first round effect: it does not necessarily mean being more

aggressive. It simply indicates that the central bank leads a more gradual pre-emptive action

in order to avoid possible large future contraction in output.

A second factor that casts doubts on an evolution towards a stricter version of inflation

targeting is that the trade-off is less favourable with a HNKPC. If the inflation target should

be respected at a shorter horizon, it could indicate that the sole final objective of price

stability is too much of a straight jacket. The HNKPC actually indicates that the short-run

trade-off between inflation and output can last a long time, so that that these two final

Page 23: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

23

objectives do not necessarily coincide, even on the medium term horizon of the inflation

target. The solution to this dilemma of the HNKPC could be either a stricter version or the

collapse of the inflation targeting regime. In the case of the latter, the constraint of respecting

the inflation target is relaxed, and the trade-off becomes more manageable (Friedman, 2006).

The experience of Brazil in 2002 is that, in practice, central bankers are pragmatic and prefer

changing the target instead of increasing conservativeness. This confirms that a HNKPC can

be consistent with a form of dual mandate. It suggests that Greenspan (2004) could be right

when he announced that inflation targeting was evolving towards the dual mandate of the

Federal Reserve. Surprisingly, Mishkin (2004) claims that the Brazilian experience, with the

renunciation of the commitment to the inflation target, is the best practice for inflation

targeting. But once again, if, in the face of a large trade-off, the inflation target is abandoned,

it is an implicit decision that the sacrifice ratio to return to the target is considered to be too

large due to inflation persistence. The output objective instead of the inflation objective is

accordingly favoured, and a dual mandate declared.

4.5 The hybrid NKPC, the Divine Coincidence and the dual mandate

In order to propose a more formal explanation of the evolution of inflation targeting towards a

dual mandate as a result of a HNKPC, the concept of ‘Divine Coincidence’ can be used.

According to advocates of the canonical NKPC, there is Divine Coincidence if, in the medium

term the objectives of inflation and output coincide. This means that stabilising inflation at the

inflation target is automatically equivalent to stabilising the output around its potential level.

It can be demonstrated by rearranging the NKPC (equation 1) to obtain:

)( *1 yyxE ttttt −==− + ααπβπ

Page 24: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

24

If the so-called ‘expectations management’ of Woodford (2003) - the basic definition of

inflation targeting – works, then agents are forward-looking and form their expectations on

the inflation forecasts produced by the central bank to obtain:

kcentralban

tttt EE 11 ++ = ππ

Then, if there is full credibility, then agents consider that at this future horizon inflation will

be equal to the inflation target, so that:

πππ == ++

kcentralban

tttt EE 11

Finally, one has approximately:

)( *yy tt −=− ππ

This last relation describes the Divine Coincidence permitted by the purely forward-looking

NKPC. Yet, if instead the NKPC is hybrid (2), the Divine Coincidence does not work. For

convenience, it is recalled that the HNKPC (equation 2) is:

ttttt xE απβπβπ +−+= −+ 11 )1( so that, ttttt xE απβπβπ +−=− −+ 11 )1( .

If the NKPC is hybrid, since the Divine Coincidence does not hold, the central bank can

hardly focus only on the sole objective of price stability )0( =− ππ t , as it is not enough. As a

consequence, due to the persistence of inflation, the central bank should adopt a more flexible

type of inflation targeting. In practice this consists of choosing a longer time horizon to return

to the inflation target, in order to change the inflation target, to activate the escape clause, or

to evolve to a dual mandate. Indeed, all these modifications are equivalent to an increase in

the weight on output in central bank loss function. If this rise is large, it is possible that the

weight of output becomes larger than the weight of inflation, thus constituting a dual mandate.

5. Conclusion

According to common wisdom, the purely forward looking NKPC is robustly based on

microfoundations, and is capable of reproducing the empirical dynamics of inflation. A meta-

Page 25: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

25

analysis tends to indicate that this perceived wisdom has to be taken carefully. It suggests that

the NKPC is empirically more hybrid than pure, as it contains a backward looking fraction, of

about one third. This result is roughly in agreement with microeconomic surveys of firms

which indicate that about 30% of firms form their prices based on past inflation.

