Top Banner
Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” INAUGURALDISSERTATION zur Erlangung des Grades eines Doktors der Wirtschaftswissenschaft (Dr. rer. pol.) des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der FernUniversität in Hagen. vorgelegt von Dipl.-Volkswirt Denis Stijepic am 11. Oktober 2010
430

Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

May 14, 2018

Download

Documents

lyhanh
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Structural Change and Economic Growth:

Analysis within the

“Partially Balanced Growth-Framework”

INAUGURALDISSERTATION

zur Erlangung des Grades eines Doktors der Wirtschaftswissenschaft (Dr. rer. pol.)

des Fachbereichs Wirtschaftswissenschaft der FernUniversität in Hagen.

vorgelegt von Dipl.-Volkswirt Denis Stijepic

am 11. Oktober 2010

Page 2: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Erstgutachter: Univ.-Prof. Dr. Helmut Wagner

Zweitgutachter: Univ.-Prof. Dr. Alfred Endres

Drittgutachter: Univ.-Prof. Dr. Thomas Eichner

Tag der Disputation: 9. März 2011

II

Page 3: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

ABSTRACT

The term “structural change” refers to changes in the sector-structure of an

economy, where “sectors” are some theoretical “groups” of goods and services

(e.g. agricultural sector, manufacturing sector, services sector). In fact, structural

change is one of the most striking empirical facts of the development process;

most prominent examples of structural change are “industrialization” and

“transition to a services economy”. Even more importantly, it is well known that

structural change has some key impacts on economy and society, especially on

(aggregate) economic growth.

Although structural change has been known for a long time, structural change

theory has not been a mainstream research topic, especially not in the growth

theory. Some new research introduced a new approach to studying structural

change, which is more in line with the mainstream growth theory. I name this

approach “partially balanced growth school” (“PBGP-school”). Broadly speaking,

this new school of structural change can be characterized upon two attributes (a

mathematical one and a theoretical one): (1) The concept of “partially balanced

growth” is used to study the differential-equation-systems of the theoretical

models. (2) The modelling framework may be regarded as “neoclassical” in many

ways.

I elaborate mathematical and theoretical foundations of the PBGP-school;

especially, I discuss the usage of partially balanced growth paths in structural

change modelling and the integration of structural change into the mainstream

neoclassical growth model (Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model). I systematize the

literature on structural-change-modelling and integrate/classify the new PBGP-

school into this scheme. Finally, I use the concepts of the PBGP-school for

analysing some actual economic topics related to structural change and (long-run)

economic growth. Especially, by using the PBGP-methods I analyse the Kuznets-

Kaldor-puzzle, the impacts of Offshoring on real GDP-growth and the effects of

demand-shifts associated with population ageing.

In fact, my work implies that the methods of the PBGP-school seem to be

valuable tools for analysing structural change. Furthermore, as I hope, my work

provides some new and interesting insights into structural change and economic

growth.

III

Page 4: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

In Chapter I, I provide an introduction to my research. Subsequently in Chapters

II and III, I explain and discuss the mathematical and modelling foundations of

my research. Chapter IV includes a systematization of structural-change-

modelling-literature and the classification of the PBGP-school and of my

research. In Chapter V, I present my efforts on modelling the Kuznets-Kaldor-

Puzzle, Offshoring and Ageing by using the PBGP-methods. Finally, in Chapter

VI there is a summary of my work.

IV

Page 5: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER I: Introduction

– Definitions, Overview, Motivation and Focus of the Analysis.............................1

1. Definition of sectors and of structural change (3) 2. Stylized structural-change-patterns: Kuznets-facts, Furastié-facts and

Baumol-facts (7) 3. Why does structural change take place? – The four main structural

change determinants ( 9) 3.1 Non-homothetic preferences across sectors (10) 3.2 Differences in TFP-growth across sectors (11) 3.3 Differences in output-elasticites of inputs across sectors (12) 3.4 Shifts in intermediates production across sectors (13)

4. Why does technology differ across sectors? (14) 5. Impact of structural change on the economy: focus on aggregate

growth (19) 6. The two schools of structural change modelling: Focus on the

neoclassical PBGP-school (22) 7. Further theoretical/analytical restrictions of the analysis (27) 8. General value of the models or: Which statements can be drawn

from the models and which not? (31) 9. Justification for the choice of topics that are analysed by using PBGP-

models (33)

CHAPTER II: Key Analytical Tool: Differential Equation-System Analysis

– Definitions, Analytical Concepts and Methods..................................................37

1. Basic terms (40) 2. Methods and key-concepts of differential-equation-system-analysis (44)

2.1 Methods of differential equation system analysis (44) 2.2. The qualitative approach to differential equation system analysis (46)

2.2.1 Dynamic equilibrium (46) 2.2.2 Stability of dynamic equilibrium (53)

2.2.2.1 Basic concepts and definitions of stability (53) 2.2.2.2 Methods for proving global and local stability of

equilibrium (58) 2.2.2.2.1 Local stability (58) 2.2.2.2.2 Global stability (60) 2.2.2.3 Transitional dynamics (71)

3. Optimal control (75) 3.1 The necessary conditions for a maximum (79) 3.2 Proof of sufficiency (80)

4. Summary: Step-by-step procedure in continuous-time growth-modeling (82) LIST OF SYMBOLS of CHAPTER II (84)

V

Page 6: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

CHAPTER III: Key Modeling Approach: Integration of Structural Change

into a Neoclassical Growth Model

– Key Assumptions, Application of Analytical Tools, Challenges in Structural

Change Modeling, Application and Premises of PBGP-method........................87

1. An unbalanced growth model (90)

1.1 Assumptions (90) 1.2 Optimality conditions (93)

2. Analytical challenges to structural-change-analysis (95) 3. A balanced-growth multi-sector-model (98) 4. A truly “neoclassical” multi-sector growth-model (104) 5. Partially balanced growth (106)

5.1 An example of a partially balanced growth model (106) 5.2 Examples from the literature on how to create partially balanced

growth paths (usage of a priori and a posteriori knife-edge conditions) (110) 6. Validity of neoclassical models in the light of structural change

and the downside of knife-edge-condition use (115) APPENDIX (119) LIST OF SYMBOLS of CHAPTER III (121)

CHAPTER IV: Classification/Systematization of Structural Change

Literature and Classification/Subordination of own Research.....................123

1. Changes in capital structure (129) 2. Changes in intermediates structure (132) 3. Changes in consumption structure (137)

3.1 “Unbalanced” school of structural change (137) 3.2 “New” (PBGP) school of structural change (142)

4. Classification of own research (146) 5. Further aspects of classification (149)

5.1 Structural change induced by trade opening (structural change theory vs. trade theory) (149)

5.2 Factor reallocation between capital industries and consumption industries (Uzawa’s structural change) (151)

5.3 Factor-reallocation between the private sector and the public sector (152) 5.4 Factor-reallocation between the research sector and the consumption

sector (153) 5.5 Outsourcing of home production (factor reallocation between home-

sector and market-sector) (154)

VI

Page 7: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

CHAPTER V: Application of the PBGP-Concept in Analysis of Structural

Change................................................................................................................155

PART I: A PBGP-Framework for the Analysis of the Kuznets-Kaldor-

Puzzle...................................................................................................................159

1. Introduction (163) 2. Stylized facts of sectoral structures (167)

2.1 Stylized facts regarding cross-sector-heterogeneity in production- technology (167)

2.2 Structural change determinants (168) 3. Model of neutral cross-capital-intensity structural change (169)

3.1 Model assumptions (169) 3.1.1 Production (169) 3.1.2 Utility function (172) 3.1.3 Aggregates and sectors (175)

3.2 Model equilibrium (178) 3.2.1 Optimality conditions (178) 3.2.2 Development of aggregates in equilibrium (178) 3.2.3 Development of sectors in equilibrium (182) 3.2.4 Consistency with stylized facts (184) 3.2.5 The relationship between structural change and aggregate-

dynamics (190) 4. A measure of neutrality of cross-capital-intensity structural change (195) 5. On correlation between preferences and technologies (203) 6. Concluding remarks (209) APPENDIX A (214)

APPROACH (1) (214) Necessary (first order) conditions for an optimum (214) Proof that sufficient (second order) conditions are satisfied (215)

APPROACH (2) (218) Producers (219) Households (220) Relationship between individual variables and economy-wide aggregates (224)

APPENDIX B (226) APPENDIX C (230) APPENDIX D (243) APPENDIX E (245) APPENDIX F (248) LIST OF SYMBOLS of PART I of CHAPTER V (252)

VII

Page 8: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

PART II: A PBGP-Framework for Analyzing the Impacts of Offshoring on

Structural Change and real GDP-growth in the Dynamic

Context.................................................................................................................263

1. Introduction (265) 2. Model assumptions (270) 3. Optimum and equilibrium (277) 4. Effects of offshoring on growth of aggregates (280)

4.1 The overall impact on aggregate growth (281) 4.2 Impact channels and their relative importance (284)

5. The effects of offshoring on structural change (290) 6. Discussion and implications (297) 7. Concluding remarks (301) APPENDIX A (306) APPENDIX B (307) APPENDIX C (309) APPENDIX D (313) APPENDIX E (315) APPENDIX F (316) LIST OF SYMBOLS of PART II of CHAPTER V (317)

PART III: A PBGP-Framework for Analyzing the Impacts of Ageing on

Structural Change and real GDP-growth...........................................................321

1. Introduction (323) 2. Model assumptions (330)

2.1 Utility (330) 2.2 Production (333) 2.3 Numéraire (335) 2.4 Aggregates and sectors (337)

3. Model equilibrium (338) 3.1 Optimality conditions (338) 3.2 Aggregates (339) 3.3 Sectors (342)

4. Effects of ageing (343) 4.1 Partially Balanced Growth Path (PBGP) without ageing (344) 4.2 Ageing and cross-sector differences in TFP-growth (347) 4.3 Ageing and cross-sector differences in input-elasticities (352)

4.3.1 Productivity effect: Impacts and channels (353) 4.3.2 Additional impacts on GDP: The price-effect (359)

4.3.2.1 Transitional effects of ageing on GDP (359) 4.3.2.2 PBGP-effects of ageing (366)

4.3.3 Dynamic aspects (367) 5. Concluding remarks (368) APPENDIX A (373) APPENDIX B (379)

VIII

Page 9: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX C (380) APPENDIX D (390) LIST OF SYMBOLS of PART III of CHAPTER V (391)

CHAPTER VI: Summary.................................................................................397

REFERENCES..................................................................................................403 Curriculum Vitae...............................................................................................419 “Erklärung laut §6(8) der Promotionsordnung” ...........................................421

IX

Page 10: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

X

Page 11: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

CHAPTER I

Introduction

- Definitions, Overview, Motivation and Focus of the Analysis -

The following chapter is aimed to provide an introduction to my research. Especially

in Section 1, some key definitions are provided. Sections 2-5 comprise some general

explanations about structural change and its impacts on the economy. In Sections 6-9,

I explain the theoretical and analytical focus and the justification of my research.

1

Page 12: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

TABLE OF CONTENTS for CHAPTER I

1. Definition of sectors and of structural change ...........................................................3

2. Stylized structural-change-patterns: Kuznets-facts, Furastié-facts and Baumol-facts

........................................................................................................................................7

3. Why does structural change take place? – The four main structural change

determinants...................................................................................................................9

3.1 Non-homothetic preferences across sectors.......................................................10

3.2 Differences in TFP-growth across sectors .........................................................11

3.3 Differences in output-elasticites of inputs across sectors ..................................12

3.4 Shifts in intermediates production across sectors ..............................................13

4. Why does technology differ across sectors?............................................................14

5. Impact of structural change on the economy: focus on aggregate growth ..............19

6. The two schools of structural change modelling: Focus on the neoclassical PBGP-

school ...........................................................................................................................22

7. Further theoretical/analytical restrictions of the analysis ........................................27

8. General value of the models or: Which statements can be drawn from the models

and which not? .............................................................................................................31

9. Justification for the choice of topics that are analysed by using PBGP-models......33

2

Page 13: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

1. Definition of sectors and of structural change In every economy several goods and services are produced and consumed. In general,

some of these goods and services share some common attributes. Hence, it can make

sense to group the goods and services that share common attributes (since, for

example, in this way it is easier to cope with the empirical data). In structural-change-

theory such groups of “similar” goods and services are named sectors. Hence, the

whole range of goods and services is subdivided into sectors, where each sector

contains goods and services that are similar regarding some attributes.

For example, the best known and the most basic sector-division of the economy is

(1) agriculture (primary sector)

(2) manufacturing (secondary sector)

(3) services (tertiary sector)

Note that the range of these sectors depends on the criterion that is used to formalize

this sector division. As discussed by Krüger (2008), p.335, and Wolfe (1955) there are

several examples:

• Fisher (1939, 1952) defines these sectors upon demand behaviour (where the

degree of necessity decreases and the income elasticity of demand increases

when approaching from sector (1) to sector (3))

• Wolfe (1955) categorizes these sectors upon the dominant factor in production

• Clark (1957) defines the range upon the nature of output of the sectors (e.g.

good vs. service).

Furthermore, the three-sector-division seems to be useful to explain the historical

development of the industrialized economies that will be discussed later (i.e. the

transition from agriculture to manufacturing and from manufacturing to services).

3

Page 14: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Another example of a (more disaggregated) sector-division, which I use in the

empirical study of Chapter V (Part I), is the sector-definition from the “Standard

Industrial Classification System”, which is used by the U.S. Department of Commerce

(Bureau of Economic Analysis). This definition includes the following sectors:

(1) Agriculture, forestry, and fishing

(2) Mining

(3) Construction

(4) Manufacturing

(5) Transportation and public utilities

(6) Wholesale trade

(7) Retail trade

(8) Finance, insurance, and real estate

(9) Services

This whole discussion implies that there are many several ways to subdivide an

economy into sectors, depending upon the attributes, which are used to group the

goods and services, and depending upon the questions, which are analysed. In my

research I do not choose any specific sector-division, in general. In fact, I study

models where production technology differs across sectors and where the degree of

disaggregation is not too high. (Furthermore, some models will assume that some

utility-function-parameters, e.g. the income elasticity of demand, differ across sectors,

as well.) My research does not require any other restriction on the definition of the

sectors. Hence, in fact every sector-definition, where the technology differs across

some sectors and the economy is not too disaggregated, is applicable to my research.

In the essay on the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle (in Chapter V) I provide empirical

evidence, which shows that production technology differs strongly across sectors, in

4

Page 15: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

general. (Intuitive explanations of cross-sector technology-disparities can be found in

Section 4 of the actual Chapter.)

To sum up this discussion I suggest the following definition:

Definition 1: Sectors are theoretical groups of goods- and services-varieties. Sectors

are defined such that

• technology differs across sectors; i.e. the “average” technology of sector i is

not the same as the average technology of sector j at least for some i and j; in

other words it is assumed that the production function, which is representative

of sector i, is not the same as the production function, which is representative

of sector j, at least for some i and j.

• the sector-division is exclusive, i.e. a good- or a service-type can be assigned

to only one sector; in other words, a sector does not include goods and

services that are assigned to another sector.

Now, we turn to the definition of the term structural change. The term structural

change, as it is used in my research, refers to a change in the sector structure of the

economy. For example, in the early stages of economic development agriculture

accounts for the largest part of real GDP, where in later stages of economic

development services constitute the biggest part of real GDP. (These empirical facts

are reviewed in Section 2 in detail.) That is, during the development process some

sectors become more important in comparison to other sectors; this is structural

change. Now, we have to find a measure of relative importance of sectors. In general,

5

Page 16: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

we could use sector-shares of real GDP1 to measure the relative importance of

sectors. However, in the literature there is another measure of structural change,

which is more appropriate for the aims of my research: sectoral employment shares2.

Hence, if employment-shares of sectors change, structural change takes place

according to my definition. Note that, in general, the dynamics of sector-shares of

real GDP and the dynamics of sectoral employment shares are quite similar (in

empirical findings and in my models); hence, they are quite interchangeable indicators

of structural change. However, in the analysis of the relationship between structural

change and real GDP-growth sectoral employment shares are a more meaningful

structural change indicator: As we will see in Section 5, the cross-sector labour-

allocation determines the average (economy-wide) labour-productivity; hence, the

allocation of labour across sectors is a determinant of real GDP(-growth). Overall, our

definition of structural change allows us to study the impacts of structural change on

real GDP-growth in the most direct way. To sum up this discussion I provide the

following definition:

Definition 2: Structural change stands for the change in the cross-sector labor-

allocation, where

• sectors are defined upon Definition 1 and

• cross-sector labor-allocation is indicated by the sectoral employment shares.3

1 „Sector-i-share of real GDP“ means the real output of sector i divided by real GDP. 2 „Employment share of sector i“ means the number (or: working hours) of persons, which are employed in sector i, divided by the number (or: working hours) of persons, which are employed in the whole economy. 3 See the previous footnote.

6

Page 17: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

2. Stylized structural-change-patterns: Kuznets-facts, Furastié-facts and Baumol-facts Structural change is a well-known empirical fact, which has been studied even since

the 1930ies. Empirical evidence on structural change can be found in the

papers/books by e.g. Fourastié (1969), Kuznets (1976), Maddison (1980), Elfring

(1989), Broadberry (1997), Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001), Raiser et al. (2003), Ngai

and Pissarides (2004), Broadberry and Irwin (2006) and Schettkat and Yocarini

(2006). Useful sources for data on structural change are:

• for EU-countries data: EU KLEMS Project (http://www.euklems.net/)

• for US-data: U.S. Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis)

(http://www.bea.gov/)

• for OECD-countries-data: OECD STAN Industry (http://www.oecd-

ilibrary.org/content/datacollection/stan-data-en).

In fact, all this empirical evidence implies some stylized facts of structural change.

Since structural change across sectors agriculture, manufacturing and services is the

most discussed one, I review the stylized facts about this structural change in this

section for the sake of completeness. I will show later that these stylized facts can be

satisfied by my models.

Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001) formulate the following stylized facts, which they

name “Kuznets facts”:

a) The employment share of agriculture declines during the development process.

b) The employment share of manufacturing is constant during the development

process.

c) The employment share of services increases during the development process.

7

Page 18: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

It should be noted that these stylized facts refer to the structural-change-patterns over

the last century. If longer periods are considered, the development of the

manufacturing-sector-employment-share is rather “hump-shaped” (as noted by Ngai

and Pissarides (2007) and Maddison (1980)). Hence, alternative stylized-facts of

structural change (which take account of the last two centuries or so) can be

formulated, which I name Furastié-facts:

a) The employment share of agriculture declines during the development process.

b) The employment share of manufacturing increases in early stages of development

(“industrialization”) and decreases in later stages of development (“tertialisation”).

c) The employment share of services increases during the development process.

I name these stylized facts after Jean Fourastié who discusses them in his book (see

Furastié (1969), pp.118ff). These stylized facts are also discussed as being the “three-

sector hypothesis” and have already been noted by Fisher (1939), according to Krüger

(2008), p.332.

Since, according to Definition 2, structural change across technologically distinct

sectors is in focus of my research, I should provide evidence that this sort of structural

change actually takes place. Empirical evidence on the fact, that in reality factors are

reallocated across technologically distinct sectors, is provided by: Close and

Schulenburger (1971), Baumol et al. (1985), Maddison (1987), p.666ff, Bernard and

Jones (1996), Broadberry (1997), Curtis and Murthy (1998), Foster et al. (1998),

Disney et al. (2003), Penderer (2003), Broadberry and Irwin (2006), Schettkat and

Yocarini (2006), UN (2006), Acemogly and Guerrieri (2008), Nordhaus (2008),

Valentinyi and Herrendorf (2008) and Duarte and Restuccia (2010).

8

Page 19: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

In fact, these essays show that even the Kuznets- and Furastié-stylized-facts imply

that factors are reallocated across technologically distinct sectors, since agriculture,

manufacturing and services use different technology. (Even within these sectors

different technologies are used.) In fact, Wolfe’s (1955)-sector-division is based on

technological differences between sectors.

Because Baumol’s (1967)-work popularized the focus on sector-differences in

technology, I name the fact, that factors are reallocated across technology in reality,

Baumol’s stylized fact.

3. Why does structural change take place? – The four main structural change determinants When looking at the evidence on structural change, one question arises: why does

structural change occur? The literature has already dealt with this question. In fact,

there are four main types of cross-sector disparities that cause structural change. I

name them “structural change determinants” and they will be discussed now.

As proposed by Schettkat and Yocarini (2006), there are three main determinants of

structural change: cross-sector shifts in final demand (non-homothetic preferences),

cross-sector shifts in intermediates production (outsourcing), and cross-sector

differences in productivity growth. Note that differences in productivity growth can

arise due to differences in TFP-growth and due to differences in output-elasticities of

inputs across sectors as will be explained below. (Some further structural change

determinants, e.g. international trade, which are not in focus of my research, are

discussed in Chapter IV, Section 5.)

Empirical evidence on the impact of these determinants on structural change is

reviewed, e.g., by Schettkat and Yocarini (2006). Further evidence is provided in Part

I of Chapter V. I discuss the evidence on the structural change determinants in Part I

9

Page 20: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

of Chapter V, since the proof of their relevance is an integral part of that Part, but is

less relevant for the other Parts of Chapter V.

The impacts of structural-change-determinants on structural change are jointly studied

in the model of Part I of Chapter V. Nevertheless, in the following, I explain how

each of these determinants causes structural change by itself and I provide some

references. Note that the following explanations are based on the long-run view of the

economy, where perfect cross-sector-mobility of factors and, in general, perfect

markets are assumed.

3.1 Non-homothetic preferences across sectors Non-homothetic preferences mean simply that income elasticity differs across goods.

Hence, when income increases, the demand does not increase uniformly across goods;

i.e. the demand for some goods increases more strongly in comparison to the demand

for other goods; i.e. demand is “shifted” across sectors, which produce these goods.

In general, it is argued that some sectors (e.g. agriculture) produce rather goods,

which are necessities (e.g. food); therefore, income-elasticity of demand is relatively

low regarding these sectors. It is argued as well, that other sectors (e.g. services)

produce rather goods which are luxury goods; hence, income-elasticity of demand is

rather high. For discussion, references and empirical evidence see e.g. Krüger (2008),

p.335, Schettkat and Yocarini (2006), pp.139ff, Laitner (2000), p.546, Curtis and

Murthy (1998). A micro-foundation of non-homothetic preferences in multi-sector

frameworks is provided by Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008) by using Engel’s Law.

The demand-shifts, which are caused by non-homothetic preferences, cause changes

in relative profitability of factor-use across sectors and thus result in factor

reallocation across sectors, i.e. structural change.

10

Page 21: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Of course, an impulse is necessary, which ensures that income increases over time. In

my models, this impulse comes from technological progress.

Non-homothetic preferences as a determinant of structural change are modeled by,

e.g., Kongsamut et al. (2001). Further literature, which studies the impact of non-

homothetic preferences in structural change frameworks, can be found in Section 3 of

Chapter IV.

3.2 Differences in TFP-growth across sectors If the growth rate of productivity differs across sectors, sectors can expand their

production at different rates for a given factor allocation. That is, production-

possibilities grow at different rates across sectors. Or the other way around: sectors

that feature relatively high productivity-growth-rates (“progressive sectors”) can

lower their prices over time more strongly in comparison to sectors with relatively

low productivity growth rates (“stagnant sectors”), for a given cross-sector factor

allocation and for a given profit rate.4 That is, the relative prices are changing.

Consumers respond to changes in relative prices; thus, demand is shifted across

sectors. These demand shifts cause factor reallocations similar to those discussed in

Section 3.1; thus, structural change arises.

Note, however, that there are two different forces regarding this factor reallocation:

On the one hand, the (relative) production possibilities increase in the progressive

sectors (in comparison to stagnant sectors). This effect implies that less factors are

required in the progressive sectors to produce a given amount of goods. – Effect 1

4 Of course, since we consider long-run perfect markets with perfect mobility, the profit rate is equal to zero.

11

Page 22: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

On the other hand, (relative) demand increases in the progressive sector due to

relative price reductions. This effect implies that more factors are required for

production in progressive sectors. – Effect 2

Hence, whether factors are reallocated to progressive sectors or withdrawn from them

depends on which of the two effects is stronger. We know that Effect 2 depends on

the price elasticity of demand. If price elasticity of demand is relatively high (low),

households react very strongly (weakly) to price-changes. Therefore, if price elasticity

of demand is relatively high (low), Effect 2 is relatively strong (weak) and factors are

reallocated to (withdrawn from) the progressive sectors.

This argumentation implies that there must be a certain price elasticity which ensures

that Effects 1 and 2 are equally strong hence no factors are reallocated across sectors.

In fact, it can be shown that this is the case when price elasticity is equal to one (see

e.g. Ngai and Pisssarides (2007)).

The impact of cross-sector-TFP-differences on structural change is modeled by, e.g.,

Baumol (1967) and Ngai and Pissarides (2007). For further literature, see Chapter IV,

Section 3.

Now, the question arises why does TFP-growth differ across sectors. Regarding this

question and empirical evidence see Section 4.

3.3 Differences in output-elasticites of inputs across sectors Assume that output-elasticity of labor differs across sectors; this may be the case

when capital is introduced into production functions. Especially, assume that there are

labor-intensive sectors (i.e. sectors that feature high output-elasticity of labor) and

capital-intensive sectors (i.e. sectors that feature low output-elasticity of labor).

Furthermore, assume that the real wage-rate increases, ceteris paribus. Hence, the

average production costs in labor-intensive sectors increase more strongly in

12

Page 23: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

comparison to the average production costs of capital-intensive-sectors, ceteris

paribus.5 Therefore, when the wage rate increases, the labor-intensive producers must

increase their prices more strongly in comparison to capital-intensive producers, for

given profit rates, ceteris paribus. That is, relative prices change. These relative price

changes cause factor reallocations in similar manner as in Section 3.2, i.e. structural

change arises. Like in Section 3.2, price-elasticity plays an important role for the

magnitude/direction of the resulting structural change.

Again, an impulse is necessary to increase the wage rate. In my models this impulse

comes from technological progress. (It is known from neoclassical growth theory, e.g.

the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model, that an income-increase associated with

technological progress, causes an increase of the wage rate. In this respect my model

is the same; see, e.g., equation (33) in Part I of Chapter V. (For a discussion of the

Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model, see, e.g., Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), pp.85ff, or

Chapter III.)

For example, Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) provide a model, which explains

exactly how cross-sector differences in output-elasticities of inputs cause structural

change. For further literature, see Chapter IV, Section 3.

In Section 4, I provide intuitive arguments for why output-elasticites differ across

sectors.

3.4 Shifts in intermediates production across sectors Assume that each sector produces not only final goods, but intermediate goods as

well, which are used in the own production and in the other-sectors production.

5 The reason for this fact is simple: labor-intensive sectors use relatively much labor (in optimum); hence, a relatively large part of their average production costs is due to wage payments.

13

Page 24: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Differences in productivity-growth across intermediates production cause changes in

intermediate prices. Hence, cost-minimizing producers change their intermediate-

input-structure. Hence, there are changes in intermediate demand across sectors; they

cause factor-reallocation across sectors.

Models, which explain this channel exactly, are provided by, e.g., Fixler and Siegel

(1999) and Ngai and Pissarides (2007). Further literature can be found in Chapter IV,

Section 2.

The fact that each sector uses intermediates from other sectors is obvious and can be

seen from Input-Output-Tables of every country. It is obvious that the most of the

today’s very complex products are produced by using many different intermediates

from many different sectors. Just think about which resources, parts and services are

necessary to produce and sell a car.

4. Why does technology differ across sectors? Empirical evidence on technology-differences across sectors (output-elasticity of

inputs as well as TFP) is discussed in Part I of Chapter V. Why these differences exist

is quite obvious: The “nature of the final-product” differs across sectors strongly.

Therefore, the (physical) production processes, the resources which are used in

production, the sectoral market-structures, the degree of technology-spillovers from

other sectors/industries as well as transfer-process of the final-product to the

consumer differ across sectors strongly. In general, these differences affect the scope

for technological innovation, rationalization (substitution of labor by capital) and

division of labor for a given level of technological development. In fact, these

differences are (in part) the key criterion of sector-division according to Wolfe

(1955).

14

Page 25: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

These aspects can be best understood by comparing the production process of a potato

and the “production process” of a service like counseling by a psychologist:

• The key restricting resource in the production process of a potato is land. Hence,

to some extent, the productivity increases in potato production are restricted by the

availability/extent of land and by growth rates of natural products (e.g. today a

potato still requires some time to grow). On the other hand, in psychological

counseling natural resources are rather unimportant. Hence, in psychological

counseling there is no scope for productivity improvements by increasing the

usability of the natural resource. The other way around, the productivity

improvements in counseling are not restricted by improvability of land-use or by

natural growth rates. (Rather, other facts restrict the productivity of counseling.)

These arguments are related to Wolfe (1955), p.414ff. To see how inclusion of

land in the agricultural production-function leads to different sectoral productivity

parameters, see, e.g., the model by Laitner (2000).

• The production of a potato includes a lot of “mechanical processes”. That is, a

human (or a machine) must move some physical matters from one place to another

in order to produce a potato, e.g. the seed must be spread and the potatoes must be

harvested. Hence, a lot of labor can be substituted by capital (= rationalization),

when relatively simple mechanical machines are invented. In contrast, mechanical

processes are not important for psychological counseling (except for the fact that

the patient must come to the psychologist). Hence, rationalization of the

counseling process by simple machine-innovations is very restricted or even

impossible. Hence, psychological counseling is necessarily labor-intensive. (This

argument is related to Wolfe (1955), pp.416ff, and Klevorick et al. (1995),

pp.187f. Klevorick et al. (1995) provide a study where they try to asses the

technological possibilities of several industries.). Therefore, in psychological

15

Page 26: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

counseling is no/few scope for productivity-increases by technological innovation

related to capital. Of course, we can think of intelligent robots that have the fine

emotional sensibility of a human. However, this seems very futuristic.

(Furthermore, the question is whether such robots are regarded as machines or as

“humans”; in the latter case the usage of such robots would not decrease the labor-

intensity of counseling). To sum up: The rationalization of some industries/sectors

may require very fine/sophisticated technology developments (e.g. micro-chip),

which must be based on some basic mechanical/chemical/physical innovations

(steel, plastic, electricity). These basic innovations may rationalize the production

process of some sectors (potatoes); therefore, even in early stages of technological

development some sectors may be rationalized, especially sectors which include a

lot of mechanical processes. However, the industries/sectors, which require fine

technology improvement for rationalization, (psychological counseling) may

remain very labor-intense over the most phases of technological/economic

development (or “for ever”).

• The amount of technology-spill-overs from other sectors is as well determined by

the “nature of the product”. The production process of a potato was very enhanced

by some technological innovations of the manufacturing sector, where the

manufacturing sector is very technologically progressive due to the effects

discussed above/below among others. In contrast, psychological counseling

profited hardly from manufacturing-sector-advances. (This argument is related to

Klevorick et al. (1995), p.190f.). The strength of technology-spill-overs from

manufacturing to potato production is among others due to the fact that both

include a lot of “mechanical processes”.

• While a potato can be transferred to a consumer within few seconds,

psychological counseling services require the permanent personal contact of the

16

Page 27: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

service provider to the “consumer”. This difference manifests the high labor

intensity of counseling services. In fact, in counseling services “labor is itself the

end-product” (Baumol (1967), p.416). This aspect has also another side (see also

Blinder (2007) for an interesting study regarding the following fact): In fact, the

psychologist could analyze its patient via life-stream via internet. However, a

masseur cannot transfer its service via communication and information

technologies. Hence, many industries, that require direct personal contact in order

to transfer the “final product” to the consumer, feature fewer productivity

improvements from to technological progress in information and communication

technologies.

• The different stages of potato production can be conducted by different

persons/producers/employees. Hence, productivity of potato production can be

increased by labor-division, by better organization of the production process and

by specialization on a specific stage of the production process (e.g. outsourcing or

labor-division a la Adam-Smith). In contrast, psychological counseling requires

that the largest part of the process is conducted by one person.

• Some further arguments/literature are/is discussed by Klevorick et al. (1995),

pp.186f, and Pavitt (1985), pp.365ff. These arguments are related to the market

structure (that is caused by nature of the final product) and its impacts on the

R&D-efforts of the firms. For example, depending upon the nature of the product,

the existing market structure may consist of large firms (potatoes), and hence more

R&D may be initiated by them in comparison to other environments (counseling)

where firms are rather small (and thus cannot cope with large R&D-sunk-costs).

Furthermore, the size of demand, the fraction of R&D-returns that a firm is able to

retain (large vs. low spillovers/externalities) and the type of competition depend

17

Page 28: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

on the nature of the final product as well and can cause cross-sector differences in

R&D and thus in technology(-progress).

In fact, this discussion implies that there is a strong time-component in cross-sector

technology differences. It seems that there is a path of technologic development: In

the beginning, there are innovations, which rationalize mechanical processes.

Rationalization of mechanical processes is relatively simple and therefore stands at

the beginning of the technological development path. Industries/sectors (especially

manufacturing), where mechanical processes are a key component of the production

process, profit from these innovations. Over time, the rationalization of mechanical

processes progresses and the technologies that are used become more and more

sophisticated and the aggregated income increases. This whole process is named

industrialization. During this process the basis for fine technologies is constituted.

This basis and the increasing income (and thus increasing demand for luxury services)

open the door for technological progress in sectors/industries, where mechanical

processes are not the core of the production process, especially in some services

industries. This phase is often named tertiarisation.

In fact, what we learn from this whole discussion is that sectoral technologies diverge

during the industrialization (when comparing manufacturing and services). However,

during the tertialisation and especially in future the technologies could converge

again. The question is, whether the technological progress in manufacturing will be

strong enough to counteract this process. In fact, as discussed by Pavitt (1985) and

Klevorick et al. (1995), there seems to be a path dependence of technological progress

to some extent. That is, much of technological progress in past constitutes much of

future technological progress. However, the new possibilities which are opened to

18

Page 29: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

technological progress in services by the development of the micro-chip could be

stronger and improve the services technology to unbelievable levels in future.

Overall, it is hard to find a strong reason for the assumption that future technology-

development-patterns will remain the same as in past.

Actually, this discussion is the basis for the long-run-independency-discussion in Part

I of Chapter V. I argue there (by using purely intuitive argumentation) that (for given

preference parameters) we have no reason to assume that high-income-elasticity-

sectors (like some services) will remain technologically inferior.

This seems to be a very interesting and valuable topic for future research. Note,

however, that I have not researched very much in this field; my research-focus was

rather on the implications of actual cross-sector technology differences, instead on the

reasons for and future development of these differences.

5. Impact of structural change on the economy: focus on aggregate growth Structural change has several effects on the society and the economy. For example,

• the Kuznets facts imply that an increasing part of manufacturing-sector-labor

is reallocated to the services sector; hence, the nature of working tasks and the

working environment changes, which may have some impact on the society;

e.g., Pugno (2006) argues that the economy-wide human capital may increase

due to this change in tasks (which may increase economic growth);

• since different sectors require different skills, structural change requires

changes in the education system, as noted by Blinder (2007);6

6 Especially, very different skill sets are required when comparing the manufacturing and the services sector.

19

Page 30: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

• the reallocation of labor across sectors may cause short-run to medium-run

unemployment, and the rate of natural unemployment may be affected by the

strength of structural change in the medium-run;7 see e.g. Aronson et al.

(2004);

• structural change affects the growth rate of aggregates (e.g. the growth rate of

real GDP, aggregate capital and aggregate consumption expenditures), as I

will show soon.

For all these reasons it seems to be important to study and predict the changes in

structural change patterns and the changes in structural change strength. In my

research I focus solely on the study of structural change itself and on the impact of

structural change on the growth rate of aggregates. The other impacts (e.g. impacts on

unemployment) are not in focus of my research.

Empirical evidence on the impact of structural change on aggregate growth is

provided by, e.g., Robinson (1971), Madisson (1987), pp.666ff, Dowrick and Gemmel

(1991), Bernard and Jones (1996), Broadberry (1997,1998), Foster et al. (1998),

Berthélmy and Söderling (1999), Poirson (2000), Caselli and Coleman (2001),

Temple (2001), Disney et al. (2003), Penderer (2003), Broadberry and Irwin (2006),

UN (2006), Nordhaus (2008), Restuccia et al. (2008) and Duarte and Restuccia

(2010).

Now, I present a very short model, which is based on the model by Baumol (1967), to

explain why structural change has an impact on the growth rate of aggregates.

Assume a long-run growth model where two sectors (A and B) exist and where labor

is the only input-factor. The sectors differ by productivity:

7 Note that in the long run structural change cannot cause unemployment, since “long-run” is defined upon full cross-sector-mobility of labor.

20

Page 31: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(1) LAlY AA =

(2) LBlY BB =

(3) 1=+ BA ll

where ( ) is the output of sector A (B), ( ) is the employment share of sector

A (B), A (B) is the exogenous productivity parameter of sector A (B) and L is the

aggregate amount of labor. Equation (3) implies that we abstract from unemployment.

AY BY Al Bl

The real GDP (Y) is some weighted average of the sectoral outputs

(4) BA YaaYY )1( −+≡

where a is the weighting factor between the sectors. (Later, I will discuss it in detail.)

Inserting equations (1) and (2) into equation (4) yields

(5) [ ]BA BlaaAlLY )1( −+=

Remember that structural change means changes in and .Al Bl8 Equation (5) implies

that changes in and lead to changes in Y. Hence, structural change has an

impact on real GDP(-growth).

Al Bl

In fact, this is the quintessence of the relationship between structural change and

aggregate growth. Of course this is a very simple model; however, it shows why

structural change affects aggregate growth. In Chapters III and V, I analyse the

generalizations of this model. For example, I assumed here that the weighting factor a

is exogenous. However, sometimes, when real GDP is calculated with the “chain-

weights-method”, the weighting factor depends on the actual sectoral outputs and

hence on structural change. (For a simple explanation regarding this fact, see e.g.

Steindel 1995). However, I will show in Parts II and III of Chapter V that, despite this

fact, structural change still has an impact on real GDP-growth. Furthermore, capital

8 If A and B grow at different rates, it could be shown that structural change takes place in this model, like in the model by Baumol (1967). Furthermore, structural change could be generated by the assumption that preferences are non-homothetic across goods A and B.

21

Page 32: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

and explicit assumptions about household-behaviour could be integrated into this

model. In this way it could be shown that structural change has an impact on the

growth rate of aggregate capital and consumption expenditures.

6. The two schools of structural change modelling: Focus on the neoclassical PBGP-school The largest part of mainstream growth theory is based on the concept of balanced

growth. That is, the most models feature assumptions which ensure the existence of a

balanced growth path (or: steady state). A balanced growth path is a trajectory where

all (relevant) variables grow at a constant rate. (For detailed discussion see Chapter

II.)

For example, the standard neoclassical growth models, like the Solow-model or the

Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model, generate an equilibrium that can be described by two

differential equations. These differential equations determine the growth paths of

consumption and capital. The assumptions of these models are such that this

differential equation-system features a stable (convergent) equilibrium growth path,

where capital and consumption grow at a constant rate. Hence, the equilibrium growth

path is a balanced growth path. (See also Chapters II and III for detailed explanations

and discussion.)

The convenient feature of the balanced growth approach is that the growth rates of the

variables are not state-dependent along the balanced growth path. That is, the growth

rates can be easily derived as functions of exogenous model parameters, and phase-

diagrams/simulations are only necessary to study the transitional dynamics. (For

details see Chapters II and III.) Furthermore, the balanced growth path is consistent

22

Page 33: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

with the empirical evidence known as “Kaldor’s stylized facts of economic

development”.9 (See also Kongsamut et al. (2001)).

Therefore, it is not surprising that nearly the whole neoclassical growth theory (see

e.g. the book by Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004)) is based on the balanced growth

concept.

Unfortunately, the theoretical literature implies that it is not easy to integrate

structural change into the balanced growth concept; see Chapter III. In the following I

provide examples of this literature. More literature-examples are provided in Chapter

IV.

• Baumol’s (1967)-model implies that the growth rate of aggregate output is not

constant, if there are at least two sectors (which differ by productivity-

growth). In contrast, the Solow-Model or the Ramsey-Kass-Koopmans-model

imply that the growth rate of aggregate output is constant along a balanced

growth path.

• Kongsamut et al. (2001) and Meckl (2002) show that neoclassical balanced

growth theory can be consistent with structural change only if some parameter

restrictions are assumed. However, they cannot provide any theoretical

rationale for these parameter restrictions.

• The paper by Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) implies that the neoclassical

balanced growth path does not exist as long as structural change takes place

and as long as sectors differ by output-elasticity of inputs.

Hence, structural change models imply that balanced growth theory is not necessarily

applicable as long as structural change takes place. This seems to be a serious critique

9 Kaldor facts are discussed in Part I of Chapter V.

23

Page 34: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

point to balanced growth theory (neoclassical growth theory), since structural change

is one of the best known empirical facts.

Overall, it seems that there exist two schools of growth theory which contradict each

other: “balanced growth school” and “structural change school”. The balanced

growth school stands for the mainstream neoclassical growth theory. The models of

the balanced growth school are micro-founded (e.g. they use utility functions). The

structural change school stands for the structural change models where no balanced

growth paths exist (as long as structural change takes place), e.g. the models by

Baumol (1967), Echevarria (1997), Laitner (2000) and Acemoglu and Guerrieri

(2008). Note that the structural change school is not necessarily consistent with

Kaldor’s stylized facts. (Kaldor’s stylized facts require that capital, consumption and

output grow at a constant rate, i.e. the growth path must be balanced, while the

structural change school features unbalanced growth paths.) Furthermore, since the

structural change school does not rely on balanced growth paths, the analysis is

relatively complicated (which will be demonstrated in Chapter III). Therefore, the

models from the structural change school make either very simple assumptions (e.g.

capital is omitted in the model by Baumol (1967)), or simulations are necessary to

obtain the model results (e.g. in the models by Echevarria (1997) and Acemoglu and

Guerrieri (2008)); see also the literature discussion in Section 3.1 of Chapter IV.

Simulations are a very useful tool in economic modeling; however, they feature

several disadvantages:

• A (numerical) simulation seems to be like a black box in comparison to

analytically solvable models: That is, in relatively complex numerically solved

models it is difficult to understand why certain growth dynamics arise. Thus, it

requires a broad knowledge about analytically solvable models to guess which

factors led to certain dynamics. Therefore, developing analytically solvable

24

Page 35: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

structural change models seems to be important: they can help to understand

the several channels along which structural change determinants affect

structural change and thus real GDP-growth; hence they can help to

understand numerically solvable models.

• The result of a numerical simulation is only applicable to the data which is

used. Hence, for example a structural change simulation for the USA, does not

say anything about structural change in Germany. Hence, for each

specification of parameters a new simulation is necessary. Therefore, it is

difficult to derive general theoretical results from numerical models. (See also

Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.113).

• Sometimes it is possible to derive the parameter-range for which the baseline

results of a numerical solution hold (however, these tests do not provide

100%-certainty). However, I have not seen such an approach in structural

change theory. Furthermore, the problem with such parameter range is that the

parameters which are displayed by the computer are solely numbers, but not

some parameter relations (equations). Hence, it is difficult to asses whether

these “numbers” will hold in future and it is difficult to derive some “micro-

foundation” for these “numbers”. In general, this problem does not appear in

analytically solvable models: if analytically solvable models feature some

parameter restrictions, these restrictions can be derived as parameter-equations

or -relations (like in the models by Kongsamut et al. (1997,2001)). Hence, it is

easier to derive a micro-foundation for these parameter restrictions. In fact, in

the essay about the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle (Chapter V) I try to derive a micro-

foundation for the parameter-restrictions of the Kongsamut et al. (1997,2001)-

model.

25

Page 36: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

So we can conclude that developing analytically solvable structural change models is

important for understanding structural change and for discussion about future

structural change.

Motivated by these challenges (in part), a new school emerged in the growth theory

(the “PBGP-school”) which attempts to merge the balanced growth school and the

structural change school by introducing the concept of “partially balanced growth”. A

“partially balanced growth path” (PBGP) features at the same time balanced growth

of aggregates and unbalanced growth of disaggregated variables. That is, along a

PBGP, aggregate output and aggregate capital grow at a constant rate and at the

same time structural change takes place (e.g. sectoral output shares change).

Hence, the convenient features of PBGP-analysis are:

• Like the neoclassical-growth-models, PBGP-models are analytically solvable.

Hence, we can derive in a convenient way relatively transparent explanations

and “general” theories about structural change (and aggregate growth). Many

aspects of structural change become easily analysable. This makes structural

change theory more transparent and more amenable to a larger group of

scientist (especially those who are familiar with neoclassical analysis.)

• The models are consistent with the Kaldor-facts (see also e.g. Kongsamut et

al. 2001).

• Since the PBGP is consistent with the equilibrium growth paths of the

“balanced-growth-school”, developing PBGP-models can help to reduce the

critique on the mainstream balanced-growth school (“Balanced growth school

is consistent with structural change.”)

However, it should be noted that the existence of a PBGP requires some restrictions in

the generality of the assumptions. Therefore, often a PBGP-model cannot depict all

26

Page 37: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

the structural change channels. Nevertheless, relevant theoretical results can be

derived by using the PBGP-concept. This topic will be discussed in Section 8 in

detail.

To my knowledge, Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001) are the first who introduced the

concept of PBGP-analysis into structural change theory. Several authors followed:

Meckl (2002), Ngai and Pissarides (2007) and Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008). (These

essays are discussed in Chapters III and IV). I focus on the PBGP-analysis of

structural change as well.

In this sense, my research aims to contribute to the development of the PBGP-school

of structural change by elaborating its foundations, classifying it and applying it to

several topics associated with structural change. Especially, I focus on three topics

which are associated with structural change and which are dealing with some key

stylized facts of economic development and/or some general macro-economic trends:

the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle, the impact of offshoring on structural change and

aggregate growth and the impact of ageing on real GDP-growth via structural change.

These topics are explained in Section 9. Note that I focused on these three topics,

since they seem to me “most” important (see Section 9). However, the PBGP-method

seems to be applicable to many more topics and it seems to be interesting for further

research to find such topics.

7. Further theoretical/analytical restrictions of the analysis I study structural change in the consumption goods sector. That is, I assume that there

are sectors that produce heterogenous consumption goods. On the other hand, it can

be assumed, e.g., that there are several types of capital and that these types of capital

are produced by different sectors. Hence, structural change in the capital-goods-sector

27

Page 38: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

could be analysed as well. However, heterogeneous capital goods (and hence

structural change in the capital-producing sector) have been studied extensively in the

neoclassical endogenous growth literature (e.g. in models where physical capital and

human capital exists). Structural change in capital production and other types of

structural change are discussed in Chapter IV.

It should be noted here that all the models, which are developed in Chapters III and V,

are long run growth models. That is, I assume that

• there is perfect factor mobility across sectors

• prices are flexible and

• capital can be accumulated.

The inclusion of capital into analysis is a key to my research for two reasons:

(1) Some theoretical/empirical questions simply require the consideration of

capital in structural change analysis. For example, the analysis of the Kuznets-

Kaldor puzzle (see also the corresponding essay in Chapter V) requires a

model of structural change that takes capital accumulation into account, since

Kaldor-facts summarize mainly some empirical facts that are related to

capital. A model, where no capital exists, is comparable to only one Kaldor

fact: “the constancy of the output-growth-rate”. All the other Kaldor-facts (i.e.

increasing capital-intensity, a constant capital-to-output-ratio, a constant real

rate of return on capital and a constant income-distribution between capital

and labor) require the inclusion of capital into analysis.

