Top Banner
The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001
45

The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Dec 28, 2015

Download

Documents

Preston Day
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy

École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC)January 2001

Page 2: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The public sector accounts

The primary balance and the debt service

Page 3: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Introduction In most countries, the government sector takes a large share of

gross national disposable income and accounts for an important part of domestic absorption.

In this context, the government ’s decisions to tax and spend are bound to have macroeconomic repercussions. If personal income taxes are increased, the households’

disposable income falls and so should do consumption and absorption, other things equal.

If corporate income taxes are decreased, the firms’ after-tax earnings are higher and other things equal, this should affect positively investment and domestic absorption.

At the same time, the government may affect absorption directly by choosing to increase or decrease its own investment and consumption spending.

Page 4: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The government’s budget balance Before examining the macroeconomic repercussions of

these decisions, it is useful to look at the basics of government budget accounting.

The government ’s overall budgetary balance (BB) is equal to the difference between total revenues (TR) and total expenditures (TE): BB = TR - TE

However, the government has little (if any) control over the debt service in the short-run. This is why we usually distinguish between program spending (PS) and debt service (DS): BB = (TR - PS) - DS

The difference between total revenues and program spending (TR-BS) is called the primary balance (PB), so we write: BB = PB -DS

Page 5: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The main items of the government budget

Total revenues (R) Tax revenue

> Direct taxes (household and corporate income taxes)

> Indirect taxes (VAT, import taxes, etc.)

Other revenue

> Dividends paid by the state-owned enterprises

> Investment income (ex.: interest on the foreign reserve assets)

Total expenditures (TE)

Program Spending (PS)

> Goods and services (G

and IG)

> Transfers and subsidies

Debt service (DS)

> Interest paid to the

holders of government

debt (treasury bills,

bonds and other

government debt

instruments)

Page 6: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Surpluses and deficits Interpretation:

The government budgetary balance would be equal to the primary balance if the government had no debt.

The government budgetary balance is positive (and there is a budget surplus)

when the primary balance is positive and higher than the debt service (PB DS).

The government budgetary balance is negative (and there is a budget deficit)

when the primary balance is negative or when the primary balance is positive but smaller than the

debt service (PB DS).

Page 7: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

A primer on fiscal policy

Keynesian fiscal policy

Page 8: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

A primer on fiscal policy

In the short-run, only the primary balance can be affected by government decisions.

In principle, the primary balance could be an intermediate target by which the government aims to influence aggregate demand and the macroeconomic equilibrium of the economy (final target).

The instruments would be government spending and taxes: If the government wants to stimulate aggregate

demand, it may reduce taxes and/or increase spending (G and IG).

PB deteriorates and AD is higher, other things equal. If the government wants to slow aggregate demand, it

may increase taxes and/or decrease spending (G and IG).

PB improves and AD is lower, other things equal

Page 9: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

AD(PB down)

P+

Y+

AD0

P

AD = AS = Y

AS

Y0

P0

AD(PB up)

Y-

P-

Page 10: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

A primer on fiscal policy

The idea that we might use the primary balance as an intermediate target for macroeconomic stabilization is at the heart of what is called keynesian fiscal policy.

The keynesian idea was that the government should be prepared to run a primary deficit in times of recession and should revert to a primary surplus in better times.

This way, the primary balance would be zero on average and there would be no growth in the public debt over the economic cycle.

The problem has been that many governments have for too long applied only the first half of the keynesian recipe and their debt has grown at an unsustainable pace.

Page 11: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Keynesian fiscal policy

Primary surplus

Primary deficit

Booming times

Recessive times

0

Page 12: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Irresponsible fiscal policy

Primary surplus

Primary deficit

Booming times

Recessive times

0

Page 13: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The government budget constraint

What is sustainable and what is not

Page 14: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The government budget constraint When PB < DS, the government budgetary balance is

negative, there is a budget deficit and this deficit must be financed somehow.

Aside from monetary financing (we’ll see that later), there are three basic sources of government deficit financing: The government may borrow from the domestic

residents and its domestic debt will increase (D > 0) The government may borrow from the foreign residents

and its foreign debt will increase (D* > 0) The government may sell its assets.