Even if the results of the meta-analysis should be received with caution, they propose a

substantial modification of the optimal monetary policy derived from the purely forward

looking NKPC. In particular the Divine Coincidence - the cornerstone of the inflation

targeting regime – is not supported by a hybrid NKPC. This rejection casts doubts on the

conduct, and eventually on the sustainability of a strict inflation targeting regime, and favours

the adoption of a more flexible type of inflation targeting.

The usual theory is that inflation targeting evolves from a strict to a flexible type as

soon as credibility is earned, i.e. when inflation expectations are anchored to the inflation

target. Inflation then becomes a purely expectation phenomenon, without inertia, leading to a

purely forward looking NKPC. The inflation targeting regime becomes more flexible because

it exploits this credibility bonus given by agents. After nearly twenty years of inflation

targeting, the meta-analysis should confirm this scenario of the evolution of this regime.

Nevertheless, the meta-analysis suggests that the evolution towards a flexible inflation

targeting has been accompanied by a hybrid NKPC. As a result, the meta-analysis proposes a

more complete scenario of the evolution whereby credibility is imperfect, so that the inflation

targeting becomes more flexible also because it is necessary in order to take inflation inertia

into account. Flexible inflation targeting is also partly an obligation. In light of the experience

of inflation targeting in Brazil, the hypothesis of flexibility as a necessity, in addition to a

bonus, seems valid.

Page 26: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

26

Appendix

Table 1. A comparison of the number of estimates collected in meta-analysis. References Number of estimates

Card and Krueger (1995) 15 Knell and Stix (2003) 559 Nijkamp and Poot (2003) 208 Nijkamp and Poot (2004) 123 De Grauwe and Costa Storti 122 Rose and Stanley (2005) 34 Doucouliagos and Paldam (2008) 543

Notes

1. See Goodfriend and King (1997 ; 2001).

2. A benchmark DSGE model is Smets and Wouters (2003).

3. See also Balakrishnan and Lopez-Salido (2002, p.10).

4. See Walsh (2003).

5. See also Cogley and Sbordone (2005), Sbordone (2005, p.1196) or Angeloni et al. (2006, p.572).

6. Another limit to the canonical NKPC is the lack of ‘cost push’ shock ε arising from wages or the exchange

rate. It is a serious matter for emerging markets under inflation targeting such as Brazil or South Africa. This

is not analysed because it is beyond the scope of this paper dedicated to inflation persistence. There are

other limits to the NKPC, such as the proxy for the real marginal cost: labour income share or output gap.

As Shown in Kurmann (2007), the coefficients βf and βb vary considerably depending on the proxy chosen.

7. See Sims (1998), Minford and Peel (2003, p.2), Buiter (2006), McCallum (2007, p.15).

8. See Roberts (2001, p.1), Mankiw and Reis (2002, p.1295), Fuhrer and Olivei (2004, p.2), Rumler (2005,

p.7), Dufour et al. (2005, p.1).

9. See Mankiw (2001).

10. See Fuhrer and Moore (1995). There is an on going controversy on the evidence of a significant decrease of

inflation persistence in the recent period. Some authors claim that the drop is effective (Kumar and

Okimoto, 2007), while author contest this drop of persistence and consider that inflation persistence has

remained fairly stable and significant (O’Reilly and Whelan, 2004 ; Pivetta and Reis, 2007).

11. Fuhrer and Moore (1995, p.127), Sims (1998).

12. Gali and Gertler (2007, p.42).

13. See Gali and Gertler (1999), Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (2005).

Page 27: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

27

14. See also Fuhrer (2006, p.52) for the distinction between ‘intrinsic’ and ‘inherited’ persistence.

15. See Rudd and Whelan (2007, p.156).

16. Fabiani et al. (2005, p.11), Alvarez et al. (2005, p.17), Leith and Malley (2005, p.13).

17. Paloviita (2005a, p.15).

18. For a recent overview of this technique in economics, see the 2005 special issue of the Journal of Economic

Surveys, volume 19, issue 3.

19. See Ma (2002), Mavroeidis (2005), Fuhrer and Olivei (2004), Nason and Smith (2005, p.1).

20. See also Kurmann (2007), or Jondeau and Le Bihan (2008).

21. See also Fuhrer and Olivei (2004, p.2).

22. See also Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001 ; 2005), Cogley and Sbordone (2005, p.2 ; 2006, p.2).