(2) Capital-accumulation is still regarded as one of the key growth drivers. It

has been extensively studied in the neoclassical growth literature. Hence, in

general, it seems important to study the relationship between structural change

and capital accumulation and vice versa. Indeed, there seems to be a

28

Page 39: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

relationship between capital-accumulation and structural change, as will be

discussed in Part II of Chapter V: First, since structural change affects the

productivity of factors, capital accumulation is affected by structural change,10

and we know from the neoclassical growth literature that capital accumulation

is important for aggregate growth. Second, the labor, which is available in an

economy, can be used for consumption-goods-production and for capital-

goods-consumption. Hence, if for some reasons labor is reallocated to capital-

production, it has to be withdrawn from consumption-goods-production. If a

smaller share of labor is used in the consumption-sector, all productivity

effects, which arise from labor-reallocation within the consumption-goods-

sector, become less important from the viewpoint of the economy as a whole.

Hence, the reallocation of labor between capital-goods-production and

consumption-goods-production has an important effect on the relationship

between consumption-goods-structural change and aggregate growth. This

argument will be of special importance in the Offshoring-essay and is also

discussed in Section 5 of Chapter IV.

(3) In reality, capital is used in production. Production functions with capital,

in general, generate (additional) structural change dynamics. For example, the

essay by Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) implies that (consumption-industries-

)structural change arises from the fact that capital and labor can be substituted

in production.

Beside of the fact that there are several consumption-goods sectors, all assumptions in

my research are very neoclassical: I assume neoclassical (representative) utility

10 Remember, that we know from neoclassical growth theory that the rate of capital accumulation depends on productivity growth; structural change affects productivity growth.

29

Page 40: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

functions and production functions. In fact the aggregate structure of my models

coincides with the neoclassical growth models (see also Chapter III).

There are two reasons for using neoclassical assumptions:

(1) As explained above, it is interesting to know to what extent the (mainstream)

neoclassical growth theory is compatible with structural change. To reassess

neoclassical growth theory neoclassical assumptions are necessary.

(2) The assumptions of the neoclassical theory have been developed and studied

over a very long period of time. Therefore it is not surprising that they are very

convenient in analysis. They ensure that

• the optimization problems can be solved in an uncomplicated manner (e.g. by

using a Hamiltonian function; i.e. the sufficient conditions for the optimality

of the solution are ensured by neoclassical assumptions in my models; see also

Chapter II)

• the resulting equilibrium growth paths are stable (as is discussed in Chapter II)

• the stability analysis of the equilibrium growth paths is relatively simple (see

also Chapter II).

Furthermore, I have tried to use as simple functional forms as possible (without

reducing the generality of the key-model results): Especially, I use Cobb-Douglas

production functions and Cobb-Douglas-based utility functions. Cobb-Douglas

production functions are sufficient to include all key structural change determinants

which have been discussed above. (This is demonstrated in the models of Chapter III.)

Last not least, it should be noted that I assume that sectors use different technology

(see Section 1); however, these cross-sector differences in technology are not

explained endogenously in my models, but are assumed to be exogenously given.

30

Page 41: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Hence, I can only justify the cross-sector technology differences in my models by

pointing to the empirical evidence, which implies that these differences existed in

past. (For this empirical evidence see Section 2 of the actual chapter and Part I of

Chapter V). This is acceptable, since the largest part of my research is either about

explaining past developments (Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle) or about the proof of

existence of some effects in frameworks with technologically heterogeneous sectors

(Ageing and Offshoring models). However, the exogenity of technology parameters

restricts my results regarding future predictions to some extent. This topic is discussed

in the next section.

8. General value of the models or: Which statements can be drawn from the models and which not? My models are not aimed to predict/explain the overall dynamics of structural change.

Rather, they are theoretical constructs, which are used to isolate some theoretical

relationships (or: channels) between structural-change-determinants and cross-sector

factor-reallocation and between structural change and aggregate growth. The

structural change in reality cannot be explained only by my model-explanations, but

requires further explanations (which in part have not been found yet). The reason for

this fact is that PBGPs never depict all structural change channels at the same time, as

will be shown in the models of Chapter III. Hence, the overall dynamics of structural

change can only be explained by more complicated models that probably require

numerical solutions. (Furthermore, further research is required to isolate further

channels, in order to be able to construct numerical models more exactly.)

Overall, my models do not depict the reality, i.e. they are not descriptive models. For

example, I do not state that the economies are on a PBGP in reality. Also I do not

state that an average household behaves in the same manner as the representative

31

Page 42: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

household in my models. The PBGP is only a theoretical construct that helps to take a

simple look at structural change.

For example, let us take the model about the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle (Chapter V).

This model states that the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle is solved along a PBGP. However, I

do not state that real economies are on the PBGP. I used the PBGP-concept, since it

allows isolating a certain type of structural change pattern (“neutral structural

change”), which is consistent with the Kaldor-Kuznets-Puzzle. That is, the model

helped me to recognise the distinctive feature of “neutral structural change”. By using

this distinctive feature I was able to test empirically to what extent is “neutral

structural change” an explanation of the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle in reality. Hence, the

PBGP itself is not an explanation of the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle, but “neutral

structural change”, and relatively neutral structural change does not necessarily

require a PBGP.

Similar arguments apply to the other models: In Chapter V, I analyse offshoring and

ageing along PBGPs, since in this way they are easy to analyse. In this way I am able

to isolate some channels along which offshoring and ageing influence aggregate

growth. These channels exist even if the economy is not on the PBGP. Hence, again

the PBGP is not the explanation for these channels, but is only a technical help to

isolate these channels. For those reasons, the results of these papers hold, irrespective

of whether the real economies are on a PBGP or not.

Hence, the general relationship between (my) PBGP-models and numerical structural

change models is: PBGP-models help to recognize impact channels (and to test their

relative importance). Numerical models help to reproduce (and predict) overall

structural change patterns. The overall structural change patterns can be explained by

the results of several PBGP-models; furthermore, the theories from the PBGP-models

32

Page 43: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

can help to asses whether the future-predictions of the numerical structural change

models are reasonable.

Last not least, remember that cross-sector technology-heterogeneity is not explained

endogenously in my models, as explained in Section 7. Hence, all the predictions of

my models regarding the future should be considered with caution. As discussed in

Section 4, it is possible that sector-technologies converge in (far) future, and hence

structural change becomes rather irrelevant regarding real GDP-growth. Therefore,

some of the effects studied in my models may become irrelevant in (far) future.

9. Justification for the choice of topics that are analysed by using PBGP-models As already mentioned, by using the PBGP-method I study three topics that are

associated with structural change: “Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle”, “Offshoring and

Structural Change” and “Ageing and Structural Change”. The criteria, which I have

used to choose these topics, are

• scientific interest (indicated by the number of topic-related publications in top-

ten economic journals)

• relevance of the phenomenon (e.g. whether it is a key macro-economic trend)

• applicability of the PBGP-concept

• whether additional results are obtainable.

Nearly all articles that study the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle are published in top-five

economic journals: Kongsamut et al. (2001), Ngai and Pissarides (2007), Foellmi and

Zweimüller (2008) and Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008)). Hence, this topic seems to

be of interest from the scientific point of view. Furthermore, the concept of PBGP has

been introduced by Kongsamut et al. (2001) to study the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle;

33

Page 44: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

hence, the PBGP-concept is applicable to this topic. Overall, my model on the

Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle contains all the key structural change determinants and it can

reproduce the empirically observable structural change patterns.

While the essay on the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle studies the traditional (or: “key”)

structural change determinants, my remaining essays study the impacts of the two key

(future) macro-economic trends that will probably have a relatively strong impact on

structural change (and thus growth) in future: offshoring and ageing.

Offshoring has been a very prominent topic in the political debate across Europe and

the United States in the 2000s, which induced a relatively extensive scientific debate,

indicated by a relative large number of publications in top journals. Therefore,

offshoring seems to be an important topic. The previous literature on offshoring is

primarily based on static models and/or models that do not include capital (in order to

keep the analysis traceable). The essay on offshoring adds to this discussion some

interesting dynamic effects of offshoring associated with structural change and

capital-accumulation. Nevertheless, the analysis in the offshoring essay remains

relatively traceable due to the application of the PBGP-concept.

Ageing is one of the key macro-economic trends in industrialized economies.

Nevertheless, the relationship between ageing and real-GDP growth via structural

change (i.e. via ageing induced cross-sector-demand-shifts) has been barely studied.

To my knowledge the only paper, that tries to model this relationship, is the one by

Groezen et al. (2005). Groezen et al. (2005) use very restrictive assumptions

regarding the consumption behaviour of the old people. By using the PBGP-concept I

was able, to generalize some of their assumptions and to show the existence of further

channels along which ageing affects structural change and thus real GDP-growth.

Of course, there seem to be many topics associated with structural change that need to

be analysed; they are left for further research.

34

Page 45: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

In the following chapter, I provide some explanations, which are necessary to

understand the mathematical aspects of my research.

35

Page 46: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

36

Page 47: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

CHAPTER II

Key Analytical Tool:

Differential Equation System Analysis

- Definitions, Analytical Concepts and Methods -

The most of dynamic economic analysis can be described as three-step procedure (in

general, I follow this procedure as well):

First, assumptions are made about the institutional/physical structures within which

the agents act, i.e. assumptions on the framework, e.g. assumptions on production

functions, resource endowments and distribution, type of market, etc.

Second, assumptions are made on the behaviour of agents, e.g. rational behaviour,

perfect foresight, profit/utility maximization, etc.).

These two sorts of assumptions create a set of dynamic equations, which describe the

dynamic development of the model. For example, in neoclassical growth theories and

especially in all my research, the two sorts of assumptions are used to formulate

equilibrium conditions/postulates and dynamic maximization problems. The latter are

(often) solved by using optimal control techniques, especially the Hamiltonian

function, yielding some dynamic and static optimality conditions. These optimality

conditions as well as the equilibrium postulates establish a dynamic equation system.

In a third step the evolution of this dynamic equation system (and hence of the model)

is analysed. This analysis is conducted by using several methods and concepts of

dynamic-equation-system-analysis.

It should be noted that dynamic equation systems can be divide into differential

equation systems (where time is continuous) and difference equation systems (where

37

Page 48: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

time is discrete). The methods of analysis (e.g. optimization, stability analysis, etc.)

differ between these two types of equation systems. In my research I prefer

continuous-time-models and therefore I discuss only the methods that are necessary

for differential equation system analysis. The technical aspects of difference equation

analysis can be found in the book by, e.g., Gandolfo (1996).

In this chapter I present some mathematical prerequisites, definitions and methods for

the analysis of differential equation systems. It should be noted that the use of the

terms, which are presented here, is not uniform across sciences, books and authors.

Therefore, the definitions, which I provide here, should be regarded as working-

definitions which I prefer to use. In my opinion a very nice introduction to dynamic

equation systems can be found in Gandolfo (1996). This book includes a very detailed

introduction and further aspects and literature on this topic. A less comprehensive and

maybe more intuitive basic discussion can be found in Chiang (1984), p.478ff. An

advanced introduction and more advanced topics can be found in Hahn (1967). I

restrict my discussion of differential equation systems only to the cases which are

directly relevant for my research. Exactly speaking, all my research deals with three-

dimensional, inhomogeneous, autonomous, ordinary, first-order differential equation

systems. In fact, first I explain what this term means (Section 1) and subsequently I

explain some aspects of the analysis of such a differential equation system (Section

2). In the third section of this chapter, I explain in short the optimal control problems

that arise in my models and their solution by the Hamiltonian function. In Section 4, I

summarize the whole discussion of this chapter by suggesting a step-by-step-

procedure in dynamic economic modelling. For further reading on all these topics I

recommend the book by Gandolfo (1996).

38

Page 49: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

TABLE OF CONTENTS for CHAPTER II

1. Basic terms...............................................................................................................40

2. Methods and key-concepts of differential-equation-system-analysis......................44

2.1 Methods of differential equation system analysis..............................................44

2.2. The qualitative approach to differential equation system analysis ...................46

2.2.1 Dynamic equilibrium ..................................................................................46

2.2.2 Stability of dynamic equilibrium ................................................................53

2.2.2.1 Basic concepts and definitions of stability...........................................53

2.2.2.2 Methods for proving global and local stability of equilibrium............58

2.2.2.2.1 Local stability................................................................................58

2.2.2.2.2 Global stability..............................................................................60

2.2.2.3 Transitional dynamics..........................................................................71

3. Optimal control........................................................................................................75

3.1 The necessary conditions for a maximum .........................................................79

3.2 Proof of sufficiency............................................................................................80

4. Summary: Step-by-step procedure in continuous-time growth-modeling...............82

LIST OF SYMBOLS of CHAPTER II........................................................................84

39

Page 50: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

1. Basic terms Assume that we have a variable y which is a function of time, i.e. . That is, y

is the dependent variable and t is the independent variable.

)(tyy =

Definition 1: A differential equation is an equation that contains a derivative with

respect to time.1

So if we go back to our example with y, we can postulate, that a differential equation

is an equation that contains a derivative of y with respect to t. For example,

(1) btayty += )()(&

is a differential equation, where the dot denotes the derivation of y with respect to

time t (a and b are some (exogenous) parameters that can be constant or time-

dependent).

Differential equations are widespread in sciences, because they can be used to

describe the development of variables over time. Hence, nearly every question that

deals with dynamics (e.g. the development of an economy or the route of a spaceship

in orbit) can be formulated and analysed by using differential equations. Many model

assumptions in economics (e.g. the assumption of intertemporal household-utility

maximization) result in differential equations. Thus, the analysis of models with such

assumptions requires the analysis of differential equations.

1 In fact the dependent variable need not being “time”, but can be everything else. If we had y=y(x), then a differential equation would be an equation that contains a derivative of y with respect to x. However, since in my research we only have differential equations with respect to time, Definition 1 seems to be a useful working definition.

40

Page 51: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

To understand that differential equations describe the dynamic behaviour of their

variables consider the following fact: the differential equation (1) can be reformulated

(exactly speaking: “solved”) by using integral calculus such that we obtain

(1a) [ ] abeabyty at //)0()( −+=

(for details see e.g. Chiang (1984), p.143f). We can see now that this formulation

allows us to depict in a y-t space, which would allow us to see directly how y

evolves over time.

)(ty

A very important aspect of equation (1a) is that the development of depends

upon the initial value of , namely . That is, depending upon the initial value,

the differential equation (1) describes different growth paths of y. Later, this fact will

be of importance for Definitions (8) and (9).

)(ty

)(ty )0(y

Now, assume that we have two other variables that are dependent upon time, e.g.

and . Furthermore, assume that for each of these variables we a have

a differential equation and that the development of some variables determines the

development of other variables, e.g.

)(txx = )(tzz =

(2) )()()( tytxtx +=&

(3) )()()()( tdytaztcxtz ++=&

where a, c and d are some (exogenous) parameters.

Definition 2: A differential equation system is an equation system that consists of two

or more differential equations, describing the development of the dependent variables.

41

Page 52: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

The number of dependent variables/equations denotes the dimension of the

differential equation system.

For example, equations (1)-(3) are a three-dimensional differential equation system.

Analysis of these three equations can reveal the development of the variables x, y and

z over time. Now, we could try to solve these equations (in a similar but much more

complicated way as we did to obtain (1a) from (1)) to study the dynamic behaviour of

y, x and z. However, in most cases this is not done, because the differential equation

systems are too complex or because the solutions are too complex and therefore have

too little intuitive meaning. Therefore, often instead of solving differential equation

systems, they are analysed by qualitative methods, which are discussed in the next

section. Remember that we have explained in the discussion of equation (1a) that the

growth path, which is described by a differential equation, depends upon the

(exogenously given) initial condition of the differential equation system ( ). The

same is true for the differential equation system. If we solved the differential equation

system we would see that the development of the variables y, x and z over time

depends upon the initial conditions , and .

)0(y

)0(y )0(x )0(z

Let us summarise all this discussion as follows:

Corollary 1: A differential equation system consists of

• dependent variables (e.g. , and ), )(ty )(tx )(tz

• independent variables (in all our discussion there is only one independent

variable, namely the time index, t) and

• exogenous parameters (e.g. a, b, c and d).

A differential equation system describes the development of the dependent variables

over time, i.e. a differential equation system determines a growth path of the

42

Page 53: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

dependent variables. The shape of this growth path depends on the values of the

exogenous variables and on the initial state of the differential equation system (e.g.

, and ). )0(y )0(x )0(z

Note that the usual assumptions of economic analysis often produce two-dimensional

differential equation systems. For example, the assumptions of the Ramsey-Cass-

Koompmans-model create a two-dimensional differential-equation system, describing

the development of the two variables capital and consumption. The biggest part of the

analysis of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model is then conducted by analysis of this

differential equation system. For the details, see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004),

p.85ff and also Wagner (1997), p.73ff.

Before approaching to the next section I may present some further (less important)

definitions:

Definition 3a: A differential equation system is inhomogenous, if at least one of the

involved differential equations is inhomogenous.

Definition 3b: A differential equation is inhomogenous, if it features an additive

exogenous parameter (e.g. btayty += )()(& is inhomogenous, while is

homogenous).

)()( tayty =&

In general the analysis of homogenous differential equation systems is easier.

Definition 4: In general, a differential equation system is autonomous, if its

exogenous parameters are not time-dependent (e.g. btayty += )()(& is autonomous,

while )()()( tbtayty +=& is non-autonomous). Exactly speaking, if the system is non-

43

Page 54: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

autonomous, its dynamic equilibrium is dependent of time, i.e. depending upon time

the system converges to different dynamic equilibriums. See also Gandolfo (1996),

p.333.

Non-autonomous differential equation systems are relatively difficult to study, since

the points of convergence change over time within the phase space. This fact will be

of importance in the next section and in Chapter III.

Definition 5: A differential equation system is ordinary, if its dependent variables are

dependent upon only one independent variable, i.e. all dependent variables (y, x, z)

must be functions of time only (e.g. btayty += )()(& is an ordinary differential

equation, while bstaysty += ),(),(& is not ordinary, where s is an independent

variable); see. e.g. Gandolfo (1996), S.147.

Definition 6: A first-order differential-equation-system features only the first

derivatives with respect to time (e.g. btayty += )()(& is a first-order differential

equation, while btaytyty +=+ )()()( &&& is a second-order differential equation).

2. Methods and key-concepts of differential-equation-system-analysis

2.1 Methods of differential equation system analysis The analysis of differential equation systems can be conducted in three ways:

(1) solution of the differential equation system

(2) simulation of the differential equation system by using a computer

(3) qualitative analysis.

44

Page 55: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

As mentioned in the previous section, the solution of a differential equation system

may be quite difficult and probably therefore approach (1) it is not very widespread in

growth theory. For a discussion of solution approaches and some examples of

economic application, see. e.g. Rommelfanger (2006) or Gandolfo (1996). In my

research I have not found any usage of this method by now. However, in general it

may be useful in structural change models. For example, since, as we will see soon,

the analysis of three-dimensional differential equation systems is quite difficult, in

some models it may be useful solving at least one of the three differential equations

and inserting it into the others. In this way, in some cases, it may be possible to

simplify a three-dimensional problem to a two-dimensional problem, which is easier

to analyse. However, by now I have not found a way to use this approach in my

analysis.

The simulation approach (2) is widespread in economic analysis; it became quite

popular due to progress in computer technology. In fact many (simple) differential

equation systems could be simulated on a standard PC. In general, a draw-back of this

approach is that its validity is restricted only to the parameter values that have been

used in simulation (see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.113). Furthermore, it

may be quite difficult to derive some intuition about the functioning of a differential

equation system (e.g. which impact channels exist) from such a (“black box”)

simulation. Therefore, as mentioned many times, I do not use this method in my

research; my focus (namely the derivation of intuitive theoretical arguments in

structural change theory) requires rather analytical solutions.

I focus on the qualitative approach (3). Therefore, I will discuss it here in detail. This

approach is very widespread in (neoclassical) growth theory. The book by Barro and

Sala-i-Martin (2004) provides many examples of use of this method in neoclassical

growth theory. In fact this approach is based on finding dynamic equilibriums in

45

Page 56: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

differential equation systems and proving their stability. Then, further analysis can be

conducted by analysing these dynamic equilibriums and by analysing the transition

period where the economy approaches to these dynamic equilibriums. Now, I provide

some definitions and methods which are used in this analysis.

2.2. The qualitative approach to differential equation system analysis The qualitative analysis starts with searching for a dynamic equilibrium of the

differential equation system. Hence, the question arises what a dynamic equilibrium is

and how to find it. These questions will be discussed in section 2.2.1. The convenient

feature of a dynamic equilibrium is that it is easy to understand; hence many intuitive

explanations can be drawn from it. However, as we will see in the next section, the

analysis of a dynamic equilibrium becomes more or less obsolete if the dynamic

equilibrium is unstable; therefore, the proof of dynamic equilibrium stability is

essential. Furthermore, since in most economic dynamic equation systems some

period of time is required until the dynamic equilibrium is reached (“transition

period”), it is important to analyse how the dynamic equation system behaves during

the transition period. The concepts and methods for analysing stability and the

transition period are introduced in section 2.2.2.

2.2.1 Dynamic equilibrium In general, the dependent variables of a differential equation system grow at different

and non-constant growth rates, and it is mostly impossible to recognise at first sight

how these growth rates develop. However, in some instances, for some parameter

values and/or at some points of time the growth rates of some of the variables of a

differential equation system may become constant and/or identical. Such singularities

46

Page 57: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

of the differential equation system are important form the theoretical point of view,

since the differential equation system becomes intuitively understandable when some

of its variables grow at constant/identical growth rates. That is, when looking at such

a singularity we can see at first sight how the differential equation system develops

over time and we may be able do derive some economically intuitive explanations

from this singularity. (In Chapter III, I demonstrate/present several types of such

singularities, and, as I hope, it becomes there obvious what I mean when I say that a

differential equation system becomes easier to understand when some variables grow

at constant rate.)

On the other hand, if such a singularity lasts only for a moment, it may become

obsolete analysing it, since a lot of the analysis may be irrelevant for all the other

points of time.

Singularities, that feature constant rates of some variables and that last more than for

an instant of time, are often named dynamic equilibrium.

We may summarize this discussion in the following definition, which is in my opinion

sufficient to understand all the discussion in my research.

Defintion 7: A dynamic equilibrium is a dynamic state of a differential equation

system that satisfies the following requirements:

(1) some of the variables of the differential equation system grow at a constant

(identical) rate

(2) if the system is in the dynamic equilibrium, it remains in the dynamic equilibrium

provided that there are no shocks/parameter changes, that shift the system out of its

equilibrium.

47

Page 58: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Requirement (1) allows for the intuitive understandably discussed above.

Requirement (2) allows for relevance over time (timely relevant singularity),

discussed above.

Definition 7 allows for several types of dynamic equilibriums that are discussed in the

literature and that will be of relevance in my research; these are

(1) balanced growth path (“steady state”)

(2) asymptotically balanced growth path (“asymptotic steady state”)

(3) partially balanced growth path (“partial steady state”)

In the following, I provide only definitions of these sorts of dynamic equilibrium and

I discuss them briefly. In Chapter III, I apply these concepts to the reference model. I

hope that this will help to understand these concepts even more.

Definition 8: A balanced growth path (“steady state”) is a trajectory where all

dependent variables of a differential equation system grow at a constant and identical

rate. Provided that a balanced growth path exists in a differential equation system,

there is a set of finite initial conditions and parameters that puts the differential

equation system directly onto the balanced growth path.

For example, in our differential equation system (1)-(3) a balanced growth path is a

trajectory along which x, y and z grow at the same constant rate. (By now, we cannot

say whether such a trajectory really exists in the system (1)-(3); however, we will

discuss this topic soon.)

The second sentence from Definition 8 (namely the statement that only a certain

initial condition brings the differential equation system directly onto a balanced

growth path), is an important distinctive feature between balanced growth and

asymptotically balanced growth which will be discussed soon. Remember that we

48

Page 59: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

have explained in the previous section (see also Corollary 1) that for each set of initial

conditions the differential equation system follows a different growth path. Hence, it

is not surprising that only one certain set of initial conditions brings the differential

equation system directly onto a balanced growth path.

Note that the distinction between a “balanced growth path” and a “steady state” is

rather linguistic/grammatical. A steady state is a balanced growth path where the

growth rate of variables is equal to zero. However, since a differential equation

system that is on a balanced growth path can be easily transformed into a differential

equation system that is in a steady state,2 from a mathematical point of view it is

irrelevant whether we use the term balanced growth path or steady state (although it is

little bit odd speaking about a steady state when a system is growing).

Note that the analysis in the neoclassical growth theory is based nearly exclusively on

the existence of balanced growth paths, which makes the balanced growth concept an

important one; see also Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001); for examples see e.g. Barro

and Sala-i-Martin (2004).

Definition 9: An asymptotically balanced growth path (“asymptotic steady state”) is

a trajectory along which the differential equation system converges to a “final

dynamic state”. In the final dynamic state all dependent variables grow at a constant

and identical rate. There is no set of finite initial conditions and parameters that puts

the differential equation system directly into the final dynamic state. That is, for all

2 This can be easily done by dividing all variables of the differential equation system by an (auxiliary) exogenous variable that grows at the same rate as the variables of the differential equation system along the balanced growth path. This procedure is often done in neoclassical growth models by expressing the variables in “efficiency units”. In this case the original variables grow at a constant rate along the balanced growth path, while the variables in efficiency units are constant (i.e. are in a steady state) along the balanced growth path. For an example with the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model, see Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.95ff or see APPENDIX C of Part I of Chapter V.

49

Page 60: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

finite parameter and initial condition settings there must be an (infinitely lasting)

transition period to the final dynamic state.

The concept of asymptotically balanced growth is less widespread in the literature;

nevertheless, most structural change models feature some sort of asymptotically

balanced growth path, e.g. Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001), Echevarria (1997) and

Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008). In the reference model of Chapter III I that an

asymptotically balanced growth path exists.

Overall, the difference between a balanced growth path (steady state) and an

asymptotically balanced growth path (asymptotic steady state) can be explained as

follows: If a steady state exists in a differential equation system, the differential

equation system jumps right into this steady state, provided that the initial values (in

our example ) are set to some specific finite values

( ). (In general, these values can be derived from model parameters.)

That is, for there is no transition period and

the economy starts in the steady state and remains in the steady state (provided that

model parameters are not altered for t>0). The things are quite different for an

asymptotic steady state: there is no finite set that puts the economy

directly into the final dynamic state where y, x and z grow at a constant rate. That is,

for any finite setting of the economy must first go through a transition

period (which lasts infinitely). The final dynamic state where all variables grow at a

constant rate is reached after an infinite period of time.

)0(),0(),0( zxy

)0(),0(),0( *** zxy

)0()0(),0()0(),0()0( *** zzxxyy ===

)0(),0(),0( *** zxy

)0(),0(),0( zxy

50

Page 61: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Definition 10: A partially balanced growth path (“partial steady state”) is a

trajectory where at least one of the dependent variables of a differential equation

system and/or some transformations of these variables grow at a constant (and

identical) rate. Provided that a partially balanced growth path exists in a differential

equation system, there is a set of finite initial conditions and parameters that puts the

differential equation system directly onto the partially balanced growth path.

The key difference between a balanced and partially balanced growth path is that a

partially balanced growth path does not require that all variables grow at a constant

rate, i.e. some variables can grow at different and non-constant rates. Furthermore,

depending upon the actual purpose of the model and analytical requirements, the

partially balanced growth path can be defined upon the constancy of the growth rate

of only one or even more variables. In our example, a partially balanced growth path

may be defined in several ways, e.g.,

• it may be defined as a a growth path where y grows at constant rate but not x and

z

• or it may be defined as a growth path where y and z grow at an identical

constant rate but not x

• or we may define a transformation of variables x and y, e.g. n := f(x,y) where f is

a function of x and y, and we may define a partially balanced growth path as a

growth path where n and z grow at a constant rate.

The concept of partially balanced growth in structural change has been introduced by

Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001) and used by e.g. Meckl (2002), Ngai and Pissarides

(2007), Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008). This concept is in focus of my research. I use

it in all the essays of Chapter V. As we will see in the next chapter, the advantage of

this concept is that it allows for structural change (since not all variables need to grow

51

Page 62: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

at constant rate), while keeping the analysis traceable (due to the constancy of the

growth rates of some variables).

The fact, that we can define a dynamic equilibrium, does not imply that such an

equilibrium exists in a differential equation system. There may be some models where

none of the above dynamic equilibriums exists. Hence, in some sense the art of

modelling is to find intuitively and empirically reasonable assumptions which produce

differential equation systems where the sort of dynamic equilibrium, that is useful for

analysing a certain phenomenon, exists. I demonstrate in Chapter III by altering the

assumptions of my reference model that different sorts of dynamic equilibrium can

exist depending upon the model assumptions.

The last question that I discuss in this section is how I can find a dynamic equilibrium

in a differential equation system. This question is less relevant for my research, since I

try to formulate the assumptions a priori such that a dynamic equilibrium exists (or I

alter models where I know that a dynamic equilibrium exists.) However, for the sake

of completeness I discuss this topic in short. To my knowledge there are two ways to

find such an equilibrium:

(1) Simply look at the differential equation system. Often, differential

equations systems are simple enough to recognize that some variables grow at

constant rates under certain circumstances. For example, such an approach is

often chosen in the discussion of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model, see e.g.

Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.99. I will also demonstrate the usage of this

method in Chapter III several times.

(2) Sometimes, by simulating the model in a computer a stationary point

(“steady state”) to which the model converges can be identified graphically.

This can be used as a starting point for using approach (1).

52

Page 63: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

If none of these approaches works (and if you are not a really bad scientist), probably

there does not exist the type of dynamic equilibrium that you have searched for.

However, probably most models approach asymptotically to some analytically

understandable “final state”. This state may be regarded as a dynamic equilibrium.

2.2.2 Stability of dynamic equilibrium As already mentioned a dynamic equilibrium is a quite nice thing. It allows us to

intuitively understand some of the model dynamics. However, outside of a dynamic

equilibrium other impact-channels may exist which dominate the impact-channels of

the dynamic equilibrium. That is, dynamic equilibrium dynamics may not represent

very well the transitional dynamics. Hence, it is important to study the transitional

dynamics of a differential equation system. Furthermore, if a dynamic equilibrium is

unstable, it appears unlikely that the dynamics of an economy during an arbitrary

period of time are well represented by dynamic equilibrium dynamics, since the

probability that the economy is outer dynamic equilibrium may be relatively high in

this case. Hence, to justify the focus on dynamic equilibrium analysis we must show

that a dynamic equilibrium is stable. In the following subsections I explain the

concepts of stability and methods that are used to prove stability and study transitional

dynamics (in my research).

2.2.2.1 Basic concepts and definitions of stability In literature there are several concepts of stability; sometimes the usage of terms is not

unified across books. Therefore, the definitions from this section may be regarded as

working definitions, which I use in my research. I do not try to formulate the

definitions as generally as possible, but I try to formulate them such that the

explanations in the essays of Chapter V are easy to understand. For extensive

53

Page 64: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

discussion I recommend Hahn (1967), p.1ff and Gandolfo (1996), p.331ff. For the

purposes of my research the definition of saddle-path stability is essential, since the

differential equation systems that result from economic dynamic optimization

problems (which are in focus of my research) typically result in saddle-paths (see also

Gandolfo (1996), p.374f on this topic). Furthermore, to evaluate the generality of my

results the distinction between local (saddle-path-)stability and global (saddle-path-

)stability is essential.

Definition 11: A dynamic equilibrium is stable if the differential equation system

converges to the dynamic equilibrium when it is not in dynamic equilibrium. That is,

even if the initial conditions of the differential equation system are such that the

differential equation system does not start in dynamic equilibrium, the differential

equation system converges to the dynamic equilibrium.

This definition is important: We have no reason to assume that the initial conditions,

that are necessary to start in a dynamic equilibrium, are satisfied in reality. Hence, it is

important to show that the differential equation system converges to the dynamic

equilibrium (and hence hopefully in the long run the dynamic-equilibrium-dynamics

are dominant) if these initial conditions are not satisfied. If a dynamic equilibrium is

unstable, it may make no sense to study the dynamic-equilibrium-dynamics, since in

most cases we cannot expect that the economy will be close to the dynamic

equilibrium. Hence, the equilibrium dynamics become less interesting. Nevertheless,

sometimes it may make sense to study even unstable dynamic equilibriums: In fact

the key feature of a dynamic equilibrium is that some impact channels do not apply in

equilibrium and/or that several impact channels offset each other; hence, dynamic

equilibrium analysis is quite simple. It can be used to study those channels which

54

Page 65: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

apply in the equilibrium and if these channels apply even outer-equilibrium, analysis

of unstable dynamic equilibriums can help to understand some important impact

channels of the model in a simple way.

Definition 12: The dynamic equilibrium of a 2-dimensional differential equation

system is saddle-path stable if the set of initial conditions, which ensures convergence

to the dynamic equilibrium, is given by a one-dimensional manifold (i.e. curve). This

curve is named saddle-path.

This definition is based on more general definitions by Gandolfo (1996), pp.373ff,

Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008), pp.484ff and Acemoglu (2009), pp.269-273. I use the

simpler definition, since in all my research I reduce the differential-equation-stability

problems to two dimensions; hence, this definition is sufficient for understanding the

essays of Chapter V. All the essays of Chapter V work with this type of saddle-path

stability.

We can see from Definition 12 that saddle path stability is a relatively weak concept:

Not every set of initial conditions yield convergence to the dynamic equilibrium, but

only the sets that are given by the saddle-path-curve lead to convergence. Hence,

there are many sets of initial conditions that do not yield convergence to the dynamic

equilibrium. Therefore, further reasoning is necessary to ensure convergence to the

dynamic equilibrium. In neoclassical growth models, this reasoning is often based on

the assumption of a rational household and neoclassical production and utility

functions: Under these conditions, the representative household chooses to be on the

converging manifold (saddle-path), since other feasible growth paths are suboptimal.

For example, in the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model it can be shown that the feasible

non-converging initial-condition sets yield growth paths that yield less consumption at

55

Page 66: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

any point of time in comparison to the saddle-path; for details see Gandolfo (1996),

pp.384-386.

Nevertheless, the concept of saddle-path-stability is very widespread in (neoclassical)

growth theory. The reason for this fact is that neoclassical growth theory tries to

provide a microfoundation of their models by assuming some (representative) agents

(households/firms). This assumption normally results in optimal control problems (see

also Section 3) and the solutions of these problems in general yield differential

equation systems with the saddle-path feature; see also Gandolfo (1996), p.374f on

this topic. (For examples of such neoclassical growth models, see e.g. Barro and Sala-

i-Martin (2004).)

Definition 13: A dynamic equilibrium is globally stable, if every arbitrary set of

(finite) initial conditions induces convergence of the differential equation system to

the dynamic equilibrium.

Definition 14: A dynamic equilibrium is locally stable, if the initial conditions, which

are close to the dynamic equilibrium, yield convergence of the differential equation

system to its dynamic equilibrium.

We can see that local stability is a relatively weak concept. Local stability means that

differential equation systems which are close to their dynamic equilibrium converge

to their dynamic equilibrium. However, we do not know what happens if the

differential equation system is not close to its dynamic equilibrium. It may be globally

stable, but also it may be not.

In general, local stability is easier to prove in comparison to global stability. In the

next subsection the methods will be discussed. There are many papers that do not

56

Page 67: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

manage it to prove global stability. For example, Acemogly and Guerrieri (2008) give

only a proof of local stability of their dynamic equilibrium. By now, in endogenous

growth theory there does not exist a general proof of global stability for models with

multiple capital goods; merely local stability has been proven by now.

Note that, in general, the fact, that only local stability can be proven, does not imply

that the model is globally instable. It is simply relatively complicated to prove global

stability; locally stable models can be globally stable or globally unstable. Hence,

such a model is not useless. If it can be shown by empirical evidence (e.g. by a

simulation) that the model dynamic-equilibrium dynamics describe the reality well,

the model may be regarded as “acceptable”. Furthermore, in some cases the proof of

global stability may be irrelevant since it is not necessary for the key-argumentation.

For example, the proof of stability is not very important in my model from the

Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle-essay (Chapter V), since the model is not aimed to be

descriptive, but seeks only to show the existence of certain structural change patterns.

The relevance of these structural change patterns can be shown either theoretically

(by showing global stability of these patterns) or empirically (by showing that these

patterns are a relatively big part of actual structural change). In fact, in the essay on

the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle both ways are chosen.

Note that models, which are merely simulated on a computer, are in most cases not

feasible of showing that the growth path that they have simulated features some sort

of global validity/stability. There may be some techniques (e.g. sensitivity analysis)

that can help to get a notion of what happens when parameters change. However,

these techniques are rather not feasible of really proving some sort of global

validity/stability of the model results.

In the essays of Chapter V I prove global saddle-path-stability. That is, I show that

there exists a saddle path to the dynamic equilibrium (for every value of the initial

57

Page 68: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

state variable) and that the representative household decides to be on this saddle path.

Hence, for every set of (finite) initial conditions the system converges to the dynamic

equilibrium.

2.2.2.2 Methods for proving global and local stability of equilibrium As mentioned there are two stability concepts: local and global stability. Local

stability is easier to prove; however, a proof of global stability is desirable, although

not always feasible. Now, I introduce the methods which I use in my research;

however, I also explain briefly some alternative methods, especially methods of

proving global stability.

2.2.2.2.1 Local stability To prove local stability I use a linear approximation approach. That is, the differential

equation system is linearly approximated around its dynamic equilibrium and then

stability of this linear approximation is proven. This approach works only if the

differential equation system is linearly approximable around its dynamic equilibrium.

As we will see, fortunately the models that I use are linearly approximable.

Furthermore, since the linear approximation is only a good approximation in the

neighbourhood of the dynamic equilibrium (point of approximation), this proof of

stability has only local validity. In the following I present a recipe for proving local

stability by using linear approximation (for further explanations regarding this recipe

see e.g. Acemoglu (2009), pp.269-273). This recipe is used by e.g. Acemoglu and

Guerrieri (2008), pp.484f, to show the local saddle-path-stability in their structural

change model. In Chapter V, I demonstrate how this recipe works in the models about

Ageing and the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle. The following steps need to be done to prove

local stability:

58

Page 69: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

1. First, the differential equation system must be reformulated such that the

dynamic equilibrium is a steady state. (That is, by using an auxiliary variable

the dependent variables of the system must be expressed in “efficiency units”;

see also the discussion of the Definition 8 and footnote 2 in Section 2.2.1.)

2. Subsequently, it has to be shown that the determinant of the Jacobian

evaluated at the steady state is different from zero. If this can be shown, we

know that the behaviour of the differential equation system can be linearly

approximated around the steady state (i.e. the steady state is “hyperbolic”,

because of the Grobman-Hartman Theorem); see also Acemoglu (2009),

p.926.

3. The number of negative eigenvalues of the Jacobian evaluated at the steady

state must be equal to the number of state-variables of the system. (State

variables are the variables that have an exogenous initial condition in optimal

control problems; see also Section 3 on this fact). In this case there is a saddle-

path in the neighbourhood of the steady state. All economies starting at this

saddle-path will converge to the steady state.

4. The question is whether for given initial value(s) of the state variable(s) the

economy will be on the saddle path (i.e. whether control variables in the initial

point of time will correspond to the control variables that lie on the saddle-

path for given initial state variables)3. Remember that I have discussed in the

previous section (during the discussion of Definition 12) that the economy

needs not necessarily starting on the saddle-path. However, I have mentioned

there as well that by using neoclassical assumptions this problem can be

solved. A mathematically exact formulation and proof of necessary and

sufficient conditions for starting on the saddle-path is given by Acemoglu

3 For distinction between control and state variables; see Section 3.

59

Page 70: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(2009), p.257 (Theorem 7.14); see Acemoglu (2009), p.272. In fact these

conditions are satisfied if we assume neoclassical production/investment

structures and neoclassical utility functions4 and if we assume the satisfaction

of a transversality condition (which is in general presumed in most

neoclassical models);5 see also Acemoglu (2009), p.269. Simply speaking, I

can ensure that my models are on the saddle-path if I take some typically

neoclassical assumptions. This among others is one reason for using

neoclassical assumptions in structural change modelling.

Corollary 2: If the determinant of the Jacobian of the differential equation system

evaluated at the steady state is non-singular and has as much negative eigenvalues as

the differential equation system has state variables, then the steady state is locally

saddle-path stable. In this case we know that the system can converges to the steady

state if the initial conditions do not deviate much from the steady state.

2.2.2.2.2 Global stability To my knowledge there are two ways of proofing global stability: by using phase

diagrams and by using Ljapunov’s Second method.

4 Exactly speaking the utility function must be concave and the dynamic constraint must be concave. The latter is concave if the sectoral production functions are concave and if the dynamic investment constraint is assumed to have the form like in the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model. These assumptions ensure that the Hamiltonian function is concave, which is a requirement for starting on the saddle path; see also Acemoglu (2009), p.269. My models feature all of these assumptions. Therefore, I am able to show that the Hamiltonian is indeed concave in my models; see e.g. APPENDIX A of the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle-essay. 5 I also presume that the necessary transversality condition holds in my models. In the context of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model, such transversality conditions are intuitively explained by ruling out Ponzi-games. That is, the representative household is not allowed to cover its interest payments on debt by borrowing more and more perpetually. That is, in the limit the value of household assets must be non-negative; see also Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.89. Since the aggregate structure of my models is regarding these facts the same as the structure of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model, this argumentation can be applied to my models as well; see also Section 3.

60

Page 71: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

The latter method may be regarded as the ultimate way, since it is applicable to

(nearly) any differential equation system. However, the drawback of this method is

that in most cases it is quite difficult to apply it (especially it seems to require a

certain amount of “ingenuity” to find “Ljapunov’s distance function”, which is

necessary to prove global stability; see Gandolfo (1996), p.411). Furthermore, this

method has originally been created to prove global stability and not global saddle-

path-stability. Remember, that we have mentioned in section 2.2.2.1 that the optimal

control problems in my research produce saddle-paths. Hence, to apply Ljapunov’s

Second Method I would have to alter it such that it proves global saddle-path

stability. For these reasons and due to the fact that I have found a way to analyse the

three-dimensional stability problems of my research in phase diagrams, I do not use

Ljapunov’s Second Method. Therefore, I do not discuss it here in more detail. For a

discussion of Ljapunov’s Second Method, see e.g. Gandolfo (1996), pp.407ff, or

Hahn (1967) pp.93ff. Overall, Ljapunov’s Second Method seems to be valuable and

there seems to be a lot of potential to this method in economics, especially since it has

not been used widely by now in economics and since it is applicable to nearly any

differential equation system. Further research on the applicability of this method in

economics would (hopefully) allow us to analyse higher-dimension differential

equation systems, which would allow us to make more general assumptions in

economic modelling. The drawback of this method (namely the difficulty of finding

Ljapunov’s distance functions) could be reduced, if this method was used more

frequently (in this way experience regarding useful/applicable Ljapunov’s distance

functions in economic models could be acquired).

Since I focus on phase diagram analysis, I explain it here in more detail. I try to give

here some general notion on how phase diagrams are used in stability analysis.

However, it is very difficult to explain the usage of phase diagrams without a concrete

61

Page 72: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

example i.e. a model. Therefore, after reading the following lines I suggest you to take

a look at the models on the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle and Ageing in Section V where

phase diagram analysis is applied.

The following steps must/should be done to prove the stability of a two-dimensional

differential equation system in phase space:

1.) The dynamic equilibrium of each of the differential equations of the

differential equation system should be found.

2.) The differential equation system must be reformulated such that the dynamic

equilibrium is a steady state. (That is, by using an auxiliary variable the dependent

variables of the system must be expressed in “efficiency units”; see also the

discussion of the Definition 8 and footnote 2 in section 2.2.1.)

3.) For each of the variables, the curve (locus) along which the variable is in

steady state must be depicted in the phase space. For example, if we have a two-

dimensional differential equation system (y, x), the loci in phase space can look as

follows (actually they look like this in the Ramsey-Cass-Koompmans model):

62

Page 73: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Figure 1: Exemplary phase space for a two-dimensional differential equation system (y, x)

x

y

combinations of x and y for which y is in steady

combinations of y and x for which x is in steady state

II

III

I

IV

4.) We can see that the steady state loci, divide the phase space into several

sections (in our example these are the sections I-IV). By studying the differential

equations of the corresponding differential equation system it can be entangled

which dynamics forces rule in each of the sectors.6 That is, for each of the

sections it can be said, whether x increases or decreases and whether y increases

or decreases over time. In general this is illustrated by small arrows, as shown in

the following Figure (where the arrows are only examples and are drawn like in

the Ramses-Cass-Koopmans-model):

6 For detailed explanations of how this is done, see e.g. the stability analysis of the essays from Section V, especially the essay on Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle or the essay on Ageing; for textbook-type explanations related to the set-up of the phase-diagram of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model, see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), pp.99ff.

63

Page 74: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Figure 2: Exemplary phase space for a two-dimensional differential equation system (y, x)

x

y

combinations of x and y for which y is in steady

combinations of y and x for which x is in steady state

II

III

I

IV S

.

These small arrows, which stand for the forces within each section, indicate in

which direction the dependent variables of the differential equation system are

moving over time, provided that these dependent variables are in the range of the

space of the section. For example, as long as the system is in section IV it will

move upwards and in direction of the y-axis over time, i.e. x will decrease and y

will increase over time. It should be noted that the closer the system is to one of

the steady state loci, the weaker/slower is the motion that is ruled by the

corresponding locus. The steady-state locus of y rules the motion of y and the

steady state locus of x rules the motion of x. The closer the system is to the

steady-state-locus of y (x), the slower the motion of y (x). For example, if the

system is in section III, the downward motion (i.e. the decrease in y) is ruled by

the steady-state-locus of y. Hence, the closer the system comes to the steady-state-

locus of y the weaker the change in y over time.

Furthermore, the intersections of the two steady state-loci are the steady states

(dynamic equilibriums) of the system: only at the intersections of the steady state

64

Page 75: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

loci both variables of the differential equation system are in steady state. Hence, S

is a steady state. It should be noted that beside of S there may be some further

steady states depending upon the model; e.g. if the Figure 2 depicted the Ramsey-

Cass-Koopmans-model the origin is a steady state among others. This point will

be discussed in step 5.

5.) Now, after the forces within the sections have been analysed and the dynamic

equilibriums (steady states) have been spotted, the analysis of the phase space is

completed and the stability analysis can start. Stability analysis means that we

look at each of the steady states in the phase diagram, and try to judge whether the

system moves towards them over time (which would imply stability) or away

from them (which would imply instability). For example, let us look at S as a

steady state. We can see that, if the system is in sections II and IV, it will not

converge to S, since the arrows imply movement away from S. On the other hand,

since the arrows in sections I and III point rather to the steady state, they imply

that there must be a path (a curve) which leads the differential equation system to

the steady state S. According to our definitions from Section 2.2.2.1, this implies

that the steady state S is saddle path stable. For those, who do not find this

argument convincing, I can recommend the method of local stability proof: In the

previous section we have provided a mathematical way to show that indeed there

is only a one-dimensional manifold that leads to the steady state. In general, in

addition to the graphical proof of saddle-path stability, the local stability proof is

provided by many authors, as a sort of approbation/confirmation of the graphical

results. We depict this discussion in the following figure:

65

Page 76: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Figure 3: Exemplary saddle-path of a two-dimensional differential equation system (y, x)

x

y

combinations of x and y for which y is in steady

combinations of y and x for which x is in steady state

II

III

I

IV S

. saddle-path

x(0)

y(0)

y’(0)

In Figure 3 the saddle-path goes through the origin and approaches infinity. Thus,

this figure implies that for every x at any point of time (e.g. for x=x(0)) there is a

corresponding y (in our example y(0)) that puts the differential equation system

onto the saddle-path. Once the system is on the saddle-path, it “travels” along this

saddle-path to the steady state (provided that there are no model-parameter

changes). This is consistent with our definition of saddle-path stability from

Definition 12 (Section 2.2.2.1).