Deficit = D + D* - Assets

Page 15: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The government budget constraintLet ’s define the total net debt (D + D* - Assets) as B. Since the budget deficit is equal to DS - PB, we can write:

B = DS - PB Suppose there is a constant average interest rate i on the

net public debt. Then the debt service DS will be equal to i B and we write:

B = i B - PB ,which in discrete time can be written as Bt - B t-1 = i B t-1 - PBt ,or Bt = (1+ i ) B t-1 - PBt

Page 16: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The government budget constraint However, the size of the debt B tells us very little unless

we know the size of the economy. Since the debt is in nominal terms, we have to compare it

to nominal GDP (YN). Let ’s define B/YN as b, PB/YN as pb and the growth rate of nominal GDP as ng. Then we have:

YNt

bt = (1+ i ) B t-1 - pbt

(1+ng)

bt = (1+ i ) b t-1 - pbt

Which can be simplified to

Page 17: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The government budget constraint We could (but will not) show that this relationship is also

true in real terms (using r instead of i and rg - the growth rate of real GDP - instead of gn:

(1 + rg)

bt = (1+ r ) b t-1 - pbt

Conclusion: When the real rate of interest is higher than the real growth rate of the economy, the debt to GDP ratio grows exponentially unless the government runs a sufficiently high primary balance surplus.

Page 18: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

An exemple of explosive debt dynamics

Canadian public finances in the middle of the 1990 ’s

Page 19: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

At the beginning of the 1990 ’s

The government ’s financial situation was rapidly

deteriorating.

The deficit and the public debt were rising to an extent

such that raised the question of the government ’s financial

credibility.

The government ’s budgetary balance had become

extremely vulnerable to a rise in the level of interest rates.

Financial markets were getting nervous.

Page 20: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The deficit was rising

27

32

37

42billions $

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994

The federal deficit

(public accounts, end of fiscal year)

Page 21: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The net public debt was exploding

35

40

45

50

55

60

65

70% of GDP

1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995Year

Public administrations net debt(national accounts)

Canada USA

Page 22: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Debt service(% of tax revenues)

65%

36%Debt service

Program spending

Debt service was taking a large share of total tax revenues leaving little to program spending

Page 23: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The origin of the problem

For two decades, the government ’s net debt (ND) had increased more rapidly than nominal GDP, that is, more rapidly than the government ’s tax base.

Consequently, debt service had come to take a large share of total tax revenues.

The situation was clearly unsustainable in the long run (debt service cannot absorb 100 % of total tax revenues - nothing would then be left for program spending -) but in the meanwhile, the government was keeping on borrowing.

The goodwill of financial markets had become critical but this had some limits.

Page 24: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Public debt and interest rates

The analytical model

Page 25: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

1/r

Nominal value

D = Demand

Supply = B = outstanding stock of government bonds

1/r0

r = rate of return on government bonds

Page 26: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

1/r

Nominal value

D = f (Sp, ra, a, )

Supply = B = Public debt

With BB <0With BB>0

1/r0

Note: Sp = private savings (depends on GDP), ra = expected rate of return on alternative assets, a= expected rate of inflation (depends on monetary policy and other things), = other factors , r = rate of return.

Page 27: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Nominal value

1/r0

1/r

D

B

1/r1

B’

Other things equal, an increase in the stock of government bonds (from B to B’)cause an increase in their rate of return (1/r falls)

Page 28: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

1/r

Nominal value

D

B

1/r0

1/r1

B’

Other things equal, a fall in the stock of government bonds (from B to B’) reduces their rate of return (1/r increases).

Page 29: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

In normal times, nominal GDP grows every year

If nominal GDP grows at the same speed as net debt

(e.g. growth rates are the same), the debt to GDP

ratio is constant.

If nominal GDP grows at a higher speed than net

debt, the debt to GDP ratio declines.

If nominal GDP grows at a lower speed than net debt,

the debt to GDP ratio increases.

Page 30: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The growth in nominal GDP feeds into a higher demand for government bonds

When nominal GDP grows, so do aggregate

revenues and savings.

For a constant saving rate, savings and GDP

would grow at the same percentage rate.

With an increase in savings, the demand for all

financial assets is stimulated.

If there are no change in the way people diversify

their portfolio between bonds, stocks and other

assets, the demand for government bonds should

grow at the same speed as savings and thus at

the same speed as GDP.

Page 31: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Nominal value

1/r0

1/r

D

B

In this case, the debt to GDP ratio is constant. The demand for bonds grows at the same speed as the supply of bonds. Other things equal, the rate of return on government bonds would stay constant.