23. See Fuhrer (1997), Rudd and Whelan (2005), Lindé (2005), Zhang and Osborn (2006).

24. See Nijkamp and Poot (2004, p.94).

25. See Knell and Stix (2003, p.6).

26. See Stanley (2001, p.134).

27. See Rose (2004, p.6).

28. Data available upon request.

29. As in Rose and Stanley (2005, p.5).

30. As done in the meta-analysis of De Grauwe and Costa Storti (2004).

31. As done in the meta-analysis of De Grauwe and Costa Storti (2004, p.6).

32. See Carré and Le Heron (2006) for a presentation of the credibility literature.

33. See Paloviita (2005b, p.20), Jondeau and Le Bihan (2005, p.522).

34. See Fuhrer and Olivei (2004, p.16).

References

Álvarez, L., Dhyne, E., Hoeberichts, M., Kwapil, C., Le Bihan, H., Lünnemann, P., Martins, F., Sabbatini, R.,

Stahl, H., Vermeulen, P. and Vilmunen, J. (2005) Sticky prices in the euro area: a summary of new micro

evidence. European Central Bank Working Paper No.563.

Angeloni, I., Aucremanne, L., Ehrmann, M., Gali, J., Levin, A. and Smets, F. (2006) New evidence on inflation

persistence and price stickiness in the euro area: implications for macro modelling. Journal of the European

Economic Association 4(2-3): 562-74.

Page 28: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

28

Balakrishnan, R. and Lopez-Salido, D. (2002) Understanding UK inflation: the role of openness. Bank of

England Working paper No. 164.

Ball, L. (1994) Credible Disinflation with Staggered Price Setting. American Economic Review 84(1): 282-9.

Barkbu, B., Cassino, V., Gosselin-Lotz, A. and Piscitelli, L. (2005) The New Keynesian Phillips Curve in the

United States and the euro area: aggregation bias, stability and robustness. Bank of England Working paper

No.285.

Blanchard, O. and Gali, J. (2007) Real Wage Rigidities and the New Keynesian Model. Journal of Money,

Credit, and Banking 39(s1): 35-65.

Buiter, W. (2006) The elusive welfare economics of price stability as a monetary policy objective: why New

Keynesian central bankers should validate core inflation. European Central Bank Working Paper No. 609.

Calvo, G. (1983) Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics

12(3):983–98.

Card, D. and Krueger, A. (1995) Time-Series Minimum Wage Studies: A Meta-Analysis. American Economic

Review 85(2):238-43.

Carré, E. and Le Heron, E. (2006) Credibility versus confidence in monetary policy. In Forstater, M. and Wray,

R. (eds) Money, Financial Instability and Stabilisation Policy (pp.58-84). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamics effects of a shock to

monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113(1): 1–45.

Cogley, T., Sbordone, A. (2005) A search for a structural Phillips curve. Federal Reserve Bank of New York

Staff Reports No. 203.

Cogley, T., Sbordone, A. (2006) Trend inflation and inflation persistence in the new Keynesian Phillips curve.

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports No. 270.

De Grauwe, P. and Costa Storti, C. (2004) The effects of monetary policy: a meta-analysis. University of Leuven

mimeo, March,

Dotsey, M. and King, R. (2005) Implications of state-dependent pricing for dynamic macroeconomic models.

Journal of Monetary Economics 52(1):213-42.

Doucouliagos, H. and Paldam, M. (2008) Aid effectiveness on growth: A meta study. European Journal of

Political Economy 24(1):1-24.

Dufour, J.M., Khalaf, L. and Kichian, M. (2005) Inflation dynamics and the new Keynesian Phillips Curve: an

identification-robust econometric analysis. Bank of Canada Working paper 2005-27.

Page 29: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

29

Estrella, A. and Fuhrer, J. (2002) Dynamic Inconsistencies: Counterfactual Implications of a Class of Rational-

Expectations Models. American Economic Review 92(4): 1013-28.

Fabiani, S., Druant, M., Hernando, I., Kwapil, C., Landau, B., Loupias, C., Martins, F., Mathä, T., Sabbatini, R.,

Stahl, H. and Stokman, A. (2005) The pricing behaviour of firms in the euro area: new survey evidence.