6.) However, as can be seen from Figure 3, saddle-path-stability implies that for

every x there is an infinite number of y’s, which do not bring the economy onto

the saddle-path, and hence into the steady state. We can see from Figure 3 that,

e.g., the point (x(0),y’(0)) does not lead the system to the steady state (the arrows

imply that from this point the system moves left downward). That is, there is an

infinite number of initial points/conditions which do not inudce convergence to

the steady state. Hence, to justify the focus on steady state analysis we have to

show that these initial conditions are not relevant and that the system always starts

66

Page 77: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

at the saddle-path. This is where normally economically intuitive arguments are

used in (neoclassical) growth theory. Hence, we cannot approach without giving

our variables an intuitive meaning. Instead of discussing here an explicit example,

which would be quite lengthy, I refer to the Parts I and III of Chapter V as

examples for how it can be ensured that the system starts on the saddle-path.

Furthermore, see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.103, or Gandolfo (1996),

p.386, for the corresponding discussion in the standard Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-

model. In the following, I briefly illustrate their arguments in order to give you a

notion of the kind of arguments that are used in general.

For example, Figure 3 depicts the phase space of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-

model, where y is interpreted as consumption and x as capital, and where a

representative household seeks to maximize its life-time-utility. In this model it is

argued/shown that all growth paths that start below the saddle-path (e.g. the path

which starts with initial condition (x(0),y’(0))) yield less consumption for any

given capital level at any point of time; see e.g. Gandolfo (1996), p.386. Hence, it

would be suboptimal for the household to choose such a growth path. On the other

hand, it can be shown that all growth-paths that start above the saddle-path hit the

y-axis in finite time, which yields a down-ward-jump in consumption due to the

Inada-conditions, which is suboptimal (intuitively spoken, jumps in consumption

are always suboptimal in neoclassical growth frameworks, which is due to

decreasing marginal utility of consumption); for details see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-

Martin (2004), p.103. Hence, the only optimal strategy for the household is to start

on the saddle-path, which ensures that the economy will approach to the steady

state.

67

Page 78: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

If these six steps are successfully completed the stability analysis of a differential

equation is completed and we hopefully know whether the (relevant) steady state is

globally stable.

It should be noted that the stability analysis by the use of phase diagrams has two

essential drawbacks:

First, the proof of stability by using a phase diagram is only applicable to two-

dimensional differential equation systems. To my knowledge, if you have a higher-

dimensional differential equation system, there is only one way to make it analyzable

within a phase diagram: You could try to solve some of the differential equations of

your differential equations system and to insert them into the other differential

equations. In this way a higher-dimension stability problem could be reduced to a

two-dimension stability problem (hence phase-diagram-analysis would become

applicable). However, this approach may not be applicable for three reasons:

(I) Solving differential equations is often rather an art than the application of

concrete receipts, since it requires integral calculus. Hence, sometimes we may

not be able to solve a differential equation (within reasonable period of time).

(II) Since the solution of a differential equation has normally some time

dependent exogenous terms (see e.g. in Section 1 equation (1a) as a solution of

equation (1)), it can happen that the resulting two-dimensional differential

equation system is non-autonomous. As mentioned in Section 1 (during the

discussion of Definition 4) and as we will see below, the analysis of non-

autonomous differential equation systems can be quite difficult (since it

includes time-varying dynamic-equilibrium-loci; see below).

(III) If we solve a differential equation and the solution is an implicit function,

it may happen that the solution of this differential equation cannot be inserted

into the other differential equations. Hence, we cannot reduce the three-

68

Page 79: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

dimensional differential equation system to a two-dimensional differential

equation system. I have had this problem in my essays on the Kuznetzs-

Kaldor-Puzzle and Ageing (see there on more explanations of this problem).

However, I have found a way to deal with this problem:

Try to find a two-dimensional transformation of your higher-dimensional

system and study the stability of this-two dimensional equation system. For

example, if you have a three-dimensional differential equation system (y, x, z)

where the differential equation for z can be solved and results in an implicit

function of z, you could define a new variable n = f(x, z). Then, by using this

definition and the solution for z, you could reformulate your original

differential equation system (y, x, z) into a two-dimensional differential

equation system (y, n), which can be analysed by using a phase diagram. This

approach features several requirements

a) It requires the solution of a differential equation (in our example z).

a) It has to be proven, that the steady state of the differential equation

system (y, x, z) has a unique coincidence with the steady state of the

differential equation system (y, n). In other words, it has to be shown

that the differential equation system (y, n) is in steady state, if and only

if the differential equation system (y, x, z) is in steady state and vice

versa. Only in this case the proof that the steady state of (y, n) is

globally stable implies that the steady state of (y, x, n) is globally

stable.

b) In general, a transformation of a three-dimensional differential

equation system into a two-dimensional differential equation system

leads to loss of information. Hence, the phase space (y, n) may include

some economically contra-intuitive spaces. Hence, the phase space (y,

69

Page 80: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

n) may be restricted, which may be difficult to handle (what happens

when the restriction is reached?)

c) The “appropriate” transformation n = f(x, z) may be difficult to find.

It has to satisfy requirement IIa, while solving the problem that z is an

implicit function.

Second, a phase diagram provides only qualitative results. In stability analysis this is

not such a big problem. However, in the analysis of the transition period (see the next

section) this may be a drawback: We cannot derive the growth rates of the variables

during the transition period from a phase diagram. We can only obtain information

about the qualitative development patterns of the variables (whether they increase or

decrease during the transition period, monotonically, cyclically, etc.).

In previous sections I have often referred to the difficulty of analysing non-

autonomous differential equation systems (see also Definition 4). In the main part of

my research (Section V) all stability analysis is about autonomous differential

equation systems. Nevertheless, for the sake of completeness and since non-

autonomous systems arise in structural change models (e.g. in the reference model of

Chapter III and in the essay by Kongsamut et al. 2001), I explain these difficulties

briefly in the following: A key feature of non-autonomous differential equation

systems is that the steady-state-curves are moving over time in phase space. Hence,

e.g. in Figure 3, the range of the sections I-IV and the steady state S would move over

time. It is possible to show stability in such frameworks, provided that the steady-

state-curves move “monotonously” (see e.g. the analysis by Kongsamut et al. 2001);

however, it may not always be possible. For example, the reference-model from

Chapter III generates a non-autonomous differential equation system. However, this

system is that complicated that it seems impossible to disentangle the movement of

the steady state curves. A further interesting difference between an autonomous and

70

Page 81: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

non-autonomous phase diagram is: As shown in Figure 3, in autonomous saddle-path-

stable differential equation systems there is only one saddle-path and if the economy

starts on the saddle-path it remains on the saddle-path during the transition to the

steady-state, irrespective of at which place of the saddle-path the economy started.

That is, there is only one path to the steady state. In non-autonomous differential

equation systems there is a unique saddle-path for each initial condition set. That is,

depending on the initial state, the way/path to the dynamic equilibrium is different.

All in all phase diagrams are a very useful tool that plays the central role in

neoclassical growth theories.

2.2.2.3 Transitional dynamics By now all the discussion focused on dynamic equilibriums. However as mentioned

many times, the economy need not being in dynamic equilibrium. We have seen in the

previous section that there is only one combination of initial conditions that lets the

economy start directly in dynamic equilibrium (namely the combination given by the

point S in Figure 3). For all other initial points/condition there is a transition period

during which the economy converges to the dynamic equilibrium (along a saddle-

path). Obviously, it is very difficult to find economically intuitive arguments that the

economy starts in S. Therefore, I have provided methods in the previous section that

can show that the dynamic equilibrium is stable. When we know that the dynamic

equilibrium is stable, we can expect that after some period of time the dynamic

equilibrium dynamics will become dominant. In fact, if the dynamic equilibrium is

stable the dynamic equilibrium forces seem to be most important (since they are the

only trends that are not transitional but persistent “forever”).

71

Page 82: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Furthermore, empirical evidence can be used to answer the question whether the

dynamic-equilibrium forces are dominant in reality. For example, one reason for the

focus of the neoclassical theory on dynamic equilibrium analysis is that the

neoclassical dynamic equilibrium is often consistent with some stylized facts of

dynamics in industrialized countries (see e.g. the discussion of the Kaldor facts in the

beginning of the essay on the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle in Chapter V).

Nevertheless, there might be (theoretical) cases where the transitional dynamic are

dominant for a very long period of time7 and/or where empirical evidence implies that

transitional dynamics rule in reality. Anyway it is interesting to know how the

economy develops during the transition period (e.g. whether the transitional dynamics

are very different in comparison to the equilibrium dynamics, which could help us,

e.g., to disentangle some empirical puzzles).

The methods from the previous section can help us to study transitional dynamics. In

fact, the phase diagram depicts the transitional dynamics. For example, in Figure 3 we

can see how the variables develop during the transition to the steady state. For

example, an economy, that starts in section I, moves upward to the steady state along

the saddle path. Hence, both variables (y and x) are increasing over time during the

transition period. Furthermore, it is self-evident that the growth-rates of the dependent

variables (y and x) during the transition period are not the same as in steady state: In

steady state the system remains in point S over time (i.e. y and x are constant), while

during transition the system moves (i.e. y and x change over time). Now, we could

study whether the growth rates of y and x are higher or lower during transition in 7 In fact there is a way to asses the speed of convergence to the dynamic equilibrium in theoretical models. For example, Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), pp.56ff, provide a method. In fact their measure is similar to the measure of radioactive decay in physics/chemistry: They calculate the “half-life of convergence”, i.e. “the time that it takes for half the initial gap [i.e. the gap between initial state and steady state] to be eliminated”. However, I do not use this method, since the speed of convergence is irrelevant for my research. For example, I can show by empirical evidence that dynamic-equilibrium-dynamics rule in my model on the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle. In detail, I focus on the study of industrialized countries in this model, and there the dynamic-equilibrium-dynamics of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model seem to rule; see also essay on the Kaldor-Kuznets-Puzzle in Chapter V.

72

Page 83: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

comparison to the steady state and whether the growth rates are increasing or

decreasing during the steady state. To do so we need an example. Instead of creating

here a lengthy example, I refer to Section V, where especially in the model on Ageing

these questions are discussed. Furthermore, for a textbook-discussion of these

questions in the context of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model, see e.g. Barro and

Sala-i-Martin (2004), pp.105ff.

From Figure 3 we can see that the transitional dynamics are monotonous and

continuous, i.e. the saddle-path is continuous and monotonous. That is, e.g. when

starting from section I, the dependent variables are increasing monotonously and

continuously over time. Furthermore, note that it can be shown that the duration of the

transition period is infinite in Figure 3: The growth rates of y and x become smaller

and smaller as the system approaches the steady state S.8 Hence, in fact the steady

state is “never reached”. However, this does not matter: The closer the system is to

the steady state, the more similar is the system-behaviour to the steady-state. Hence, if

the system is relatively close to the steady state, it behaves quite similar as in steady

state.

In fact, these transitional dynamics (monotonous, continuous and infinitely lasting

transition dynamics) are representative of the transitional dynamics in all my models,

as we will see in Chapter V. There, I apply the methods of this section and study the

transitional dynamics in more detail by studying the models (as examples).

As mentioned in the previous section a drawback of studying transitional dynamics

only with phase diagrams is that phase diagrams deliver only qualitative results. For

example, from a phase diagram we do not learn by how much the growth rate during

the transition period is higher/lower in comparison to the steady state growth rate.

8 Remember that I have explained in the previous section (in point 4.)) that the closer the system comes to the steady-state-loci, the slower/weaker the movement/dynamics become.

73

Page 84: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Note that we have shown in the previous section that there are also some methods for

proving local stability. In fact these methods can be used to study the transition close

to the dynamic equilibrium as well. Remember that the proof of local stability

requires showing that the dynamics around the dynamic equilibrium is adequately

approximated by a linear differential equation system. Hence, the transitional

dynamics close to the dynamic equilibrium are qualitatively the same as those of a

linear differential equation system. Therefore, if we prove local stability, we know

that the transitional dynamic are monotonous, continuous and infinitely lasting, as

above. However, since the proof of local stability has only local validity, by using

local stability methods we cannot say what the transitional dynamic are when the

system is far away from the dynamic equilibrium.

Last but not least, there is another way to study some transitional dynamics:

simulations. By simulating the system on a computer we can see how the differential

equation system develops from the initial state to the steady state. A drawback of this

method is that it requires finding meaningful/adequate parameters for the model. This

is often difficult, since some model parameters may be very theoretical and difficult to

measure/estimate. Furthermore, an estimation does not provide any general result: the

results from a simulation with some specific parameter values need not being valid for

other parameter values. Hence, authors often try to run simulations for several

parameter constellations to show that at least the qualitative results of the simulation

are valid for many other reasonable parameter constellations. Hence, de facto, the

simulation approach to transitional dynamics can provide only general qualitative

results. Furthermore, these qualitative results are not necessarily of general validity,

since by using many different parameter constellations it can never be proven that the

qualitative results hold for all relevant parameter constellations.

74

Page 85: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

3. Optimal control In all my models and in the most part of neoclassical growth theory it is assumed that

there exists a representative household that seeks to maximize its life-time utility by

consuming. The representative household has a time preference and faces a dynamic

restriction: at every point of time the household can consume and invest a part of its

wealth; the more the household consumes the less remains for investment. Since

investment is associated with capital accumulation and thus with expansion of future

production/consumption possibilities the household faces a dynamic optimization

problem: the decision on consumption quantities at one instant of time affects not

only actual utility, but also the future consumption possibilities and thus future utility.

Hence, the rational household tries to choose a plan/program of consumption

quantities that maximizes its life-time utility, while taking into account that more

consumption today is associated with less consumption tomorrow. In other words, we

have a maximization problem, where a target function is maximized subject to a

dynamic constraint. Such problems are often named optimal control problems.

The solution of such problems has already been derived by mathematicians. In fact

they have derived a “recipe” on how to solve such an optimization problem. While the

derivation of this recipe requires rather the skill level of an intermediate to advanced

mathematics student, the application of the recipe is taught to beginning to

intermediate economics students. Therefore, I will not derive the recipe (since it

would be redundant); instead I will simply explain in short how to use the recipe.

It should be noted that the method of solution of a dynamic maximization problem

(i.e. the recipe) depends on whether a model of continuous or discrete time is

assumed. In my research I use continuous time models and the corresponding solution

method (recipe) focuses on the “Hamiltonian”. (In discrete time models the Bellman-

equation is used rather; see e.g. de la Fuente (2000), pp.549ff). Introduction to

75

Page 86: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

dynamic optimization, optimal control problems, application of the Hamiltonian and

heuristic derivation of the Hamiltonian can be found, e.g., in the books by Gandolfo

(1996), pp.374ff, de la Fuente (2000), pp.549ff and 566ff, and Barro and Sala-i-

Martin (2004), pp.604ff.

Now, I describe the procedure for solving a dynamic optimization problem in

continuous time by using a Hamiltonian. I restrict the discussion only to the case that

is relevant for my research: I assume that there is only one dynamic constraint. Let us

assume the following maximization problem:

(4) s.t. ( )∫∞

021 ),(),(),...(),(max dtettytxtxtxu t

(5a) ( )ttytxtxtxfty m ),(),(),...(),()( 21=&

(5b) 0)0( yy =

(.)u is the target function and (5a) is the dynamic constraint. Only the initial

condition for the state variable (5b) is exogenously given. The initial condition for the

control variable can be chosen by the household. This is in fact the reason for the fact

that later in stability analysis of the resulting equilibrium we need some intuitive

argumentation to show that the household will actually chose the initial condition for

the control variable such that the economy starts on the saddle-path (see section

2.2.2.2.2, step 6).

Furthermore, in general some non-negativity constraints and other restrictions (e.g.

Inada-conditions) are imposed on the variables. These further constraints have to be

considered in the phase-diagram analysis of the Hamiltonian optimum (see later).

76

Page 87: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Variables, that are determined by a dynamic constraint (i.e. ), are named state

variables. The other variables (which do not have a dynamic constraint a priori), i.e.

,… , are named control variables.

)(ty

)(1 tx )(txm

The maximization problem (4),(5) can be solved by maximizing the (“current value”)

Hamiltonian.

The (“current value”) Hamiltonian (H) for the problem (4),(5) is given by (compare

also Gandolfo (1996), p.375):

(6)( )( ) ( )ttytxtxtxftttytxtxtxu

tttytxtxtxH

mm

m

),(),(),...(),()(),(),(),...(),(),(),(),(),...(),(

2121

21

ψψ

+=

where )(tψ is an auxiliary variable named co-state variable. In the final set of

optimality conditions this variable does not appear. In fact, this variable has a similar

meaning like the Lagrange multiplier in constrained static optimization: it is the

shadow price of the restriction, i.e. it implies by how much the utility would increase

if the dynamic constraint was slacked/relaxed by one marginal unit. Exactly speaking,

)(tψ is the value of one additional marginal unit of y at time t expressed in utility

units, i.e. if at time t one additional unit of y was available, the utility in time t would

increase by )(tψ units; compare Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.607. Hence, )(tψ

is the “current value” of one marginal unit of y in time t.

Furthermore, we have to assume that a transversality condition is satisfied. This

among others is necessary to ensure that the optimality conditions, which are derived

from the Hamiltonian, are not only necessary but also sufficient (compare Acemoglu

(2009), pp.268f, de la Fuente (2000), p.572, and Gandolfo (1996), p.376). The

transversality condition is given by

77

Page 88: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(7) 0)()(lim =−

∞→

t

tetyt ρψ

In fact, this transversality condition has an intuitive meaning: Remember that we have

just explained that )(tψ can be interpreted as the shadow price of y. Hence, )()( tytψ

is the (current) value of y that exists at time t. If we “discount” this value with the

time preference rate (i.e. multiply )()( tytψ with ), we obtain the present value of

y (i.e. the value of y expressed in units of utility at time 0). Now, think of as a

“final state”. That is, the representative household does not live beyond . Hence,

is the present value of y that is left over at the end of households

“life”. That is, implies that the household does not leave over

anything after its “death” (compare also Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.611). This

seems to be reasonable: Why should the household leave over any resources for the

time after its existence: if the household consumes these resources in its life time it

can draw utility from them; otherwise these resources would be wasted, which would

be suboptimal. Exactly speaking, if I do not exist in infinity why should I leave over

some resources for infinity, when I benefit from consumption only in my life time.

For these reasons is never larger than zero, in models which I use, i.e.

in models with rational households and perfect foresight. Furthermore, note that

cannot be negative under usual conditions as well: y is a real resource

(in my models this real resource is capital); hence, it cannot be negative; furthermore,

since (at least in my models) the real resources bring utility and no disutility, the value

of these resources

te ρ−

∞→t

∞=t

t

tetyt ρψ −

∞→)()(lim

0)()(lim =−

∞→

t

tetyt ρψ

t

tetyt ρψ −

∞→)()(lim

t

tetyt ρψ −

∞→)()(lim

)(tψ cannot be negative.9

9 See also section 2.2.2.2.1 and there point 4.), footnote 5, for a similar explanation proposed by Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004).

78

Page 89: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

In fact, the solution of the maximization problem (4),(5) by using a Hamiltonian is a

two step procedure: First, the necessary conditions for an optimum of (4),(5) are

formulated; second, it is shown that these necessary conditions are also sufficient;

hence, a household that acts according to the necessary and sufficient optimality

condition maximizes its life time utility.

3.1 The necessary conditions for a maximum The necessary conditions, which are derived from the Hamiltonian (6), are given as

follows:

(8) 0)(

(.),...0)(

(.),0)(

(.) !!

2

!

1

=∂∂

=∂∂

=∂∂

txH

txH

txH

m

(9) )()()(

(.) !tt

tyH ψρψ &−=∂∂

As mentioned above, I do not prove the validity of these optimality conditions; this

has already been done by mathematicians. Heuristic proofs of these conditions can be

found in e.g. in Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), pp.606ff, and de la Fuente (2000),

pp.567ff.

Optimality conditions (8) are often referred to as intratemporal optimality conditions,

since they determine the optimal allocation of budget across goods for a given point

of time. Condition (9) (and condition (5)) is often referred to as intertemporal

optimality condition since it determines the optimal allocation of budget across time.

Conditions (5), (7), (8) and (9) describe the optimal path of variables, ,… ,

and

)(1 tx )(txm

)(ty )(tψ . If representative household acts according to these conditions, the

Hamiltonian (6) is maximized and the life time utility (4) is maximized. In general, in

79

Page 90: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

economic analysis conditions (7), (8) and (9) are restructured further (where equation

(5) is used as well). In doing so, )(tψ is eliminated from the equations and a (m+1)-

dimensional differential equation system is obtained that describes the development of

the state variable ( ) and control variables ( ,… ). (For examples of how

this restructuring is done, see e.g. the essays on the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle and

Ageing from Chapter V.) This differential equation system is then analyzed regarding

the existence and stability of a dynamic equilibrium by using the methods from the

previous sections.

)(ty )(1 tx )(txm

3.2 Proof of sufficiency In general, the optimality conditions (5), (7), (8) and (9) can only be regarded as

necessary conditions for a solution of the maximization problem (4),(5). That is, by

now we do not know whether the household really maximizes its life-time utility if it

acts according to conditions (5), (7), (8) and (9). However, there are several cases

where we can be sure that these necessary conditions are sufficient as well. In these

cases we can be sure that the household maximizes its life-time utility by acting

according to conditions (5), (7), (8) and (9). To my knowledge there are two such

cases:

(1) The target function and the dynamic constraint are both concave in

( ,… , ); see e.g. de la Fuente (2000), p.575, and also Acemoglu

(2009), p.269, and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.610. In this case,

conditions (5), (7), (8) and (9) are also sufficient conditions for solving

problem (4),(5). Hence, by proving concavity of the target function and the

dynamic constraint, we can prove the sufficiency of our necessary conditions.

This approach is very useful for problems with only one state variable (y) and

)(1 tx )(txm )(ty

80

Page 91: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

only one control variable (x), since then the target function and the dynamic

constraint are functions of only two variables (x and y) in general, and the

concavity can be proven by calculating some second partial derivatives of the

functions (for detailed description of the proof of concavity of functions with

two independent variables, see e.g. Kamien and Schwarz (2000), p.300).

Nevertheless, even in this simple case, the proof can be quite lengthy and

complicated. However, since in general in most neoclassical growth models it

is a priori assumed that the utility function and the production function are

concave, the proof of concavity of the target function and the dynamic

constraint is almost given a priori; see e.g. Acemoglu (2009), p.268f, for how

simple this proof becomes. However, showing concavity of the target function

and the dynamic restriction features some drawbacks as a proof of sufficiency:

(a) This approach becomes the more complicated the more state and/or control

variables are involved. Showing concavity of functions with three or more

independent variables requires showing that the corresponding Hessian matrix

is negative (semi)definite, which requires calculating determinants, which in

turn becomes the more complex the more independent variables are included.

(b) Concavity of the target function and the dynamic constraint are stronger

than necessary conditions (see e.g. de la Fuente (2000), p.575, and Barro and

Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.610). That is, even if not both, the target function and

the dynamic constraint, are concave, the optimality conditions (5), (7), (8) and

(9) can be sufficient. In this case the following approach may be useful.

(2) It can be shown that optimality conditions (5), (7), (8) and (9) are sufficient

for solving the problem (4),(5) by using the Arrow-Kurz-criterion; see e.g.

Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004),p.610, Gandolfo (1996), p.376, Acemoglu

81

Page 92: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(2009), p.257, and de la Fuente (2000), pp.575/577. This sufficiency proof

includes three steps:

(a) Maximize the Hamiltonian (6) with respect to the control variables

for given state variable ( ), co-state-variable (y ψ ) and time (t). In fact

this results in the optimality conditions (8).

(b) Insert these optimality conditions (8) into the Hamiltonian (6). The

resulting Hamiltonian ( H~ ) is only a function of the state variable ( ),

co-state-variable (

y

ψ ) and time (t), i.e. . )),(),((~~ tttyHH ψ=

(c) Show that is concave in the state variable ( ) for

given co-state-variable (

)),(),((~ tttyH ψ )(ty

)(tψ ) and time (t). It is well known that

is concave in for given )),(),((~ tttyH ψ )(ty )(tψ and t, if

0))((

~2

2

<∂∂

tyH .

If 0))((

~2

2

<∂∂

tyH , the optimality conditions (5), (7), (8) and (9) are sufficient for

solving the problem (4),(5). A proof of the validity of this sufficiency criterion

can be found in de la Fuente (2000), p.575f.

I use the first procedure whenever I can. However, I have to use the second procedure

(Arrow-Kurz-criterion) in PART I of CHAPTER V.

4. Summary: Step-by-step procedure in continuous-time growth-modeling The methods and concepts from this chapter are applied to a reference model (and

thus explained further) in the following chapter. Before doing so, I provide a short

summary of Section II. In this way a more or less general procedure in (continuous-

82

Page 93: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

time) growth modeling is presented. This procedure will be applied in the following

sections.

Analytical procedure in further modeling:

1. Assumptions are made about the environment in which the agents act and about the

behavioral patterns of the agents (aims).

2. These assumptions are used to formulate maximization problems.

3. The maximization problems are solved by using a Hamiltonian:

a) The necessary optimality conditions are derived.

b) Sufficiency of the optimality conditions is shown.

4. The necessary and sufficient conditions from the Hamiltonian maximization are

restructured such that (economically) intuitive differential equation systems result.

5. These differential equation systems are analyzed regarding the existence and

stability of a dynamic equilibrium.

6. Economically intuitive results are derived from the dynamic equilibrium analysis,

e.g. impact channels.

7. The transition period is analyzed and economically intuitive results are derived for

the transition period.

In the following chapter, I discuss the modeling foundations of my research.

83

Page 94: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

LIST OF SYMBOLS of CHAPTER II * Indicates the steady-state or dynamic equilibrium value(s) of the

corresponding variable.

(.)H Hamiltonian.

(.)~H Maximum of the Hamiltonian with respect to the control variables.

S The steady-state-point in a phase diagram.

a Exogenous parameter of a differential equation (system).

b Exogenous parameter of a differential equation (system).

c Exogenous parameter of a differential equation (system).

d Exogenous parameter of a differential equation (system).

(.)f A function.

n A function (transformation) of variables x and y.

s Independent variable of a differential equation (system).

t Time index. (Independent variable of a differential equation (system).)

(.)u Target function of an optimal control problem.

)(tx Dependent variable of a differential equation (system); function of time.

)(),...(1 txtx m Control variables of an optimal control problem.

)(ty Dependent variable of a differential equation (system); function of time and/or

state variable of an optimal control problem.

)0('y An initial level of in a phase diagram that does not induce convergence

to the steady state.

)(ty

0y Initial condition for the state variable of an optimal control problem.

)(tz Dependent variable of a differential equation (system); function of time.

84

Page 95: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

ρ Time-preference rate.

)(tψ Co-state variable.

85

Page 96: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

86

Page 97: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

CHAPTER III

Key Modeling Approach: Integration of Structural Change into a Neoclassical Growth Model

- Key Assumptions, Application of Analytical Tools, Challenges in Structural

Change Modeling, Application and Premises of PBGP-method -

In this chapter I present a “relatively general”1 model to explain several concepts and

questions that are of importance for understanding all the previous explanations

regarding the importance of my research. The assumptions of the model are nearly the

same as in the third model by Kongsamut et al. (1997). However, the approach in

model analysis is quite different. (In their third model, Kongsamut et al. (1997)

analyze an equilibrium growth path which features only a constant real interest rate

(growth rates are not constant along this growth path); I analyze other dynamic

equilibriums.) The following model includes the most key-assumptions, that are used

in the main part of my research (namely in the essays of Chapter V). Furthermore, all

the models, which exist in the neoclassical structural change school by now, can be

derived as special cases of the following model. Therefore, the model, which is

presented in the following, seems to be a good starting point and a good reference

model. By using this model I explain

1.) the application of the concepts of unbalanced growth, asymptotically balanced

growth, partially balanced growth and balanced growth,

2.) the standard mainstream neoclassical growth model and how structural change

affects its validity

1 “Relatively general” means here that all key structural change determinants are included; however, I use relatively simple functional forms to keep the discussion traceable.

87

Page 98: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

3.) the general analytical challenges to structural change modeling, namely the

difficulties in understanding the dynamics of such models (transitional as well as

“equilibrium dynamics”) and

4.) what is the key to generating partially balanced growth (“a priori” and “a

posteriori” knife-edge conditions regarding model parameters).

During the discussion of the latter point I also demonstrate how the previous literature

generates partially balanced growth paths.

88

Page 99: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

TABLE OF CONTENTS for CHAPTER III

1. An unbalanced growth model ..................................................................................90

1.1 Assumptions.......................................................................................................90

1.2 Optimality conditions.........................................................................................93

2. Analytical challenges to structural-change-analysis................................................95

3. A balanced-growth multi-sector-model ...................................................................98

4. A truly “neoclassical” multi-sector growth-model ................................................104

5. Partially balanced growth ......................................................................................106

5.1 An example of a partially balanced growth model ..........................................106

5.2 Examples from the literature on how to create partially balanced growth paths

(usage of a priori and a posteriori knife-edge conditions) .....................................110

6. Validity of neoclassical models in the light of structural change and the downside

of knife-edge-condition use .......................................................................................115

APPENDIX................................................................................................................119

LIST OF SYMBOLS of CHAPTER III.....................................................................121

89

Page 100: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

1. An unbalanced growth model

1.1 Assumptions All model assumptions are quite the same as in the standard one-sector Ramsey-

(Cass-Koopmans-)model, i.e. they are very “neoclassical”.2 That is, we have a long-

run growth model with perfect markets3 and with a rational representative household

with perfect foresight. The only difference is that I assume the existence of multiple

(heterogeneous) sectors.

The representative household maximizes the following utility function by consuming

heterogeneous goods ),...1( mi =

(1) , ∫∞

−=0

21 ),...,( dteCCCuU tmttt

ρ 0 >ρ

where

(2) ( ) ∑∑ =>+== i

ii

m

i

it

iti

mtt SCCCu 1;0,)ln(,...

1

1 βββ

where t is the time index. denotes the “market consumption” of good i (i.e.

consumption of goods that are purchased on the market);

itC

ρ is the time preference

rate. We can see that the preference function (1) is quite the same as the functions

used in standard growth literature (i.e. it is time-separable). The only difference is that

there exist multiple goods. To meet the requirements regarding the structural change

determinants (mentioned in Chapter I) the instantaneous utility function u(.) must be

non-homothetic across goods i=1,…m and the price elasticity must be different from

one. A function that satisfies these requirements is given by (2). This function is very

similar to the one used by Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001). I have decided for this

2 For detailed explanations of the standard Ramsey-(Cass-Koopmans)-model see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), 85ff. However, in this chapter I provide some explanations on this model as well. 3 Perfect markets means that there are no information asymmetries or information delays (information is instantaneously available and processed and all agents react immediately to changing conditions), all markets are polypolistic and producers are marginalistic (price takers) there are no entry barriers.

90

Page 101: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

function, since it is analytically very convenient (i.e. a lot of intersectoral dynamics

can be determined by the setting of the constant parameters itS ). i

tS are exogenous. If

a itS is negative, it can be interpreted as the basic need regarding good i (e.g. food,

basic education). If a itS is positive, it can be interpreted as an endowment regarding

good/service i, e.g. a household that can repair cars has some positive endowment

regarding the service “car repairing”. Furthermore, itS could stand for some free

services and grants that are provided (and guaranteed) by the government. In this

case, if some itS are assumed to be negative, they can be interpreted as goods/services

that have to be provided to the government (a sort of “tax”), e.g. military service;

Some itS could be assumed to be constant and/or equal to zero.

Since income-elasticity and price-elasticity of demand differ across goods i and are

different from unity (as long as not all 0=itS ), the preferences allow for structural

change caused by non-homothetic preferences and relative-price-changes.4

Each of the goods is produced by a polypolistic sector. Each sector produces its

output by a Cobb-Douglas production function )( itY

(3) miBgBnk

BKnBY i

tiitii

t

it

it

tit

it

it

i

,...1,,10, =∀=<<⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= &α

α

where I have normalized the aggregate amount of labor to unity. represents the

aggregate amount of capital; and represent respectively the fraction of capital

and labor devoted to sector i; is a sector-specific technology-parameter that grows

at the exogenous, sector-specific and constant rate . Equation (3) implies that the

TFP-growth rate differs across sectors. Furthermore, since

tK

itk i

tn

itB

ig

iα differ across sectors,

4 See Section 3 in Chapter I.

91

Page 102: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

the output-elasticity of labor differs across sectors. Thus, again all requirements

regarding the structural change determinants are satisfied by these production

functions.

All capital and labor have to be used in production

(4) ∑∑ ==i

it

i

it nk 1;1

That is, there is no unemployment and I assume full labor mobility across sectors,

reflecting the long-run-character of the model.

Like Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001) and Ngai and Pissarides (2007), I assume that

only sector m produces capital (and consumption goods). That is, the output of sectors

is used for consumption only and the output of sector m is used for

consumption and as capital:

mi ≠

(5) mttt

mt CKKY ++= δ&

(6) miCY it

it ≠∀= ,

where δ is the depreciation rate. This assumption seems to be reasonable at low

disaggregation levels, since in reality for example the manufacturing sector produces

consumption goods and capital goods.

Like Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001) and Ngai and Pissarides (2007), I define

aggregate output and aggregate consumption-expenditures as follows )( tY )( tE

(7) ; ∑≡i

it

itt YpY ∑≡

i

it

itt CpE

where denotes the relative price of good i. Sector itp mi = is numéraire

(8) 1=mtp

92

Page 103: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

1.2 Optimality conditions When there is free mobility of factors across sectors, the intratemporal and

intertemporal optimality conditions for this model are given by

(9) iCuCu

KkYKkY

nYnYp m

t

it

tit

it

tmt

mt

it

it

mt

mti

t ∀∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

= ,/(.)/(.)

)(/)(/

)(/)(/ and

ρδ −−∂∂

=−)( t

mt

mt

m

m

KkY

uu&

,

where . These optimality conditions can be obtained by maximizing

equations (1)-(2) subject to equations (3)-(8), by using the Hamiltonian. A proof is in

the APPENDIX.

mtm Cuu ∂∂≡ /(.)

These conditions imply the following equations, describing the development of

aggregates and sectors:

Equilibrium Aggregate-Behavior

(10) m

mmmt

mt

mmt

mt

mtmtt n

kkn

KBYα

αα αα ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+= − 1)()( 1

(11) tttt EKYK −−= δ&

(12) ρδαρδ −−=−−∂∂

=++

mt

mt

t

tm

tmt

mt

tt

tt

kn

KY

KkY

VEVE ~

)(

&&

(13) tmm

ti

iimti

ii

m

tmt

mt

Y

EVW

kn

~)1(

11

αα

βααβα

α −

⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎝

⎛−−⎟

⎞⎜⎝

⎛+

+−=∑∑

Equilibrium Sector-Behavior (represented by employment shares)

(14) ( )

( ) ( )mi

KBnk

SY

VEnii

i

tit

i

i

m

mmt

mt

it

t

tti

m

iit ≠∀

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

−−

+−−

=−

,

11

~)1()1(

1 ααα

αα

αα

βαα

93

Page 104: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(15) ( )t

mt

t

ttmttmt Y

SY

VEKKn ~~ −+++

=βδ&

where

(16) mmm mt

mtt

mtt nkKBY ααα )/()()(~ 1−≡

(17) ∑≡i

it

itt SpV

(18) ∑⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡

i

it

it

itti

t

iti

t i

nBkKB

SW α

(19) i

nBkK

nBkK

pi

m

it

it

itt

i

mt

mt

mtt

mit ∀

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

= −

,1

1

α

α

α

α

(20) i

i

m

mmt

mt

it

it

nk

nk

αα

αα

−−

=1

1

The equation-system (10)-(20) describes the dynamics of our economy when all

markets are in equilibrium. Any further analysis of the model (e.g. the analysis of

structural change patterns) has to deal with these equations.

I omit here the intuitive discussion of equations (10)-(20), since this is only a

reference model which will be altered in the following sections and in doing so I will

explain more and more the intuition behind these equations. Nevertheless, here are

just two short intuitive explanations:

1.) Note that equations (10)-(12) are nearly the same as in the “normal” one-

sector Ramsey-model (thus the intuitive explanation of these equations is

nearly the same as well), beside of the fact that they contain the terms

and . The latter terms reflect the fact that we have here multiple sectors and

mt

mt nk /

tV

94

Page 105: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

that reallocations between these sectors affect the behavior of aggregates (Y, K

and E). Hence, a lot of analysis of multi-consumption-goods models can be

done by focusing on the aggregate equations and the terms which reflect the

impact of sectoral reallocation on aggregates (i.e. and ). Only if

sectoral behavior is of interest (and mostly it is) sectoral equations (14) and

(15) need to be analyzed in more detail.

mt

mt nk / tV

2.) The dynamic equation system (10)-(20) implies that in general the

equilibrium development of the variables is unbalanced. That is, in general the

variables do not grow at constant rate and in general the variables grow at

different rates (which contradicts in some respect to the mainstream

neoclassical growth school as we will see). Hence, this is an unbalanced

growth model, i.e. structural change takes place (i.e. e.g. employment share are

changing). For some parameter values, however, (partially) balanced behavior

may arise. This fact will be discussed in the following sections.

Now, I discuss several points by using this model as an example for structural change

models.

2. Analytical challenges to structural-change-analysis Now, the question arises how the variables of interest (e.g. the employment shares)

develop over time. To answer this question, we could try to simulate the model by

using a computer or try to get some answers on this question by an analytical

approach. As already mentioned many times, the focus of my research is on the

analytical approach.

Only by looking at the equation-system (10)-(20) we cannot obtain much information

about the dynamics: the sectoral variables are dependent upon each other and upon

95

Page 106: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

the aggregate variables and vice versa, making it very difficult to disentangle the

dynamics of the system at first sight. (These difficulties arise despite the fact that I

kept the model quite simple by, e.g., using as simple functional forms as possible and

by using many simplicity-promising assumptions like perfect markets.) As explained

in Chapter II, the typical approach to analytical analysis of such problems is studying

the existence and the stability of a hopefully existing dynamic equilibrium and by

studying the transitional dynamics (i.e. the way to this dynamic equilibrium) by using

e.g. phase diagrams. To do so, we have to study a three-dimensional differential

equation system consisting of variables E, K and V. The development of these

variables is primarily given by equations (11), (12) and (17), where all the remaining

equations of the system (10)-(20) have to be inserted into these equations to make the

equation-system (11)-(12)-(17) only functions of the variables E, K and V. We could

try this; however, it seems not recommendable for several reasons:

1.) The equation-system is very complicated and seems to be difficult to

interpret; thus even if we managed it to transform the dynamic-equation

system (10)-(20) into a differential equation system with only three equations,

we would probably get only little economic intuition from it.

2.) In general, we can say that the equilibrium growth path of the model is

unbalanced, i.e. the growth rates of Y, E and K are not constant and

employment shares change (since the equations from above do not give us any

reason to believe that at least some variables grow at the same rate for general

parameter settings). However, it seems to exist an asymptotic steady state5 in

this differential equation system. That is, as time goes on, the equation system

converges to a “state” where all variables grow at the same constant growth

5 see also Definition 9 in Chapter II.

96

Page 107: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

rate6. In this steady state, the system becomes easier to understand (see also

the next section); however, no structural change takes place in this steady

state, since all variables and thus the employment shares grow at a constant

rate. (For a detailed analysis of such a steady state, see the next section.)

Hence, looking only at this asymptotic steady state does not help us very much

to understand the structural change dynamics.

3.) To understand the structural change we would have to analyze the

transitional dynamics (i.e. the way to the asymptotical steady state). However,

the differential equation system is non-autonomous due to non-homotheticity

of preferences (non-homothetic preferences are required as a structural change

determinant); hence, the analysis of transitional dynamics in a phase-diagram

is difficult or even not feasible. Furthermore, we even cannot use a phase

diagram for analysis of transitional dynamics, since phase diagrams cannot be

used for three-dimensional differential equation systems (and I see no way of

simplifying the differential equation system to only two dimensions); see also

Section 2.2.2.2.2 in Chapter II.

All these points are not very encouraging regarding my plans: even in such a simple

model we cannot study structural change analytically. The only way seems to simplify

the model. To do so there are two approaches:

1.) I can omit capital from analysis and restrict analysis to only two sectors.

This has been done in the traditional structural change school, e.g. by Baumol

(1967). In this case the model becomes quite simple and relatively intuitively

understandable even without computer simulations. I have presented this

6 This can be seen from equations (1) and (2): Since the constant parameters iS become relatively unimportant with increasing consumption quantities, the utility structure becomes more and more like a Cobb-Douglas-utility, provided that consumption increases (see also Kongsamut et al. (2001)). With Cobb-Douglas utility there is no structural change and a balanced growth path exists in this model (the proof of this fact is provided in the following section).

97

Page 108: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

approach in Chapter I. However, as explained in Chapter I, including capital

into analysis is important (at least for the questions which I am dealing with,

e.g. for offshoring or for joining neoclassical growth theory with structural

change). Therefore, I focus on the second way, which is:

2.) Finding parameter restrictions or assumptions which ensure that the

structural change analysis keeps being traceable even with capital. This is what

I name “using a priori or a posteriori knife-edge conditions for generating

partially balanced growth paths” along which structural change can be

analyzed analytically.

Before discussing the latter approach, I present in the next section a special case: In

the model from above I set the a priori assumptions (or: a priori knife-edge

conditions) such that structural change is restricted completely. In this way we obtain

a quite neoclassical multi-sector model, which we can use to explain the mainstream-

concept of balanced growth in more detail and thus explain the neoclassical

mainstream approach to long-run growth analysis.

3. A balanced-growth multi-sector-model To explain the concept of balanced growth we have to change our assumptions such

that no structural change takes place, i.e. all sectors grow at a constant rate. As

explained in the previous section a balanced growth path (see Definition 8 from

Chapter II) does not exists in the model from Section 2 for general parameter setting.

However, the parameter setting could be changed such that a balanced growth path

exists. The following parameter knife-edge restriction ensures balanced growth:

(21) iS it ∀= ,0

98

Page 109: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

This knife-edge condition reduces our utility function (2) to a logarithmic Cobb-

Douglas-function:

(2’) ( ) ∑∑ =>== i

ii

m

i

iti

mtt CCCu 1;0,ln,...

1

1 βββ

When keeping all other assumptions the same, the equilibrium dynamic equation

system (10)-(20) becomes:

Equilibrium Aggregate-Behavior

(10’) m

mmmt

mt

mmt

mt

mtmtt n

kkn

KBYα

αα αα ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+= − 1)()( 1

(11’) tttt EKYK −−= δ&

(12’) ρδα −−= mt

mt

t

tm

t

t

kn

KY

EE ~&

(13’) tmm

ti

iim

mt

mt

Y

E

kn

~)1(1

αα

βαα

⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎝

⎛−

−=∑

Equilibrium Sector-Behavior (represented by employment shares)

(14’) miYEn

t

ti

m

iit ≠∀

−−

= ,~)1()1( β

αα

(15’) t

tmttmt Y

EKKn ~βδ ++

=&

where

(16’) mmm mt

mtt

mtt nkKBY ααα )/()()(~ 1−≡

(17’) 0=tV

(18’) 0=itW

99

Page 110: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(19’) i

nBkK

nBkK

pi

m

it

it

itt

i

mt

mt

mtt

mit ∀

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

= −

,1

1

α

α

α

α

(20’) i

i

m

mmt

mt

it

it

nk

nk

αα

αα

−−

=1

1

Lemma 1: The equation system (10’)-(20’) features a unique balanced growth path

along which and YEK ,, Y~ grow at the constant rate and where are constant

for .

mg in

i∀

Proof: In the following a variable with a “^” denotes the growth rate of the

corresponding variable. According to Definition 8 from Chapter II, a balanced growth

path requires that all variables grow at a constant rate. We start with searching for a

growth path where E and K grow at a constant rate:

(21) . ˆ constK =

(22) .ˆ constE =

(12) and (22) imply

(23) 0ˆˆˆ~=−−+ KknY mm

Equation (16) implies that )ˆˆˆ()1(~ KkngY mmmmm −−−−= αα ; hence, it follows due to

(23) that

(24) mmm gKknY =++−= ˆˆˆ~

(21) and (24) imply

(25) .ˆˆ constkn mm =+−

(13), (22) and (24) imply

(26) mgE =ˆ

100

Page 111: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(16) and (24) imply

(27) mgK =ˆ

(10), (25) and (27) imply

(28) mgY =ˆ

Equations (14) and (15) together with (24), (26), (27) and (28) imply that the

employment-shares are constant. Q.E.D.

Lemma 2: The balanced growth path from Lemma 1 is saddle-path stable.

Proof: The dynamic equation system (10’)-(20’) is simply a special case of the

models from Chapter V (especially of the models about the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle

and Ageing). Hence, the proof of global saddle-path stability from these models

applies here too. Therefore I omit it. See there for details. Q.E.D.

Lemma 1 implies that no structural change takes place along the balanced growth

path. However, we could take a look at the transition period. Equations (14) and (15)

imply that during the transition period (i.e. when YE ~/ is not constant) structural

change takes place primarily between the capital-producing sector m and the other

(consumption-goods-only-producing) sectors.7 In fact, this sort of structural change is

already well known. As will be explained in Chapter IV, this sort of structural change

has already been studied in neoclassical-like frameworks, especially by Uzawa

(1964), and is rather not in focus of my research. This sort of structural change arises

from the fact that during the transitions period (in contrast to the steady state) the

savings-rate is changing and hence the investment-to-consumption ratios are changing

7 Equation (14) implies that even during the transition period the employment shares of all sectors

grow at identical rate. Hence, relative employment between the industries ( ) remains stable.

mi ≠ jt

it nn /

101

Page 112: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

as well (this can be seen from the standard growth models, e.g. Solow-model or

Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model)8. Therefore, correspondingly, factors are reallocated

across these industries (investment and consumption industries). Furthermore, it is

well known from the standard growth theory that whether the savings-rate is

increasing or decreasing during the transition period depends upon whether the initial

capital level (in efficiency units) is larger or lower in comparison to the steady-state-

capital-level (in efficiency units). In this way we could find out whether factors are

reallocated from the capital production to the consumption production. However, in

this section these considerations are rather uninteresting.