When net debt grows at the same speed as nominal GDP

B’

D’

Page 32: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Nominal value

1/r0

1/r

D

B

What about if net debt grows more rapidly than nominal GDP ?

B’

In this case, the debt to GDP ratio increases. The demand for bonds increases by less than the supply of bonds. The rate of return on government bonds must go up to clear the market.

1/r1D’

Page 33: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Nominal value

1/r0

1/r

D

B

And if net debt grows less rapidly than nominal GDP ?

B’

In this case, the debt to GDP ratio decreases. The demand for bonds increases by more than the supply of bonds. The rate of return on government bonds must go down to clear the market.

1/r1

D’

Page 34: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Eliminating the deficit

How can this be achieved ?

Page 35: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The equation The budgetary balance(BB) is

equal to the difference between

the primary balance (PB) and

the debt service (DS):

For the deficit to be eliminated

(BB<0), the primary balance

(PB) must thus become equal to

or higher than the debt service

(DS).

Page 36: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

-10

0

10

20

30

40

50

1993-1994 1994-1995 1995-1996 1996-1997 1997-1998

Debt service

Primary balance

Billions $

Page 37: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Predict and decide In order to reach a budgetary target, the

government must thus reach a target for the primary balance..

Of course, budget decisions will have an impact on the trajectory of the debt.

They can even influence the level of interest rates.

However, these two variables will affect debt service payments only over time.

Predicting how much will be spent on debt service is very important but then, decisions have to be taken (given the predicted growth rate of nominal GDP) so as to reach the primary balance target.

Page 38: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Predict and decide

Since the primary balance is equal to the difference between total budget revenues (TR) and program spending (PS):

For the primary balance to be positive, total revenues have to be higher than program spending.

Given the predicted growth rate of nominal GDP, the government has no other choice than raising tax rates and reducing program spending, if it wants to eliminate the deficit.

Page 39: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Paul Martin’s strategy

A strategy emphasizing reductions in spending

12,0

13,0

14,0

15,0

16,0

17,0

18,0

1993-1994 1994-1995 1995-1996 1996-1997 1997-1998

Revenues

Program spending

% of GDP

Page 40: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The fiscal dividend

Where it comes from? What can be done with it ?

Page 41: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The fiscal dividend

When the government is running a budget surplus (BB>0), net debt (B) falls and other things equal, the debt to GDP ratio declines.

In nominal GDP increases, the ratio declines even more rapidly.

Debt service (DS) can be approximated by the following expression: DSt = it • Bt-1

where i represents the average interest rate paid on the net debt

Page 42: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The fiscal dividend

Other things equal then, when the debt to GDP ratio goes down so does the debts service to GDP ratio

Since BB/YN = PB/YN - DS/YN: The primary balance (in % of GDP)

required to reach a given budgetary target (in % of GDP) declines.

This means that the same budgetary balance can be maintained while relaxing the pressure on the primary balance. In other words, tax rates can be reduced and/or program spending (in % of GDP) can be increased.

Of course, the same primary balance (in % of GDP) could be maintained but then, the budgetary balance would keep on growing in percentage of GDP.

Page 43: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Choosing among three alternatives Three ways of allocating the fiscal dividend are

thus possible. The government can choose to: reduce tax rates increase program spending accelerate debt reduction through a growing

budget surplus Each one has its set of advantages and its

opportunity costs. By reducing taxes and increasing program

spending, the government can reach a number of objectives in the present but at the expense of a lower fiscal dividend in the future.

By accelerating debt reduction, the government can reach more ambitious goals in the future but at the expense of current objectives.

Page 44: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

Choosing among three alternatives The allocation of the fiscal dividend responds to

a choice between spending (reducing taxes and/or increasing program spending) and saving (increasing the budget surplus).

Choosing among the three alternatives is choosing between the present and the future trading off between short term and long term objectives. Do we want to stimulate the economy in the

short run ? Do we want to provide more funding to

programs ranking very high in the list of priorities ?

Do we want to reach particular taxation objectives ? How quickly do we want to reach these targets ?

Do we want to set up a cushion in the anticipation of future spending or simply because the future is uncertain ?

These are some of the questions raised by the existence of a fiscal dividend.

Page 45: The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC) January 2001.

The government budget constraint and the scope for fiscal policy

École des Hautes Études Commerciales (HÉC)January 2001