European Central Bank Working Paper No.535.

Friedman, B. (2006) What objectives for monetary policy? Paper presented at the conference Central banks as

Economic Institutions. Paris: Centre Cournot.

Friedman, M. (1968) The Role of Monetary Policy. American Economic Review 58(1): 1-17.

Fuhrer, J. and Moore, G. (1995) Inflation persistence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(1): 127–59.

Fuhrer, J. and Olivei, G. (2004) Estimating forward-looking Euler equations with GMM estimators: an optimal

instruments approach. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Working paper 04-2.

Fuhrer, J. (1997) The (un)importance of forward-looking behaviour in price specification. Journal of Money,

Credit and Banking 29(2): 338-50.

Fuhrer, J. (2006) Intrinsic and inherited persistence. International Journal of Central Banking 2(3):49-86.

Gagnon, E. and Khan, H. (2001) New Phillips curve with alternative marginal cost measures for Canada, the

United States, and the Euro Area. Bank of Canada Working Paper 2001-25.

Gali, J. and Gertler, M. (1999) Inflation dynamics: a structural econometric analysis. Journal of Monetary

Economics 44(2): 195–222.

Gali, J. and Gertler, M. (2007) Macroeconomic modelling for monetary policy evaluation. Journal of Economic

Perspectives 21(4): 25-45

Gali, J., Gertler, M. and Lopez-Salido, J.D. (2001) European Inflation Dynamics. European Economic Review

45(7): 1237–70.

Gali, J., Gertler, M. and Lopez-Salido, J.D. (2005) Robustness of the estimates of the hybrid New Keynesian

Phillips curve. Journal of Monetary Economics 52(6): 1107-18.

Goodfriend, M. and King, R. (1997) The New Neo-Classical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy. In

Bernanke, B. and Rotemberg, J. (eds), NBER Macroeconomics Annual (pp.231-82). Cambridge, MA: MIT

Press.

Goodfriend, M. and King, R. (2001) The case for price stability. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working

Paper 01-02.

Page 30: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

30

Goodhart, C. (2006) Otmar Issing and the Monetary Pillar. Paper presented at the colloquium Monetary policy: a

journey from theory to practice, Frankfurt: European Central Bank.

Greenspan, A. (2004) Risk and uncertainty in monetary policy. American Economic Review 94(2):33-40.

Jondeau, E. and Le Bihan, H. (2005) Testing for a forward-looking Phillips curve. Additional evidence form

European and US data. Economic Modelling 22(3): 521-50.

Jondeau, E. and Le Bihan, H. (2008) Examining bias in estimators of linear rational expectations models under

misspecification. Journal of Econometrics 143(2): 375-95.

Knell, M. and Stix, H. (2003) How robust are money demand estimations? A meta-analytic approach. National

Bank of Austria Working Paper No. 81.

Kumar, M. and Okimoto, T. (2007) Dynamics of persistence in international inflation rates. Journal of Money,

Credit and Banking 39(6): 1457-79

Kurmann, A. (2007) VAR-based estimation of Euler equations with an application to New Keynesian pricing.

Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31: 767–96.

Leith, C. and Malley, J. (2005), A sectoral analysis of price-setting behaviour is US manufacturing industries.

Working Paper, University of Glasgow, December 15.

Lindé, J. (2005) Estimating New Keynesian Phillips curves: a full information maximum likelihood approach.

Journal of Monetary Economics 52(6): 1135-49.

Lucas, R. (1976) Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series 1:19-46.

Ma, A. (2002) GMM estimation of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve. Economics Letters 76: 411–7.

Mankiw, G. (2001) The inexorable and mysterious trade-off between inflation and unemployment. The

Economic Journal, 111(471): 45-61.

Mankiw, G. and Reis, R. (2002) Sticky information versus sticky prices: A proposal to replace the New

Keynesian Phillips curve. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4): 1295-1328.

Mavroeidis, S. (2005) Identification issues in forward-looking models estimated by GMM, with an application to

the Phillips curve. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 37(3): 421-48.

McCallum, B. (1997) Comments on An optimization-based econometric framework for the evaluation of

monetary policy by Rotemberg, J. and Woodford, M. In Bernanke, B. and Rotemberg, J. (eds), NBER

Macroeconomics Annual (pp.355-9). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

McCallum, B. (1998) Stickiness: A comment. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 49:357-

63.