What we should learn from this section is that even if there are multiple

technologically distinct sectors a balanced growth path can exist and structural change

need not taking place necessarily. The reason for the existence of this balanced

growth path is simply the very restrictive assumption on the preferences. Cobb-

Douglas preferences are homothetic. Hence, no structural change arises from the

demand side, which allows for balanced growth. Furthermore, Cobb-Douglas-

preferences feature a unitary price-elasticity. Hence, changes in relative prices cause

one-to-one changes in relative consumption. This fact hinders structural change:

Remember that we have seen in Section 3.2 and 3.3 of Chapter I that cross-

technology-disparities cause changes in relative production possibilities of the sectors

and that the changes in relative production possibilities are reflected by relative

prices. If consumption reacts one-to-one to relative price changes, the change in

production possibilities is exactly covered by the change in demand (which arises due

to relative price changes). Hence, labor reallocation across sectors is not necessary to

meet demand changes or production possibility changes. (On impact of relative price

8 For a discussion of these models see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004).

102

Page 113: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

changes on demand and change in production possibilities due to cross-sector

technology-disparity, see the Sections 3.2 and 3.3 in Chapter I.)

Note that the aggregate behavior of this model is not directly comparable to the one-

sector Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model for two reasons:

(1) In the corresponding Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model equations (10’), (11’)

and (12’) would be the same, but would be equal to one. Along the

aggregate balanced growth path of our model this fact is rather irrelevant,

since is simply a constant factor along the balanced growth path. Thus,

the dynamics of our model along the balanced growth path are (quite) the

same as the dynamics of the standard Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model along its

balanced growth path. However, during the transition period responds

to the changes in the savings rate (cf. equation (13)). Therefore, the

transitional dynamics are (quantitatively) different from the standard Ramsey-

Cass-Koopmans model. (Qualitatively, the transitional dynamics are quite the

same: monotonous and continuous.)

mt

mt nk /

mt

mt nk /

mt

mt nk /

(2) Equation (19) implies that relative prices change all the time in this model.

We have defined our aggregate output (Y) in manufacturing terms (cf.

equation (8)), i.e. manufacturing is numéraire. In reality and in the Ramsey-

Cass-Koopmans-model output is rather measured in some other compound

numéraire. (See also the detailed discussion in the Offshoring- and Ageing-

model in Chapter V). Hence, the output of our model is not comparable to the

output of the standard Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model.

All in all the results of this chapter imply that the results of the standard Ramsey-

Cass-Koopmans model are not necessarily consistent/reconcilable with the existence

103

Page 114: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

of multiple technologically distinct sectors, even if structural change does not take

place. The aggregate development of our model becomes the same as the standard

Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model only if technologically homogenous sectors are

assumed. This is demonstrated in the next section.

4. A truly “neoclassical” multi-sector growth-model In addition to Cobb-Douglas preferences (cf. (2’)), we assume now that sector-

technologies are identical, i.e. and titi BB == ,αα ggi = , it,∀ . In this case the

production functions become

(3’) migBBnk

BKnBY tti

t

it

t

titt

it ,...1,,10, =∀=<<⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= &α

α

When keeping all other assumptions the same, the equilibrium dynamic equation

system (10)-(20) becomes:

Equilibrium Aggregate-Behavior

(10’’) αα )()( 1ttt KBY −=

(11’’) tttt EKYK −−= δ&

(12’’) ρδα −−=t

t

t

t

KY

EE&

(13’’) 1=mt

mt

kn

Equilibrium Sector-Behavior (represented by employment shares)

(14’’) miYEn

t

ti

it ≠∀= ,β

104

Page 115: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(15’’) t

tmttmt Y

EKKn βδ ++=&

where

(16’’) tt YY =~

(17’’) 0=tV

(18’’) 0=itW

(19’’) ipit ∀= ,1

(20’’) mt

mt

it

it

nk

nk

=

We can see at first sight that the aggregate structure of this model (especially

equations (10’’), (11’’) and (12’’)) is the same as the structure of the standard

Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model with Cobb-Douglas production function and

logarithmic utility. Hence, the proof of existence and saddle-path-stability of the

balanced growth path from the standard Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans-model applies here

as well. In fact, this model behaves the same as the Ramsey Cass-Koopmans model

during the transition period and along the balanced growth path. Note that for this

result the assumption of Cobb-Douglas utility is not necessary; any other homothetic

neoclassical utility function would yield the same result.

The results regarding structural change in this section are the same as in the previous

section: structural change takes place only during the transition period between

capital-production and consumption-goods-production.

All in all, what we learn from these sections is that in fact the results of the standard

neoclassical growth model are compatible with the existence of multiple sectors only

if all sectors have identical production functions. As discussed in Chapters I and V

105

Page 116: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

several times, empirical evidence implies that sector technologies differ significantly.

So far, the results of the neoclassical growth theory seem not to be compatible with

multiple technologically-heterogeneous sectors. This seems to be a challenge to

neoclassical growth theory to some extent. However, we will discuss this topic later in

detail (in Section 6).

5. Partially balanced growth

5.1 An example of a partially balanced growth model The models from previous sections were not very useful for studying structural

change analytically: The quite general model from Section 1 and 2 featured no

structural change in its asymptotic steady state, while being such complicated that the

transitional dynamics (which allow for structural change) are not examinable

analytically. I simplified this model strongly by using knife-edge parameter-

restrictions in Sections 3 and 4. However, these restrictions hindered structural change

(in steady state and during transition) strongly. In this section we will see that there is

a way between these two extremes. By assuming some less restricting knife-edge

restrictions I create a partially balanced growth path. Along this growth path the

model features structural change while still being analytically comprehensible. In fact,

the trick is finding such a “less restricting” knife-edge parameter restriction. I have

found one: Assume that model parameters are such that

(29) tWV tt ∀== ,0

In this case the model equations (10)-(20) become:

Equilibrium Aggregate-Behavior

(10’’’) m

mmmt

mt

mmt

mt

mtmtt n

kkn

KBYα

αα αα ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+= − 1)()( 1

106

Page 117: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(11’’’) tttt EKYK −−= δ&

(12’’’) ρδα −−= mt

mt

t

tm

t

t

kn

KY

EE ~&

(13’’’) tmm

ti

iim

mt

mt

Y

E

kn

~)1(1

αα

βαα

⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎝

⎛−

−=∑

Equilibrium Sector-Behavior (represented by employment shares)

(14’’’)

( ) ( )mi

KBnk

SYEn

ii

i

tit

i

i

m

mmt

mt

it

t

ti

m

iit ≠∀

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

−−

−−

=−

,

11

~)1()1(

1 ααα

αα

αα

βαα

(15’’’) t

mt

t

tmttmt Y

SY

EKKn ~~ −++

=βδ&

where

(16’’’) mmm mt

mtt

mtt nkKBY ααα )/()()(~ 1−≡

(17’’’) 0=tV

(18’’’) 0=itW

(19’’’) i

nBkK

nBkK

pi

m

it

it

itt

i

mt

mt

mtt

mit ∀

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

= −

,1

1

α

α

α

α

(20’’’) i

i

m

mmt

mt

it

it

nk

nk

αα

αα

−−

=1

1

Lemma 3: A unique partially balanced growth path exists in the dynamic system

(10’’’)-(20’’’), where aggregates ttt YKE ~,,( and grow at the constant rate

and is constant. Furthermore, structural change takes place along this

)tY mg

mt

mt nk /

107

Page 118: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

equilibrium growth path, i.e. the employment shares of sectors change. Note,

however, that here equations (14’’’) and (15’’’) imply that the employment shares

change in the dynamic equilibrium in contrast to Lemma 1.

)( itn

Proof: Note that the dynamic equation systems (10’’’)-(20’’’) and (10’)-(20’) are

identical. Hence, the proof of the existence and uniqueness of the dynamic

equilibrium from Lemma 1 applies here. Q.E.D.

Lemma 4: The partially balanced growth path from Lemma 3 is saddle-path stable.

Proof: See proof of Lemma 2. Q.E.D.

We can see that parameter restriction (29) creates an aggregate dynamic system

(equations (10’’’)-(13’’’) and (16’’’)) that is identical to the aggregate dynamic

system of Section 3 (equations (10’)-(13’) and (16’)), which was created by parameter

restriction (21). However, at the disaggregate level the two models differ: the model

from the current section features much more sectoral dynamic (cf. (14’’’) and (15’’’),

since iS need not being equal to zero to satisfy parameter restriction (29). Therefore,

in the model from the current section structural change takes place even in the

dynamic equilibrium. (Furthermore, in contrast to Section 3, the (transitional)

structural change dynamics are “richer”, i.e. factors are not only reallocated between

capital-production and consumption-goods-production, but also between the

consumption goods sectors).

We can see that the structural change dynamics and the factors which cause them are

quite easily identifiable in the dynamic equilibrium: Since in equations (14’’’) und

(15’’’) the first terms respectively and are constant and since mt

mt nk / tY~ and K grow

108

Page 119: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

at constant rate (cf. Lemma 3), the following is true for the structural change

patterns in the dynamic equilibrium

mg

• Sector-m-employment share increases or decreases monotonously, depending

upon the sign of mS . Furthermore, the speed of change is determined by . mg

• In sectors , the direction of structural change depends upon the sign of mi ≠

iS as well, and the patterns are monotonous. Furthermore, the speed of this

decrease is determined primarily by the magnitude of the term

miii gg αα +− )1( .

Note that these structural change patterns are (primarily quantitatively) different

during the transition period: Since during the transition is not constant and mt

mt nk /

tY~ and K grow at non-constant rates different from , the structural change patterns

may be weaker or stronger, depending on from where the economy starts (below or

above the partial steady state) and depending upon how close the economy is to the

steady state. Furthermore, in some cases even the direction of structural change may

change during the transition period: We know that in dynamic equilibrium the

denominator of the second term on the right-hand side of equation (14’’’) is

increasing (cf. Lemma 3). However, during the transition period this term may be

decreasing, for example if the economy starts above the partial steady state and the

capital level must be reduced during the transition period. These points could be

analysed in more detail by studying the phase diagram

mg

9 and the development of

etc. However, these questions are not in focus of this chapter. mt

mt nk /

Note that during the transitional period an additional structural-change-channel arises:

As discussed in Section 3, the structural change patterns modelled by Uzawa (1964)

9 The phase diagram of this model can be derived in similar way as the phase diagrams of the models about the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle and Ageing (see Chapter V). In fact the phase diagram of this model is qualitatively the same as the phase diagrams of the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle and Ageing models.

109

Page 120: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

arise. That is, additionally, factors are reallocated between the consumption-goods-

production and capita-goods-production. (This can be seen, e.g., from equation

(14’’’): since the savings rate “ tt YE ~/ ” is not constant during transition, employment

shares change due to change in the savings rate.). This point could be studied in more

detail, as well, by studying the phase diagram etc. However, I omit this discussion

here, since these questions are not in focus of my research.

What we should learn from this section is that very complicated and not intuitively

understandable models can be made understandable by “clever” usage of cross-

parameter restrictions. In this way we have obtained a quite understandable model

that can be used for many analytical topics. In other words, by clever usage of knife-

edge conditions a model can be created that inherits the best of two worlds: It has the

analytical transparency of a balanced growth model and rich sectoral dynamics of an

unbalanced growth model.

5.2 Examples from the literature on how to create partially balanced growth paths (usage of a priori and a posteriori knife-edge conditions) It should be noted that I have not been the first that uses knife-edge conditions in

structural change modelling to create intuitively understandable models. In fact, they

have been used since ever. I like thinking of knife-edge conditions as being divisible

into two classes:

(1) A priori knife-edge conditions. This means that right from beginning some

knife-edge restrictions are imposed by using restrictive assumptions regarding

utility and production. For example, in Section 3 I assume Cobb-Douglas

utility. The model-results (especially the existence of a balanced growth path)

110

Page 121: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

exist only with the Cobb-Douglas utility. More general assumptions would not

allow for balanced growth. For example, I have shown in Sections 1 and 2 that

with Stone-Geary-preferences no balanced growth path exists. With CES-

preferences a balanced growth path would not exist in the model as well. (This

can be seen from the model by Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008).) Therefore, we

can say that balanced growth is a knife-edge case, and I have obtained it in

Sections 3 and 4 by imposing a priori knife-edge restrictions (i.e. restrictive

assumptions). A priori knife-edge conditions are widespread. In fact, every

model uses some less general functional forms (e.g. time separable

preferences, identical households), which ensure the existence/transparency of

the model-results. A priori conditions may be justified by empirical evidence.

For example, if the empirical evidence implies that the elasticity of

substitution is equal to 1, the usage of a Cobb-Douglas function as a priori

knife-edge condition may be justified.

(2) A posteriori knife-edge conditions. These knife-edge conditions are not

imposed by assumption of specific functional forms, but are imposed on

specific functional forms. For example, restriction (29) cannot be expressed a

priori as a functional form. That is, we have to presume a functional form (like

(2)) and then impose this restriction on it. In fact, all a priori knife-edge

conditions can be expressed as a posteriori knife-edge conditions. For

example, assuming a CES function and imposing a posteriori that substitution

elasticity is equal to one, is the same as assuming a priori a Cobb-Douglas

function. In general, a posteriori knife-edge conditions could be justified by

showing empirically that they are satisfied.

I have introduced this distinction since it seems very important to understand the

following discussion. We will see that previously some authors have imposed a priori

111

Page 122: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

knife-edge conditions and some authors have imposed a posteriori knife-edge

condition. The latter have been “criticized” by the former for using knife-edge

conditions. This criticism seems, however, pointless: in fact both of them are using

knife-edge conditions. This fact becomes especially clear, when we see that all the

previous literature is only special cases of the model of Section 1. All these special

cases are obtained by assuming some knife-edge conditions. In general, a knfe-edge

condition is a severe restriction whether it is imposed a priori or a posteriori. What

matters is that it does not contradict empirical evidence; however, in fact, all previous

authors use knife-edge conditions that are clearly not supported by empirical evidence

or that no evidence has been provided for.

Kongsamut et al. (2001) use a posteriori knife-edge conditions. Their model is a

special case of the model from Section 5.1. Simply assume tiggii ,∀=∧=αα in

model from section 5.1 and you obtain the model by Kongsamut et al. (2001). Hence,

their model features as well a partially balanced growth path which exists only if an a

posteriori condition is satisfied. However, their structural change dynamics are less

rich, since their sectoral production functions are nearly identical (their production

functions differ across sectors only by a constant multiplicative parameter).

Meckl (2002) integrates the demand side of the model from Section 1 into an

endogenous growth model. His results regarding the existence of a partially balanced

growth path are quite the same as those by Kongsamut et al. (2001), since the utility

modelling and the a posteriori knife-edge conditions are quite the same as in the

model by Kongsamut et al. (2001). Nevertheless, his model is valuable for explaining

the role of indeterminacy for creating partially balanced growth.

Ngai and Pissarides (2007) use a priori knife-edge conditions. Their model is nearly

identical to the model of Section 3. As mentioned in Section 3, the assumption of

112

Page 123: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Cobb-Douglas preferences in this model restricts structural change very much (due to

unitary price elasticity). Therefore, Ngai and Pissarides (2007) use CES-preferences,

which feature price elasticity different from one. Furthermore, they restrict the model

from Section 3 further to allow for partially balanced growth: they assume

tii ,∀=αα . (It has been shown by Acemogu and Guerrieri (2008) that a partially

balanced growth path does not exist in this model, if not tii ,∀=αα .) For details of

the model by Ngai and Pissarides (2007), see the Offshoring model in Chapter V.

Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008) use a quite different framework in comparison to the

previously discussed authors. In fact, to ensure that partially balanced growth exists in

their model Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008) assume identical production functions

across sectors, which is again an a priori knife-edge condition. The model from

Section 5.1 can be used to see how this knife-edge condition works. Simply set

tiBBii ,∀=∧=αα in the model from Section 5.1. Nevertheless, the very valuable

contribution of the paper by Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008) is that their model

features the maximal degree of disaggregation; hence, it provides a lot of micro-

foundation for less disaggregated structural change models.

Note that knife-edge conditions are not only being used to create partially balanced

growth paths, but are used as well to make (simulatory) structural change models,

where no partially balanced growth paths exist, more intuitively understandable.

Examples are:

• The model by Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) is nearly identical to the model

of Section 3, which features a priori knife-edge restrictions. As mentioned in

Section 3, the assumption of Cobb-Douglas preferences in this model restricts

structural change very much (due to unitary price elasticity). Therefore,

113

Page 124: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) use CES-preferences, which feature price

elasticity different from one. For this reason, no partially balanced growth

path exists in the model by Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008), but only an

asymptotically balanced growth path. Nevertheless, their a priori knife-edge

restriction (usage of homothetic preferences instead of non-homothetic

preferences) makes the model easier to understand intuitively; nevertheless,

they require a simulation to show some results.

• The model by Baumol (1967) uses a priori restrictions as well. Baumol omits

capital from analysis and assumes only two sectors. In this way he was able to

prove his arguments with his simple model without any simulation, despite

the fact that there is no partially balanced growth path in his model.

• The second and third model by Kongsamut et al. (1997) could be mentioned

here as well. They are special cases of the model from Section 5.1. Their

second model results by simply assuming tii ,∀=αα in the model from

section 5.1. The assumptions of their third model are nearly identical to the

assumptions of Section 5.1. However, in both of their models they impose an

a posteriori knife-edge condition that is different from that of Section 5.1

(equation (29)). Therefore, a partially balanced growth path does not arise in

their model, but only a growth path with a constant real interest rate.

Therefore, among others, their model is still very difficult to study (e.g. they

do not provide a stability analysis or an interpretation of structural change).

• …

We learn from this discussion that, in fact, all essays from the partially balanced

growth school use severe knife-edge restrictions to create intuitively understandable

models. In fact, all of these restrictions either contradict empirical evidence (e.g.

114

Page 125: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

tii ,∀=αα , or tiBBi ,∀= , or tiggi ,∀= contradicts empirical evidence as discussed

in Chapter I), or are not empirically proven (e.g. the a posteriori knife-edge

restrictions).

6. Validity of neoclassical models in the light of structural change and the downside of knife-edge-condition use We have seen in the previous sections that a balanced growth path, as studied in the

neoclassical mainstream theory, is not easy to obtain by using neoclassical modeling

techniques when taking structural change into account. The model from Sections 1

and 2 does not reproduce a balanced growth path. Only strong knife-edge parameter

restrictions can ensure that despite structural change the neoclassical feature of

balanced growth is achieved. Hence, from this point of view the neoclassical growth

theory seems to be “inconsistent” with structural change, since its results can be

obtained only by imposing very restrictive knife edge conditions.

However, the usage of knife-edge conditions in economic modelling is not new, and

every model features some knife-edge conditions, whether it is a time-separable

utility, logarithmic utility, Cobb-Douglas-functions or cross-parameter restrictions in

the manner of restriction (29). Any model has to simplify in some way to become

understandable. Therefore, to say it in the words of Acemoglu (2009), pp.702f: when

comparing the advantages of such knife-edge conditions (i.e. comprehensibility), the

shortcomings of such conditions are “worth nothing”.

The key shortcoming of restrictions like (29) is that we have no reason to assume that

these conditions hold in reality. Hence, when some features of the model (especially

features associated with partially balanced growth) are used to explain some empirical

questions, the explanation of the model will always be that the knife-edge condition

115

Page 126: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(29) is the actual explanation of the empirical question. Hence, to make such models

more usable, we need a micro foundation for such restrictions.

As an example for this fact, the essay on the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle (see Chapter V)

may be considered: To make the things short: the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle implies that

the reality behaves as being close to a partially balanced growth path from Lemma 3.

Hence, we could use the model from this section and Lemma 3 as an explanation for

the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle. However, the partially balanced growth path in this

model exists only due to the assumption of restriction (29): without this restriction a

partially balanced growth path does not exist in our model, and hence the model is not

consistent with/an explanation of the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle. Therefore, the actual

explanation for the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle is restriction (29): Only if we find an

intuitive explanation for this restriction, the partially balanced growth path of the

model (together with the intuitive explanation of restriction (29)) is the explanation of

the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle. In fact, this is what I do in the essay on the Kuznets-

Kaldor-Puzzle: I argue that independency between preferences and technologies yield

the satisfaction of restriction (29) and we show that preferences and technologies are

independent in realty in part. (Of course, my empirical proof of independency is only

a first step; much more theoretical and empirical work has to be done to provide a

solid theoretical basis for the assumption of independent preferences and

technologies.)

Furthermore, it should be noted that, in general, any usage of knife-edge conditions

eliminates some impact channels (provided that the knife-edge-conditions make the

model simpler). For example, by imposing knife-edge conditions in the previous

models, we have always eliminated some structural change patterns: e.g. in Sections 3

and 4 structural change between the consumption-goods-sectors has been eliminated

by imposing the knife-edge conditions; e.g. in Section 5.1 structural change between

116

Page 127: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

the capital-goods-production and consumption-goods-production has been eliminated

in dynamic equilibrium by using the knife-edge conditions. This fact should be kept in

mind when using knife-edge-conditions, and the model-results should always be

examined upon whether they are only due to the knife-edge conditions or whether

they have more general meaning. In the essays from Section V, I have always tried to

focus on the results that have rather general meaning (i.e. results which are not

restricted in validity by the validity of the knife-edge condition); otherwise, as in the

essay on the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle, I have tried to provide some empirical evidence

for the validity of the knife-edge condition, to asses the validity of the model results.

However, it seems that often decades are required to discuss whether the results, that

are derived by a knife-edge condition, are general enough. The best example is the

neoclassical growth theory. This theory started in the 1950ies by assuming hyper-

rational identical households with time-separable preferences (which are knife-edge

conditions), etc, and today we still have a discussion about these assumptions, their

implications and the appropriateness of their usage.

All in all, from the viewpoint of the neoclassical growth theory it seems important to

find intuitive/theoretical explanations for the knife-edge conditions which are

necessary to make it consistent with technologically heterogeneous sectors. In the

essay on the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle a first step in this direction is done by showing

that the required knife-edge conditions may be explained by the assumption of

consumers that do not care about the production process. However, of course there

seems to be a lot of further research necessary to completely find a micro-foundation

for these knife-edge conditions.

In this way we may also get a notion of the micro-economic presumptions that are

required by standard neoclassical growth literature. Searching deeper and deeper into

117

Page 128: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

the microeconomics for foundation of the knife-edge conditions can reveal the real

individual behavior that underlies neoclassical growth theory.

In general, all my models contribute to justifying neoclassical growth theory, since I

show that a lot of structural change dynamics is consistent with aggregate growth

paths that are similar to the neoclassical growth paths.

In the following chapter I systematize the literature on structural transformation and

classify my own research.

118

Page 129: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX Efficient allocation of labor across sectors requires that the values of marginal

productivity of labor are equal across sectors (when there is free mobility of labor

across sectors), which implies:

(A.1) minYnY

pp

it

it

mt

mt

mt

it ≠∀

∂∂∂∂

= //

The representative household maximizes its lifetime-utility given by (1) and (2)

subject to equations (3)-(8). The corresponding Hamiltonian is given by:

(A.2) ( ) )(,..., 21 mtt

mtt

mttt CKYCCCuH −−+= δψ

where

121 ,..., −mttt CCC are given by (cf. (6)), miYC i

tit ≠∀= ,

mttt YYY ,..., 21 are given by (3),

mtk is given by (cf. (4)), ∑

−=mi

it

mt kk 1

and is given by (cf. (4)). mtn ∑

−=mi

it

mt nn 1

Control variables are: and . is state variable. ,,..., ,,..., 121121 −− mttt

mttt kkknnn m

tC tK

Thus, optimality conditions are given by:

(A.3) ⇔≠∀=∂∂

∂∂

+∂∂

∂∂

=∂∂ mi

kkK

KkYK

KkY

Cu

kH

it

mt

tt

mt

mt

ttt

it

it

it

it

0)()(

(.) !ψ

(A.4) miKk

YKk

YCu

tmt

mt

tt

it

it

it

≠∀∂∂

=∂∂

∂∂

)()((.) ψ

⇔≠∀=∂∂

∂∂

+∂∂

∂∂

=∂∂ mi

nn

nY

nY

Cu

nH

it

mt

mt

it

tit

it

it

it

0(.) !ψ

(A.5) minY

nY

Cu

mt

mt

tit

it

it

≠∀∂∂

=∂∂

∂∂ (.) ψ

119

Page 130: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

⇔=−∂∂

=∂∂ 0(.) !

tmt

mt C

uCH ψ

(A.6) tmtC

u ψ=∂∂ (.)

(A.7) ( ) ( ) tttmt

tmt

mt

tmi

it

tit

it

itt

kKk

YkKk

YCu

KH ρψψδψψ −=⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

∂∂

+∂∂

∂∂

−=∂∂

− ∑≠

&!(.)

From (A.4)-(A.6) follows that:

(A.8) minYnY

CuCu

it

it

mt

mt

mt

it ≠∀

∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

(.)(.)

(A.9) minYnY

KkYKkY

it

it

mt

mt

tit

it

tmt

mt ≠∀

∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

)()(

Inserting first (A.4) and then (4) into (A.7) results in:

(A.10) ( ) t

t

tmt

mt

KkY

ψψρδ&

−=+−∂∂ )(

(9) follows from (A.1), (A.6), (A.8), (A.9) and 8. Q.E.D.

120

Page 131: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

LIST OF SYMBOLS of CHAPTER III ^ Denotes the growth rate of the corresponding variable.

itB Parameter indicating technology/productivity level of sector i at time t.

(exogenous)

itC Consumption of sector-i-output at time t; indicates how much of the output of

sector i is consumed at time t.

E Aggregate consumption expenditures; index of overall consumption-

expenditures of the representative household

(.)H Hamiltonian.

K Aggregate capital; i.e. the amount of capital that is used for production in the

whole economy.

itS Parameter of the utility function; closely related to the utility of . May be

interpreted as minimum consumption regarding good i (e.g. subsistence level),

if positive. May be interpreted as “natural” endowment of good i, if negative.

(exogenous)

itC

U Life-time utility of the (representative) household.

tV Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

tW Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

Y Aggregate output; index of economy-wide output-volume.

tY~ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

itY Output of sector i at time t.

ig Growth rate of labor-augmenting technological progress in sector i.

i Index denoting a sector.

121

Page 132: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

j Index denoting a sector.

itk Capital-share of sector i at time t; indicates which share of aggregate capital

(K) is used in sector i.

itl Employment-share of sector i at time t; indicates which share of aggregate

labor is used in sector i.

m Number of sectors.

t Index denoting time.

(.)u Instantaneous utility-function.

mu First derivative of u(.) with respect to . mtC

iα Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function of sector i; is equal to

output-elasticity of labor in sector i. (exogenous)

iβ Parameter of the utility function; closely related to the utility of . itC

δ Depreciation rate on capital (K). (exogenous)

ρ Time-preference rate. (exogenous)

)(tψ Co-state variable.

122

Page 133: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

CHAPTER IV

Classification/Systematization of Structural Change Literature and Classification/Subordination of own

Research

In this Chapter, I suggest a classification/systematization of structural change

literature and show the position of my research within this system. Exactly speaking, I

review here only the formal/mathematical modelling efforts, since the focus of my

research is on mathematical structural change modelling. Essays, where structural

change is discussed rather in verbal/anecdotal/empirical manner (which is especially

true for the early structural change literature), have been reviewed in Chapter I.

In general, there are many ways to classify/systematize the structural change

literature. My systematization is designed such that it becomes clearly visible how my

research differs from other research, as I hope. Although it is usual to discuss the

categorization of the literature relatively at the beginning of an essay, I discuss it in

this chapter, since I think that the previous Chapters II and III are necessary to really

understand the following categorization.

Note that this chapter is aimed to be a systematization of literature, which is only

loosely related to the applications of my research in Chapter V. Additional literature,

which is directly relevant to Chapter V, is discussed in the essays of Chapter V, since

only in this way the argumentation in the essays can be made clear.

Furthermore, note that structural change is a word with many meanings in economics.

For example, institutional changes, changes in the behaviour of the agents, changes in

regulatory policy, etc, are often named “structural change”. However, such imprecise

and too general definitions of the word “structural change” are not practicable in

model-oriented research, since many of the facts, which are named “structural

123

Page 134: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

change” in the literature, require completely different methods of analysis, models

and/or time horizons (and thus are not related to my research). Therefore, I categorize

here only the literature that deals with long-run (trend) changes of real production

structures; especially, there must be some reallocation across real production sectors.

This literature may be similar to my research at least regarding the analytical methods

and many model assumptions. Nevertheless, we will see that the field of literature that

analyses the questions, which I analyse, and that uses the methods, which I use, is

quite small.

I suggest the following classification, where the class of my approach is emphasised:

Figure 1: A systematization of structural change literature

Long-run Changes in Real Sectoral Production Structures

Changes in Capital Structure Changes in Intermediate Structure

Changes in Consumption Structure

Traditional (unbalanced) School New (partially balanced) School

In the following I discuss this figure. Before doing so let me point to three other

criterions by which the structural change literature can be systematized parallely to

the system of Figure 1:

(1) Structuralist Approach vs. Neoclassical Approach to Structural Change

Modelling. This distinction is inspired by Wagner’s (1997) systematization of

124

Page 135: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

development theories (see there p.38ff). The structuralist approach presumes

some structural rigidities. These rigidities are, however, not micro-founded.

That is, some (rather: many) relationships are assumed to be exogenously

given; however, there are no other (mathematical) models that explain what

determines these relationships and why the relationships are such as they are in

reality (i.e. the argumentation for these parameter values is rather “verbal”). In

contrast, the neoclassical approach aims to provide micro-foundation of as

much relationships as possible. Especially, this micro-foundation is based on

the assumption of more or less rational agents and capital accumulation plays

often a crucial role. In fact, none of the structural change models is clearly

structuralist or neoclassical. However, there are clear tendencies regarding

whether the model features rather neoclassical assumptions (hence, a lot of

neoclassical micro-foundation applies) or rather some exogenously given

relationships. We will see that my approach is rather neoclassical.

(2) Analytical Approach vs. Simulation Approach to Structural Change

Modelling. As mentioned many times there is always a trade-off in economic

modelling: more general models are often less intuitively understandable and

therefore require simulations to disentangle their dynamics; to make a model

intuitively understandable simplifying assumptions are required often, which

reduce the generality of the model. Again, the distinction between analytical

and simulation models is not discrete. That is, in every model some results can

be derived analytically, irrespective of how complicated the model is. As

mentioned a lot of times, I focus on analytical analysis of models.

(3) Degree of Disaggregation. The degree of disaggregation is very important

regarding the question what the adequate assumptions for a model are. To my

knowledge, all authors that model low degree of aggregation (e.g. sector-

125

Page 136: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

division: agriculture, manufacturing and services) assume perfect markets and

especially perfect factor mobility in the long run. However, the higher the

degree of disaggregation, the more important become such things as

monopoles, oligopoly, strategic behaviour of agents, etc. Furthermore, at very

low degree of disaggregation the stylized facts of structural change across

sectors (see Chapter I) are not relevant, but other stylized facts (regarding

structural change across product-varieties) are relevant, e.g. product-life-

cycles. Overall, at very high degree of disaggregation (e.g. when looking at

individual entrepreneurs/product-varieties) completely other assumptions and

model-results are required in comparison to the assumptions and results of

cross-sector-structural change models. Furthermore, the most authors, who

analyse models with high degree of disaggregation (e.g. Schumpeterian

models), do not draw any references to structural change across broad sectors

like manufacturing and agriculture. (However, there are exemptions, like

Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008).) In general, it requires further theoretical

reasoning/models to explain how the micro-reallocations at high degree of

disaggregation (“structural change across product-varieties”) are related to the

reallocations at less disaggregated level (“structural change across sectors”).

(For example, Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008), p.1322, develop a theory that

the services sector may include rather new product-varieties, since services

satisfy “less urgent needs”.) My research focuses on reproducing structural

change patterns across sectors (and not across product-varieties), i.e. I focus on

low degree of disaggregation.

In the following discussion, mostly, I classify the models as structuralist or

neoclassical and as analytical or simulation models. However, as mentioned above

126

Page 137: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

these classifications imply solely a tendency; every model is structuralist in some

sense and every model is analytically understandable to some degree. Furthermore,

although I study structural change rather at low degree of disaggregation, in every

section I also mention some models that feature high degree of disaggregation.

127

Page 138: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

TABLE OF CONTENTS for CHAPTER IV

1. Changes in capital structure ...................................................................................129

2. Changes in intermediates structure ........................................................................132

3. Changes in consumption structure .........................................................................137

3.1 “Unbalanced” school of structural change.......................................................137

3.2 “New” (PBGP) school of structural change.....................................................142

4. Classification of own research ...............................................................................146

5. Further aspects of classification.............................................................................149

5.1 Structural change induced by trade opening (structural change theory vs. trade

theory) ....................................................................................................................149

5.2 Factor reallocation between capital industries and consumption industries

(Uzawa’s structural change) ..................................................................................151

5.3 Factor-reallocation between the private sector and the public sector ..............152

5.4 Factor-reallocation between the research sector and the consumption sector .153

5.5 Outsourcing of home production (factor reallocation between home-sector and

market-sector) ........................................................................................................154

128

Page 139: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

1. Changes in capital structure This point refers to the fact that there are many heterogeneous capital goods in the

real economy, which are produced by different sectors/technologies. For example, the

simplest case is the assumption that there is (physical) capital and human capital.

However, physical capital and human capital can be subdivided further, depending

upon which technology is used to produce them or depending upon the output-

elasticity of the respective capital-sort.

Changes in capital demand and/or differences in production technologies across

capital goods can yield structural change across capital producing sectors similar to

structural change modelled in Chapter III. However, in contrast to the models of

structural change of Chapter III, changes in the capital structure are closely related to

endogenous growth, as shown in the neoclassical endogenous growth literature. In

fact, there is a large body of neoclassical growth literature dealing with the existence

of heterogeneous capital goods. In some of this literature, the heterogeneous capital

goods are produced by technologically heterogeneous sectors; hence, these models

depict structural change across capital-goods sectors. An example of such models is

the Uzawa-Lucas-model with physical capital and human capital that are produced by

two technologically distinct sectors (for discussion see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin

(2004), pp.247ff). More general models (i.e. models where many heterogeneous

capital goods are produced by technologically heterogeneous sectors) are presented

by, e.g., Benhabib and Nishimura (1979), Kaganovich (1998) and Takahashi (1992,

2008). (See there for further literature on this topic.) In general, these models are

treated rather in analytical manner, and of course they are rather neoclassical.

It should be noted that in all my models there is only one capital good and only one

capital-producing sector. (Usually, sector m is producing capital.) That is, structural

change across capital goods and all its impacts are exogenous in my model (i.e. all the

129

Page 140: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

impacts of this sort of structural change are contained in the exogenous parameters,

like the technology parameters of sector m). The reasons for the fact that I do not

model structural change across capital sectors, but across consumption sectors, is

simple: First, I have not found any research topic that is feasible for me in this field.

Structural change across consumption goods sectors seemed to me relatively less

elaborated in comparison to structural change across capital goods sectors. The

second reason is rather technical: the mathematical challenges of studying such

models, as will be explained now.

Beside the fact that structural change across capital-goods can generate endogenous

growth in contrast to my models, there is a key analytical difference, which is related

to the dynamic systems that are created by multi-capital-goods-models. In general,

every capital good that is assumed to exist in a model creates a dynamic restriction

(i.e. a dynamic capital accumulation equation). The discussion in Section 3 of Chapter

II has shown that every dynamic constraint establishes a state variable. The dimension

of the dynamic system (that results from the Hamiltonian optimality conditions) is

equal to the sum of the number of control and state variables. Hence, the more capital

goods are included into a model the higher the dimension of the dynamic system that

has to be analysed in final analysis. I have explained in Sections 2 and 3.2 of Chapter

II that this analysis becomes the more complicated the higher the dimension of the

dynamic system is. (Especially, stability analysis, study of transitional dynamics and

proof of sufficiency of necessary Hamiltonian optimality-conditions become quasi

“not feasible”.)

The nice thing in my models (where only heterogeneous consumption goods exist) is

that the final dynamic system, which has to be analysed, features maximally 3

dimensions, irrespective of how much consumption goods are assumed to exist. (In

fact, this has been demonstrated in the models of Chapter III.) The reason is, that the

130

Page 141: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

number of consumption goods, in general, constitutes the number of control variables;

and the dynamics of control variables can, in general, be described by one dynamic

equation (and several static equations) when using the Hamiltonian optimality

conditions. At the same time, the number of dynamic equations, which describe the

development of state variables, cannot be reduced. Hence, the dimension of the final

dynamic system is, in general, at least equal to the number of the state variables.

Therefore, increasing the number of capital goods always creates higher-dimensional

dynamic systems in comparison to increasing the number of consumptions goods,

and, as explained above, this makes the systems very difficult to analyse. Therefore

among others, global stability of relatively general heterogeneous-capital-sector-

models has not been proven by now, to my knowledge (see e.g. Takahashi (2008),

p.48). Furthermore, due to the analytical complexity of these models, structural

change across capital-sectors (during the transition) is very difficult to study (in

models with three or more capital goods).

Nevertheless, a lot of “interesting” research seems to be possible in this field at more

disaggregated level: At low degree of disaggregation, capital goods are produced

primarily by one sector, i.e. the manufacturing sector (see e.g. Kongsamut et al.

2001). Therefore, for explaining the stylized facts of structural change across broad

sectors (like agriculture, manufacturing and services) cross-capital structural change

may be less interesting. However, for explaining the structural change within the

manufacturing sector, cross-capital structural change seems very important. Stylized

facts about the labour-reallocation that is induced in the manufacturing sector by

cross-capital structural change and corresponding mathematical models may be

formulated. However, by now, I have not researched much in this field; hence I am

not sure to what extent the existing literature can be adapted to study these topics.

131

Page 142: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

2. Changes in intermediates structure In reality, the output of each sector is not only produced by using capital and labour

but also by using intermediate products that are produced in other sectors (by using

capital and labour and other intermediates); furthermore, in general, each sector

produces intermediates for other sectors as well. Hence, the production structure of an

economy is a huge cob-web of relations between sectors, where each sector is supplier

and receiver of intermediate services and goods.

In the static context, this cob-web can be depicted by input-output tables, where the

relations between the sectors are depicted by constant empirically measured input-

coefficients. (On discussion of these input-output tables and their practical use, see

e.g. Pasinetti, 1988, p.57ff.) Input-output-tables may be analysed dynamically as well,

where it is assumed, that the input coefficients are constant over time. However, there

is little intuition behind dynamic input-output tables, since the input-coefficients are

not micro-founded in any sense (furthermore, we have no reason to believe that input

coefficients are constant in the long-run). Therefore, such dynamic input-output tables

are rather not useful as theoretical structural change models, but are rather of interest

for empirical “short-run” questions, like the Leontjef-systems; for discussion, see e.g.

Pasinetti (1988), pp.77ff. The latter may be known to most growth theoreticians by

the relatively restrictive production function, which is derived from them (“Leontjef

production function” or “limitational production function”), which is a special case of

the (in Neoclassics) well known CES-production function (see e.g. Maußner and

Klump, 1996, pp.56ff). An application of Lenontjef-tables in structural change

analysis is provided by, e.g., Greenhalg und Gregory (2001).

In models, which omit intermediates, it is implicitly assumed that for each good the

amounts of capital and labour (that are used in final and intermediate production) are

summed up and inserted into a production function that depicts the sectoral output as

132

Page 143: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

a function of capital and labour only; the eventual productivity effects of intermediate

restructuring are assumed to be implicitly contained in the (exogenous) productivity

parameters of the sectors.

Of course, it is interesting to disentangle how the intermediate structure affects the

sectoral production functions and in this way provide a more detailed “micro”-

foundation of the sectoral parameters. This is done, among others, by the “Sraffa-

Pasinetti-school” of structural change: The starting point of this school are input-

output-systems, which provide a detailed description of the cob-web of intermediate

suppliers and receivers. In fact, these quasi purely descriptive input-output-systems

are filled/micro-founded with economic intuition, which is based primarily on

classical economic theories (e.g. Ricardian assumptions, like subsistence wages, etc.);

see e.g. Pasinetti (1988), pp.53, 71ff, 95, and Harris (1982), p.28f. Then, the input-

output-systems are transformed to vertically integrated sectors. In this way, for each

good the whole amount of embodied labour (used in final and intermediate

production) is obtained. (For mathematical derivation of vertically integrated sectors

see Pasinetti (1988), p.97.) Overall, a relationship is constituted between “sectoral

production functions” (which are functions of labour only) and the cob-web of

intermediate relations from the input-output-tables; compare also Harris (1982), p.31.

The analysis is primarily analytical.

These (rather static) concepts are generalized/complemented/extended (among others

by alternative derivations of “sectoral production functions” and by including

dynamic aspects) by Passineti (1981, 1993), Andersen (2001), Gualerzi (2001),

Godwin and Punzo (1987), etc. An overview/discussion of these efforts can be found

in the essays by Harris (1982), Malinvaud (1995), Nayak et al. (2009), Krüger (2008),

Punzo (2006) and Landesmann and Stehrer (2006).

133

Page 144: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Beside of these quite general approaches (“many sectors”, “many intermediate

linkages”), which are based on input-output-tables, there are also some two-sector

models, where only one of the sectors provides intermediates to sector-external firms,

for example Fixler and Siegel (1999), Oulton (2001), Sasaki (2007) and Restuccia et

al. (2008). Despite their simplicity, these models provide interesting/relevant results

regarding the question what impacts have (changes in) intermediate linkages on the

sectoral productivity parameters. These models are rather structuralist simulation

models. (However, many intuitive results can be derived from them even without

simulation, since they are relatively “simple”.)

Last (not) least, neoclassical endogenous growth theory (including “Schumpeterian

endogenous growth models”) features as well models with multiple intermediate

products. For description of such models see, e.g., Grossman and Helpman (1991),

pp.43ff, Aghion and Howitt (1998), pp.85ff, Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004),

pp.285ff. These endogenous growth models are rather analytically solvable and

feature a high degree of disaggregation, i.e. they analyse structural change across

product-varieties. However, due to very restrictive preference and technology

assumptions, the models are, in general, not very useful for studying structural

change, since no structural change takes place (across technologically heterogeneous

sectors); see also Krüger (2008), pp.340ff and Montobbio (2002), p.410. It should be

noted that there are few exemptions: These are the models by Meckl (2002) and

Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008), which will be discussed in Section 3.2, and the model

by Aghion and Howitt (1998), pp.86ff. The latter features unbalanced expansion of

intermediate-variety-producers (see there p.87). However, when the model is

extended to include capital in production, all sectors expand at the same rate, i.e. there

is no structural change anymore (see there p.95 and see also Krüger (2008), p.341).

134

Page 145: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

The study of intermediate restructuring is not in focus of my research; respectively,

my research is not adequate for studying intermediate restructuring in detail. I include

intermediate sectors in all of my models (for the sake of generality and to show how

much intermediate restructuring can be integrated into structural change models by

my approach). However, I restrict the functional forms, which rule the dynamics of

intermediate restructuring, severely by assuming Cobb-Douglas intermediate indices.

In this way a big part of intermediate restructuring is eliminated (as can be seen, e.g.,

in the Offshoring-model and in the Kuznets-Kaldor-model from Chapter V, or in the

model by Ngai and Pissarides (2007)). In other words, the biggest part of intermediate

restructuring is exogenous in my models (i.e. the effects of intermediate restructuring

are rather represented by the changes in the exogenous model parameters, e.g.

technology parameters). Overall, studying intermediate restructuring requires

probably other models than mine.

I restrict (endogenous) intermediate restructuring in my models, since I have not

found a way to make it consistent with partially balanced growth, by now. (As

mentioned many times, I focus on the partially balanced method.) In fact, it seems

that only very restrictive assumptions on intermediate structures are feasible with

partially balanced growth (within the neoclassical framework), as shown by Ngai and

Pissarides (2007). As can be seen in the Offshoring- and Kuznets-Kaldor-model of

Chapter V, Cobb-Douglas-intermediate structures can be feasible with partially

balanced growth; however, they eliminate a lot of intermediate restructuring (as

elaborated especially in the Kuznets-Kaldor-model, Lemmma 7/Appendix E).

Overall, integrating more complex intermediate sector assumptions into my models

would make simulations necessary to derive the key model results.

It may appear contradictory that I study offshoring in Chapter V (where intermediate

restructuring is an integral part of offshoring), while stating in the actual section that

135

Page 146: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

my models are not adequate for studying intermediate restructuring. However, a

closer look at the Offshoring-model shows that there is actually no contradiction: The

key mechanism in the Offshoring-model is: offshoring (i.e. import of intermediates)

increases productivity-growth; this increase in productivity-growth accelerates capital

accumulation and therefore slows down final-goods structural change. That is, in

some sense the restructuring of intermediates is exogenous in my model: after

opening of international borders intermediates are imported from abroad (i.e. the

intermediate structure changes immediately). The proof, that this opening increases

productivity (and thus capital accumulation), does not actually require complicated

modelling of intermediate sector structure. (In fact the only necessary assumption is

that at least some sectors use intermediates.) In this sense, I do not study the long-run

impact of offshoring on intermediate restructuring, but I simply show the existence of

a long-run impact of offshoring on final-goods structural change. Therefore, too

simple intermediate sector assumptions can only affect the quantitative results of my

model (“How strong is the structural change slow-down?”); however, they do not

affect the qualitative result (namely the fact that consumption-goods-structural change

is slowed-down by offshoring). Since, anyway, my models are not designed to

produce quantitatively good results1, complicated modelling of the intermediate

sector is not necessary in the Offshoring essay.

Of course, it may be interesting to integrate offshoring into models, where

intermediate structures are more complicated than my intermediate structures. This

topic is already studied by some researchers (on literature, see the Offshoring-essay in

Chapter V). However, I guess that, nevertheless, there are still open questions

regarding this topic, especially, regarding the implications of offshoring for (longer-

run) dynamics of intermediate restructuring. 1 In fact, in most cases only simulation-models of structural change can produce quantitatively adequate results; see also Chapter I.

136

Page 147: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Again, it should be noted that I have focused on consumption goods structural change

(instead of focusing on intermediate restructuring) only for practical reasons: I have

not found enough questions in intermediate restructuring that are feasible for me.

3. Changes in consumption structure More and more, we come closer to the actual topic of my research: change in

consumption structures. In general, in my research I refer only to this sort of

restructuring as “structural change”. In reality, there are several sectors that produce

consumption goods (e.g. agriculture, manufacturing and services). The reallocation of

labour between these sectors is named structural change (in my research). For

example, the term structural change comprises the fact that the labour share of

agriculture is decreasing and the labour share of services is increasing (in

industrialised countries). In general, the literature on (consumption) structural change

can be divided into an “unbalanced approach” and a relatively new “partially balanced

growth approach”. The difference between these two approaches is rather

methodological, as we will see. The methods of the new approach are rather familiar

with the methods of (mainstream) neoclassical growth theories. Hence, this approach

may be amenable to a larger part of researchers in comparison to the unbalanced

approach. Therefore, among others, the partially balanced growth approach has the

potential for bringing the structural change theory closer to the mainstream.

3.1 “Unbalanced” school of structural change Traditionally, structural change theory is “unbalanced”, since structural change

requires (per definition) unbalanced expansion of sectors (i.e. structural change means

137

Page 148: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

that sectors expand at different (non-constant) rates). Hence, balanced growth paths

do not exist in “unbalanced school”-models (for general parameter settings), i.e. the

“unbalanced school” focuses on analysis of unbalanced growth paths.

Remember that I have discussed in Chapter II that balanced growth paths are

advantageous, since they make a lot of analysis simple/intuitively understandable. In

fact, I have demonstrated in Chapter III that a balanced growth model is quite easy to

understand (see there Sections 3 and 4), while the corresponding unbalanced growth

model is very difficult to study (see there Sections 1 and 2).

Probably therefore among others, the “unbalanced school” has never been regarded as

mainstream theory of economic development. Rather, the neoclassical growth

theories, which base their analysis heavily on balanced growth paths, were

“mainstream”. Note that neoclassical growth theories feature as well models with

multiple sectors; however, there is no relevant structural change within these models,

due to restricting assumptions (as explained in the previous section and as will be seen

below). That is, the neoclassical growth models are rather “balanced”.

Note that, furthermore, “unbalanced school”-models feature (often) asymptotically

balanced growth paths.

In the following I provide some literature references. This literature features models

where the focus is on the study of unbalanced growth paths and where the degree of

disaggregation is relatively low. Since the models are unbalanced, they rather require

simulations to disentangle their dynamics. However, often many interesting results

can be derived from these models even without simulations.

On the one side, there are models where nearly all key results can be derived

analytically, due to simplicity of assumptions, e.g Baumol (1967) and Gundlach

(1994). The tools, which are used in this literature to increase the degree of simplicity

(and hence to increase the degree of analytical derivability of results), are:

138

Page 149: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(1) restricting the analysis to only two sectors and/or

(2) omitting capital accumulation from analysis and/or

(3) omitting (mathematical/explicit) micro-foundation of demand

behaviour and/or

(4) omitting some structural change determinants (e.g. by assuming

homothetic preferences, identical output-elasticities of inputs across

sectors).

In fact, Baumol (1967) uses all of these tools.

On the other side, there are models which, in fact, require simulations to derive their

key results. These models use only few or none of the simplifying tools from above.

For example, Echevarria (1997, 2000) uses none of the tools from above, and the

resulting model features quite complex dynamics/simulations.

Between these two extremes there is a lot of literature. In the following I subdivide

this literature according to three criterions:

• Which structural change determinants are included (demand-side- vs.

supply-side-structural change determinants; see also Chapter I)?

• Are demand patterns micro-founded (in the sense of utility

maximization by a representative household)?

• Is capital included into analysis?

I use these three criterions, since in this way I can subdivide the literature into groups

that are more or less comparable to my research, as we will see below. These groups

are:

Baumol (1967) (in conjunction with Baumol et al. (1985)) and Beissinger (2000)

provide models where only supply-side-determinants are considered, capital is

139

Page 150: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

omitted and demand patterns are not micro-founded. Hence, these models are rather

structuralist and analytically interpretable.

Jensen and Larsen (2004), Zuleta and Young (2007) and Acemoglu and Guerrieri

(2008) focus on supply-side-determinants of structural change as well; however, they

include capital into analysis and a micro-foundation of demand patterns (utility

maximization). Hence, these models are rather micro-founded in neoclassical way.

Buera and Kaboski (2009b) provide a “micro-founded” model, where structural

change is caused by the demand-side. They omit capital accumulation and assume

quite restrictive Leontjef-production functions (in part), which makes the model more

“structuralist” again.

The remaining literature includes both, demand-side- and supply-side-determinants of

structural change. Demand-side structural change is caused by some sort of non-

homothetic preferences. These preferences are mostly based on Stone-Geary

preferences in this literature. Supply-side structural change is caused primarily by

cross-sector differences in technological progress. Some models include also other

supply-side-structural change determinants, like cross-sector differences in input-

elasticites of output.

This literature can be systematised as follows.

First, there is a group of rather structuralist models that do not include capital and

utility maximization into analysis, e.g. Gundlach (1994), Notarangelo (1999),

Mickiewicz and Zalewska (2001) and Raiser et al. (2003).

The second group, includes utility maximization; however, capital is omited from

analysis; e.g. Appelbaum and Schettkat (1999), Messina (2003), Pugno (2006)

(includes human capital), Duarte and Restuccia (2010), Rogerson (2008) and Boppart

(2010)..

140

Page 151: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

The third group may be rather described as “neoclassical” approach to structural

change modelling, since demand patterns are “micro-founded” by utility-

maximization and capital is included into analysis. The papers belonging to this group

are, e.g., Echevarria (1997, 2000), Laitner (2000) (includes land), Golin et al. (2002),

Greenwood and Uysal (2005), Bah (2007) (includes land), Golin et al. (2007) and

Buera and Kaboski (2009a).

In fact, the papers from group three are, if at all, comparable to my research, since, I

include capital and micro-foundation into analysis, like they. Some of these papers

use more restrictive assumptions on sectors and technologies or additional

assumptions (inclusion of land) in comparison to me. However, the key difference to

my research is simply that I use another method of analysis (PBGP), which makes

analytical study of structural change possible. In contrast, the papers of group three

may be regarded as simulation models. In general, if all the assumptions, which I use

in my models, were integrated into the models of group three, all the models of group

three would become such complicated, that nearly no intuitive results could be

derived from them (without simulations).

Note that the theories from Section 2, e.g. Fixler and Siegel (1999), Oulton (2001),

Sasaki (2007) and Restuccia et al. (2008), could be mentioned in this section as well,

since they also include heterogeneous consumption goods. In fact, they

complement/micro-found the results of the theories of the actual section.

Furthermore, in fact, many of the neoclassical endogenous growth theories, that

feature heterogeneous intermediates, could be interpreted as having heterogeneous

final consumption goods (see e.g. Grossman and Helpman (1991), p.46). Therefore,

they could be discussed in this section as well. However, as explained in the previous

section, these theories are not very useful for studying structural change, due to some

141

Page 152: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

very restricting assumptions (see there for details). (These theories feature very high

degree of disaggregation.)

Last not least, there is some “evolutionary structural change literature” (with very

high degree of disaggregation). Like evolutionary literature in general, evolutionary

structural change literature departs strongly from the assumptions which are used in

other models discussed in this chapter. For example: there are no standard utility and

production functions; quite a lot of assumptions are structuralist (sometimes proven

by empirical laws); bounded rationality and heterogeneous agents are assumed in part;

some “laws”, that are known from biological evolutionary theory (sorting and

selection), are shown to be true regarding industry-behaviour; etc. These

characteristics can be seen in the models by, e.g., Montobbio (2002), Saviotti and

Pyka (2004) and Metcalfe et al. (2006). An extensive discussion of the evolutionary

structural change literature and further references are provided by Krüger (2008),

p.344ff.

The evolutionary approach is a relatively new approach to structural change theory. It

may be very promising. However, in contrast to the approach discussed in the next

section, a lot of mathematical micro-foundation seems to be inexistent by now and

often simulations are necessary due to complexity of assumptions; see e.g. Krüger

(2008), p.345.

In general, Krüger (2008) and Pugno (2006) seem to be very useful references for

alternative structural change literature overviews.

3.2 “New” (PBGP) school of structural change Finally, we have arrived at the group of literature, to which my research belongs. The

key feature of the PBGP-school is that it tries to create analytically interpretable

models, without using the simplification tools (1)-(4) from the previous section.

142

Page 153: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Hence, this group can analyse some questions analytically, which cannot be analysed

analytically by using the models from the previous section. Especially, many

questions, that require the consideration of capital in structural change analysis, can

be analysed by using the PBGP-approach. In general, all models from the previous

sections, that include capital into analysis, become such complicated that simulations

are necessary to disentangle their dynamics. Especially therefore, the PBGP-school

seems very useful. (I discuss in Chapter I, why it is important to include capital into

analysis of structural change.)

The PBGP-school uses, in general, neoclassical assumptions. Furthermore, these

assumptions are restricted to some extent (by usage of knife-edge-conditions) to

ensure the existence of partially balanced growth paths, see also Chapter III.

As discussed in Chapter III, the development of structural change is quite intuitively

understandable along a PBGP even without simulations. Hence, the PBGP-school

seems to be especially useful for deriving (qualitative) theories of structural change.

The quantitative aspects of structural change rather cannot be derived from the PBGP-

school, since, as discussed in Chapters I and III, the simplifying assumptions, which

are necessary to ensure the existence of a PBGP, restrict some structural change in

general. This opinion is supported by the empirical study by Buera and Kaboski

(2009a), which shows that the models by Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001) cannot

generate sufficiently strong structural change patterns. Especially, they argue that the

usage of Stone-Geary preferences restricts the quantitative adequacy of the

Kongsamut et al.-models. (In fact, the quantitative restrictiveness of Stone-Geary-

preferences has already been mentioned by Samuelson (1948). I use Stone-Geary-

based preferences in my Kuznets-Kaldor-essay as well.) As can be seen from the

models of Chapter III, Stone-Geary preferences are very useful for generating PBGPs,

since the demand-dynamics, which are created by Stone-Geary-preferences, can be

143

Page 154: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

controlled by the preference parameters in a very detailed and direct fashion. (In

detail, the knife-edge conditions, that ensure the existence of PBGPs in the models

from Chapter III, are functions of the Stone-Geary-parameters. Other non-homothetic

utility functions, e.g. the one used by Echevarria (1997, 2000), do not allow for such

knife-edge conditions; hence, they do not allow for PBGPs; see also Meckl (2002),

footnote 2.)

The models of the PBGP-school have already been discussed in Chapter III regarding

the knife-edge-conditions that they use. In the following, I provide an overview that

discusses this literature regarding the structural change determinants that are used:

Kongsamut et al. (2001) study structural change by employing demand side structural

change determinants (Stone-Greary-preferences).

Meckl (2002) integrates this utility structure into an endogenous model with

intermediate production, similar to the models of Grossman and Helpman (1991),

which allows showing that neoclassical endogenous growth theory can be consistent

with structural change to some extent. However, Meckl (2002) does not include

capital-accumulation into analysis. Therefore, he omits a lot of (consumption

industries) structural change dynamics that have been shown to be important by

Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2009).

Ngai and Pissarides (2007) study supply-side structural change determinants.

Especially, they analyse the effects of cross-sector differences in TFP-growth.

Furthermore, they also analyse to what extent their model is feasible with

intermediate restructuring. (In fact, they show that the PBGP is not really consistent

with rich intermediate restructuring dynamics in their model.) Furthermore, since they

assume identical output-elasticites of inputs across sectors, their model omits the

structural change dynamics that have been shown to be important by Acemoglu and

144

Page 155: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Guerrieri (2008). Ngai and Pissarides (2008) extend this model for demand-side

structural change (in detail, they include outsourcing of home production).

Last not least, Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008) study the PBGP of a demand-side

structural-change-model with very high degree of disaggregation. Their model

provides a lot of interesting micro-foundation for the other less-disaggregated PBGP-

models of structural change.

Note that all of these models do not consider the structural change patterns, which

have been studied by Acemogly and Guerrieri (2008). The latter show that structural

change arises if output-elasticity of inputs differs across sectors, provided that capital

is accumulated. In fact, their model implies that this sort of structural change is in

general not consistent with PBGPs. In the essay on the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle I show

that these structural change patterns are consistent with PBGPs provided that

preferences and technologies are independent.

It should be mentioned that there are two further models that actually do not fit into

the PBGP-school, but which approach of analysis is similar to the PBGP-school in

some sense: the second and third model by Kongsamut et al. (1997). In these models

the authors do not search for a growth path where some aggregates behaviour is

balanced (PBGP) but simply search for a growth path where the real interest rate is

constant. They derive the necessary knife-edge conditions for the existence of this

growth path. However, the difference of a growth path with a constant real interest

rate in comparison to the (other) PBGPs is that it is still very difficult to disentangle

the structural change dynamics along such a growth path. That is, a constant-real-

interest-rate-growth-path is a more general approach to structural change analysis in

comparison to the (other usual) PBGPs and therefore it is more difficult to study

analytically. As can be seen from the discussion by Kongsamut et al. (1997), in their

145

Page 156: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

second and third model neither the stability of the equilibrium growth path can be

shown, nor clear intuitive description of structural change can be derived.

4. Classification of own research My research belongs clearly to the PBGP-school (Section 3.2). In fact, as explained in

Chapter I, my research is devoted to the elaboration of the foundations and the

exploration of the applicability of the PBGP-school to questions associated with

structural change. Many of my assumptions are very similar to the models of the

PBGP-school, especially they are very neoclassical. In general the aggregate structure

of my model is very similar to the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model (see also Chapter

III on several aspects of this model). In the following, I compare my models (from

Chapter V) to the models of the previous section:

The model on the Kuznets-Kaldor puzzle is close to the third model by Kongsamut et

al. (1997). In contrast to all other PBGP-frameworks (Kongsamut et al., Ngai and

Pissarides, Meckl and Foellmi and Zweimüller), it features all key structural change

determinants: non-homothetic preferences, cross-sector differences in TFP-growth,

cross-sector differences in output-elasticites of inputs (combined with capital

accumulation) and outsourcing. (Outsourcing is not modelled in the models by

Kongsamut et al. (1997).) I use the very simple/restrictive intermediate structure

suggested by Ngai and Pisssarides (2007) for PBGP-frameworks. The key differences

in comparison to the third model by Kongsamut et al. (1997) are:

(1) I introduce another economy structure: there are multiple subsectors and each

subsector decides for one production technology. For simplicity, there are only two

production technologies available in the model. When the subsectors are aggregated,

each sector can result in using more than only one technology.

146

Page 157: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(2) I use a slightly another preference structure, which allows to determine whether

preferences are independent from technology or not.

(3) I use another dynamic equilibrium concept: as discussed in the previous section,

Kongsamut et al. (1997) analyse a constant-real-interest-rate growth path in their third

model, which makes their analysis quite difficult; I use a PBGP along which

aggregates (capital, output and consumption) grow at a constant rate.

I use this framework, since it allows me to describe the concept of independency and

its implications for structural change. Furthermore, this framework is general enough

for the question that I analyse, i.e. it features all the key structural change

determinants.

In fact, one interesting aspect of the Kuznets-Kaldor model is that it shows for the

first time in the literature that the structural change patterns studied by Acemoglu and

Guerrieri (2008) can be consistent with PBGPs. Furthermore, to some extent it

provides an intuitive explanation for the many knife-edge conditions that are used in

the PBGP-school: It shows that independency of preferences and technologies can be

a “micro-foundation” of these knife-edge-conditions. It should be noted that

previously it has been mentioned by Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008) that some sort of

independency may be useful for generating PBGPs. However, they have not

studied/proven this argument in detail.

In fact, the model on Offshoring is an extension of the work by Ngai and Pissarides

(2007). I choose this simple framework, since it was good enough to show the results,

that I was seeking for. More complex assumptions (e.g. the inclusion of all structural

change determinants) are not necessary for the arguments of this essay. The only

necessary assumptions to prove the key-results of the offshoring model are: capital

accumulation, cross-sector differences in TFP-growth and usage of intermediates; and

147

Page 158: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

these are exactly the assumptions that the model by Ngai and Pissarides (2007)

features. Of course, to study offshoring I introduce intermediate trade into this model.

(Furthermore, I simplify the model’s intermediate structure further, to adapt it for my

needs.) Moreover, I introduce and justify a real GDP-measure in this model. The

GDP-measure is based on the GDP-measures used in reality. The impacts of structural

change on GDP are, in general, not adequately described by the original model by

Ngai and Pissarides (2007); for discussion see the essay on Offshoring.

The essay on Ageing contains two models: a complex and a simplified version. The

complex version is similar to my model on the Kuznerts-Kaldor-puzzle except for

three facts:

(1) The preference structure in the Ageing models features additional demand shifts

which depend upon the growth rate of the old population.

(2) Each sector uses only one technology. The assumption that a sector uses several

technologies is not necessary to show the key-model-results, but would complicate the

analysis enormously.

(3) Similar to the Offshoring-model, I introduce a measure of real GDP into the

Ageing-model.

The simpler version of the Ageing model assumes that output-elasticities are equal

across sectors. Hence, this model rules out the structural change patterns analysed by

Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008). This simplifying assumption makes the model much

easier to understand and, at the same time, it still allows for some interesting results

regarding the impacts of Ageing via structural change.

148

Page 159: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

5. Further aspects of classification The above systematization of structural change literature (Figure 1 and Sections 1, 2

and 3) represents only one way to systematize the literature. Depending upon the

definition of structural change and the actual focus of research, alternative

systematizations may be useful. During my research on my topic I have found several

papers/topics that seem to me somehow related to my topic and/or that seem to be

analysable with similar methods/models as my topic. In the following I discuss these

aspects as possible alternative systematizations of the “structural change literature”.

This discussion should help to further classify my research and to explain which

facts/channels are studied explicitly in my models and which not.

5.1 Structural change induced by trade opening (structural change theory vs. trade theory) Traditionally, the theory (of factor reallocation) has always been divided into trade

theory and structural change theory. Simply speaking, the former analyses the impacts

of trade-opening onto domestic factor allocation; the latter analyses the relationship

between the traditional/domestic structural change determinants and domestic factor

(re)allocation. It is obvious that one must specialise in one or another, since trade-

theory itself constitutes a large body of literature and studying this whole literature

constitutes an own topic. The focus of my research is on structural change theory and

not trade theory. An overview of trade-theoretical results related to sectoral

reallocation is provided by, e.g., Barry and Walsh (2008).

It may seem contradictory that I state here that I do not focus on trade theory, while I

present in Chapter V a model on Offshoring. However, actually it is not contradictory.

A closer look at the essay on Offshoring reveals that the effects of offshoring in my

model can be divided into two types: Transitional effects and PBGP-effects. After

149

Page 160: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

opening of borders, some reallocations are induced during a transition period and the

economy is converging to a PBGP. The reallocations during the transition period are

in fact those that are studied in the trade literature: some domestic production is

substituted by foreign production, some domestic production is increased by exports

and, in general, these reallocations cause an increase in productivity of the domestic

economy. This is nothing new and is well known from trade theory. I explain these

effects for the sake of completeness in my essay, and I have no ambitions regarding

the study of these effects, since they are extensively studied in the trade theory.

Instead, the key-results of my essay are related to the PBGP. By analysing the

resulting PBGP we can find the following impact channel of offshoring: The

productivity increase by offshoring (which has just been explained) accelerates capital

accumulation, and thus makes the consumption industries less relevant in comparison

to the capital industries (in terms of employment). Hence, the traditional/domestic

structural change in consumption industries becomes less relevant for real GDP-

growth. We can see that this key result is clearly related to traditional structural

change theory and is rather not studied in trade theory. Therefore, the Offshoring-

essay is a contribution to structural change theory. In fact it analyses how the

traditional relationship between structural change and productivity growth is affected

by one big macro-trend (i.e. globalisation). However, as I believe, it won’t hurt trade

theorists, if they take a look at my Offshoring-essay. As discussed in the Offshoring-

essay, it could point to impact-channels of trade that are omitted in standard

Offshoring theory by now (due to omit of capital accumulation).

In general, it can be questioned whether trade has an impact on sector structure at low

degree of disaggregation. Only if a country specialises in a specific sector, sector

structure of the economy is affected by trade; otherwise, only the speed of structural

change and/or the sectoral productivity growth parameters are affected. (Regarding

150

Page 161: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

the latter see, e.g., the study by Fagerberg (2000)). Some evidence implies indeed that

trade seems to be a relatively unimportant determinant of sector structure at low

degree of disaggregation in the past in the industrialized countries (see e.g. Rowthorn

and Ramaswamy (1999)).

Nevertheless, there are authors who believe that, in general, structural change should

be analysed in open economy settings and who provide corresponding models (e.g.

Matsuyama (2009), Hsieh und Klenow (2007)). In fact, although I focus on the

traditional approach to structural change analysis, my Offshoring-essay is a

contribution to such an open economy theory of structural change, since it draws a

relationship between standard structural change theory (impact of domestic structural

change determinants) and globalization.

5.2 Factor reallocation between capital industries and consumption industries (Uzawa’s structural change) In general, the whole production of the economy can be divided into capital-goods

production and consumption goods production. These two sectors may feature

different production functions and factors may be reallocated between them. Models,

which study the reallocation of factors between the capital-sector and the

consumption-sector, where the two sectors differ by production technology, include,

e.g., Uzawa (1964) and Boldrin (1988) and (in open economy setting) Hsieh und

Klenow (2007).

In my models there are always some sectors that use a different production

technology in comparison to the capital producing sector. Uzawa’s structural change

occurs only during the transition period of my models; along the PBGP there is no

reallocation between consumption and capital industries (since the savings rate is

constant along the PBGP); see also Sections 3 and 5 in Chapter III. Therefore and

151

Page 162: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

since I focus primarily on PBGP-analysis in my essays, Uzawa’s structural change is

rather not in focus of my research issues. However, in the Offshoring-essay from

Chapter V, Uzawa’s structural change is the connecting link between transitional

effects (studied in the trade theory) and PBGP-effects (studied in the structural change

theory) of Offshoring. As explained in Section 5.1, the transitional effects cause a

productivity increase, which accelerates capital accumulation. Hence, Uzawa’s

structural change is induced (i.e. factors are reallocated from consumption-goods

production to capital-goods-production). In fact, this effect causes the slow-down of

structural change (across the consumption-goods industries) along the PBGP. (For

details, see also the Offshoring-essay in Chapter V.)

5.3 Factor-reallocation between the private sector and the public sector In general, the economy-wide labour is employed in the private and public sector. It is

an interesting question, what the (long-run) reallocation patterns of labour between

these two sectors are, especially if productivity growth differs between the two

sectors. In fact, this is a “classic” topic in economics that has been studied even since

1883 more or less directly under the title “Wagner’s law”. (“Wagner’s law” refers to

an increase in the share of the public sector in national income; see, e.g., Oxley

(1994), p.286.) Discussion/application of Wagner’s law and in general factor

reallocation between the public and private sector can be found in the essays by Vogt

(1973), Oxley (1994), Kongsamut et al. (2001) and Simpson (2009).

In my research I have not explicitly modelled the public sector. However, it may be

interesting for further research to analyse to what extent my models could be

interpreted as including a public sector and whether interesting/new results are

generated by them regarding the public-private-sector reallocation.

152

Page 163: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

5.4 Factor-reallocation between the research sector and the consumption sector Especially in some neoclassical endogenous growth theories, it is assumed that there

is a research sector which produces in some sense the technological progress. Hence,

the society has to decide on the division of factor-use between the research sector and

the consumption sector.

For example, in the model by Romer (1990), p.S83, the economy has to decide on the

allocation of human capital between the research sector and the consumption sector;

in the model by Meckl (2002), p.250, the economy has to decide on the allocation of

(exogenous) factors between the consumption and research sector. In the dynamic

equilibriums of these models there is no factor reallocation between the research

sector and consumption sector (see Romer (1990), p.S90, and Meckl (2002), p.253).

Unfortunately, both essays provide no results regarding the factor reallocation during

the transition period: Romer (1990) does not attempt to do such an analysis (see there

p.S90); Meckl’s (2002)-model features no transition period (see there p.261, footnote

14).

In contrast, the model by Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.303, features a transition

period; however, they do not explicitly discuss the allocation of factors between

research and consumption during the transition period. As far as I can see, the rate of

innovation is changing during the transition period of their model (see the phase

diagram on p.304 of their book); therefore, the costs of research and development are

changing (cf. equation 6.36 on p.303 of their book); therefore, the allocation of

resources between research and development is changing.

However, I have not studied this topic in detail. Especially, it should be noted that in

my research neither endogenous growth nor a research sector are modelled explicitly.

153

Page 164: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

5.5 Outsourcing of home production (factor reallocation between home-sector and market-sector) In fact, some services can be “produced” at home or bought on the market, e.g.

repairing a car, cutting hair, cooking a meal, etc. If home services are outsourced to

the market (e.g. going to a restaurant instead of cooking and eating at home), the

household gets more leisure time and the market demand increases. Eventually, some

of the leisure time is not only used for fun, but additional labour is supplied on the

market. Overall, outsourcing of domestic services is associated with demand changes

(increase in demand for services in comparison to demand for manufactured goods)

and eventually with labor supply changes. Hence, factors are reallocated between

domestic and market production (and across sectors). Essays that study this process

are provided by, e.g., Ngai and Pissarides (2008) and Buera and Kaboski (2009b).

In my research, this outsourcing process is not explicitly modelled, but may be

regarded as being implicitly depicted in the development of exogenous model

parameters.

In the following Chapter V, I present the application of my research, where the

PBGP-method is applied to problem-analysis associated with the Kuznets-Kaldor-

Puzzle, Dynamic Effects of Offshoring and Structural Change Effects of Ageing.

154

Page 165: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

CHAPTER V

Application of the PBGP-Concept in Analysis of Structural Change

In the following, I analyse several questions that are associated with structural change

by using the PBGP-method. Especially, I analyse the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle, the

dynamic effects of Offshoring and the structural change impacts of population

Ageing. The justification of these topics is given in Chapter I.

In fact, this chapter provides four models, which can be used to analyse many

questions associated with structural change. (The essay on ageing contains 2 models;

therefore Chapter V contains four models.). For example, the exogenous demand

shifts in the ageing models need not necessarily being interpreted as resulting form

ageing, but may be interpreted in another way (e.g. as resulting from outsourcing of

home production). That is, the models become even more valuable, if we regard them

merely as mathematical models, which can be filled with intuition as necessary.

Remember that I have discussed in Chapters II and III that it is very difficult to find

assumptions that ensure the existence of a PBGP and that it is even more difficult to

find assumptions that additionally make the proof of sufficiency of Hamiltonian

conditions and global stability of the PBGP feasible (when all structural change

determinants are included into analysis). Hence, I provide in the following nice

mathematical a-priori-solutions, which can be adapted to analyse some new economic

questions associated with structural change. Depending upon the question, the

adequate model may be chosen, where the complex model on ageing features the

richest structural change dynamics and thus the strongest impacts on real GDP-

growth.

155

Page 166: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Before approaching to the models, I provide here just a short explanation of the

meanings of the different postulate-types that I use. As I know, these are not

uniformly used across sciences and scientist; therefore, here follows an explanation of

how I use them:

A Lemma is a rather unimportant postulate, which is aimed to help proving more

important postulates.

A Theorem is a very important postulate. In general, theorems are the key-results of

the paper.

A Proposition is a rather unimportant postulate, which is not used in proving other

postulates.

A Corollary is a summary of the results from other postulates or an interpretation of

another postulate(s).

Hence, if you have no time or fun in reading mathematical proofs, just focus on the

Theorems, Propositions and Corollaries.

156

Page 167: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

TABLE OF CONTENTS for CHAPTER V (Detailed tables of contents are provided in each PART.)

PART I: A PBGP-Framework for the Analysis of the Kuznets-Kaldor-

Puzzle.........................................................................................................................159

PART II: A PBGP-Framework for Analyzing the Impacts of Offshoring on

Structural Change and real GDP-growth in the Dynamic Context............................263

PART III: A PBGP-Framework for Analyzing the Impacts of Ageing on Structural

Change and real GDP-growth....................................................................................321

157

Page 168: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

158

Page 169: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

PART I of CHAPTER V

A PBGP-Framework for the Analysis of the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle

The Kuznets-Kaldor stylized facts are one of the most striking empirical

observations about the development process in the industrialized countries: While

massive factor reallocation across technologically distinct sectors takes place, the

aggregate ratios of the economy behave in a quite stable manner. This implies that

cross-technology factor reallocation has a relatively weak impact on the

aggregates, which is a puzzle from a theoretical point of view.

I apply the PBGP-method to this puzzle, since the PBGP can be defined such that

the Kaldor-Kuznets-facts are satisfied. Hence, the study of this PBGP and the study

of the conditions, which are required for the existence of this PBGP, seem to be

predestined for a discussion of the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle. I provide a model that

can explain the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle by independent preferences and

technologies along a PBGP. Furthermore, I show by empirical evidence that this

model is in line with 55% of structural change.

The model which I present here is a modification of the reference-model from

Chapter III (Section I). That is, it is still a multi-sector Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans

model. However, as I will explain in detail later, I modify the reference model as

follows: I restrict the number of technologies and sectors for simplicity (only two

technologies and three sectors). Furthermore, I add intermediate production

structures (intermediate products) to discuss some issues related to them.

Moreover, to discuss the “independency between preferences and technologies” I

159

Page 170: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

add subsectors to each sector and I introduce a slightly different utility structure in

comparison to the reference model.

160

Page 171: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

TABLE OF CONTENTS for PART I OF CHAPTER V

1. Introduction .........................................................................................................163

2. Stylized facts of sectoral structures .....................................................................167

2.1 Stylized facts regarding cross-sector-heterogeneity in production-

technology .................................................................................................167

2.2 Structural change determinants ...........................................................168

3. Model of neutral cross-capital-intensity structural change..................................169

3.1 Model assumptions ..............................................................................169

3.1.1 Production...............................................................................169

3.1.2 Utility function .......................................................................172

3.1.3 Aggregates and sectors ...........................................................175

3.2 Model equilibrium ...............................................................................178

3.2.1 Optimality conditions .............................................................178

3.2.2 Development of aggregates in equilibrium ............................178

3.2.3 Development of sectors in equilibrium ..................................182

3.2.4 Consistency with stylized facts...............................................184

3.2.5 The relationship between structural change and aggregate-

dynamics..........................................................................................190

4. A measure of neutrality of cross-capital-intensity structural change ..................195

5. On correlation between preferences and technologies ........................................203

6. Concluding remarks.............................................................................................209

APPENDIX A..........................................................................................................214

APPROACH (1): .......................................................................................214

Necessary (first order) conditions for an optimum..........................214

Proof that sufficient (second order) conditions are satisfied ...........215

APPROACH (2) ........................................................................................218

Producers .........................................................................................219

Households ......................................................................................220

Relationship between individual variables and economy-wide

aggregates ........................................................................................224

APPENDIX B..........................................................................................................226

APPENDIX C..........................................................................................................230

APPENDIX D..........................................................................................................243

APPENDIX E..........................................................................................................245

161

Page 172: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX F ..........................................................................................................248

LIST OF SYMBOLS of PART I of CHAPTER V .................................................252

162

Page 173: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

1. Introduction As shown by Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001), the development process of the

industrialized countries during the last century satisfies two types of stylized facts:

“Kuznets facts” and “Kaldor facts”. Generally speaking, Kuznets facts state that

massive structural change takes place during the development process.1 Especially,

in the early stages of economic development factors are primarily reallocated from

the agricultural sector to the industrial sector and in later stages of development

factors are primarily reallocated from the manufacturing sector to the services

sector. (It has also been shown, that structural change takes place at more

disaggregated level.) On the other hand, the Kaldor facts state that some key

aggregate measures of the economy are quite stable during the development

process; especially, the aggregate capital-to-output ratio and the aggregate income

shares of capital and labor are quite stable whereas the aggregate capital-to-labor

ratio increases (at a fairly constant rate) in the industrialized countries.2 That is, the

growth process seems to be “balanced” at the aggregate level. As discussed by

Kongsamut et al. (2001) and Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008), the coexistence of

Kuznets and Kaldor facts seems to be a puzzle, since strong factor-reallocations

across sectors in general imply that Kaldor-facts are not satisfied (“unbalanced”

growth of aggregates). In fact it has been shown in Chapter III that in general the

1 Papers that provide empirical evidence for the massive labor reallocation across sectors during the growth process are e.g. Kuznets (1976), Maddison (1980), Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001) and Ngai and Pissarides (2004). Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001) formulate the following stylized facts of structural change for the last hundred years: 1.) the employment share of agriculture decreases during the growth process; 2.) the employment share of services increases during the growth process; 3.) the employment share of manufacturing is constant. Ngai and Pissarides (2007) note that the development of the manufacturing employment-share can be regarded as “hump-shaped” in the longer run. See also Chapter I for detailed discussion of the stylized facts. 2 In detail, Kaldor’s stylized facts state that the growth rate of output per capita, the real rate of return on capital, the capital-to-output ratio and the income distribution (between labor and capital) are nearly constant in the long run; capital-to-labor ratio increases in the long run. It is widely accepted that these facts are an accurate shorthand description of the long run growth process (at the aggregate level) in industrialized countries. A discussion of these facts can be found in the paper by Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001) and in the books by Maußner and Klump (1996) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004).

163

Page 174: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

behavior of aggregates is unbalanced, as long as structural change takes place.

Therefore, I name the empirically observable coexistence of Kuznets and Kaldor

facts “Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle”.

The literature, which deals with the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle more or less explicitly,

includes Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001), Meckl (2002), Foellmi and Zweimueller

(2008), Ngai and Pissarides (2007), Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) and Boppart

(2010).

We learn from this literature, in general, that the solution of the Kuznets-Kaldor-

Puzzle in neoclassical growth frameworks requires the use of some knife-edge

conditions. In fact, all papers used very severe restrictions to solve the Kuznets-

Kaldor-Puzzle: all of them omitted some structural change determinants (which is

the same as imposing some implicit knife-edge conditions) and/or imposed some

explicit knife-edge parameter restrictions (like Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001) and

Meckl (2002)). Such (implicit and explicit) knife-edge conditions are severe

restrictions, if their validity is not proven by empirical and/or theoretical reasoning,

as discussed in Section 6 of Chapter III. (For a discussion of structural change

determinants see section 2.2.)

I include all key structural change determinants into analysis and then try to

analyze whether the knife-edge conditions, which are required for the solution of

the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle, are empirically reasonable. Furthermore, I point to a

possible theoretical micro-foundation of these knife-edge conditions.

The starting point of my analysis is the following fact: The key challenge to

solving the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle is already known since Baumol (1967): If

production technology differs across sectors, the reallocation of factors across

sectors causes unbalanced growth, i.e. Kaldor-facts are not satisfied.

Then, I approach as follows:

164

Page 175: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

First, I show that Kaldor facts can be satisfied despite the fact that factors are

reallocated across technologically distinct sectors. In this sense my results postulate

that structural change across technology can be irrelevant regarding the

development of aggregate ratios. I name this type of factor reallocation “neutral

(cross-capital-intensity) structural change”. Of course, the existence of neutral

structural change requires some knife-edge conditions (which will be analyzed

below). Previously, Ngai and Pissarides (2007) have shown that neutral structural

change can arise when all sectors have the same capital-intensity. However,

Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) have shown that their results do not hold if capital-

intensities differ across sectors, i.e. they show that in this case growth is in general

unbalanced. In some sense, my result contradicts Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008),

since neutral structural change arises despite the fact that capital-intensities differ

across sectors in my model. I am able to obtain my results, since, in contrast to

Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008), I assume a utility function that has non-unitary

price elasticity of demand (i.e. each good has its own specific price elasticity) and

since I assume that at least one of the three sectors uses two technologies. (As I

will discuss in my essay, the latter assumption is consistent with empirical

evidence, which postulates that e.g. the services sector is quite technologically

heterogeneous.) Furthermore, in contrast to Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008), I

model sectors that feature non-constant output-elasticities of inputs.

Second, I study the empirically observable patterns of structural change and

analyze whether they were neutral or non-neutral. In this sense, I analyze implicitly

whether the knife-edge conditions, which ensure the satisfaction of the Kuznets-

Kaldor-facts in my model, are given in reality. I develop an index of neutrality of

structural change and show with the data for the US between 1948 and 1987 that

about 55% of structural change was neutral structural change. Hence, neutrality of

165

Page 176: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

structural change seems to be a relatively large explanatory variable regarding the

Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle. I argue as well that this result applies to the most of the

previous literature, implying that the previous literature can explain (maximally)

55% of structural change.

Third, I argue that low (no) correlation between preference parameters and

technology parameters can explain the prevalence (existence) of neutral structural

change in reality (my model).3 I also argue that the assumption of uncorrelated

preferences and technologies may be theoretically reasonable in long run growth

models. In this sense, the independency between preferences and technologies can

be a theoretical foundation of the knife-edge conditions that are necessary for the

solution of the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle.

In the next section (section 2) I provide some evidence on sectoral structures that

are observed in reality, in order to provide an empirical basis for my discussion and

model assumptions. Then, in section 3, I provide a PBGP-model of structural

change in order to show the existence of neutral structural change. (There I also

generalize some of the model results in Proposition 4.) Section 4 is dedicated to the

empirical analysis, where among others I develop an index of neutrality of

structural change and analyze the cross-capital-intensity structural change patterns

in detail. In section 5 I discuss the assumption of low correlation between

technology and preferences. Finally, in section 6 I provide some concluding

remarks and hints for further research.

3 It should be noted here that previously it has been mentioned by Foellmi and Zweimueller (2008) that some type of independency between technology and preferences may be useful for generating aggregate balanced growth. However, this topic has not been studied further by them.

166

Page 177: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

2. Stylized facts of sectoral structures 2.1 Stylized facts regarding cross-sector-heterogeneity in production-technology Empirical evidence implies the following stylized facts of sectoral production

functions:

1. TFP-growth differs across sectors. Empirical evidence implies that TFP-growth

rates differ strongly across sectors. For example, Bernard and Jones (1996) (pp.

1221f.), who analyze sectoral TFP-growth in 14 OECD countries between 1970

and 1987, report that e.g. the average TFP-growth rate in agriculture (3%) was

more than three times as high as in services (0.8%). Similar results are obtained by

Baumol et al. (1985), who report the TFP-growth-rates of US-sectors between

1947 and 1976.

2. Capital intensity differs across sectors. Empirical evidence implies that factor

income shares differ strongly across sectors (hence, capital intensities differ

strongly across sectors as well4). For example, Kongsamut, Rebelo and Xie (1997)

provide evidence for the USA for the period 1959-1994. Their data implies that, for

example, the labor income share was relatively high in manufacturing and

construction (around 70%) in this period. At the same time, e.g. the labor income

share in agriculture, finance, insurance and real estate was relatively low (around

20%). Similar results for the USA are obtained by Close and Shulenburger (1971)

for the period 1948-1965 and by Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) for the period

1987-2004. Some new evidence for the USA (presented by Valentinyi and

Herrendorf (2008)) supports these results as well. Gollin (2002) (p. 464) analyzes

4 If labor income shares (or: output elasticities of labor) differ across sectors, it follows that capital intensities differ across sectors as well, since in optimum capital intensity is determined by factor prices and by output elasticities of capital and labor. We will see later that this is true within my model.

167

Page 178: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

the data from 41 countries reported in the U.N. National Statistics. He confirms

that factor income shares vary widely across sectors.

A model that analyzes structural change across sectors should be consistent with

these “stylized” facts of sectoral production functions. This is especially important,

since these stylized facts have an impact on structural change (and hence on

aggregate balanced growth), as we will see now.

2.2 Structural change determinants As discussed in Chapter I, there a four main determinants of structural change. I

recapitulate them here, since they are important for the following discussion:

1. Non-homothetic preferences across sectors – relevance for structural change

analyzed empirically and theoretically, e.g., by Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001).

2. Differences in TFP-growth across sectors – empirical relevance for structural

change shown, e.g., by Baumol (1985); theoretical relevance for structural change

shown, e.g., by Ngai and Pissarides (2007).

3. Differences in capital intensities across sectors – relevance for structural change

analyzed empirically and theoretically, e.g., by Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008).

4. Shifts in intermediates production across sectors – relevance for structural

change analyzed empirically and theoretically, e.g., by Fixler and Siegel (1998).

So I can conclude that all these determinants influence the structural change

patterns. Since the aggregate economy is the weighted average of its sectors, the

aggregate behavior depends on the structural change patterns. That is, all four

168

Page 179: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

structural change determinants influence the behavior of the aggregate economy.

Hence, only if I include all four structural change determinants into a model, I can

adequately analyze whether balanced growth with respect to aggregates can coexist

with structural change.

3. Model of neutral cross-capital-intensity structural change 3.1 Model assumptions

3.1.1 Production I assume an economy where two technologies exist (the model could be modified

such that it includes more technologies; the key results would be the same). The

technologies differ by capital intensity (i.e. output elasticities of inputs differ across

technologies) and by total factor productivity (TFP) growth. TFP-growth rates are

constant and exogenously given. Goods ni ,...1= are produced in the economy.

Goods are produced by using technology 1 and goods are

produced by using technology 2 ( . I assume that three inputs are used for

production: capital (K), labor (L) and intermediates (Z). All capital, labor and

intermediates are used in the production of goods

mi ,...1= nmi ,...1+=

)mn >

ni ,...1= . The amount of

available labor grows at constant rate ( ). Since I want to model TFP-growth, I

assume Hicks-neutral technological progress. It is well known that the existence of

a balanced growth path in standard balanced growth frameworks requires the

assumption of Cobb-Douglas production function(s) when technological progress

is Hicks-neutral. (Later, we will see that the aggregate production function

“inherits” the attributes of sectoral production functions along the PBGP, i.e. the

Lg

169

Page 180: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

aggregate production function is of type Cobb-Douglas.) These assumptions imply

the following production functions:

(1) miZzKkLlAY iiii ,...1,)()()( == γβα

where .;0,,;1 constgAA

A ==>=++&

γβαγβα

(2) nmiZzKkLlBY iv

iii ,...1,)()()( +== μχ

where .;0,,;1 constgBB

B ==>=++&

μνχμνχ

(3) ∑∑∑===

===n

ii

n

ii

n

ii zkl

1111;1;1

(4) .constgLL

L =≡&

where denotes the output of good i; and denote respectively the fraction

of labor, capital and intermediates devoted to production of good i;

iY ii kl , iz

K is the

aggregate capital; aggregate labor; L Z aggregate intermediate index. Note that I

omit here the time index. Furthermore, note that the index i denotes not sectors but

a good or a group of similar goods. I will define sectors later.

Of course, it is not “realistic” that there are only two technologies and that some

goods are produced by identical production functions. However, every model

simplifies to some extent and it is only important that the simplification does not

affect the meaningfulness of the results. My assumption is only a “technical

assumption”, which is necessary to make my argumentation as simple as possible.

My key arguments (namely the existence of neutral structural change) could also

170

Page 181: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

be derived in a framework where each good is produced by a unique production

function. (I show this fact in Proposition 4.) However, it would be much more

difficult to formulate the independency assumptions (which are formulated in the

next subsection). Instead of the simple restrictions, which I use in the next

subsection, I would have to derive complex restrictions which would not be such

transparent. Anyway, later my focus will be on the analysis of only three sectors

(which are aggregates of the products i=1,…n); thus, two technologies are

sufficient to generate technological heterogeneity between these three sectors. In

this sense, I have introduced technological diversity into my framework in the

simplest manner (by assuming that there are only two technologies).

It may be easier to accommodate with my assumption of only two technologies by

imagining that an economist divides the whole set of products of an economy into

two groups (a technologically progressive and a technologically backward) and

estimates the average production function for the two groups. Such approaches are

prominent in the literature: e.g. Baumol et al. (1985) and Acemoglu and Guerrieri

(2008) approach in similar way in the empirical parts of their argumentation.

Furthermore, note that much of the new literature on the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle

assume very similar sectoral production functions (e.g. Kongsamut et al. (2001)

and Ngai and Pissarides (2007)) or assume even identical sectoral production

functions (e.g. Foellmi and Zweimueller (2008)). Hence, my assumption of only

two (completely distinct) technologies is an improvement in comparison to some

previous literature. Note that the empirical study of my paper (section 4) uses the

more general assumption, i.e. each good is produced by a unique production

function.

I assume that all goods can be consumed and used as intermediates. Furthermore, I

assume that only the good m can be used as capital. (Note, that the model could be

171

Page 182: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

modified such that more than one good is used as capital e.g. in the manner of Ngai

and Pissarides (2007).) This assumption implies:

(5) mihCY iii ≠∀+= ,

(6) KKhCY mmm δ+++= &

where denotes consumption of good i; iC δ denotes the constant depreciation rate

of capital; is the amount of good i that is used as intermediate input. ih

I assume that the intermediate-inputs-index Z is a Cobb-Douglas function of ’s

which is necessary for the existence of a PBGP (see Ngai and Pissarides 2007):

ih

(7) ∏=

=n

ii

ihZ1

ε

where ∑=

=∀>n

iii i

11;,0 εε

3.1.2 Utility function I assume the following utility function, which is quite similar to the utility function

used by Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001):

(8) , ∫∞

−=0

1 ),...( dteCCuU tn

ρ 0>ρ

where

(9) ⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−= ∏

=

n

iiin

iCCCu1

1 )(ln),...( ωθ

172

Page 183: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(10) ∑=

=m

ii

1

(11) ∑+=

=n

mii

1

where U denotes the life-time utility of the representative household and iω , iθ

and ρ are constant parameters. In contrast to the model by Ngai and Pissarides

(2007), the assumption of logarithmic utility function (equation (9)) is not

necessary for my results, i.e. I could have assumed a constant intertemporal

elasticity of substitution function of the consumption composite in equation (9).

We can see that this utility function is based on the Stone-Geary preferences.

Without loss of generality I assume that iθ s are not equal to zero and that they

differ across goods i. The key reason why I use this utility function is that it

features non-unitary income-elasticity of demand and non-unitary price-elasticity

of demand. That is, each good has its own income elasticity of demand and its own

price elasticity of demand (as long as iθ differs across goods). For example, the

good i=4 has another price elasticity of demand than good i=7 (provided that

74 θθ ≠ ). Due to this feature, I can determine the own price elasticity and the own

income elasticity for groups of goods. For example, by setting the iθ in a specific

pattern I can determine that the (average) price elasticity of demand for the goods

i=7,…14 is larger than for goods i= 56,…79.

This is the key to my argumentation about preference and technology correlation

later: By setting parameter restrictions (10) and (11) I determine that

173

Page 184: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

1.) on average, the income elasticity of demand for technology-1-goods is not

larger or smaller in comparison to the income elasticity of demand for technology-

2-goods.

2.) on average, the “relative price elasticity of demand” (i.e. elasticity of

substitution) between technology-1-goods and technology-2-goods is equal to one.

Hence, preferences and technologies are not correlated on average. This means for

example, that demand for some of the goods that are produced by technology 1 can

be price-inelastic and for some of the technology-1-goods price-elastic, while at the

same time the demand for some goods that are produced by technology 2 can be

price-elastic and for some of the technology-2-goods price inelastic. However, on

average, the elasticity of stubstitution between technology-1-goods and

technology-2-goods is equal to unity.

This restriction (equations (10) and (11)) reduces the generality of my model.

Nevertheless, for my further argumentation it does not matter. It is simply a

technical assumption in order to show in the simplest manner the existence of

neutral-cross-capital-intensity structural change. That is, due to this assumption I

can pursue my analysis along a PBGP, which is technically simple. Without this

assumption, I would have to numerically solve the model and the distinction

between neutral and non-neutral cross-capital-intensity structural change would be

quite difficult. Nevertheless, I will discuss theoretical reasonability of this

restriction later and I will show empirically that the largest part of structural change

is in line with this restriction.

Overall, my utility function allows for structural change caused by all structural

change determinants: In general the goods have a price elasticity of demand that is

different from one (as discussed above). Hence, changing relative prices can cause

structural change in this model (see also Ngai and Pissarides 2007 on price

174

Page 185: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

elasticity and structural change). Intertemporal elasticity of substitution differs

across goods i and is not equal to unity, despite of the fact that equation (9) is

logarithmic. Equations (8)-(11) imply that the utility function is non-homothetic

across goods i, i.e. income elasticity of demand differs across goods i (depending

on the parameterization of the iθ ’s).