Page 31: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

31

McCallum, B. (2007) Basic Calvo and P-Bar models of price adjustment: a comparison. Working Paper,

Carnegie Mellon University.

Minford, P. and Peel, D. (2003) Calvo contracts – A critique. Working Paper, Cardiff Business School.

Mishkin, F. (2004) Can central bank transparency go too far? In Kent, C. and Guttmann, S. (eds), The future of

Inflation Targeting (pp.48-65). Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia.

Nason, J. and Smith, G. (2005) Identifying the New Keynesian Phillips curve. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Working paper 2005-1.

Nijkamp, P. and Poot, J. (2003) The last word on the wage curve? A Meta-analytic assessment. Tinbergen

Institute Discussion paper No. 2002-029/3.

Nijkamp, P. and Poot, J. (2004) Meta-analysis of the effect of fiscal policies on long-run growth. European

Journal of Political Economy 20(1):91-124.

O’Reilly, G. and Whelan, K. (2004) Has euro-area persistence changed over time? European Central Bank

Working paper No. 335.

Paloviita, M. (2005a) The role of expectations in euro area inflation dynamics. Bank of Finland Scientific

Monographs E:32.

Paloviita, M. (2005b) Comparing alternative Phillips curve specifications: European results with survey-based

expectations. Bank of Finland Discussion papers No. 22/2005.

Phelps, E. (1967) Inflation expectations and optimal unemployment over time. Economica 34(135): 254-81.

Phillips, A. (1958) The relationship between unemployment and the rate of change of money wages in the

United-Kingdom 1861-1957. Economica 25 (100): 283-99.

Pivetta, F. and Reis, R. (2007) The persistence of inflation in the United States. Journal of Economic Dynamics

and Control 31(4): 1326–58.

Roberts, J. (1995) New Keynesian economics and the Phillips curve. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking

27(4): 975-84.

Roberts, J. (2001) How well does the New Keynesian sticky-price model fit the data? Finance and Economics

Discussion Series No. 2001-13, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Rogoff, K. (1985) The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of

Economics 100(4): 1169-89.

Rose, A. (2004) A meta-analysis of the effect of common currencies on international trade. NBER Working

Paper No. 10373.

Page 32: THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS · THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE: A META-ANALYSIS Emmanuel Carré University of Bordeaux – GREThA carre.emnl@gmail.com Abstract.

32

Rose, A. and Stanley, T. (2005) A meta-analysis of the effect of common currencies on international trade.

Working Paper, Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley.

Rudd, J. and Whelan, K. (2005) New tests of the New Keynesian Phillips curve. Journal of Monetary Economics

52(6):1167-81.

Rudd, J. and Whelan, K. (2007) Modeling inflation dynamics: A critical review of recent research. Journal of

Money, Credit and Banking 39(3):155-70.

Rumler, F. (2005) Estimates of the open economy New Keynesian Phillips curve for euro area countries

European Central Bank Working paper No.496.

Sbordone, A. (2005) Do expected future marginal cost drive inflation dynamics? Journal of Monetary

Economics 52(6): 1183–97.

Sims, C. (1998) Stickiness. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 49: 317-56

Smets, F., Wouters, R. (2003) An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the Euro area.

Journal of the European Economic Association 1(5):1123-75.

Stanley, T. (2001) Wheat from chaff: meta-analysis as quantitative literature review. Journal of Economic

Perspectives 15(3):131-50.

Stanley, T. (2005) Beyond publication bias. Journal of Economic Surveys 19(3): 309-45.

Stanley, T. (2008) Meta-regression methods for detecting and estimating empirical effects in the presence of

publication selection. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 70(1):103-27.

Taylor, J. (1999) Staggered price and wage setting in macroeconomics. In J. Taylor and Woodford, M. (eds),

Handbook of Macroeconomics, (Vol. I, pp.1009-50). Amsterdam: North-Holland, Elsevier.

Walsh, C. (2003) Monetary Theory and Policy. 2nd edition, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

Woodford, M. (2003) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton

University Press.

Zhang, C. and D. Osborn (2006) On the successful estimation of the New Keynesian Phillips curve. Economic

Studies, University of Manchester.