3.1.3 Aggregates and sectors I define aggregate output (Y), aggregate consumption expenditures (E) and

aggregate intermediate inputs (H) as follows:

(12) ; ; ∑=

≡n

iiiYpY

1∑=

≡n

iiiCpE

1∑=

≡n

iiihpH

1

where denotes the price of good i. I chose the good m as numéraire, hence: ip

(13) 1=mp

Note that in reality the manufacturing sector is not the numérarire in the real GDP

calculations. Hence, my definition of aggregate output Y is not the same as real

GDP. However, the choice of numérarie is irrelevant when discussing ratios or

shares (see e.g. Ngai and Pissarides (2004, 2007)), since the numérarire of the

numerator and the denominator of a ratio offset each other. Therefore, I focus my

discussion on the shares and ratios in my paper (e.g. aggregate capital-intensity,

capital-to-output ratio, income-share of capital and labor), where the numérarire

choice is irrelevant. My results regarding the other Kaldor-facts, which are dealing

175

Page 186: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

with the development of the real-GDP-growth rate and the real interest rate, should

be considered with caution. However, as discussed by Barro and Sala-i-Martin

(2004), the constancy of the real interest rate (as a Kaldor fact) may anyway be

questionable. Furthermore, as shown by Ngai and Pissarides (2004, 2007) the real

GDP as measured in reality and the real GDP in manufacturing terms seem to

behave quite similar. Therefore, possibly my results regarding the real GDP

development may be to some extent related to the real GDP as measured in reality.

Last but not least I have to define the sectors of our economy. Without loss of

generality I assume here that there are three sectors which I name for reasons of

convenience (according to the tree sector hypothesis): agriculture, manufacturing

and services. Furthermore, I assume that without loss of generality

• agricultural sector maai <<= 1;,...1

• manufacturing sector includes goods nsmsai <<+= ;,...1

• services sector includes goods nsi ,...1+= .

Hence, the agricultural sector uses only technology 1, the manufacturing sector

uses technology 1 and 2 and the services sector uses only technology 2. Note, that

this whole division is not necessary for my argumentation, neither the naming of

the sectors. I could also assume that the capital-producing manufacturing sector

uses only one technology (and the services sector both technologies). I could even

assume that there are more sectors (and more technologies). In all these cases my

key results would be the same. Furthermore, note that the assumption that a sector

uses both technologies is plausible. For example, the service sector includes

services that feature high TFP-growth and/or high capital intensity, e.g. ICT-based

services, as well as services that feature low TFP-growth and/or low capital

intensity, e.g. some personal services like counseling and consulting (for discussion

and empirical evidence see e.g. Baumol et al. 1985 and Blinder 2007). Similar

176

Page 187: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

examples can be found in the manufacturing sector (e.g. a traditional clock maker

vs. a car producer). Furthermore, my sector-division implies that only sector M (the

manufacturing sector) produces capital. This is consistent with the empirical

evidence, which implies that most capital goods are produced by the manufacturing

sector (see e.g. Kongsamut et al. 1997).

According to my classification, I can define the outputs of the agricultural, services

and manufacturing sector ( , and ) and the consumption expenditures

on agriculture, manufacturing and services ( , and ) as follows:

.agrY .manY .serY

.agrE .manE .serE

(14) ∑∑∑+=+==

≡≡≡n

siiiser

s

aiiiman

a

iiiagr YpYYpYYpY

1.

1.

1. ;;

(15) ∑∑∑+=+==

≡≡≡n

siiiser

s

aiiiman

a

iiiagr CpECpECpE

1.

1.

1. ;;

Furthermore, note that employment shares ( , and ), capital shares

( , and ) and intermediate shares ( , and ) of sectors

agriculture, manufacturing and services are given by:

.agrl .manl .serl

.agrk .mank .serk .agrz .manz .serz

(16)

∑∑∑

∑∑∑

∑∑∑

+=+==

+=+==

+=+==

≡≡≡

≡≡≡

≡≡≡

n

siiser

s

aiiman

a

iiagr

n

siiser

s

aiiman

a

iiagr

n

siiser

s

aiiman

a

iiagr

zzzzzz

kkkkkk

llllll

1.

1.

1.

1.

1.

1.

1.

1.

1.

;;

;;;

;;;

177

Page 188: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

3.2 Model equilibrium

3.2.1 Optimality conditions I have now specified the model completely. The intertemporal and intratemporal

optimality conditions can be obtained by maximizing the utility function (equations

(8)-(11)) subject to the equations (1)-(7) and (12)-(16) by using e.g. the

Hamiltonian. When there is free mobility of factors across goods and sectors these

(first order) optimality conditions are given by:

(17) ihZ

ZzY

ZzYZzY

KkYKkY

LlYLlYp

im

m

ii

mm

ii

mm

ii

mmi ∀

∂∂

∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

= ,)()(/

)(/)(/)(/

)(/)(/

(18) iCuCup

m

ii ∀

∂∂∂∂

= ,/(.)/(.)

(19) ρδ −−=− ruu

m

m&

where and mm Cuu ∂∂≡ /(.) )(/ KkYr mm ∂∂≡ is the real interest rate (see

APPENDIX A for proofs). I show in APPENDIX A that these are the sufficient

conditions for an optimum (together with the transversality condition).

3.2.2 Development of aggregates in equilibrium To be able to derive some theoretical arguments from the model, we have to insert

equations (1) to (16) into optimality conditions (17) to (19) in order to transform

the optimality conditions into some explicit functions of model-variables and

model-parameters. To get an impression of how this is done, see the corresponding

derivations in my Ageing-model (especially APPENDIX A of PART III of

178

Page 189: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

CHAPTER V). In fact the derivations there are very similar to the derivations

which are necessary to obtain the following equations. Therefore, I present the

following equations, which describe the optimal aggregate structure of the

economy, without explicit proof:

(20) HEKKY +++= δ&

(21) qqq

m

m KGLlkY −

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= 1~

(22) ρδβ −−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= −−

111

qqq

m

m KGLkl

EE&

(23) ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+=

m

m

klccYH 21

(24) YHc

YEc

kl

m

m ~~1 43 −−=

where

(25)

m

m

klcc

YY65

~

+≡

(27) 0)1(1

)1(>

−−−+−

≡μεεγγνεμεβq

(28) εμεγ

γ

ε

εμνεε ε

χγαμ

χβαν

αχγ

−−−

=

⎪⎭

⎪⎬⎫

⎪⎩

⎪⎨⎧

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡ ∏

)1(1

1

1n

ii

iBAAG

(29) ∑+=

≡n

mii

1

εε

179

Page 190: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

and

21 1 cc −≡ ,

χβανχγαμ

−≡

1

12c ,

=

+⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−≡ n

ii

n

mi

c

1

13 1

ω

ω

αχ

χβαν , ∑

+=⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−≡

n

miic

14 1 ε

αχ

χβαν ,

and 65 1 cc −≡

χβανχα

−≡

1

16c .

Note that G grows at positive constant rate, q is positive and 1<ε .5

Equations (20)-(28) look actually more complicated than they are. As we will see

soon they are quite the same as in the standard one-sector Ramsey-Cass-

Koopmans-model6 or Solow-model. The key difference is that my equations

feature the term , which reflects the impact of cross-capital intensity

structural change on the development of aggregates. However, before discussing

these facts I start with my definition of an equilibrium growth path which is quite

similar as the definition used by Ngai and Pissarides (2007).

mm kl /

Definition 1: A partially balanced growth path (PBGP) is an equilibrium growth

path where aggregates (Y, Y~ , K, E and H) grow at a constant rate.

Note that this definition does require balanced growth for aggregate variables.

However, it does not require balanced growth for sectoral variables (e.g. for

sectoral outputs). Hence, it allows for structural change.

5 The term within the {}-brackets in equation (28) grows at constant positive rate since ε is positive and smaller than one (see equation (29)). Furthermore, the exponent of the {}-brackets is positive as well, since 1)1( <+− εμεγ (a weighted average of numbers that are smaller than one (γ and μ ) is always smaller than one). As well, q>0, since 1)1( <+− εμεγ . 6 For a discussion of the Ramsey-model see e.g. Barro, Sala-i-Martin (2004) pp. 85ff.

180

Page 191: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Lemma 1: Equations (20) to (28) imply that there exists a unique PBGP, where

aggregates (Y, Y~ , K, E and H) grow at constant rate and where is

constant. The PBGP-growth rate is given by

*g mm kl /

LBA gggg +

+−+−

=χεγαεμεγεμ

)1()1(* .

Proof: See APPENDIX B.

Proposition 1a: A saddle-path, along which the economy converges to the PBGP,

exists in the neighborhood of the PBGP.

Proposition 1b: If intermediates are omitted (i.e. if 0== μγ ), the PBGP is locally

stable.

Proof: See APPENDIX C.

Proposition 1 ensures that the economy will approach to the PBGP even if the

initial capital level is not such that the economy starts on the PBGP.

Proposition 2: Along the PBGP the aggregate dynamics of the economy are

represented by the following equations: ; and EKKY ++= δ&ˆ qq KLGY −= 1~ˆ

ρδλ −−=KY

EE ˆ&

, where G is a parameter growing at constant rate (“Hicks-

neutral technological progress”),

~

Y denotes aggregate output without

intermediates production (i.e. Y-H) and λ is a constant (see APPENDIX B for

details of these parameters).

Proof: See APPENDIX B.

181

Page 192: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

In fact Proposition 2 implies that the aggregate structure of our economy is quite

the same as the structure of the standard Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans- or Solow-model

(with Cobb-Douglas production function and logarithmic utility).

Now, the question arises, whether structural change takes place along the PBGP. I

discuss this question in the following.

3.2.3 Development of sectors in equilibrium By inserting equations (1) to (16) into optimality conditions (17) to (19), the

following equations that describe the optimal sector structure of the economy

(represented by the employment shares) can be obtained:

(30a) ∑=

+Λ=a

iiagragr Y

l1

.. ~1 θ

(30b) ∑∑+=+=

Γ++Λ=s

mii

m

aiimanman Y

l11

.. ~1 θθ

(30c) ∑+=

Γ+Λ=n

siiserserl

1.. θ

where

(31a) ∑∑

∑=

=

= +≡Λa

iin

ii

a

ii

agr YH

YE

1

1

1. ~~ ε

ω

ω

(31b) Y

KKYH

YE s

mii

m

aiin

ii

s

mii

m

aii

man ~~~11

1

11.

δεαχε

ω

ωαχω

++⎟

⎞⎜⎝

⎛++

+≡Λ ∑∑

∑∑+=+=

=

+=+=&

182

Page 193: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(31c) ∑∑

∑+=

=

+= +≡Λn

siin

ii

n

sii

ser YH

YE

1

1

1. ~~ ε

αχ

ω

ω

αχ

(31d) εμεεεμβ

γμμ

χγαμ

χβαν −−(−

+−+

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡Γ

)11)1(

/

1vv

m

mv

LlKkL

AGB

Again, to get an impression of how these equations can be derived, see the

derivations in my Ageing-model (especially APPENDIX A of PART III of

CHAPTER V).

Note that ... ,, sermanagr ΛΛΛ and Γ can be easily derived as functions of exogenous

parameters along the PBGP.7 However, I omit here the explicit proof, since it is

trivial and irrelevant for further discussion (for a sketch of the proof see footnote

7).

Lemma 2: Structural change takes place along the PBGP. That is, the employment

shares of sectors agriculture ( ), manufacturing ( ) and services ( ) are

changing along the PBGP.

.agrl .manl .serl

7 In APPENDIX B (equation (B.17)) I have derived as function of exogenous model

parameters. This function can be used to derive

mm kl /

Y~ and Y as functions of exogenous model parameters by using equations (21) and (25). Then, when I have Y~ and as functions of

exogenous model parameters, I can derive mm kl /

H as a function of exogenous model parameters by using equation (23). Finally, I can use Y and H to derive E as function of exogenous model parameters (via equation (20); note that the initial capital endowment is exogenously given;

hence 0K

K can be calculated by using and the equilibrium growth rate of capital , where

is a function of exogenous model parameters as shown in Lemma 1). When I have ,

0K *g *g

mm kl / Y~ , K

and E as functions of exogenous model parameters, I can derive ... ,, sermanagr ΛΛΛ and as functions of exogenous model parameters.

Γ

183

Page 194: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Proof: This Lemma is implied by equations (30) and (31). Note that ,

and are constant along the PBGP (due to Lemma 1);

.. , managr ΛΛ

.serΛ Y~ grows at rate

along the PBGP (see Lemma 1).

*g

Γ decreases at constant rate along the PBGP. The

latter fact comes from Lemma 1 and equation (28). Note that G/A grows at positive

constant rate; see equation (28) and footnote 5. Furthermore, note that the exponent

εμγεεεμβ

−−(−+−

+ )11)1( v

v is positive, since 1)1( − + εμ <εγ as explained in footnote 5. Q.E.D.

Now, the remaining exercise is to show that along the PBGP my model is indeed

consistent with all the stylized facts mentioned in the introduction and section 2 of

my paper.

3.2.4 Consistency with stylized facts

Lemma 3: The PBGP of my model satisfies the Kaldor facts regarding the

development of the great ratios. That is, the aggregate capital intensity (K/L) is

increasing; the aggregate capital-income-share ( or ), the

aggregate labor-income-share ( or

YrK / )/( HYrK −

YwL / )/( HYwL − ) and the aggregegate

capital-to-output ratio (K/Y or K/(Y-H)) are constant (where r is the real rate of

return on capital and w is the real wage rate).

Proof: The constancy of K/Y and K/(Y-H) as well as the increasing capital-intensity

(K/L) are directly implied by Lemma 1. Since I assume perfect polypolisitic

markets, the marginal productivity of capital (of labor) in a sub-sector i is equal to

the real rate of return on capital (real wage rate) for all i. This implies for example

for : mi =

184

Page 195: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(32) KY

kl

KkYr

m

m

m

m~

)(β=

∂∂

=

(33) LY

LlYwm

m~

)(α=

∂∂

=

Hence, Lemma 1 and equations (32) and (33) imply that YrK ,

HYrK−

, YwL and

HYwL−

are constant. Q.E.D.

Note that there are two further Kaldor-facts: namely Kaldor stated that the

aggregate volume of production grows at a non-decreasing rate and that the real

rate of return on capital is constant. As discussed in section 3.1, due to numéraire

choice I cannot say whether these two Kaldor-facts are satisfied approximately in

my model. However, as mentioned before, the constancy of the real interest rate

seems to be rather not a fact in reality. Furthermore, the results by Ngai and

Pissarides (2004, 2007) imply that the aggregate output expressed in manufacturing

terms (as in my model) behaves quite similar as the aggregate output that is

measured in reality (by using some compound numéraire). Hence, my model could

be consistent with a constant real rate of aggregate output.

Lemma 4: Along the PBGP the development of sectoral employment shares over

time (equations (30)-(31)) can be monotonous (monotonously increasing,

monotonously decreasing or constant) or non-monotonous (“hump-shaped” or

“U-shaped”), depending on the parameterization of the model.

Proof: This Lemma is implied by equations (30)-(31). In the proof of Lemma 2 I

have shown that , and .. , managr ΛΛ .serΛ are constant along the PBGP, Y~ grows at

185

Page 196: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

rate along the PBGP (see Lemma 1) and *g Γ decreases at constant rate along the

PBGP. Hence, since and Y~/1 Γ grow at different rates, equation (30b) implies that

the development of the manufacturing-employment-share over time ( ) can be

non-monotonous, provided that has not the same sign as . That is, it

can be hump-shaped or U-shaped depending on the parameterization. Hence, the

model can reproduce a “hump-shaped” development of the manufacturing-

employment share over time, which has been emphasized by Ngai and Pissarides

(2007) and Maddison (1980). Note that only sectors, which use at least two

technologies, can feature non-monotonous development of their employment share

over time. However, as discussed in section 3.1 the manufacturing sector (i.e. the

capital producing sector) need not using two technologies, i.e. the model could be

set up such that the agricultural sector or the services sector uses two technologies.

Hence, in fact any of the sectors could feature non-monotonous dynamics of its

employment-share over time. The proof that

.manl

∑+=

m

aii

1

θ ∑+=

s

mii

1

θ

• can be monotonously increasing, monotonously decreasing or constant, .agrl

• can be monotonously increasing or monotonously decreasing, and .manl

• can be monotonously increasing, monotonously decreasing or constant .serl

is obvious when taking into account that , and can be

negative, positive or equal to zero respectively. Q.E.D.

∑=

a

ii

1

θ ∑∑+=+=

s

mii

m

aii

11

, θθ ∑+=

n

sii

1

θ

Lemma 5: Agriculture, manufacturing and services have different production

functions in my model. Especially, the optimal capital intensity differs across these

sectors.

186

Page 197: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Proof: Since I assumed that agriculture (services) uses only technology 1 (2) its

production function is represented by technology 1 (2). Hence, we know that the

technology (especially the TFP-growth-rate and the capital-intensity) differ across

agriculture and services. Furthermore, manufacturing uses both technologies.

Hence, the average manufacturing technology is a mix of technology 1 and 2.

Hence, the representative production function of the manufacturing sector is

different in comparison to the services sector or the agricultural sector which each

use only one technology. Nevertheless, since I have an emphasis on the cross-

capital-intensity structural change, let us have a close look on the capital-intensity

(LlKk

LlKk

man

man

agr

agr

.

.

.

. , and LlKk

ser

ser

.

. ), the output-elasticity of labor ( .agrλ , .manλ and .serλ )

and the output-elasticity of capital ( .agrκ , .manκ and .serκ ) in each sector:

(34) χβαν

χβαν

LlKk

LlKk

LlKk

LlKk

LlKk

LlKk

m

m

ser

ser

m

m

man

man

m

m

agr

agr =≠⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+=≠=

.

.

.

.

.

. 1

(35) χλ

χα

αλαλ ==≠+

==≠==

∑ ∑+= +=

.

..

1 1

.

.

..

.

..

ser

serserm

ai

s

miii

man

man

manman

agr

agragr Y

Lwl

ll

lY

LwlY

Lwl

(36) νκ

χαχβαν

βκβκ ==≠+

+==≠==

∑ ∑

∑ ∑

+= +=

+= +=

.

..

1 1

1 1

.

..

.

..

ser

serserm

ai

s

miii

m

ai

s

miii

man

manman

agr

agragr Y

Krk

ll

ll

YKrk

YKrk

(Note output elasticity of factors is equal to the factor-income shares due to the

assumption of perfect markets and perfect factor mobility.) Overall, capital

intensities and output-elasticities of inputs differ across sectors agriculture,

manufacturing and services. Q.E.D.

187

Page 198: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Lemma 6: Along the PBGP the factor reallocation across the agricultural,

manufacturing and services sector is determined by cross-sector-TFP-growth

disparity, by cross sector capital-intensity-disparity and by non-homothetic

preferences.

Proof: As discussed above, the TFP-growth rates and the capital-intensities differ

across the sectors agriculture, manufacturing and services; see also Lemma 5.

Equations (30)-(31) (and equations (21) and (28)) imply that cross-sector-

differences in TFP-growth-rates and cross-sector-differences in output-elasticities

of inputs (which determine the capital-intensities) determine the strength of the

factor reallocation between the sectors agriculture, manufacturing and services.

Especially, they affect the sectoral employment shares ( , and ) via the

terms

.agrl .manl .serl

Y~ and Γ , which are among others functions of the parameters that

determine the sectoral TFP-growth rates and sectoral capital intensities (see

equations (21), (31d) and (28) and Lemma 5).

Furthermore, equations (8) to (11) imply that preferences are non-homothetic

across sectors agriculture, manufacturing and services. A detailed proof is in

APPENDIX D, where I show among others that the terms , and

determine the pattern of non-homotheticity across sectors agriculture,

manufacturing and services. Equations (30)-(31) imply that this non-homotheticity

determines the strength and direction of structural change (via terms ,

and ). Q.E.D.

∑=

a

ii

1θ ∑∑

+=+=

s

mii

m

aii

11, θθ

∑+=

n

sii

∑=

a

ii

1

θ

∑∑+=+=

s

mii

m

aii

11, θθ ∑

+=

n

sii

188

Page 199: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Lemma 7: Intersectoral outsourcing (i.e. shifts in intermediates production across

sectors) takes place along the PBGP. That is, along the PBGP manufacturing-

sector-producers shift more and more intermediates production to services-sector-

producers (i.e. changes), provided that services-sector-production becomes

cheaper and cheaper (or less and less expensive) in comparison to manufacturing-

sector-production (i.e. provided that relative prices change), and vice versa. Any

direction of relative price changes (and hence any direction of intermediate-

production shifts between the manufacturing and the services sector) can be

generated along the PBGP, depending on the parameterization.

ji hh /

Proof: See APPENDIX E.

Theorem 1: The PBGP satisfies simultaneously the following stylized facts:

• Kaldor-facts regarding the development of the great ratios,

• Kuznets facts regarding structural change patterns,

• “stylized facts regarding cross-sector-heterogeneity in production-

technology” (see section 2 as well), and

• empirical evidence on structural change determinants in industrialized

countries (see section 2).

Proof: The consistency of the PBGP with the Kaldor facts is implied by Lemma 3.

Note that empirical evidence on structural change between agriculture,

manufacturing and services in industrial countries implies the following stylized

facts for the development of the employment shares over the last century:

• the agricultural sector featured a monotonously decreasing employment

share,

• the services sector featured a monotonously increasing employment share,

and

189

Page 200: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

• the manufacturing sector featured a constant or “hump-shaped” employment

share (depending on the length of the period considered).

These stylized facts have been formulated by Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001); on

the “humped shape” of the manufacturing-employment share see e.g. Ngai and

Pissarides (2004, 2007) and Maddison (1980). In the proof of Lemma 4 I have

shown that my model can reproduce these stylized facts regarding the development

of the agricultural, manufacturing and services employment shares. Hence, the

PBGP is consistent with the Kuznets-facts.

The consistency of the PBGP with the “stylized facts regarding cross-sector-

heterogeneity in production-technology” is shown in Lemma 5, where I show that

production technology differs across agriculture, manufacturing and services in my

model.

Finally the consistency of the PBGP with the empirical evidence on structural-

change-determinants in industrialized countries is shown in Lemmas 6 and 7.

Q.E.D.

3.2.5 The relationship between structural change and aggregate-dynamics Now I turn to the question about the relationship between structural change and

aggregate growth, i.e. I ask how structural change affects aggregate growth, which

is important for understanding the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle. In the following I will

show that there are two types of cross-capital-intensity structural change, which are

distinguished according to their impact on the aggregate structure of the economy.

Definition 2: The term “cross-capital-intensity structural change” stands for

factor reallocation across sectors that differ by capital intensity.

190

Page 201: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

It can be shown that

(37) ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛++=≡ .

.

..

.

..

.

.ser

ser

serman

man

managr

agr

agr

m

m

m

m lllkll

λκ

λκ

λκ

αβ

where .agrλ ( .agrκ ), .manλ ( .manκ ) and .serλ ( .serκ ) are respectively the income-share

of labor (capital) in sectors agriculture, manufacturing and services. Equation (37)

follows from the assumption of factor mobility across sectors and from the

assumption of perfect markets.

Equation (37) and Lemma 1 imply that there are two sorts of cross-capital-

structural change:

(1) Cross-capital-intensity structural change where l is not constant. Lemma 1

implies that the economy is on a PBGP, only if is constant; furthermore,

equation (37) implies that the constancy of

mm kl /

l is required for the constancy of

. Hence, as long as mm kl / l is not constant, the economy is not on a PBGP and the

Kaldor-facts are not satisfied (exactly). That is, this type of structural change is not

compatible with the Kaldor facts (unless structural change is very weak such that

its impact via l is weak which would imply that Kaldor facts are approximately

satisfied).

(2) Cross-capital-intensity structural change that is compatible with a constant l .

Hence, an economy can be on a PBGP, even when cross-capital-intensity factor

reallocation takes place, provided that this factor reallocation is such that l = const.

(see also Lemma 1).

So I can give the following definition and theorem:

191

Page 202: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Definition 3: “Neutral structural change” stands for cross-capital-intensity

structural change that satisfies the following condition:

(38) ...

..

.

..

.

. constllll serser

serman

man

managr

agr

agr =⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛++≡λκ

λκ

λκ

Theorem 2: Along the PBGP, the cross-capital-intensity structural change

(between agriculture, manufacturing and services) is “neutral” in the sense of

Definition 3.

Proof: Note that I have shown in Lemma 5 that sectors agriculture, manufacturing

and services differ by technology, and especially by capital intensity and by output-

elasticities of inputs/income-shares of inputs. Lemma 2 implies that structural

change takes place across these sectors. Equation (37), Definition 3 and Lemma 1

(necessity of a constant for a PBGP) imply the rest of the theorem. Q.E.D. mm kl /

Theorem 3: Neutral structural change is an explanation for the Kuznets-Kaldor-

Puzzle in my model.

Proof: Remember that the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle was about the empirical

question why cross-capital-intensity structural change is compatible with the

stability of the great ratios (Kaldor facts). Theorem 2 implies that neutral-cross-

capital-intensity structural change takes place along the PBGP, while Theorem 1

shows that the PBGP is consistent with the Kaldor facts. Thus, Kaldor-facts are

satisfied, since cross-technology structural change needs not necessarily to

contradict the Kaldor facts, which is satisfied in my model only neutral cross-

capital-intensity structural change patterns. Furthermore, Theorem 1 shows the

192

Page 203: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

generality of my proof: neutral cross-technology structural change is not only

consistent with the Kaldor facts about the great ratios but also with the other

stylized facts which are relevant for the analysis of the relationship between

structural change and aggregates. Hence, Theorem 1 shows that I solved the

Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle under consideration of the most important structural change

determinants and under assumption of sectoral cross-technology disparities

observed in reality. Q.E.D.

The convenient feature regarding latter two theorems is that I can use them to test

my theory empirically: I can calculate l , and then decompose which share of

structural change does not change the value of l and which share of structural

change changes the value of l . In this way I can evaluate the quantitative

significance of my model-explanation for the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle, since my

explanation focuses only on structural change that does not change l (due to

Theorem 2).

However, before doing so I show two further interesting results

Proposition 3: The output-elasticity of inputs ( .manλ , .manκ ) is not constant in the

manufacturing sector along the PBGP, but changes according to the amount of

inputs used in this sector.

Proof: This is implied by equations (35) and (36). Note, that any sector that uses

two technologies has a non-constant output-elasticity of inputs in my model setting.

Q.E.D.

193

Page 204: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

This result is interesting: in fact it implies that observed technology changes in

sectors need not necessarily resulting form technological progress at sector level,

but can also result from structural change. Of course this requires that sectors use

several technologies, which seems to be a reasonable assumption. This fact could

be of importance for further research, especially when analyzing endogenous

technological progress at sector level. That is, Proposition 3 implies that such

research will require considering technology change at sector level with caution,

since some technology change may not result from technological progress at sector

level.

As argued in section 3.1 I assume that there are only two technologies in my

model, but that there is an arbitrary number of subsectors. Hence, some subsectors

have to use identical technologies. As explained there, I use this assumption to

explain the concept of “uncorrelated preferences and technologies” in a traceable

way, which will be of interest later in this paper. However, the assumption of partly

identical production functions is not necessary for the key results of the actual

section: the following proposition shows that the key result of this section (namely

for the existence of neutral cross-capital-intenstity structural change) can be

derived even all (sub-)sectors have completely different production functions.

Proposition 4: Generalization of my results: In a framework where

• all sub-sectors (i) have sub-sector-specific production functions,

• sub-sector production functions are general neoclassical production

functions

• and intermediate production is omitted

a necessary condition for neutrality of cross-capital-intensity structural change

and for the satisfaction of Kaldor-facts is

194

Page 205: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(39) .~ constlli i

i =≡ ∑ λ

where iλ is the output-elasticity of labor in subsector i which is equal to the labor-

income share in sector i.

Proof: See APPENDIX F.

4. A measure of neutrality of cross-capital-intensity structural change In the previous section, I have presented a model that explains the Kuznets-Kaldor-

puzzle with a certain structural change pattern which I name “neutral structural

change”. In Theorem 2 and Proposition 4 I have shown that this structural change

pattern must satisfy condition (38). Due to lack of data I cannot consider

intermediates production explicitly. Therefore, I assume that capital and labor are

the only inputs in the production function in this section. In this case condition (38)

transforms into condition (39).

In proposition 4 I have generalized the validity of condition (39) to a more general

framework than that that of section 3. Hence, the development of this condition is

not only of interest for my model, but for all models that analyze PBGP’s.

I can use condition (39) to asses to what extent neutral structural change takes

place in reality.

For the calculations in this section I use the data for the U.S.A., which is available

at the web-site of the U.S. Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic

Analysis). I use the U.S.-Gross-Domestic-Product-(GDP)-by-Industry-Data, which

195

Page 206: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

is based on the sector-definition from the “Standard Industrial Classification

System”, which defines the following sectors:

(1) Agriculture, forestry, and fishing

(2) Mining

(3) Construction

(4) Manufacturing

(5) Transportation and public utilities

(6) Wholesale trade

(7) Retail trade

(8) Finance, insurance, and real estate

(9) Services

My calculations are based on the data for the period 1948-1987. Uniform data for

longer time-periods is not available, since the “Standard Industrial Classification

System” has been modified over time (hence, the sector definition after 1987 is not

the same as the sector definition before 1987).

To calculate the sectoral labor income shares ( iλ ) I divided “(Nominal)

Compensation of Employees” by “(Nominal) Value Added by Industry” in each

sector. The sectoral employment shares ( ) are calculated by using the sectoral

data on “Full-time Equivalent Employees”. (This approach is similar to that used

by Acemogu and Guerrieri (2008)).

il

Figure 1 depicts the development of , calculated by these data: l~

196

Page 207: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Figure 1: Development of over time l~

1,65

1,7

1,75

1,8

1,85

1,9

1,95

2

2,05

2,1

2,15

1948

1950

1952

1954

1956

1958

1960

1962

1964

1966

1968

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

We can see that is decreasing and not constant. The question is, how small the

decline of is. The decline in could have been much stronger or much weaker.

If the decline is relatively small, I could postulate that is “approximately”

constant from a theoretical point of view, hence the model of neutral structural

change would be relatively good in explaining the Kuznets-Kaldor puzzle. Hence, I

have to develop an index which indicates how strong the decline is. In the

following I develop such an index. This index is based on calculating the strongest

possible decline in and then relating the actual decline to it.

l~

l~ l~

l~

l~

Any actual l~ can be expressed as a unique combination of neutral and “maximally

non-neutral structural change”. “Maximally non-neutral structural change” is the

pattern of factor reallocation that causes the maximal decline in l~ for a given

amount of reallocated labor over a period. Hence, maximally non-neutral structural

change is a diametric concept of neutral structural change: while neutral structural

change is defined upon no change in l~ , maximally non-neutral structural change is

197

Page 208: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

defined upon maximal change in l~ . This allows me to create an index that shows

us whether a given amount of reallocated labor has been reallocated rather in the

neutral way or rather in the maximally non-neutral way. According to this

discussion the following relation must be true:

(40) max)~()~)(1()~( lIlIl Nneutral

Nactual Δ+Δ−=Δ

where is a weighting factor between neutral and maximally non-neutral

structural change, i.e. it indicates whether structural change was rather neutral or

non-neutral; if =1, structural change is maximally non-neutral over the

observation period; if =0 structural change is neutral over the observation

period.

NI

NI

NI

actuall )~(Δ measures the change in l~ that really took place between 1948

and 1987; measures the maximal change in lmax)~( lΔ ~ , that would be

(hypothetically) possible with the given amount of cross-sector factor reallocation

between 1948 and 1987, i.e. max)~( lΔ stands for “completely non-neutral structural

change”. neutrall )~(Δ measures the change in l~ that is caused by neutral structural

change. Since per definition is equal to zero, I can rearrange the

condition from above as follows:

neutrall )~(Δ

(41) max)~(

)~(llI

actual

N ΔΔ

where max)~( lΔ and actuall )~(Δ are defined as follows:

198

Page 209: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(42) ∑∑ −=−≡Δi i

i

i i

iactual lllll 1948

1948

1987

1987

19481987~~)~(

λλ

(43) ∑∑ −=−≡Δi i

i

i i

i lllll 1948

1948

1987

max1987

1948max

1987max ~~)~(

λλ

where , , and denote respectively the employment share of

sector i in 1948, the employment share of sector i in 1987, the labor-share of

income in sector i in 1948 and the labor-share of income in sector i in1987.

stands for the hypothetical employment share of sector i, which would result, if the

labor, which has been reallocated between 1948 and1987, were reallocated in such

a manner that the maximal decrease in

1948il

1987il

1948iλ

1987iλ

max1987il

l~ was accomplished between 1948 and

1987. That is, the ’s stand for the hypothetical factor allocation in 1987,

which yields the maximally non-neutral structural change between 1948 and 1987.

max1987il

Last but not least, since my definition of requires knowing how much labor

has been reallocated between 1948 and 1987, I propose the following index of

observable factor reallocation between 1948 and 1987:

max1987il

∑ −≡Δi

ii lll 19481987

21

This measure indicates how much labor has been reallocated between 1948 and

1987. This measure is set up as follows: First, the change in the employment share

in each sector is measured. The absolute values (modulus) of these changes are

summed up (otherwise, without taking absolute values, that sum of the sectoral

changes would always be equal to zero, since ∑ =i

il 1 per definition). Since the

199

Page 210: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

change in the employment share in one sector has always a corresponding change

in the employment shares of the other sectors (labor is reallocated across sectors),

the sum of the absolute values of the changes must be divided by two to avoid

double-counting.

It is possible that between 1948 and 1987 in some sectors the employment share

increased first and decreased then. Hence, the pure difference would

indicate less reallocation than actually took place. My index of factor reallocation

( ) neglects such non-monotonousity in sectoral employment shares. Hence, it

underestimates the real amount of labor reallocated between 1948 and 1987.

Therefore, my index underestimates the neutrality of structural change: if more

labor were reallocated during the period, the hypothetical maximal change in

19481987ii ll −

NI

l~

( ) would be larger; hence, would be smaller, which would imply more

neutrality. Overall, for these reasons, my index indicates less neutrality than

actually is.

max)~( lΔ NI

NI

Note that it is important that my measure of maximally non-neutral structural

change ( max)~( lΔ ) is based on the actual amount of reallocated labor ( ). In this

way I distinguish between strength and direction of structural change. Strength of

structural change implies how much labor has been reallocated (e.g. as measured

by ). The direction of structural change implies how the labor has been

reallocated across technology. Neutrality of structural change is not related to

strength but only to direction, since condition (39) can be satisfied by more or less

strong structural change patterns. What counts for satisfying condition (39) is the

direction of structural change. If there is no significant direction of structural

change (39) is satisfied. Therefore, when calculating the neutrality index it is

important to be cautious about not defining

max)~( lΔ such that it features stronger

200

Page 211: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

structural change than actual structural change is. Therefore, I calculate by

using the actual amount of reallocated labor (

max)~( lΔ

lΔ ).

The data that I need for my calculations is given in the following table:

Table 1

Sector 1948/1 iλ 1987/1 iλ 1948il 1987

il

(8) 5.248981966 3.997781119 0.039609477 0.077711379

(1) 6.874359747 3.921756596 0.05019623 0.019310549

(2) 2.62541713 3.240100098 0.024056398 0.008630482

(5) 1.632072868 2.20691581 0.099835263 0.063265508

(6) 1.937362752 1.72651328 0.062648384 0.070192118

(7) 1.988458748 1.649066345 0.141770435 0.191092947

(3) 1.495168451 1.505702087 0.056228499 0.059919498

(4) 1.505805486 1.447391372 0.376011435 0.229516495

(9) 1.681140684 1.444831355 0.149643878 0.280361023

Now, by using these data, I have to do the following steps to calculate : NI

1.) Calculate the amount of reallocated labor between 1948 and (1987), which

results in 0.23. ≈Δl

2.) Calculate max1987~l . According to my definition of max

1987~l , I have to do the following

steps:

a.) Find the sector that has the smallest . This is actually sector (9). 1987/1 iλ

b) Make a ranking of the remaining sectors according to their . This ranking

is given by (8)-(1)-(2)-(5)-(6)-(7)-(3)-(4), where sector (8) has the largest

and sector (4) has the smallest in this ranking.

1987/1 iλ

1987/1 iλ

1987/1 iλ

201

Page 212: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

c) By using the ranking from b) reallocate the labor from the sectors with the

largest to sector (9). I first use the whole amount of labor, that has been

employed in sector (8) in 1948, then the whole amount of labor, that has been

employed in sector (1) in 1948, and so on, stepping up in the ranking until I have

hypothetically reallocated the whole

1987/1 iλ

≈Δl 0.23. Hence, I obtain the following

maximally non-neutral factor allocation for the year 1987

Table 2

Sector max1987il

(8) = 0

(1) = 0

(2) = 0

(5) = 0

(6) = = 0.046969461 )( 1948)8(

1948)5(

1948)2(

1948)1(

1948)6( llllll −−−−Δ−

(7) = = 0.141770435 1948)7(l

(3) = = 0.056228499 1948)3(l

(4) = = 0.376011435 1948)4(l

(9) = = 0.37902017 ll Δ+1948)9(

3.) The rest of the calculations is quite simple: by inserting the data from Tables 1

and 2 into equations (41)-(43), we can obtain . NI

My calculations imply an index = 0.45. This implies that actual structural

change was slightly closer to its neutral extreme than to its non-neutral extreme. In

NI

202

Page 213: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

other words, the actual structural change between 1948 and 1987 was by 55%

neutral and by 45% maximally non-neutral.

In this sense, my model can explain 55% of the structural change between 1948

and 1987.

Note that my measure underestimates the neutrality of structural change. That is, in

reality more than 55% of structural change can be regarded as neutral. There are

two reasons: as discussed above, my measure assumes monotonousity of factor

reallocation; furthermore, as will be discussed close to the end of next section, the

period, which I used for analysis, is quite short and structural change is more

neutral over very long periods of time.

5. On correlation between preferences and technologies In section 3.1 I have assumed that preferences and technologies are uncorrelated in

my model. In detail, I have assumed that

• on average the income elasticity of demand is equal when comparing

technology-1-goods and technology-2-goods

• on average the elasticity of substitution is equal to unity when comparing

technology-1-goods and technology-2-goods.

In the following I will discuss the rationale for these assumptions. I focus here on

the elasticity of substitution, but the corresponding arguments apply for the income

elasticity of demand.

Assuming that the relative price-elasticity of demand between two goods is

different from unity implies that the household has a certain preference for the one

good over the other: Imagine that there are only two goods (good A and good B). If

the relative price of the good A increases by one percent and the relative demand

203

Page 214: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

for this good decreases by less than one percent, good A is regarded as more

important than good B by the household in the dynamic context. That is, the price

change causes a weaker reaction than it would be if the two goods were regarded as

equivalents. Only if two goods are regarded as equivalents, a one-percent-change

in the relative price between these goods would yield a (minus) one-percent-change

in the demand-relation between these goods (hence, elasticity of substitution

between these goods being equal to one).

Now, the same argument could be applied to two groups of goods (group A and

group B): if the household regards the two groups as equivalents, the average

elasticity of substitution between the two groups is equal to unity. Otherwise, we

would have to postulate that on average group A includes goods that are preferred

over group B (or the other way around).

Now, imagine that the whole range of products in an economy is divided into two

groups according to their production technology. Group A includes goods that are

regarded as technologically progressive and group B includes goods that are

produced by a backward technology. Furthermore, let us make the following

assumptions:

(a) The household doesn’t know anything about the production process, i.e. the

household’s preference depends only on the “objective taste” of the goods (but not

on the knowledge that the good is produced at e.g. high-capital-intensity).

“Objective taste” means the taste which depends only on the physical/chemical

properties of the good or on the basic properties (i.e. actual quality) of the service,

but not on the knowledge about the production process of the good or service. For

example, if two goods are produced by different capital intensities, but if the two

goods are basically the same (i.e. have the same physical and chemical properties),

the objective taste of the two goods is the same. A further example is the following

204

Page 215: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

experiment: imagine that a live concert is recorded and then later replayed as a

playback to a similar audience (while the original musicians pretend performing

music). The labor-intensity of the original concert is higher in comparison to the

playback concert, since pretending is easier (i.e. less labor-intense) in comparison

to performing live music. The objective taste of the two concerts would be the

same. (However, the “subjective taste” of the two concerts would differ, if the

audience knew that the second concert is only a playback.)

(b) The “objective taste” of a good is on average not dependent on the technology

that is used to produce it. That is, some very tasty goods are produced by

progressive technology and some very tasty goods are produced by backward

technology; as well, some less tasty goods are produced by progressive technology

and some less tasty goods are produced by backward technology.

With these assumptions we would conclude that on average group-A-goods are not

preferred over group-B-goods and group-B-goods are not preferred over group-A-

goods. That is, the groups are regarded as equivalents; hence, on average the

elasticity of substitution between these two groups will be close to one (according

to the discussion above).

Now let us make a further assumption:

(c) I look only on the averages over very long periods of time and I assume that

there are many technologies and goods.

Hence, from this perspective due to the law of large numbers the elasticity of

substitution between the two groups is equal to unity.

In other words, if preferences and technologies are uncorrelated (i.e. if the taste

does not depend on production technology), the household behavior will not

display any preference for the technology-level (group A or group B), provided

205

Page 216: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

that very long periods of time are considered and provided that there are many

goods.

This is what I assumed in section 3.1: I assumed that there are two technologies

and that there are many goods that are produced with these technologies and that

the preference structure does not display any preference for a certain technology.

This is what I did by assumptions (10) and (11). These assumptions ensure that on

average the relative price-elasticity between technology-1-goods and technology-2-

goods is equal to unity.

Now the question is whether the assumptions (a), (b) and (c) are suitable in long

run growth models.

Assumption (c) seems not to be problematic, since the long-run growth theory is

anyway based on analyzing long-run-averages (e.g. the time preference rate is

assumed to be constant in standard neoclassical growth models). Furthermore,

since I look at very long run, any accidental correlations between technology and

preferences, which may arise from a relatively low number of products, may as

well offset each other over the period’s average.

Assumption (b) is less problematic in comparison to assumption (a). In fact, the

technological progress during the last century has implicitly shown that the basic

physical/chemical properties of a good are not necessarily dependent on its capital-

intensity. In industrialized countries nearly all goods featured some technological

progress that substituted labor by capital, while the basic physical properties of the

goods remained the same basically. The most obvious example is agriculture. Food

has for the most part the same basic physical properties today as earlier in the

century, while the capital-intensity of agriculture increased significantly. Such

developments are also apparent in manufacturing (e.g. regarding the increasing

capital-intensity of car-production) and services (e.g. cash-teller-machines).

206

Page 217: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Furthermore, today we can imagine for nearly every good or service a relatively

realistic technology that could substitute the labor by capital, without changing the

basic physical properties of the good. It is not plausible to assume that in the very

long run technological progress is restricted to certain types of goods. In the last

two decades many service-jobs, which were regarded as labor-intensive, were

replaced by computer-machines and the substitutability of human by machines in

services is increasing. Hence, when developing a long run theory of structural

change, the dependency between technology and certain types of goods (and hence

certain preferences) seems to be difficult to defend. Therefore, overall, the

assumption that the “objective taste” of a good is independent of the capital-

intensity of the production process seems to be acceptable to some degree,

especially when assuming (c).

It is more difficult to evaluate assumption (a) a priori. Assumption (a) requires that

the representative household behaves like he doesn’t know about the actual capital

intensity of a good, i.e. it is required that the household’s demand reaction to a

price and/or income change is based only on physical/chemical properties of a

good. What we know from basic microeconomics (e.g. form the discussion about

“Giffen-goods”) is that the price elasticity (and income elasticity) depends on the

basic physical/chemical properties of the good, i.e. whether the physical/chemical

properties of a good are such that it is feasible to satisfy the basic needs of a

household. (The price elasticity for such goods is low.) On the other hand, there is

also a discussion about a “snob” effect, where some very labor-intensity services

(like a full time servant) are used to signal the wealth of the household. Such

services have a relatively high income-elasticity and price-elasticity. However, as

well, there are many high-capital-intensity-goods that have high price-elasticity of

demand and high income-elasticity of demand, like very expensive cars. Hence,

207

Page 218: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

there is both: capital-intensive and labor-intensive goods that feature a relatively

high price-elasticity and a relative high income-elasticity. My model requires that

on average (i.e. when looking at the average of all consumption goods) the income

(price) elasticity of demand does not depend on the capital-intensity of a good.

Last not least, the increasing complexity of the products and of the production

process, international outsourcing and increasing variety of products make it

increasingly unlikely that the household has clear information about the capital-

intensity of a large part of its consumption bundle.

All in all, the empirical evidence from the previous section implies that the

assumption of no/low correlation between technology and preferences can explain

a part of the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle. The fact that there is some correlation

between technology and preferences results probably from the fact that assumption

(a) has not been satisfied over the time-period of my sample. That is, probably high

labor-intensity of a service has been regarded as an aspect of quality and/or luxury.

Hence, high-labor-intensity services have probably had high income-elasticity of

demand on average, which caused the correlation between technology and

preferences in the past.

The fact that there has been some correlation between preferences and technologies

in my sample does not necessarily imply that we can presume such correlation in

future:

I analyzed only a 40 year period. This is a very short period to satisfy assumption

(c) and to study growth theory empirically in general. Remember that Kaldor-facts

(which I seek to explain in my paper) do not necessarily apply to such a short

period. The probability is very high that over such a short period “accidental”

correlation between technology and preferences arises, which does not persist over

the long run. It seems that this was the case: The technological innovation between

208

Page 219: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

1940 and 1980 allowed to a big part an increase in capital-intensity in non-service-

sectors (such as manufacturing and agriculture). That is, the technological break-

throughs were such that they were easy to implement in non-services sectors but

they were hardly implementable in the services sector8. Hence, if services have

high income-elasticity of demand, some correlation between technology and

preferences may have been arisen due to such biased technological progress.

However, new sorts of technological break-through occurred after this period,

especially in the information and communication technology. Such break-throughs

have increased the capital-intensity in the services sector and have a high potential

for increasing the capital-intensity of the services sector drastically (e.g. by

progress in computers and robotics, which is implementable in services).

Hence, my empirical results probably over-estimate the long-run degree of

correlation between preferences and technologies; the long-run correlation between

preferences and technologies is probably very low or even inexistent. In this sense,

my model of independent preferences and technologies predicts quite well the

future structural change impacts on aggregates.

6. Concluding remarks In this essay I have searched for a solution of the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle. In fact,

the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle states that aggregate ratios behaved in a quite stable

manner in industrialized countries, while at the same time massive factor

reallocation took place across sectors, which differ by technology (and especially

by capital-intensity).

8 Of course, the term “services” means here rather personal services (i.e. services which require face-to-face contact, e.g. counselling) and rather not such services as transportation. The latter featured strong increases in capital-intensity. See for example Baumol et al. (1985) on discussion and empirical evidence about progressive and stagnant services.

209

Page 220: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

For the first time in the literature, I have shown that a PBGP can exist even when

factors are reallocated across sectors that differ by capital intensity. I name the

cross-capital-intensity structural change that is compatible with a PBGP “neutral

structural change”.

To test the actual neutrality of structural change I developed an index of neutrality.

In fact, my measure of neutrality indicates the weighting between two measures

( )neutrall~Δ and ( )max~lΔ . ( )neutral

l~Δ measures the hypothetical change in l~ that would

result, if the empirically observed amount of reallocated labor ( ) were

reallocated in the neutral way.

( )max~lΔ measures the hypothetical change in l~ that

would result, if lΔ were reallocated in the maximally non-neutral way. Hence, the

weighting between these two measures implies how much labor has been

reallocated in the neutral way and how much labor has been reallocated in the non-

neutral way between 1948 and 1987. This index implies that 55% of structural

change can be regarded as neutral. I provided also some theoretical/verbal

arguments which imply that over the (very) long run significantly more than 55%

of the structural change is neutral (see section 5).

I also made a first step towards a micro-foundation of neutrality of structural

change by showing that neutral structural change can arise if preferences and

technologies are uncorrelated. Therefore, my neutrality index could also be

interpreted as an index of correlation between technology and preferences. In this

sense, my empirical findings imply that the correlation between preferences and

technologies is rather low. (Exactly speaking, the actual correlation was closer to

the extreme of “no correlation” than to the extreme of “maximal correlation”).

Note that I could try to assess the degree of correlation between preferences and

technologies in an alternative way: First I would have to estimate the price

210

Page 221: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

elasticity of demand, the income elasticity of demand and the production functions

for all sectors and then I would have to try to somehow figure out the degree of

correlation between the estimated preference and technology parameters. This

approach would be problematic for two reasons:

(1) Estimation of preference parameters (and especially of income elasticity of

demand) is very difficult, since there are problems in measuring the changes in

quality of goods and services. Hence, it is difficult to isolate whether demand for a

good increased due to relatively high income-elasticity of demand or due to an

increase in quality of the service; see e.g. Ngai and Pissarides (2007).

(2) Even if I could measure the preference and technology parameters exactly there

would be a problem in defining a measure of correlation between preferences and

technologies, since we have actually two sorts of preference parameters (income

elasticity of demand and price elasticity of demand). Hence, if we have two

economies (A and B), which are identical except for their correlation between

income elasticity and technology and between price elasticity and technology, it

would be difficult to say in which economy the correlation between preferences

and technologies is lower: For example, if the correlation between income elasticity

and technology is slightly lower in country A in comparison to country B and if the

correlation between price elasticity and technology is slightly lower in country B in

comparison to country A, we could not say whether preferences and technologies

are more or less correlated in country A in comparison to country B. My approach

omits this problem by focusing on the factor reallocation across technology, which,

as modeled in my paper, reflects the degree of correlation between preferences and

technologies.

Furthermore, note that my empirical findings are valid for all the literature that

analyses structural change along PBGP’s (and where capital is included into

211

Page 222: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

analysis): I have shown in Proposition 4 that every PBGP, that satisfies the Kaldor-

facts (exactly), must feature neutral structural change. Hence, we can say that the

papers by Kongsamut et al. (2001), Ngai and Pissarides (2007) and Foellmi and

Zweimueller (2008) are compatible with 55% of structural change observed.

Overall, my explanation for the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle is the following: There is a

certain degree of independency between technologies and preferences. As

discussed in the previous section, over the very long run such independency comes

from the assumption that the household’s consumption decisions are based on the

physical and chemical properties of the goods, but not on the capital-intensity (i.e.

households are not interested in the production process of the consumption goods

but only on the “taste” of the goods). If preferences and technologies are

uncorrelated (or independent), structural change patterns can arise that satisfy all

the empirical observations associated with the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle (especially

factors are reallocated across sectors that differ by capital intensity). I show that

this explanation is compatible with 55% of the structural change.

The remaining task is to answer the question why the remaining 45% of the

structural change are compatible with the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle. One answer may

be that these 45% are quantitatively small hence their aggregate impact is relatively

low (in comparison to the other aggregate-growth determinants, e.g. technological

progress) at least at the level of stylized facts. In fact, this is implied by the paper

by Acemogly and Guerrieri (2008). However, there may be other explanations as

well. For example, the aggregate effect of these 45% of structural change may be

offset by the aggregate effects of other growth determinants, e.g. some sort of

“economy-wide technological progress” may have accelerated between 1948 and

1987 which would have offset the (negative) impacts of non-neutral structural

change. Further research could analyze this question in more detail. Furthermore, it

212

Page 223: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

seems interesting to search for other micro-foundations of neutral structural

change: I explained the parameter restrictions, which are necessary for the

existence of neutral structural change, by uncorrelated preferences and

technologies; however, there are certainly other micro-foundations that can explain

these parameter restrictions.

213

Page 224: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX A There are two approaches to solve my model, which are known from the literature

on the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model: (1) I can assume that there is a social

planer who maximizes the welfare of the representative household (“benevolent

dictator”); or (2) I can assume that there are many marginalistic households and

entrepreneurs who maximize their life-time utility and profits in perfect markets.

Both ways of solution lead to the same first order optimality conditions. I explain

approach (1) in short and focus on the approach (2).

APPROACH (1):

Necessary (first order) conditions for an optimum The benevolent dictator maximizes the utility function of the representative

household (equations (8)-(11)) subject to the equations (1)-(7) and (12)-(16).

The Hamiltonian for this control problem is given by:

( ) )(,..., 21 mmmHn hCKYCCCuHAM −−−+= δψ

where Hψ is the co-state variable.

The variables of this Hamiltonian are determined as follows:

iC are given by mihYC iii ≠∀−= , (cf. (5)),

iY are given by (1) and (2),

Z is given by (7)

mk is given by (cf. (3)), ∑≠

−=mi

im kk 1

ml is given by (cf. (3)), ∑≠

−=mi

im ll 1

mz is given by (cf. (3)) ∑≠

−=mi

im zz 1

214

Page 225: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Control variables are:

m

n

nmm

nmm

nmm

Chh

zzzzzkkkkk

lllll

,,...,,...,,...,,,...,,...,

,,...,,...,

1

1121

1121

1121

+−

+−

+−

K is state variable.

As explained in Section 3 of Chapter II, the first order optimality condition can be

derived by

• setting the first derivatives of the Hamiltonian with respect to the control

variables equal to zero

• setting the first derivative of the Hamiltonian with respect to the state

variable equal to HH ψρψ &− .

Then after some algebra, the first order optimality conditions (17)-(19) can be

obtained. Q.E.D. I omit this derivation, since it is trivial. See, e.g., the

APPENDIX of Chapter III for an example on how this can be done.

Proof that sufficient (second order) conditions are satisfied Note that the proof that the first order conditions are sufficient for an optimum is

quite difficult in this APPROACH (1). Especially the proof of concavity in Step 1

becomes quite “impossible” as we will see. Therefore, the following proof of

sufficiency of the optimality conditions may be regarded as incomplete. As we

will see, in APPROACH (2) this problem does not arise.

To prove the sufficiency of these necessary conditions I use the Arrow-Kurz-

criterion. For a description of this criterion see Section 3.2 in Chapter II. In the

following I apply the steps described there. Note that in the following I omitted

215

Page 226: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

intermediates production, i.e. 0== μγ , for simplicity. (Analogous results can be

obtained with intermediate production.)

Step 1: Maximize the Hamiltonian with respect to the control variables for

given state variable, co-state variable and time.

In fact, this implies 0!=

∂∂

mCHAM and (17). The latter together with (1), (2), (3) and

(12) implies (21), (24) and (25).

From (9) and (17) I obtain

(A.1) ip

CC ii

mm

m

ii ∀+

−= θθωω

Inserting this equation into (12) yields

(A.2) m

mmCEω

θ−=

Inserting (A.1) and (A.2) into (9) yields after some algebra:

(A.3) ωω +−= nn pEu lnln(.)

where ∑+=

≡n

miin

1

ωω and ∑≡i

ii )ln(ωωω

and where I have obtained from (1), (2) and (17)

(A.4) νβ

αχνχ

νβ

χα

−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡

m

mn Ll

KkABp /1

Equations (9) and (A.2) and condition 0!=

∂∂

mCHAM imply

(A.5) EH1

Now note that we have just derived the first order conditions for a maximum.

These conditions are sufficient only if the Hamiltonian is jointly concave in the

216

Page 227: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

control variables for given state variable, co-state variable and time. This requires

determining the signs of the first minors of the Hessian determinant of the

Hamiltonian (with respect to the control variables for given state variable, co-state

variable and time); see e.g. Chiang 1984, p.336. Since we have an arbitrary (and

large) number of state variables this becomes impossible (at least for me), due to

the difficulties in calculating determinants. (Note that sometimes these difficulties

do not arise if the Hessian is a diagonal matrix. However, in my model it is not.)

Therefore, Step 1 may be regarded as incomplete. I have not researched for a

solution of this problem, since, as mentioned above, the model can be solved by

using APPROACH (2). The proofs of sufficiency in APPROACH (2) are feasible

for me.

Step 2: Insert the optimality conditions from Step 1 into the Hamiltonian, in

order to obtain ),,(~~ timeKMAHMAH Hψ= !

Inserting (A.3) and (A.5) into the Hamiltonian yields:

(A.6) ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−++−⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= KYptKMAH

HHnn

HH δ

ψψωω

ψψ 1ln1ln),,(~

where can be derived as (implicit) function of np Hψ by using equations (A.4),

(24), (21) and (A.5) (remember that in equation (24) H=0, due to (23) and

0== μγ ) and

where Y can be derived as (implicit) function of Hψ by using equations (25), (21),

(24) and (A.5) (again, remember that in equation (24) H=0, due to (23) and

0== μγ ).

217

Page 228: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Step 3: Show that is concave in K for given ),,(~~ tKMAHMAH Hψ= Hψ and

time, by showing that 0)(

),,(~2

2

<∂

∂K

tKMAH Hψ .

This step is quite lengthy and includes calculating implicit derivatives, but straight

forward. After some algebra it can be shown that

(A.7) 0)1(

1

)()(

),,(~2

22

2

<+

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+

−−=

∂∂ β

αβ

αχωψ

m

m

m

m

nH

lk

lkK

KtKMAH

This relation is true, since equation (24) implies that 0)(1 <>−m

m

lk

if 0)(<>−αχ

(remember that in equation (24) H=0, due to (23) and 0== μγ ).

Since we have accomplished all three steps, the Arrow-Kurz-criterion implies

that conditions (17)-(19) are sufficient for an optimum (together with the

transversality condition). Q.E.D. (Remember, however, that there are some

difficulties in Step 1, as explained there.)

APPROACH (2) As mentioned above in this section I assume that there exist many marginalistic

and identical households and producers. (Of course the producers are identical

within a sector, while they differ across sectors.) The assumption of marginalistic

agents implies that all agents consider the prices and factor prices as exogenous;

i.e. all agents are “price-takers”. The prices, factor prices and quantities are

determined by laws of (aggregate) demand and (aggregate) supply on the

corresponding markets (where market clearing is assumed).

218

Page 229: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

This interpretation of the Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model is suggested by Cass

(1965) and it is well known in the literature (see any book on growth economics,

e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), pp.86ff).

Remember, however, that although APPROACH (1) and APPROACH (2) interpret

my model in different ways, both approaches yield the same first order optimality

conditions (and results in general).

For simplicity I omit intermediates production in this section, i.e. I set 0== μγ .

(Analogous results can be obtained with intermediate production.)

Producers Since I have assumed that each sector is polypolistic and since there is perfect

mobility of factors across sectors, we know that the value of marginal factor-

productivity in each sector must be equal to the (economy-wide) factor-price, i.e.

(A.8) iwLl

Ypi

ii ∀=∂∂ ,

)(

(A.9) irKk

Ypi

ii ∀=∂∂ ,

)(

where is the real wage rate and w r is the real rate of return on capital; see also,

e.g., Kongsamut et al. (2001). These conditions can be obtained by maximizing the

sector-profit function { }KrkLwlYp iiii −− with respect to factor inputs and

, while sector demand, sector-price and factor-prices are exogenous. (That is,

the sector behaves like a price-taker; the reason for this fact is that all entrepreneurs

of the sector are price-takers. This fact could be proved by modeling explicitly each

sector as consisting of identical marginalistic profit-maximizing producers; then

conditions (A.8) and (A.9) could be obtained by calculating the first-order

Lli

Kki

219

Page 230: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

conditions for profit-maximization of each individual producer and by aggregating

over all producers of a sector.)

We know that the wage rate and the rental rate of capital are equal across sectors

due to the following fact: differences in factor-prices across sectors are eliminated

instantly by cross-sector factor-migration due to the assumption of perfect cross-

sector factor-mobility.

Equations (A.8) and (A.9) imply jiLl

Yp

LlYp

j

jj

i

ii ,,

)()(∀

∂∂

=∂∂ and

jiKk

Yp

KkYp

j

jj

i

ii ,,

)()(∀

∂∂

=∂∂ . This in turn implies for mj = due to (13):

(A.10) iKkYKkY

LlYLlYp

ii

mm

ii

mmi ∀

∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

= ,)(/)(/

)(/)(/

which is part of optimality condition (17) (Q.E.D.).

Inserting (1) and (2) into (A.10) yields

(A.11) mipi ,...1,1 ==

(A.12) nmipLlKkABp n

m

mi ,...1,/1 +=≡⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=

νβαχ

νχ

νβ

χα

Households In this section the index ι denotes the corresponding variable of the individual

household. For example, while E stands for consumption expenditures of the

whole economy, ιE stands for consumption expenditures of the household ι . I

assume that there is an arbitrary and large number of households ( x,...1=ι ),

sufficiently large to constitute marginalistic behavior of households. Hence, it

follows from equations (8)-(11) that each household has the following utility

220

Page 231: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(A.13) , ιριιι ∀= ∫∞

− ,),...(0

1 dteCCuU tn 0>ρ

where

(A.14) ι θ ωιιιι ∀⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−= ∏

=

,)(ln),...(1

1

n

iiin

iCCCu

(A.15) ∑ =

=m

ii

1

0ιθ

(A.16) ∑+=

=n

mii

1

0ιθ

Furthermore, each household has the following dynamic constraint:

(A.17) ιδ ιιι ∀−−+= ,)( EWrLwW&

where ιW is the wealth/assets of household ι , ιE are consumption expenditures of

household ι and L is the (exogenous) labor-supply of household ι . The latter

implies that each household supplies the same amount of labor at the market.

The dynamic constraint (A.17) is standard (compare for example Barro and Sala-i-

Martin (2004), p.88). It implies that the wealth of the household increases by labor-

income and by (net-) interest-rate-payments and decreases by consumption

expenditures.

Note that I assume that the labor supply of each household is exogenously

determined.

In line with (12), consumption expenditures of a household are given by

(A.18) ι ιι ∀= ∑ ,i

iiCpE

Each household maximizes its life-time-utility (A.13)-(A.16) subject to its dynamic

constraint (A.17). Since this optimization problem is time-separable (due to the

221

Page 232: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

assumption of separable time-preference and marginalistic household), it can be

divided into two steps; see also, e.g., Foellmi and Zweimüller (2008), p.1320f:

1.) Intratemporal (static) optimization: For a given level of consumption-budget

( ιE ), the household optimizes the allocation of consumption-budget across goods.

2.) Intertemporal (dynamic) optimization: The household determines the optimal

allocation of consumption-budget across time.

Intratemporal optimization:

The household maximizes its instantaneous utility (A.14)-(A.16) subject to the

constraint (A.18), where it regards the consumption-budget ( ιE ) and prices ( ) as

exogenous. (Remember that the household is price-taker.) The corresponding

Lagrange-function is given by

ip

ιψθ ιιωιι ∀⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−−⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−= ∑∏

=

,)(ln1 i

iiL

n

iii CpECLG i

where Lψ is the LaGrange-multiplier (shadow-price).

The first order necessary optimality conditions are given by

(A.19) ιψθ

ωιι ,,0 ip

C iLii

i ∀=−−

These conditions are also sufficient for an optimum (maximum), since the target

function is concave and the restriction linear. (The non-negativity constraints are

studied in the phase diagram in APPENDIX C.)

From (A.19) and (13), we have

(A.20) ιθθωω ι

ιιι ,, i

pCC i

i

mm

m

ii ∀+

−=

Inserting (A.20) into (A.18) yields

222

Page 233: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(A.21) ιω

θιι ∀

−= ,

m

mmCE

Intertemporal optimization

Inserting (A.11), (A.12), (A.20) and (A.21) into (A.14)-(A.16) yields after some

algebra:

(A.22) ιωωι ∀+−= ,lnln(.) nn pEu

where ∑+=

≡n

miin

1

ωω and ∑≡i

ii )ln(ωωω

Now, we have determined the instantaneous utility as function of consumption-

budget (and prices). (Remember that the household is price-taker, i.e. prices are

exogenous from the household’s point of view.) Inserting (A.22) into (A.13) yields

(A.23) ( ) ιωω ριι ∀+−= ∫∞

− ,lnln0

dtepEU tnn

Thus, the intertemporal optimization problem is to optimize (A.23) subject to the

dynamic constraint (A.17). This is a typical optimal control problem. The

Hamiltonian for this problem is as follows:

(A.24) [ ] ιδψωω ιιι ∀−−+++−= ,)(lnln EWrLwpEHAM Hnn

where Hψ is the co-state variable. ιE is control-variable and ιW is state variable.

The prices ( ) and factor prices ( w and np δ−r ) are regarded by the household as

exogenous (since the household is marginalistic and thus price-taker.) Remember

that L is exogenous. It may be confusing that is time varying (while being

regarded as exogenous in the optimal control problem of the household). However,

this fact does not prevent us from using the Hamiltonian, since the Hamiltonian

function allows in general that time enters the target function explicitly (i.e. via

np

223

Page 234: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

exogenous “parameters”); see e.g. Gandolfo (1996), p.375, on a general

formulation of the control-problems that are solvable by using the Hamiltonian.

The first order optimality conditions are given by 0!=

∂∂

ιEHAM and

HHWHAM ρψψι +=∂∂

− &!

. These conditions imply (after some algebra) that

(A.25) ιρδι

ι

∀−−= ,rEE&

Note that this first order condition is also a sufficient condition for an optimum.

This can be immediately concluded from the Hamiltonian. Equation (A.25) has the

same concavity features as the Hamiltonian of the standard one-sector Ramsey-

Cass-Koopmans model. Especially, the target function is concave in the control-

variable and the restriction (i.e. the term within the squared brackets) is linear in

the control and the state variable. Therefore, we know that the Hamiltonian is

concave; therefore, the optimality conditions are sufficient. Q.E.D.

Relationship between individual variables and economy-wide aggregates Aggregate consumption expenditures are given by

(A.26) ∑∑ ==i

iiCpEE ι

ι

ι

where the following relation holds:

(A.27) iCC ii ∀=∑ ,ι

ι

There is no unemployment, i.e.

(A.28) ∑=ι

LL

Last not least, since the wealth/assets can only be invested in production-capital

(K), the following relation must be true

224

Page 235: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(A.29) ∑=ι

ιWK

(see also, e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004), p.97). That is, all assets are invested

in capital (capital-market-clearing).

Furthermore, the “subsistence needs” of the whole economy are simply equal to the

sum of the subsistence needs of its individuals, i.e.

(A.30) iii ∀=∑ ,ι

ιθθ

Equation (A.20), (A.27) and (A.30) imply

(A.31) ip

CC ii

mm

m

ii ∀+

−= ,θθωω

This equation corresponds to equation (18). Q.E.D. Exactly speaking, inserting

(9) into (18) yields (A.31).

(A.25) and (A.26) imply

(A.32) ρδ −−= rEE&

This equation corresponds to equation (19). Q.E.D. Exactly speaking, (19) can

be transformed into (A.32) by using (1), (2), (8)-(12), (17) and (18).

225

Page 236: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX B Equations (20) to (29) are relevant for aggregate analysis. Now let us search, like in

the “normal” Ramsey model, for a growth path where E and K grow at constant

rate, i.e.

(B.1) EgEE !=

&

(B.2) KgKK !=

&

Equations (B.1) and (22) imply that

(B.3) .constLL

ll

KK

kk

m

m

m

m =−−+&&&&

Requirement (B.3) and equation (21) imply that

(B.4) .~~

constYY=

&

(B.2) and (B.3) imply

(B.5) ( ) .// constlklkmm

mm =&

(B.1), (B.2) and (B.4) imply

(B.6) ( ) .~/

~/ constYEYE

=&

and ( ) .~/

~/ constYKYK

=&

Equations (B.2), (20) and (25) imply

(B.7) YKg

YH

YE

klcc K

m

m ~)(~~65 δ+++=+

226

Page 237: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Solving equation (24) for YH~ and inserting it into equation (B.7) yields after some

algebra:

(B.8) YKg

kl

cc

YE

cc

cc K

m

m ~)(1~11

46

4

3

45 δ++⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+−⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−=−

Remember that and Kgcccc ,,,, 6543 δ are constants. Furthermore, note that

(B.5) and (B.6) imply that m

m

kl

YE ,~ and

YK~ grow at constant rate. Hence, equation

(B.8) can be satisfied at any point of time only if m

m

kl

YE ,~ and

YK~ are constant (i.e.

they grow at the constant rate zero), i.e.

(B.9) ..,~ constklconst

YE

m

m == , .~ constYK=

Equations (B.9), (23), (25) imply

(B.10) .~~

constHH

YY

KK

YY

EE

=====&&&&&

Q.E.D.

Let denote the constant growth rate from equation (B.10). Hence, (B.9), (B.10),

(21) and (26) imply

*g

(B.11) Lgq

GG

g +−

=1

*

&

Inserting equations (27) and (28) into equation (B.11) yields after some algebra:

(B.12) LBA gggg +

+−+−

=χεγαεμεγεμ

)1()1(*

Q.E.D.

227

Page 238: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Note that in all the calculations from above I searched for an equilibrium growth

path where E and K grow at constant rate. As a result I obtained that H grows at

constant rate along this growth path. Hence, I can treat H like exogenous

technological progress along this growth path. Let HYY −≡ˆ . In this case equation

(20) can be written as follows:

(B.13) EKKY ++= δ&ˆ

Q.E.D.

Inserting equations (21), (23) and (25) into HYY −≡ˆ yields:

(B.14) qq KLGY −= 1~ˆ

where ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+−⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡

m

m

q

m

m

klcccc

lkGG )(~

2615 γγ grows at constant positive rate due to

(B.9) (G~ grows at constant positive rate). Q.E.D.

Inserting equation (B.14) into equation (22) yields:

(B.15) ρδλ −−=KY

EE ˆ&

where ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+−≡

m

m

m

m

klcccc

kl )( 2615 γγβλ is constant due to (B.9). Q.E.D.

Equations (B.14) and (B.15) include the term . This term is constant along

the equilibrium growth path and can be derived as function of model parameters by

setting equation (22) equal to and solving afterwards for

mm kl /

*g mm kl / :

(B.16) KLGg

lk q

q

m

m −−

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ ++= 1

11

1*

βρδ

228

Page 239: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Note that the term LG q−11

is a function of exogenous parameters and grows at rate

(see equation (B.11) for ). K grows at rate along the equilibrium growth

path as well (see Lemma 1). Hence, the term

*g *g *g

KLG q−1

1

is constant along the

equilibrium growth path, so that I can rewrite equation (B.16) in terms of initial

values of exogenous parameters (the index zero denotes the initial value of the

corresponding variable):

(B.17) 0

011

0

11

*

)(KLGg

lk q

q

m

m −−

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ ++=

βρδ

where q, and are given by equations (27), (28) and (B.12). Q.E.D. 0G *g

I have shown now that along an equilibrium growth path where E and K grow at

constant rate H grows at constant rate as well and is constant. When this

fact is taken into account, the economy in aggregates is represented by equations

(B.13)-(B.15). These equations are similar to the Ramsey-model regarding all

relevant features; hence, they imply that this equilibrium growth path exists and is

unique. Q.E.D.

mm lk /

229

Page 240: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX C First, I show by using linear approximation that the saddle-path-feature of the

PBGP is given (Proposition 1a). Then I prove local stability by using a phase

diagram (Proposition 1b).

Existence of a saddle-path (Proposition 1a) First I rearrange the aggregate equation system (20)-(29) as follows:

(C.1) Kq

ggEK

kl

kl

K GL

q

m

m

q

m

m ˆ)1

(ˆˆ)(ˆ−

++−−+⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=

δβα&

(C.2) q

ggK

kl

EE G

Lq

q

m

m

−−−−−⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= −

ˆˆ

11

ρδβ&

(C.3)

αχεγεμ

ωαβ

ανχββνεγεμ

+−

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

−−+−

=

1

ˆ

ˆ1 q

m

mq

n

m

m klK

E

kl

where aggregate variables are expressed in “labor-efficiency units”, i.e. they are

divided by qLG −11

; hence qLG

KK−

≡1

1ˆ and

qLG

EE−

≡1

1ˆ . Furthermore, is the

growth rate of G given by (28) and

Gg

∑+=

≡n

miin

1ωω .

These equations imply that and have the following values along the

PBGP

EK ˆ,ˆmm kl /

(C.4) *

11

*ˆ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= −

m

mq

kl

K σ

(C.5) *

11

1*ˆ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+= −−

m

mqqq

kl

E ρσασ

230

Page 241: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(C.6) σ

βρωανχβεμαχγα

ωανχβεμβνγββα

n

n

m

m

kl

)()(

)()(*

−+−+

−−−+=⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

where

qg

g GL −+++

1ρδ

βσ

where an asterisk denotes the PBGP-value of the corresponding variable.

The proof of local saddle-path-stability of the PBGP is analogous to the proof by

Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) (see there for details and see also Acemoglu

(2009), pp. 269-273, 926).

First, I have to show that the determinant of the Jacobian of the differential

equation system (C.1)-(C.2) (where is given by equation (C.3)) is different

from zero when evaluated at the PBGP (i.e. for

mm kl /

*** ,ˆ,ˆ

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

m

m

kl

EK from equations

(C.4)-(C.6)). This implies that this differential equation system is hyperbolic and

can be linearly approximated around *

** ,ˆ,ˆ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

m

m

kl

EK (Grobman-Hartman-Theorem;

see as well Acemoglu (2009), p. 926, and Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008)). The

determinant of the Jacobian is given by:

(C.7) EK

KE

EE

KK

EE

KE

EK

KK

J ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

∂∂

∂∂

−∂∂

∂∂

=

∂∂

∂∂

∂∂

∂∂

=&&&&

&&

&&

The derivatives of equations (C.1)-(C.2) are given by:

231

Page 242: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(C.8)

Ekl

kl

qKE

qg

gKkl

EE

Kkl

kl

Kqkl

KqEKE

Ekl

kl

qkl

qKEK

qg

gKkl

kl

qkl

qK

kl

kl

KqKK

m

mq

m

mq

GL

qq

m

m

m

mq

m

mqq

m

mq

m

mq

m

m

q

m

mq

GL

m

mq

m

m

q

m

mq

q

m

m

q

m

mq

ˆ)1(ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ)1(ˆ)1(ˆ

ˆˆ

1ˆ)1(ˆˆˆ

1ˆ)1(ˆ

ˆˆˆ

1

11

11

2

1

1

11

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛∂

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+

⎟⎟

⎜⎜

−−−−−⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=

∂∂

⎟⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜⎜

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛∂

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−=

∂∂

−∂

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛∂

⎟⎟

⎜⎜

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−=

∂∂

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

++−∂

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛∂

⎟⎟

⎜⎜

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+

⎟⎟

⎜⎜

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛=

∂∂

−−−

−−−

−−

β

ρδβ

β

βα

δβα

βα

&

&

&

&

where the derivatives of equation (C.3) are given by

(C.9)

⎟⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜⎜

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

−⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −++⎟

⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −+

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

=∂

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛∂

⎟⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜⎜

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

−⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −++⎟

⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −+

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

−=∂

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛∂

+

q

m

mq

n

q

m

mq

n

m

m

q

m

mq

n

q

q

m

m

nm

m

klK

Eq

klK

Eq

Kkl

klK

Eq

Kkl

Ekl

1

1

1

1

1

ˆ

ˆ111

ˆ

ˆ

ˆ

ˆ

ˆ111

ˆˆ

ωαβ

ανχβααμχγε

ααμχγε

ωαβ

ανχβ

ωαβ

ανχβααμχγε

ααμχγε

ωαβ

ανχβ

232

Page 243: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Inserting the derivatives (C.8) and (C.9) into (C.7) and inserting the PBGP-values

from equations (C.4)-(C.6) yields after some algebra the following value of the

determinant of the Jacobian evaluated at the PBGP:

(C.10) ( )

q

m

mq

n

nn

klK

Eq

KEq

J

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

−+

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−

+−−−=

1**

*

*

*

*

)ˆ(

ˆ)(ˆ

ˆ)1(

ωβανχβα

σβ

ωανχβαρωανχβ

where ( ) 0>−+≡ αμχγεαα and q is given by equation (27).

This equation can be transformed further by using equations (27) and (C.4)-(C.6):

(C.11) ( )[ ]

αβ

βαα

ωανχββσα

2*

*

*

* ˆˆ

+⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

−−−=

m

m

n

kl

KE

J

where ( ) 0>−+≡ βμνγεββ . Note that *

*

ˆˆ

KE and

*

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

m

m

kl are positive and are given

by equations (C.4)-(C.6). Furthermore, note that following relations, which are

useful for deriving equation (C.11), are true: εμγγβα )(1 −+−=+ , βα

β+

=q

(from (27)) and σ

βρωανχβα

ωανχβββα

n

n

m

m

kl

)(

)(*

−+

−−=⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ (from (C.6)).

We can see that the determinant evaluated at PBGP is different form zero. Hence,

the PBGP is hyperbolic. Furthermore, equations (C.10) and (C.11) imply that

0* <J . (Equation (C.10) implies that 0* <J , if 0>−ανχβ ; equation (C.11)

implies that 0* <J , if 0<−ανχβ as well.)

Our differential equation system consists of two differential equations ((C.1) and

(C.2)) and of two variables ( E and K ), where we have one state and one control-

233

Page 244: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

variable. Hence, saddle-path-stability of the PBGP requires that there exist one

negative (and one positive) eigenvalue of the differential equation system when

evaluated at PBGP (see also Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) and Acemoglu (2009),

pp. 269-273). Since 0* <J we can be sure that this is the case. ( 0* <J can exist

only if one eigenvalue is positive and the other eigenvalue is negative. If both

eigenvalues were negative or if both eigenvalues were positive, the determinant

*J would be positive.) Therefore, the PBGP is locally saddle-path-stable, i.e.

Proposition 1a is proved. Q.E.D.

Local stability (Proposition 1b)

In the following, I omit intermediates for simplicity, i.e. I set 0== μγ .

Furthermore, I study here only the case where output-elasticity of capital in

investment goods industries (i=m) is relatively low in comparison to the output-

elasticity of capital in the consumption goods industries ( mi ≠∀ ), i.e. I assume

αχ < . This is consistent with the empirical evidence presented and discussed in

Valentinyi and Herrendorf (2008) (see there especially p.826). Note, however, that

the qualitative stability results for the other case (i.e. αχ > ) are the same.

To show the stability-features of the PBGP, the three-dimensional system (C.1)-

(C.3) has to be transformed into a two dimensional system, in order to allow me

using a phase-diagram. By defining the variable m

m

lkK

≡κ , the system (C.1)-(C.3)

can be reformulated as follows (after some algebra):

(C.12) ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

+++−= −

βρδβκ β

1ˆˆ

1 GL

gg

EE&

234

Page 245: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(C.13)

β

ββ

κω

βχα

ρκωαβ

χακβ

δκ

κκ

E

Egg

n

nG

L

ˆ1

)1

( 11

−+

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ −−−

−++−

=

−−

&

where ∑+=

≡n

miin

1ωω

I can focus attention on showing that the stationary point of this differential

equation system is stable: The discussion in APPENDIX B implies that κ and E

are jointly in steady state only if K , E and are jointly in steady state and

that

mm lk /

K , E and are jointly in steady state only if mm lk / κ and E are jointly in

steady state. Therefore, the proof of stability of the stationary point of system

(C.12)-(C.13) implies stability of the stationary point of system (C.1)-(C.3). Hence,

in the following I will prove stability of the stationary point of system (C.12)-

(C.13).

It follows from equations (C.12) and (C.13) that the steady-state-loci of the two

variables are given by

(C.12a)

β

βρδ

βκ

⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜

−+++

==

11

*

1

:0ˆˆ

GL

ggEE&

(C.13a) κκω

αβχαρ

βδκ

κκ

β

β

κ−

= −−

−++−

==1

1

0

1

)1

(ˆ:0

n

GL

gg

E &

&

Now, I could depict the differential equation system (C.12)-(C.13) in the phase

space ( ). Before doing so, I show that not the whole phase space ( ) is

economically meaningful. The economically meaningful phase-space is restricted

by three curves ( ), as shown in the following figure and as derived below:

κ,E κ,E

321 ,, tt RRR

235

Page 246: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Figure C.1: Relevant space of the phase diagram

κ

E

1R

30=tR

20=tR

Only the space below the 1R -line is economically meaningful, since the

employment-share of at least one sub-sector i is negative in the space above the

1R -line. This can be seen from the following fact:

It follows from equations (1), (2), (3) and (17) after some algebra that

(C.14) ∑+=

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ −−=

n

mii

m

m lkl

11

χβανχβ

Note that αχανχβ −=− when 0== μγ .

Since, cannot be negative (hence , ) this equation implies that il 101

≤≤ ∑+=

n

miil

(C.15) χβαν

<m

m

kl

Inserting equation (24) into this relation yields

(C.16) βκωχ

α

n

ER 1ˆ:1 <

236

Page 247: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(remember that in equation (24) H=0, due to (23) and 0== μγ ).

Hence, the space above 1R is not feasible. When the economy reaches a point on

1R , no labor is used in sub-sectors i=1,…m. If I impose Inada-conditions on the

production functions, as usual, this means that the output of sub-sectors i=1,…m is

equal to zero, which means that the consumption of these sectors is equal to zero.

Our utility function implies that life-time utility is infinitely negative in this case.

Hence, the household prefers not to be at the 1R -curve. Note that actually the 1R -

curve is only an outer limit: Since we have existence-minima in our utility

function, the utility function becomes infinitely negative when the consumption of

one of these goods falls below its subsistence level. Hence, even when the

consumption of all goods is positive, it may be the case that the utility function is

infinitely negative due to violation of some existence minima. Therefore, the actual

constraint is somewhere below the 1R -curve. However, this fact does not change

the qualitative results of the stability analysis.

Now I turn to the and -curves. I have to take account of the non-negativity-

constraints on consumption (

2tR 3

tR

iCi ∀> 0 ), since our Stone-Geary-type utility

function can give rise to negative consumption. By using equations (A.1), (A.2)

(A.11) and (A.12) from APPENDIX A and equations (27) and (28) the non-

negativity-constraints ( iCi ∀> 0 ) can be transformed as follows (remember that I

assume here 0== μγ ):

(C.17) miLA

Ei

i ,...11ˆ1 =

−>

αωθ

(C.18) nmiLBA

E vi

i ,...111ˆ2 +=⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−> −− β

αβν

χ

κνβ

χβαν

ωθ

237

Page 248: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

This set of constraints implies that at any point of time only two constraints are

binding, namely those with respectively the largest i

i

ωθ− . Hence, the set (C.17),

(C.18) can be reduced to the following set:

(C.19) αω

θ1

2 1ˆ:LA

ERj

jt

−>

where mii

i

j

j ,...1=−>

−ωθ

ωθ

and mj ≤≤1 .

(C.20) βαβν

χ

κνβ

χβαν

ωθ

−−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−> v

x

xt

LBAER 11ˆ: 2

3

where nmii

i

x

x ,...1+=−

>−

ωθ

ωθ

and nxm ≤≤+1

These constraints are time-dependent. It depends upon the parameter setting

whether or whether is binding at a point of time. In Figure C.1 I have

depicted examples for these constraints for the initial state of the system. Only the

space above the constraints is economically meaningful, since below the

constraints the consumption of at least one good is negative. Last not least, note

that equations (C.19)/(C.20) imply that the -curve and the -curve converge to

the axes of the phase-diagram as time approaches infinity.

2tR 3

tR

2tR 3

tR

Now, I depict the differential equation system (C.12)-(C.13) in the phase space

( ). κ,E

238

Page 249: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Figure C.2: The differential equation system (C.12)-(C.13) in the phase-space for

βδχαρω

αβ

−++

<−

1

1)( G

Ln

gg

κ

E

0=κ& 0ˆ =E&

S

saddle-path

κ T poleκ

0=κ&

R

Note that I have depicted here only the relevant (or: binding) parts of the

restriction-set of Figure C.1 as a bold line R.

As we can see, the 0=κ& -locus has a pole at β

χαρωαβκ

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

=1

1

)(n

pole .

The phase diagram implies that there must be a saddle-path along which the system

converges to the stationary point S (where S is actually the PBGP). The length of

the saddle-path is restricted by the restrictions of the meaningful space

(bold line). In other words, only if the initial

321 ,, tt RRR

κ ( 0κ ) is somewhere between 0κ and

239

Page 250: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

κ 9, the economy can be on the saddle-path. Therefore, the system can be only

locally saddle-path stable. Now, I have to show that the system will be on the

saddle-path if κκκ << 00 . Furthermore, I have to discuss what happens if 0κ is

not within this range.

Every trajectory, which starts above the saddle-path or left from 0κ , reaches the

1R -curve in finite time. As discussed above, the life-time utility becomes infinitely

negative if the household reaches the 1R -curve. These arguments imply that the

representative household will never choose to start above the saddle path if

κκκ << 00 , since all the trajectories above the saddle-path lead to a state where

life-time-utility is infinitely negative.

Furthermore, all initial points that are situated below the saddle-path or right from

κ converge to the point T. If the system reaches one of the constraints ( )

during this convergence process, it moves along the binding constraint towards T.

However, the transversality condition is violated in T. Therefore, T is not an

equilibrium. To see that the transversality condition is violated in T consider the

following facts: The transversality condition is given by , where

32 , tt RR

0lim >−

∞→

t

tKe ρψ ψ

is the costate variable in the Hamiltonian function (shadow-price of capital; see

also APPENDIX A). By using the equations from APPENDIX A this transversality

condition can be reformulated such that we obtain: 01

lim 1 >−

−−−−

→∞ βδβκ β G

Lt

gg ,

which is equivalent to:

β

βδ

βκ

∞→

⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜

−++

<

11

1

limG

Lt gg

. However, equation (C.13a)

9 Note that κ must be somwhat smaller than depicted in this diagram, since, as discussed above,

1R -curve is only an „outer limit“.

240

Page 251: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

implies that in point T in Figure C.2

β

βδ

κ

⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜

−++

=

11

1

1G

Lgg

. Hence, the

transversality condition is violated if the system converges to point T.

Overall, we know that, if κκκ << 00 , the household always decides to be on the

saddle-path. Hence, we know that for κκκ << 00 the economy converges to the

PBGP. In this sense, the PBGP is locally stable (within the range κκκ << 00 ).

If the initial capital is to small ( 00 κκ < ), the economy converges to a state where

some existence minima are not satisfied (curve 1R ) and thus utility becomes

infinitely negative. This may be interpreted as a development trap. For example,

Malthusian theories imply that in this case some part of the population dies, which

would yield an increase in per-capita-capital (and hence an increase in 0κ ).

On the other hand, if initial capital-level is too large ( κκ >0 ), all trajectories

violate the transversality condition. Therefore, in this case, the representative

household must waste a part of its initial capital to come into the feasible area

( κκκ << 00 ).

Furthermore, note that there are always some happenings that reduce the capital

stock, e.g. wars (like the Second World War) or natural catastrophes. These

happenings could shift the economy into feasible space ( κκκ << 00 ). These

thoughts could be analyzed further in order to develop a theory that the Second

World War is the reason for the fact that many economies satisfy the Kaldor-facts

today.

241

Page 252: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

The alternative is to assume that the transversality condition needs not to hold

necessarily. In this case the point T would be an equilibrium. All economies, that

start at κκ >0 , would converge to this equilibrium. However, I have no idea of

how I could omit the transversality condition. We know that the transversality

condition implies that the value of capital is not allowed to be negative at the

household’s death (at infinity). In the actual model, there seems to be no adequate

theory of allowing for the violation of the transversality condition.

Note that Figure C.2 depicts the phase diagram for parameter constellations, which

satisfy the condition

βδχαρω

αβ

−++

<−

1

1)( G

Ln

gg. For parameter constellations,

which satisfy the condition

βδχαρω

αβ

−++

>−

1

1)( G

Ln

gg, the discussion and the

qualitative results are nearly the same. The only difference is that the 0=κ& -locus

is humpshaped (concave) for poleκκ < . However, all the qualitative results remain

the same (local stability of PBGP for some range κκκ << 00 and “infeasibility”

for 00 κκ < and κκ >0 ). Q.E.D.

242

Page 253: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX D It follows from the optimality condition (18) that

(D.1) ipEC i

in

ii

ii ∀+=

∑=

θω

ω

1

For the sake of simplicity I consider only the non-homotheticity between the

services sector and the conglomerate of the agriculture and manufacturing sector.

Inserting equation (D.1) into equations (15) yields (remember equation (10)):

(D.2) 21.. dEdE managr +=+

(D.3) 43. dEdEser +=

where ... seragrmanagr EEE +=+

=

=≡ n

ii

s

ii

d

1

11

ω

ω, , ∑

+=

≡s

miipd

12 θ

=

+=≡ n

ii

n

sii

d

1

13

ω

ω and

. Note that p is given by ∑+=

≡n

siipd

14 θ

)(/)(/

LlYLlYp

nn

mm

∂∂∂∂

= and stands for the relative

price of sub-sectors . nmi ,...1+=

If preferences are non-homothetic across sectors consumption expenditures on

agriculture and manufacturing ( ) do not grow at the same rate as

consumption expenditures on services ( ), when treating relative prices as

constants. Hence, I have to show that and do not grow at the same

rate when treating - as constants. It follows from equations (D.2) and (D.3)

that when treating - as constants the following equations are true

.. managrE +

.serE

.. managrE + .serE

1d 4d

1d 4d

(D.4) E

ddE

EEE

managr

managr

1

2..

..

1

1

+=

+

+&&

243

Page 254: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(D.5) E

ddE

EEE

ser

ser

3

4.

.

1

1

+=&&

which shows that and do not grow at the same rate when treating -

as constants, i.e., preferences are non-homothetic between the services sector

and the conglomerate of the agriculture sector. In the same way it can be shown

that preferences are non-homothetic between the manufacturing sector and the

agriculture sector. Q.E.D.

.. managrE + .serE 1d

4d

244

Page 255: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX E The optimality condition (17) implies after some algebra that

(E.1) ipHh

iii ∀= ,ε

Hence,

(E.2) i

j

j

i

j

i

pp

hh

εε

= for sai ,...1+= and nsj ,...1+=

In equation (E.2) i stands for the manufacturing sector and j for the services sector.

Let us now take a look at an arbitrary producer of the manufacturing sector, e.g. the

producer i = 3, where a+1<3 < s. I rewrite equation (E.2) as follows to show the

viewpoint of “producer 3”:

(E.3) 3

33

pp

hh j

jj εε

= for nsj ,...1+=

From the view point of “producer 3” equation (E.3) determines the ratio between

the input of own intermediates (i.e. the amount of intermediates that is produced by

“producer 3” and used by “producer 3”) and input of services-sector-produced

intermediates (i.e. the amount of intermediates that is produced by “producer j”

from the services sector and used by “producer 3”). (Remember that and

enter the production function of “producer 3” via equations (1) and (7).) Hence, for

example, a decrease in

3h jh

jhh3 means that “producer 3” increases the input of

producer-j-intermediates relatively more strongly than the input of own

intermediates, i.e. “producer 3” substitutes own intermediate inputs by external

intermediate inputs, i.e. “producer 3” outsources additional intermediates

production to producer j. Therefore, I can conclude from equation (E.3) that

245

Page 256: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

“producer 3” outsources more and more to “producer j” (i.e. jh

h3 decreases),

provided that 03

3 <−pp

pp

j

j && (i.e. provided that the price for the good j in terms of

the good 3 )(3p

p j decreases; or in other words: provided that the output of “producer

j” becomes cheaper and cheaper (or less and less expensive) in comparison to the

output of “producer 3”).

From this discussion and from equation (E.2) I can conclude the following:

manufacturing-sector-producers ( sai ,...1+= ) shift more and more intermediates

production to services-sector-producers ( nsj ,...1+= ), i.e. j

i

hh decreases, provided

that services-sector-production becomes cheaper and cheaper (or less and less

expensive) in comparison to manufacturing-production, i.e. provided that

0<−i

i

j

j

pp

pp &&

, and vice versa. Q.E.D.

Note that relative prices are determined by exogenous parameters. Hence, which

producers outsource and whether outsourcing from manufacturing to services

increases (or the other way around) depends on the parameterization of the model.

In general both cases are possible. By using optimality condition (17) the relative

prices can be calculated, so that I can reformulate equation (E.2) after some algebra

as follows

(E.4) μγμγϖνβ

ϑχα

εε −

−+−

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= D

LK

lk

BA

hh

m

m

j

i

j

i

)(1 for mai ,...1+= and

nsj ,...1+=

246

Page 257: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(E.5) j

i

j

i

hh

εε

= for smi ,...1+= and nsj ,...1+=

where μν

γμ

χα

βν

χαϑ ⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡ ,

γεμγενββϖ−−+

−−≡

)(1)( and

εμεγε

εμν

εχγαμ

χβαν

αχγ

−−−

= ⎪⎭

⎪⎬⎫

⎪⎩

⎪⎨⎧

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡ ∏

)1(11

1

n

ii

i

ABAD .

From equation (E.5) we can see that some of the manufacturing sector producers

(i.e. producers ) do not change their outsourcing behavior (i.e. these

producers keep their ratio of external to own intermediates production (

smi ,...1+=

j

i

hh

)

constant). Equation (E.4) implies that the rest of the manufacturing sector

producers (i.e. the producers mai ,...1+= ) change their outsourcing behavior.

Calculating the growth rate of equation (E.4) yields (remember Lemma 1):

(E.6) DDggg

hhhh

BAji

ji&&

)())((/

)/( * μγμγϖνβ −+−+−+−= for

and

mai ,...1+=

nsj ,...1+=

ϖ , and D are positive. I omit here a detailed discussion of *g D /&ji

ji

hhhh

/)/( &

, since

it is less relevant for my purposes. The only important thing is that ji

ji

hhhh

/)/( &

can be

positive (e.g. if 0,0 >−>− νβBA gg and 0>− μγ ) or negative (e.g. if

0,0 <−<− νβBA gg and 0<− μγ ) depending on the parameterization of the

model. Hence, the intermediates-production may be shifted from manufacturing to

services or the other way around, depending on the parameterization of the model.

Q.E.D.

247

Page 258: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX F It is well known that balanced growth requires either labor-augmenting

technological progress (or production function(s) of type Cobb-Douglas.)

Furthermore, a standard assumption in macroeconomic models is that the

production function has constant returns to scale. (Later, we will see that the

aggregate production function has the same structure as the sectoral production

functions.) Since I want to reassess the standard growth theory I do not depart from

these assumptions. Therefore, I assume now that sectoral production functions are

given by:

(1)’ ( ) niLflBY iiiii ,...1 =∀Ω=

where

(26)’ niLBlKk

ii

ii ,...1 =∀≡Ω

iB stands for the level of sector-specific and labor augmenting technological

progress; is a sector-specific function of )( iif Ω iΩ ; it is the intensive form of a

“standard” constant returns to scale function, where in this appendix denotes

the capital-to-labor ratio in efficiency units in sector i.

The sectoral growth rates of labor-augmenting technological progress ( ) are

constant, i.e. . The following equations remain the same as in the

previous discussion:

ig

igBB iii ∀=/&

(3)’ ∑ =i

ik 1

(3)’’ ∑ =i

il 1

(12)’ ∑≡i

iiYpY

248

Page 259: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

I still assume that sector m is numéraire (m<n) (although I do not make here any

assumptions about which sector produces capital). Hence, equation (13) holds.

When labor and capital are mobile across sectors and markets are polypolistic the

following efficiency conditions must be true:

(17)’ jiLlYLlY

KkYKkY

pp

ii

jj

ii

jj

j

i ,)(/)(/

)(/)(/

∀∂∂

∂∂=

∂∂

∂∂=

(32)’ iKkYpr iii ∀∂∂=+ )(/δ

Note, that I do not make here any assumption about the household behavior. The

assumptions above are sufficient to derive Proposition 4.

The capital share of income in sector i (or: the elasticity of capital with respect to

output in sector i) is given by:

(F.1) ( ))()()(

ii

iii

i

iiiii f

fY

KkKkYΩΩ′

Ω=∂∂

≡Ωκ

where i

iiii

ffΩ∂Ω∂

≡Ω′)()( .

By inserting equations (1)’, (26)’ and (13) into equation (32)’ I obtain:

(F.2) )( mmfr κδ ′=+

Inserting first equations (1)’ and (26)’ into equation (17)’ and then inserting

equation (F.1) into this term yields:

(F.3) ( )( )

( )( ) i

lk

lk

mm

mm

m

m

ii

ii

i

i ∀ΩΩ−

=ΩΩ−

κκ

κκ 11

Solving this term for and inserting it into equation (3)’ yields (remember that ik

11

11

−−

=− ii

i

κκκ and ): ∑ =

iil 1

(F.4) ( )( ) ( )

1

11

1−

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

Ω−=

ΩΩ− ∑

i ii

i

mm

mm

m

m llk

κκκ

Equations (13) and (17)’ imply:

249

Page 260: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(F.5) ( )( ) i

ffBffBp

iiiiii

mmmmmmi ∀

Ω′Ω−ΩΩ′Ω−Ω

=)()(

)()(

Inserting equations (1)’, (F.1) and (F.5) into equation (12)’ yields:

(F.6) ( )∑ −Ω−Ω=

i ii

immmmm

lLfBY)(1

)(1)(κκ

κ

Inserting equation (F.4) into equation (F.6) yields equation

(F.7) [ ] ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛Ω−+Ω

ΩΩ

=m

mmtmmm

m

mm

lkf

KY )(1)()( κκ

Definition F.1: A PBGP is a growth path where KY and

YrK are constant.

Definition F.1 is consistent with Definition 1 (and with the Kaldor facts). In fact

both definitions yield the same equilibrium growth path (but Definition 1 is

stronger than necessary). However, now I use Definition F.1 in order to

demonstrate that the necessary condition for the PBGP is independent of the

numéraire. (Remember that, since KY and

YrK are ratios, they are always the same

irrespective of the choice of the numérarire.)

Lemma F.1: A necessary condition for the existence of a PBGP (according to

Definition F.1) is or equivalently ./ constkl mm = .)(1

constli ii

i =Ω−∑ κ

.

Proof: Definition F.1 requires that KY and

YrK are constant; hence r must be

constant; hence must be constant (due to equation (F.2)). Due to equation

(F.7), and

.constm =Ω .constKY

= require ./ constkl mm = . and

require

./ constkl mm =

.constm =Ω .)(1

constli ii

i =Ω−∑ κ

(due to equation (F.4)). Note that

iii λκ =Ω− )(1 , since I assume that there are only two production factors capital

250

Page 261: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

and labor. ( iλ stands for the output-elasticity of labor in sector i or equivalently for

the labor-income share in sector i.) Q.E.D.

251

Page 262: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

LIST OF SYMBOLS of PART I of CHAPTER V * Denotes the PBGP-value of the corresponding variable.

A Parameter indicating technology/productivity level of

technology 1. (exogenous)

B Parameter indicating technology/productivity level of

technology 2. (exogenous)

iB Parameter indicating technology/productivity-level in sector i.

(exogenous)

iC Consumption of subsector-i-output; indicates how much of the

output of subsector i is consumed.

D Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous model-

parameters.)

E Aggregate consumption expenditures; index of overall

consumption-expenditures of the representative household

E E in “efficiency units”.

.agrE Consumption-expenditures on agricultural goods.

.. managrE + Consumption-expenditures on agricultural and manufacturing

goods.

.manE Consumption-expenditures on manufacturing goods.

.serE Consumption-expenditures on services.

G Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous model-

parameters.)

G~ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

0G Level of G at the initial point of time of the model.

252

Page 263: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

H Aggregate intermediate output; index of the value of all

intermediates produced in the economy

HAM Hamiltonian function.

MAH~ Maximum of the Hamiltonian function with respect to the

control-variables, given the state variable, co-state variable and

time.

NI Weighting factor between NEUTRAL and maximally non-

neutral structural change, i.e. it indicates whether structural

change was rather neutral or non-neutral.

J Determinant of the Jacobian matrix.

K Aggregate capital; i.e. the amount of capital that is used for

production in the whole economy.

K K in “efficiency units”.

0K Level of K at the initial point of time of the model.

L Aggregate labor; i.e. the “amount” of labor that is used for

production in the whole economy. (exogenous)

L Average labor supply. (exogenous)

0L Level of L at the initial point of time of the model. (exogenous)

LG Lagrange function.

1R Function restricting the economically meaningful space in the

phase-diagram.

2tR Function restricting the economically meaningful space in the

phase-diagram.

253

Page 264: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

3tR Function restricting the economically meaningful space in the

phase-diagram.

T A point in the phase diagram.

U Life-time utility of the (representative) household.

ι Wealth/Assets of household W ι .

Y Aggregate output; index of economy-wide output-volume.

Y~ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

Y Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

.agrY Output of the agricultural sector.

iY Output of (sub)sector i.

.manY Output of the manufacturing sector.

.serY Output of the services sector.

Z Index of intermediate production. Indicates how much

intermediate inputs are used in the whole economy.

a Auxiliary parameter used to assign the range of subsectors to

the sectors. Determines the upper range of the agricultural

sector and the lower range of the manufacturing sector.

(exogenous)

1c Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

2c Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

254

Page 265: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

3c Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

4c Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

5c Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

6c Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

1d Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

2d Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

3d Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

4d Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

(.)if Sector-specific neoclassical production function (intensive

form).

*g Growth rate of aggregates along the PBGP.

Ag Growth rate of A. (exogenous)

Bg Growth rate of B. (exogenous)

Eg Growth rate of E.

Gg Growth rate of G.

Kg Growth rate of K.

Lg Growth rate of L . (exogenous)

255

Page 266: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

ig Growth rate of labor-augmenting technological progress in

sector i.

ih Intermediates produced by subsector i; indicates how much

output of subsector i is used as intermediate in the whole

economy.

i Index denoting a sector or a subsector.

j Index denoting a sector or a subsector.

.agrk Capital-share of agriculture; indicates which share of aggregate

capital (K) is used in agriculture.

ik Capital-share of (sub)sector i; indicates which share of

aggregate capital (K) is used in (sub)sector i.

.mank Capital-share of manufacturing; indicates which share of

aggregate capital (K) is used in manufacturing.

.serk Capital-share of services; indicates which share of aggregate

capital (K) is used in services.

l Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

Indicates whether cross-capital-intensity structural change is

consistent with the PBGP (of the model with intermediates).

l~ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

Indicates whether cross-capital-intensity structural change is

consistent with the PBGP (of the model without intermediates).

.agrl Employment-share of agriculture; indicates which share of

aggregate labor (L) is used in agriculture.

256

Page 267: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

il Employment-share of (sub)sector i; indicates which share of

aggregate labor (L) is used in (sub)sector i.

.manl Employment-share of manufacturing; indicates which share of

aggregate labor (L) is used in manufacturing.

.serl Employment-share of services; indicates which share of

aggregate labor (L) is used in services.

1948il Employment share of sector i in 1948.

1987il Employment share of sector i in 1987.

max1987il Hypothetical employment share of sector i, which would result,

if the labor, which has been reallocated between 1948 and1987,

were reallocated in such a manner that the maximal decrease in

l~ was accomplished between 1948 and 1987.

lΔ Indicates the amount of labor that has been reallocated between

1948 and 1987.

actuall )~(Δ Measures the change in l~ that took place between 1948 and

1987.

max)~( lΔ Measures the maximal change in l~ , that would be

(hypothetically) possible with the given amount of cross-sector

factor reallocation between 1948 and 1987.

neutrall )~(Δ Measures the change in l~ that is caused by NEUTRAL

structural change.

m Index-number limiting the range of subsectors that use

technology 1.

n Number of subsectors.

257

Page 268: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

p Relative price of goods nmi ,...1+= , where good m is

numéraire.

ip Relative price of good i, where good m is numéraire. Indicates

how many units of good m can be obtained for one unit of good

i on the market.

np Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

q Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

r Real rental rate of capital.

s Auxiliary parameter used to assign the range of subsectors to

the sectors. Determines the upper range of the manufacturing

sector and the lower range of the services sector.

t Index denoting time.

(.)u Instantaneous utility-function.

w Real wage-rate.

.agrz Intermediate-share of agriculture; indicates which share of

intermediate input-index (Z) is used in agriculture.

iz Intermediate-share of subsector i; indicates which share of

intermediate input-index (Z) is used in subsector i.

.manz Intermediate-share of manufacturing; indicates which share of

intermediate input-index (Z) is used in manufacturing.

.serz Intermediate-share of services; indicates which share of

intermediate input-index (Z) is used in services.

Γ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

258

Page 269: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

.agrΛ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

.manΛ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

.serΛ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

iΩ Capital-to-labor-ratio “in efficiency units” in sector i.

α Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to

output-elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

α Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

β Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to

output-elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

β Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

γ Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to

output-elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

δ Depreciation rate on capital (K). (exogenous)

ε Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

iε Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas-intermediate-index; indicates

the elasticity of Z with respect to . (exogenous) ih

iθ Parameter of the utility function; closely related to the utility of

. May be interpreted as minimum consumption regarding

good i (e.g. subsistence level), if positive. May be interpreted as

“natural” endowment of good i, if negative. (exogenous)

iC

259

Page 270: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

ϑ Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

ι Index denoting a household.

ϖ Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

κ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

κ Upper level of κ , which separates the phase-diagram into a

convergent and divergent section.

0κ Lower level of κ , which separates the phase-diagram into a

convergent and divergent section at the initial point of time.

0κ Level of κ at the initial point of time of the model.

.agrκ Income-share of capital in the agricultural sector.

.manκ Income-share of capital in the manufacturing sector.

poleκ Level of κ at the pole of the 0=κ& -locus.

.serκ Income-share of capital in the services sector.

λ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

.agrλ Income-share of labor in the agricultural sector.

iλ Income-share of labor in sector i; output-elasticity of labor in

sector i in the model without intermediates.

.manλ Income-share of labor in the manufacturing sector.

.serλ Income-share of labor in the services sector.

1948iλ Labor-share of income in sector i in 1948.

1987iλ Labor-share of income in sector i in 1987.

260

Page 271: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

μ Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to

output-elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

ν Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to

output-elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

ρ Time-preference rate. (exogenous)

σ Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

χ Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to

output-elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

Hψ Co-state variable of the Hamiltonian function.

Lψ Lagrange multiplier.

ω Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

nω Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant

model-parameters.)

iω Parameter of the utility function; closely related to the utility of

. iC

261

Page 272: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

262

Page 273: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

PART II of CHAPTER V

A PBGP-Framework for Analyzing the Impacts of Offshoring on Structural Change and real GDP-

growth in the Dynamic Context

In the following I propose a framework for studying the effects of offshoring on

structural change and real GDP-growth. It is a multi-sector-growth-model where

(consumption-)sectors differ by TFP-growth and where capital accumulation

takes place. I argue that “standard offshoring theory” neglects important

productivity effects of offshoring by excluding capital accumulation and demand

patterns associated with Baumol’s “cost disease”. My model implies as well that

the transition from a manufacturing economy to a services economy, which takes

place in modern societies, is slowed down by offshoring in the long run.

Again, I modify the reference-model from Section 1 of Chapter III to adapt it to

the topic that is analyzed. The resulting model is a multi-sector Ramsey-Cass-

Koopmans model with some trade. I will discuss these modifications in detail

later; however, here are some short explanations: I simplify the preference-,

technology- and sector-structure for simplicity (homothetic preferences, identical

capital-intensity across sectors and only three sectors) and I add intermediate

structures; hence, the resulting model is similar to the model by Ngai and

Pissarides (2007). However, in contrast to Ngai and Pissarides (2007), I add

intermediate trade, introduce a measure of real GDP and focus on the impacts of

offshoring on real GDP-growth.

263

Page 274: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

TABLE OF CONTENTS for PART II of CHAPTER V

1. Introduction .................................................................................................... 265

2. Model assumptions ......................................................................................... 270

3. Optimum and equilibrium .............................................................................. 277

4. Effects of offshoring on growth of aggregates ............................................... 280

4.1 The overall impact on aggregate growth .................................................. 281

4.2 Impact channels and their relative importance ......................................... 284

5. The effects of offshoring on structural change............................................... 290

6. Discussion and implications ........................................................................... 297

7. Concluding remarks........................................................................................ 301

APPENDIX A..................................................................................................... 306

APPENDIX B..................................................................................................... 307

APPENDIX C..................................................................................................... 309

APPENDIX D..................................................................................................... 313

APPENDIX E..................................................................................................... 315

APPENDIX F ..................................................................................................... 316

LIST OF SYMBOLS of PART II of CHAPTER V ........................................... 317

264

Page 275: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

1. Introduction Let us first start with a definition of offshoring, since numerous definitions of the

term offshoring exist in the literature. Offshoring means here that firms shift

activities abroad (to unaffiliated firms or to own affiliates). Especially, a part of

the intermediate production is shifted abroad. The case where the whole

production process is shifted abroad is not analysed here; for this case traditional

(final-goods)trade theory may be more adequate.

Although a well known fact for a long time, offshoring has become one of the

most prominent terms in political debate in last years. For example, fears about

offshoring to the “new” EU-member countries in the Eastern Europe arose in

Western Europe; see e.g. Marin, 2006, for data on European offshoring. In the

United States of America fears about offshoring to India or China dominate the

political and scientific debate. These fears arose due to opening of international

borders, which has been caused by change in political regime/directives in (ex-

)communist countries, and due to new progress in information, communication

(but as well transportation) technologies, which made offshoring more profitable

and feasible. As a result, offshoring is “one of the most rapidly growing

components of trade” (Grossman and Helpman, 2005, p. 36) with the potential for

being the “next industrial revolution” (Blinder, 2007b).1

An overview of empirical and theoretical literature related to offshoring can be

found for example in Garner (2004), GAO (2005), Mankiw and Swagel (2006)

and Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud (2007). The two main discussion points in the

literature are: (1) whether offshoring leads to an increase in welfare (in the long

run in the industrialized countries) and (2) to what extent is offshoring associated

with unemployment. As discussed by Rodriguez-Clare (2007) there are two

1 For estimates of offshoring potential see Blinder (2007a), Jensen and Kletzer (2006) and Van Welsum and Vickery (2005).

265

Page 276: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

opposing effects which are decisive for point (1): the positive productivity effect,

which refers to the increase in productivity of the domestic economy that is

caused by internalization of cross-country production-cost-differences, and the

negative terms-of-trade effect, which refers to a worsening of terms of trade due

to an increase in the supply of the domestic good on the world market. Regarding

point (2), e.g. Blinder (2005, 2007b) argues that offshoring can lead to a long

transition period with high unemployment, where the unemployment may be the

stronger, the more labor is reallocated across sectors that differ by skill type (not

skill level; e.g., the services sector requires relatively well developed soft-skills

whereas the manufacturing sector requires mathematical/engineering skills).

The aim of my paper is to contribute to both discussion-points (welfare and

unemployment) by studying (1) the productivity effect in detail (i.e. in addition to

the direct productivity effects of offshoring, which are in general studied in the

literature, I study the role of the productivity effects via structural change2

associated with Baumol’s cost disease3 and via capital accumulation), and (2) the

cross-sector reallocations (i.e. structural change) associated with offshoring. The

latter are not only important for assessing unemployment but are also relevant for

nearly every long run policy. Furthermore, I provide a dynamic framework for

studying the effects of offshoring (in contrast to the static frameworks studied by,

e.g., Bhagwati et al., 2004, and Samuelson et al. 2004). In this way I can analyze

the effects of offshoring on GDP-growth and on dynamic structural-change-

patterns between technologically distinct sectors. These dynamic effects are rather

2 Structural change means here reallocation of labor across sectors such as manufacturing, services and agriculture, where sectors differ by technology (e.g. by the growth rate of total-factor-productivity (TFP)). 3 Baumol (1967) shows that, if demand is price inelastic, there is a GDP-growth-slowdown in a multi-sector economy, since factors are reallocated to low-productivity-growth-sectors (hence average factor-productivity growth slows down). In the literature this slowdown is often referred to as the growth slowdown associated with Baumol’s “cost disease”. For some new evidence on the effects associated with Baumol’s cost disease see, e.g., Nordhaus (2008).

266

Page 277: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

rarely analyzed in the literature4 (since they are difficult to study, i.e. there are no

balanced growth paths5).

My framework is based on the model presented by Ngai and Pissarides (2007),

i.e. I do not rely on a (static) trade model but work with a growth model.6 The

aggregate structure of the model is similar to the Ramsey-model (for a discussion

of the Ramsey-model, see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 2004). A part of the

intermediates production is taken over by the foreign country, i.e. offshoring takes

place. Differences in prices across countries come from differences in technology

(TFP-growth) across countries. Of course, since different technologies are used

across countries, I assume that domestic and foreign intermediates are not perfect

substitutes. Overall, I model an economy where capital is accumulated and where

the sectors differ by TFP-growth.7 The importance of analyzing offshoring in a

framework where capital is accumulated has been mentioned by Milberg et al.

(2006), pp. 6/7. Furthermore, the importance of analyzing offshoring in a

framework where technologically distinct sectors exist is implied by the previous

literature: As noted by Blinder (2005, 2007b) offshoring of high-productivity-

growth-activities (that became possible by progress in information and

communication technologies) could lead to a GDP-growth slowdown in the

economy, if the redundant factors are reallocated to sectors with lower

productivity growth (according to the framework of Baumol’s, 1967, “cost

4 There is some empirical literature on the productivity-growth-effects of offshoring at the industry and plant level, e.g. Amiti and Wei (2005, 2006), Mann (2004) and Girma and Gorg (2004). (A further overview of the literature can be found in Olsen, 2006.) However, no clear patterns as to how offshoring affects productivity can be concluded from this literature (see Olsen, 2006, p. 28). Furthermore, Rodriguez-Clare (2007) studies offshoring in a dynamic model. However, he omits cross sector differences in productivity growth and capital accumulation, which are crucial to our analysis. 5 On difficulties in the analysis of dynamic multi-sector models (no existence of balanced growth paths) see e.g. Kongsamut et al. (2001). 6 An overview of trade models dealing with offshoring can be found in Baldwin and Robert-Nicoud (2007). 7 Evidence on different TFP-growth rates across sectors is presented by, e.g., Baumol et al. (1985).

267

Page 278: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

disease”). The findings by Fixler and Siegel (1999) imply that (domestic)

outsourcing has impacts on sector-productivity and on structural change in a

framework similar to that by Baumol (1967) (i.e. in a framework where

productivity growth differs across sectors). Therefore, one can expect that

offshoring (or international outsourcing) has similar effects, as well. Note that my

model may be regarded as a Ricardian model, since trade arises due to differences

in relative sector-productivities across countries.

My model postulates a chain of dynamic effects along which offshoring can

increase GDP-growth:

(1) Offshoring influences the (implicit) total-factor-productivity-growth of

intermediates-production. This effect implies that offshoring acts like a sort of

technological progress in intermediates-production by integrating the foreign

cost-advantages into domestic production. In fact, this effect is studied in classical

trade theories. (2) The productivity-changes in intermediates-production (effect

(1)) have an indirect effect on aggregate growth as well: they influence the rate of

capital-accumulation. This effect is similar to the effect of an increase in

technological progress in neoclassical growth models, e.g. in the Ramsey-model.

(3) The increase in capital accumulation leads to factor-reallocation from

consumption-industries to capital-industries. Since the structural change patterns

associated with Baumol’s cost disease arise in consumption industries (but not in

capital-industries), the withdrawal of factors from consumption-industries implies

that a smaller share of aggregate factor-use is exposed to Baumol’s structural

change patterns. This effect has a positive impact on GDP-growth, since

Baumol’s structural change patterns have a negative impact on real GDP-growth.

In general, models that exclude capital accumulation and structural change

associated with Baumol’s cost disease do not take channels (2) and (3) into

268

Page 279: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

account. My model implies that therefore (in some cases) these models omit the

quantitatively more important part of the productivity effect: I show that the

growth effects via channel (1) are smaller than the other effects, provided that the

economy-wide output-elasticity of capital is higher than the economy-wide

output-elasticity of labor.

Furthermore, my results imply that offshoring of high-productivity-growth (hpg)

activities and offshoring of low-productivity-growth (lpg) activities are different

regarding the terms of trade development: Offshoring of lpg activities can be

beneficial for the home country even when the terms of trade worsen in the long

run. However, offshoring of hpg activities can be beneficial only if the terms of

trade improve in the long run. The reason for this fact is that lpg activities feature

increasing prices due to “Baumol’s cost disease”. Thus, even when the terms of

trade worsen in the long run, it can be “cheaper” importing intermediates than

producing them at home. This result may be of interest for the debate about

(future) hpg services offshoring.8

My results imply that structural change patterns are slowed down by offshoring

(and thus less unemployment due to inter-sectoral barriers may exist in reality) in

the long run equilibrium. (As explained above, the structural change slowdown

comes from the shift from consumption production to capital production.) These

results imply that offshoring can have different effects in comparison to domestic

outsourcing: While my results imply that offshoring leads to a structural change

slowdown, the results by Fixler and Siegel (1999) imply that domestic

outsourcing leads to an acceleration of structural change.

8 It is argued in the literature that, while offshoring of manufacturing activities included mainly lpg activities (see e.g. the discussion in Mankiw and Swagel (2006)), future services offshoring may include hpg activities; see e.g. Blinder (2005, 2007a, 2007b) and Irwin (2005).

269

Page 280: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Last but not least, my results imply that the economy, that offshores, first goes

through a turbulent phase before reaching the phase described above (i.e. the

long-run equilibrium where structural-change-smoothing occurs and higher

growth rates are achieved). During the turbulent phase there are strong

reallocations across sectors (thus, in reality high unemployment may be the case)

in order to adapt the production-structures to the effects of offshoring (in detail:

there are changes in exports, investment goods production and demand for

domestic intermediates). This result supports the argumentation by Blinder (2005,

2007b). All reallocations during the turbulent phase lead to a “manufacturing-

sector renaissance” in my model. That is, the manufacturing employment share

(which is normally decreasing in industrialized countries) increases during this

phase due to increased capital demand (and exports). This result may explain the

fact that offshoring is not associated with higher unemployment in the

manufacturing sector in empirical studies (e.g. by Amiti and Wei, 2005).

The rest of the paper is set up as follows: In the next section (section 2) I present

the model assumptions. Then I calculate the model-optimum and equilibrium

(section 3). Subsequently, I analyze the effects of offshoring on growth (section

4) and structural change (section 5). In section 6 I discuss the results/extensions of

my model, i.e. endogenous terms of trade, negative growth effects of offshoring,

the distribution of effects across phases, implications for unemployment,

“manufacturing renaissance” and “partial offshoring”. Finally, I summarize my

main results and suggest some topics for further research (section 7).

2. Model assumptions The model is a sort of disaggregated Ramsey-model with international trade. Due

to model-setting there exists an aggregate balanced growth path that features

270

Page 281: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

balanced growth with respect to aggregates, but unbalanced growth (i.e. structural

change) with respect to disaggregated variables (for details see also Ngai and

Pissarides, 2007).

I assume that there are three types of goods and services (i). However, the model

could be extended for an arbitrary number of goods. To follow the recent

discussion about services offshoring9 I could assume, e.g., that the goods and

services are classified as follows: manufacturing goods (M), personal services (P)

and impersonal services I, i.e. IPMi ,,= . Blinder (2007a) suggests dividing the

service jobs into personal services, i.e. services that cannot be delivered

electronically from far away without degradation in quality (e.g. child care and

surgery), and impersonal services that can be delivered electronically from far

away without degradation in quality (e.g typesetting and programming).

Impersonal services are offshorable (or tradable), but personal services are not.

The representative household consumes all three types of goods and services. I

assume the lifetime utility function suggested by Ngai and Pissarides (2007).

They have proven that the lifetime utility (U) has to be a logarithmic function of

the consumption composite in order to allow for aggregate balanced growth. The

consumption composite itself is a CES-function of consumption ( ) of goods

and services ( ):

iC

IPMi ,,=

(1) IPMidte t

iiiCU ,, ,

0

ln)1/(

/)1( =−∫∞

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎝

⎛−

−∑= ρεε

εεω

(2) ii ∀><< 0 ,;10 ωρε

9 see e.g. Amiti and Wei (2005, 2006), Garner (2004) and Blinder (2005, 2007b) on the role of progress in communication and information technology for services offshoring and the future importance of services offshoring.

271

Page 282: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(3) ∑ =i

i 1ω

where t is the time index.

Since I assume here 1<ε , the goods are poor substitutes and relative demand is

price inelastic, which is necessary for analyzing the growth slowdown associated

with Baumol’s cost dissease. (For further explanations with respect to the features

of this utility function see Ngai and Pissarides, 2007.) These goods and services

are produced by the corresponding domestic sectors. Each sector produces its

output via a Cobb-Douglas production function by using labor, capital and

intermediate inputs. The amount of labor available is constant and normalized to

unity. However, exogenous population growth could be integrated into this model

easily. Total factor productivity (TFP) grows in each sector at a sector specific

rate : )( ig

(4) , βαβα )()(1 ZzKknAY iiiii−−= PIMi ,,=

0, >βα and 01 >−− βα

(5) ii

i gAA

=&

, PIMi ,,=

where is the output of sector i; iY K is the aggregate capital; Z is an index of the

total “amount” of intermediate inputs; , and represent respectively the

fraction of capital, labor and intermediate inputs devoted to the production of

sector i; is a sector-specific productivity parameter.

ik in iz

iA

I assume that sectors M and P do not produce intermediate inputs. In the autarky,

intermediate inputs are produced by sector I; hence,

272

Page 283: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(6a) IhZ =

where is the “amount” of domestic intermediate inputs produced by sector I.

When I allow for trade, I assume that the intermediate inputs index (Z) is a Cobb-

Douglas-function of domestic and foreign intermediate inputs:

Ih

(6b) , ϕϕ −= 1)( FI hhZ 10 << ϕ

where is the “amount” of foreign intermediate inputs. Note that this function

implies that foreign intermediates are not a perfect substitute for domestic

intermediates, since when using foreign intermediates domestic intermediates are

still necessary in production (i.e. there is only partial-offshoring). This may come

from the fact that foreign and domestic intermediates are produced by different

productions functions (which allows for price differences between abroad and

home). For example, if software is produced less expensively abroad, it may be

lower quality software (since foreign programmers have lower quality education);

hence, domestic software-programming may be necessary to repair software

failures which may show up later. Anyway some domestic services are always

necessary to integrate foreign services into domestic production (see also Blinder,

2007b). The assumption of equation (6b) is also consistent with the empirical

findings that domestic and foreign intermediate inputs complement each other in

the production of final goods (see e.g. Desai et al., 2005, or Hanson, et al., 2003).

Fh

Note that the parameter ϕ could overall be interpreted as a quality/tradability

parameter of foreign intermediates: The lower ϕ , the better substitutes are

foreign and domestic intermediates. ϕ can represent e.g. the quality of foreign

education, but also the quality of the transfer process (tradability) of services. For

273

Page 284: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

example, if ϕ is very close to zero, the foreign services are nearly perfectly

tradable and their quality is comparable to the quality of domestic services, and

therefore intermediates will be produced nearly only abroad. Furthermore, ϕ

could also be interpreted as a measure of uncertainty regarding foreign

intermediates as modeled by Choi (2007).

Since the economy imports intermediate inputs, it has to “pay” for them by

exporting goods and services. Let sector P represent all goods and services that

cannot be exported. That is, only the output of sector M can be exported.

Alternatively, I could also assume that sector-P-output can be exported and

sector-M-output cannot. However, the key-model results would be the same. (I

assume here in accordance with the standard trade theory that the output of sector

I is not exported, i.e. the foreign country has some comparative advantage in I-

production. That is, I assume that goods and services that are exported are not

imported at the same time. However, the model could be modified easily to

include at the same time exports and imports of the same good.) I abstract from

any other trade not associated with offshoring in order to isolate the effects of

offshoring. Let denote the exports of sector M. Furthermore, let denote the

price of good i ( ). Thus, aggregate exports (E) are given by

Me ip

PIMi ,,=

(7) MM epE =:

I assume now that aggregate exports (E) are related to imports ( ) in the

following manner:

Fh

(8) FThE =

274

Page 285: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

where T is the ratio of exports to imports associated with offshoring. It

determines how much the economy has to export in order to get one unit of

intermediates-imports (offshoring). Therefore, T is corresponding to the

(reciprocal of) “offshoring-terms of trade”. I assume that the offshoring-terms of

trade is changing at a constant rate ( ): Tg

(9) TgTT=

&

Later, in section 6, I will discuss the endogenous range of these terms of trade.

Capital (K) is produced only in sector M. (Therefore, this sector could also be

interpreted as the manufacturing sector10.) Capital depreciates at rate δ . Thus,

overall, sector-M-output is consumed ( ), exported and used as capital-input: MC

(10) MMM eKKCY +++= δ&

As explained above, the output of sector (I) is consumed ( ) and used as

intermediate input:

IC

(11) III hCY +=

The output of sector P is consumed ( ) only, as explained above: PC

(12) PP CY =

10 For empirical evidence that the manufacturing sector produces nearly all investment goods see e.g. Kongsamut et al. (1997).

275

Page 286: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

I assume that capital, labor and intermediate inputs are mobile across sectors. All

capital, labor and intermediate inputs have to be used in domestic production, thus

(13) ∑ ==i

i PIMik ,, 1

(14) ∑ ==i

i PIMin ,, 1

(15) ∑ ==i

i PIMiz ,, 1

Furthermore, I define aggregate consumption expenditures (C) and aggregate

output (Y) as follows:

(16) ∑ ==i

ii PIMiCpC ,, :

(17) ∑ ==i

ii PIMiYpY ,, :

I choose the output of sector M as numéraire, thus:

(18) 1=Mp

Overall, we should keep in mind that the domestic country imports intermediate

inputs (that are substitutes for sector-I-output) and exports a part of the sector-M-

output. There is no labor mobility across countries and the households of the two

countries can invest their savings respectively only in the capital of their domestic

countries.

276

Page 287: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

3. Optimum and equilibrium Now, the model is fully specified. Equations (1)-(18) (where we use equation (6b)

and not (6a)) can be optimized by using a Hamiltonian.11 Then, after some

algebra the following intertemporal and intratemporal optimality conditions can

be obtained for my model (I subdivide the equations describing the optimal

solution into aggregated and disaggregated level equations):

Aggregates

(19) ββ

βα

η −−= 11KAY M

(20) KCYK δβ −−−= )1(&

(21) ρδα −−=KY

CC&

(22) ββα

η −−= 11

1KZ

(23) YE βϕ)1( −=

where η is a function of exogenous model parameters growing at constant rate:

(24) ϕ

ϕϕ ϕϕβη−

− ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛−=

11)1(

TpA I

I

Sectors

(25) iAAp

i

Mi ∀=

11 The optimality conditions which are obtained by the Hamiltonian, provided that there is free mobility of labor across sectors, are (u(.) denotes the instantaneous utility function from equation (1), i.e. u(.)=ln[…]):

iZzYZzY

KkYKkY

LlYLlY

CuCup

ii

MM

ii

MM

ii

MM

M

ii ∀

∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

= ,)(/)(/

)(/)(/

)(/)(/

/(.)/(.) ;

IM

MI h

ZZz

Yp∂∂

∂∂

=)(

;

FM

M

hZ

ZzYT

∂∂

∂∂

=)(

; ρδ −−∂∂=− )(/ KkYuu

MMM

M& ; where MM Cuu ∂∂= /(.) .

277

Page 288: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(26) YThhp FII βϕϕ=

−=

1

(27) izkn iii ∀==

(28) iXx

CCp iii ∀=

(29) YC

Xx

YYp

n PPPP ==

(30) ( ) βϕδ )1(* −+++==YKg

YC

Xx

YYp

n MMMM

(31) ϕβ+==YC

Xx

YYp

n IIII

where and X are time varying auxiliary variables and functions of exogenous

model parameters:

ix

(32) iAA

CCpx

i

M

M

i

M

iii ∀⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛==

−εε

ωω

1

:

(33) ∑==i

iM xCCX /:

*g denotes the equilibrium growth rate of aggregates in the equilibrium. (I will

discuss this growth rate and all the equations later in detail.)

Now, following Ngai and Pissarides (2007), I define a partially balanced

growth path (PBGP) such that aggregate consumption (C), aggregate output (Y)

and capital (K) grow at the same rate, thus, being consistent with the Kaldor facts.

This definition requires balanced growth with respect to aggregates. However, it

allows for unbalanced growth with respect to disaggregated variables such as

output shares, etc., i.e. structural change can take place.

278

Page 289: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Theorem 1a: A unique and globally saddle-path-stable PBGP exists in my model.

Proof: The equations describing the aggregate optimum (especially equations

(19)-(21)) resemble the ones from the “normal” one-sector Ramsey-model in all

relevant features. Thus, the model in aggregates behaves like a normal Ramsey

model. Therefore, we now that a unique and saddle-path-stable growth-path exists

in my model, where Y, K and C grow at a constant rate. For a discussion of the

normal one-sector Ramsey-model (or sometimes also named Ramsey-Cass-

Koopmans-model), see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004). Q.E.D.

Theorem 1b: Along the PBGP all aggregates (Y, K, C and E) grow at the

constant rate 12*g , which is given by

(34) βαββ η

−−

+−=

1)1(* gg

g M

where

(35) .)1(: constgppgg T

I

II =⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−+==

&&ϕ

ηη

η

and where is given by equation (25). II pp /&

Proof: Equation (19) implies that if K and Y grow at (the same) constant rate,

their growth rate is given by equation (34). Provided that K and Y grow at rate

, equations (20), (21) and (23) imply that aggregate consumption expenditures

(C) and aggregate exports (E) grow at rate as well. Q.E.D.

*g

*g

12 It follows from equation (22) that Z grows at a constant rate as well. However, its growth rate is different from . *g

279

Page 290: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Theorem 1c: Structural change takes place along the PBGP, i.e. sectoral factor-

input-shares ( ) and sectoral consumption-shares change over

time.

iii zkn ,, )/( CCp ii

Proof: Equations (27)-(33) imply that although K, C and Y grow at a constant

rate, and change over time. This result comes from the fact

that and X are functions of time-varying exogenous parameters. Hence, they

are not constant along the PBGP. Q.E.D.

iii zkn ,, CCp ii /

ix

Theorem 1d: The extent of offshoring changes along the PBGP, i.e.

changes.

FI hh /

Proof: This Theorem is implied by equations (25) and (26) as well as by Theorem

1b. Q.E.D.

Theorem 1e: is the (implicit) TFP-growth rate of intermediates-production

(Z).

ηg

Proof: see APPENDIX A.

4. Effects of offshoring on growth of aggregates First, I discuss the overall impact of offshoring on aggregate growth. Then in the

next subsection I will discuss the channels along which offshoring influences

GDP-growth and their relative importance. The analytical approach is as follows:

I compare the PBGP of an economy, which offshores, to the PBGP of an

economy, which is in autarky, ceteris paribus. I also discuss the factor

reallocations during the transition period in section 5.

280

Page 291: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

4.1 The overall impact on aggregate growth Up to now I modeled an economy that offshores intermediate inputs. The

following Theorem implies how we can modify the model equations to describe

an economy without offshoring:

Theorem 2: The model describes an economy without offshoring if we set 1=ϕ

and in all model equations. In this case equation (6b) becomes (6a), i.e.

only the output of sector I is used as intermediate input.

0=Me

Proof: Note that in equation (24) 1=ϕ does not imply that 0=η , since .

The rest of the proof is trivial. Q.E.D.

100 =

Theorem 3a: Offshoring increases the growth rate of the economy ( ), provided

that the price of domestically produced intermediates ( ) grows at higher rate

than the price of imported intermediates (T), ceteris paribus. That is, the PBGP-

growth rate of an economy, which offshores, is higher in comparison to the

growth rate of an economy, which does not offshore, provided that

*g

Ip

0>− TI

I gpp& ,

ceteris paribus.

Proof: This Theorem is implied by equations (34) and (35) and by Theorem 2.

The economy, which offshores, features 1<ϕ ; the economy, which does not

offshore, features 1=ϕ . Note that I

I

pp& is a function of exogenous model

parameters; see equation (25). Q.E.D.

281

Page 292: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Theorem 3b: If 0<− TI

I gpp& , offshoring decreases the growth rate of the

economy ( ) in comparison to the state without offshoring, ceteris paribus. In

this case, the relative amount of offshoring ( ) decreases.

*g

IF hh /

Proof: The proof is analogous to the proof of Theorem 3a. Note that is

given by equation (26). Q.E.D.

IF hh /

Note that, in general, the negative outcome (Theorem 3b) will not occur, since, if

terms of trade develop unfavorably, the economy can return to the state of autarky

(i.e. equation (6a) becomes valid instead of equation (6b)). Hence, the growth rate

will never be lower than in autarky. However, in section 6 I will discuss some

extensions of the model where this negative case may occur.

Definition 1: High-productivity-growth-sectors are sectors where the TFP-

growth-rate is higher than the TFP-growth-rate of the capital-producing sector;

i.e. a sector i is named high-productivity-growth-sector, provided that

. Low-productivity-growth-sectors are sectors where the TFP-

growth-rate is lower than the TFP-growth-rate of the capital-producing sector;

i.e. a sector i is named low-productivity-growth sector, provided that

.

Migg Mi ≠> ,

Migg Mi ≠< ,

Theorem 4: Offshoring of high-productivity-growth-activities ( )

increases the growth rate of the economy ( ) only if the terms of trade improve

in the long run, i.e. only if

MI gg >

*g

0<Tg . On the other hand, offshoring of low-

productivity-growth-activities ( MI gg < ) can increase the growth rate even *g

282

Page 293: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

when the terms of trade worsen in the long run, i.e. (provided that 0>Tg

0>− TI

I gpp& ).

Proof: Equation (25) implies that high-productivity-growth-activities have

decreasing prices, i.e. 0<i

i

pp&

for , and vice versa. The rest of the proof

is implied by equations (34) and (35) and Theorem 2. Remember: The economy,

which offshores, features

Mi gg >

1<ϕ ; the economy, which does not offshore, features

1=ϕ . Q.E.D.

Overall, Theorem 4 implies that even when the terms of trade worsen in the long

run, offshoring can increase the growth rate of aggregate output, provided that

low-productivity-growth-activities are offshored. The reason for this fact is that

these activities feature increasing prices due to the “cost disease” (see also

Baumol, 1967, and Ngai and Pissarides, 2007). Hence, even when the terms of

trade worsen (i.e. the price for foreign intermediates grows) it can be cheaper

using foreign intermediates instead of domestic intermediates (provided that the

price for domestic intermediates grows at higher rate than the price for foreign

intermediates). Overall, for positive growth effects of offshoring it is not merely

relevant whether the terms of trade improve or not, but rather how the terms of

trade develop in comparison to the price of the domestic sector (I) that is

competing with the foreign sector (Theorems 3 and 4).

283

Page 294: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

4.2 Impact channels and their relative importance An interesting question within this model is along which channels offshoring

influences the growth rate of aggregate output (Y). It follows from equations (4),

(17), (22) and (27) that Y is determined as follows:

(19a) ∑−−=i

iii nApKY ββ

βα

η 11 .

This equation implies that there are five sources (or: channels) of growth within

this model (note that all variables with zero as exponent denote the initial value of

the corresponding variable):

(1) Intermediates production productivity (via term ββ

η −1 ). Remember that I

have shown in Theorem 1e that can be interpreted as the TFP-growth-

rate of intermediates-production (Z). An increase in

ηg

η increases Y, ceteris

paribus.

(2) Price-effect of structural change/technological cross-sector-disparity (via

). Cross-sector differences in technology (TFP-growth) cause

changes in relative prices (see equation (25)). In general, structural change

(reallocation of labor across sectors) leads to changes in relative prices as

well.

∑i

iii nAp 00

13 Changes in relative prices cause changes in aggregate output,

ceteris paribus.

(3) Quantity-effect of structural change (via ∑i

iii nAp 00 ). Labor-reallocation

across technologically distinct sectors (i.e. changes in ) leads to changes in

13 Note that, although in our model structural change does not directly lead to changes of relative prices, in general it does. This fact will be discussed later.

284

Page 295: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

in aggregate output, ceteris paribus. In my model this effect is negative

due to the growth-slowdown associated with Baumol’s cost dissease: In

APPENDIX B I show that factors are reallocated from sectors with high

TFP-growth-rates to sectors with low-TFP-growth rates along the PBGP,

provided that demand is price-inelastic )1( <ε . That is labor, is

reallocated to low-productivity sectors; hence, average productivity of

labor decreases (see also the explanations by Ngai and Pissarides, 2007,

and Baumol, 1967 ).

(4) Technological progress (via ∑i

iii nAp 00 ). Changes in (exogenous)

technology parameter(s) ( ) lead to changes in aggregate output, ceteris

paribus.

iA

(5) Capital accumulation (via βα−1K ). An increase in capital increases

aggregate output, ceteris paribus.

Effects (2) and (3) are well known form standard structural change theory. Effects

(4) and (5) are known from the neoclassical growth theory. In fact, my model is

neoclassical in the sense that changes in productivity (due to effects (1)-(4)) lead

to changes in capital accumulation and thus to even more aggregate output-

growth. This mechanism is the same as in the standard one-sector Ramsey-(Cass-

Koopmans-)model.

My model implies that offshoring has an impact on channels (1), (3) and (5):

• Equation (35) and Theorems 1e and 2 imply that offshoring

increases the productivity of intermediates production by

internalizing the price-difference between domestic and foreign

intermediates production. (Remember that only the case

285

Page 296: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

0>− TI

I gpp& is relevant). Hence, aggregate output-growth is

increased by channel (1).

• Higher productivity in intermediates-production leads also to an

increase in capital accumulation and to more aggregate output-

growth via channel (5) (like in the normal Ramsey model); this fact

is implied by Theorems 1 and 3 and by equation (34).

• I show in the next section that this increase in capital accumulation

leads to a slowdown of structural change patterns in the long run;

i.e. due to offshoring the changes in over time along the PBGP

become smaller (see Theorem 5b). In other words, the structural

change patterns associated with Baumol’s cost disease are slowed

down by offshoring in the long run, which implies that less labor is

reallocated to low-productivity-growth-sectors. Hence, there is a

positive effect of offshoring on aggregate output-growth via

channel (3).

in

• This positive effect increases the rate of capital accumulation again

and thus aggregate output-growth and so on.

It should be noted that in my model channels (2) and (3) (and (4)) always “offset”

each other regarding Y -growth, since equations (14) and (25) imply that

Mi

iMi

i =ii

M

iiii AnAnA

AAnAp == ∑∑∑ . Hence, whether the changes in are

slowed down by offshoring or not, Y is always the same since equation (19a)

reduces to

in

(19b) MAKY ββ

βα

η −−= 11 .

286

Page 297: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

However, this fact does not imply that offshoring has no impact on GDP-growth

via channel (3) in my model and in general. The reasons are the following:

I. Aggregate output (Y), as defined in my model, is not equivalent to the real

GDP, as measured in reality. Equations (17) and (18) imply that Y stands for

the aggregate output expressed in manufacturing terms (i.e. the manufacturing

sector is numéraire). In contrast, real GDP is not measured in manufacturing

terms but there is a compound numéraire. In APPENDIX C I show that real

GDP is given in my model by the following measure:

(19c) ∑−

=

i i

iM A

nA

YGDP )1( β

We can see from equation (19c) that changes in have an impact on real

GDP. I show in APPENDIX C that structural change has a negative impact on

real GDP-growth in my model, since factors are withdrawn from high-

productivity-sectors and reallocated to low-productivity-sectors. I show in the

next section (Theorem 5b) that this reallocation process is slowed down by

offshoring. Thus, offshoring has a positive impact on real GDP-growth.

in

II. In my model sectors are aggregated by using their current weights (i.e. by

using current (relative) prices) (see equation (17)). However, in reality, real

GDP is not calculated by using current weights, but by using fixed weights or

chain-weights. For example, Steindel (1995) discusses the usage of such fixed

weights and chain-weights in the GDP-growth calculations by the U.S.

Department of Commerce’s Bureau of Economic Analysis. The discrepancy

between aggregate output, as measured in my model, and real GDP as

287

Page 298: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

measured in reality is mentioned as well by Ngai and Pissarides (2007) and

discussed in detail by Ngai and Pissarides (2004), pp. 21 ff.. (Due to this

discrepancy, some models use a fixed-weight definition of aggregate output,

e.g. Baumol, 1967, and Echevarria, 1997.) I show in APPENDIX D that

structural change determines the growth rate of real GDP, provided that real

GDP is calculated by the fixed-weights-method or the chain-weights-method.

Furthermore, I show in the next section that structural change is slowed down

by offshoring. Hence, offshoring has an impact on real GDP-growth via

channel (3), provided that real GDP is calculated by using the fixed-weights-

method or the chain-weights-method.

III. In general, the effects (2), (3) and (4) do not offset each other even regarding

Y -growth. This fact is well known from the structural change literature: More

complex assumptions, e.g. the assumption that output-elasticities of inputs

differ across sectors, would yield that in my model effects (2), (3) and (4) do

not offset each other regarding Y -growth. I omit here the explicit proof, since

it is well known in the literature (see e.g. the models by Acemoglu and

Guerrieri (2008) and Kongsamut et al. (1997)). Nevertheless, in APPENDIX

E I provide an example: I show that structural change has an impact on the

growth rate of Y, if sector differ by output-elasticites of inputs. I show in the

next section that structural change is slowed down by offshoring. Hence, we

know that in general offshoring has a “final” effect on Y-growth via channel

(3). (In my paper I do not use the more general assumption (equation (4a)

from APPENDIX E), but use equation (4), since in this way I can present my

results in the most comprehensible way: The assumption of equation (4a)

would complicate my analysis (i.e. a closed-form solution for the model could

not be derived, and I would have to rely on simulations), but would not

288

Page 299: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

change my key result, namely the fact that offshoring has an impact on

channels (1), (3) and (5).)

Note that in models, where capital accumulation is excluded from analysis and

where structural change patterns associated with Baumol’s cost disease are not

taken into account, offshoring influences GDP-growth only via channel (1).

Hence, these models neglect the effects of offshoring via channels (3) and (5).

Therefore, it may be interesting to analyze what is the relative importance of

effect (1) in comparison to the other effects. Equation (19a) implies (remember

that ) Mi

iii AnAp =∑

(36) MgbaYY

++=&

where *

1ga

βα−

= and ηββ gb−

=1

.

Remember that offshoring acts in my model like an increase in . Hence, the

direct impact of offshoring on aggregate output-growth via channel (1) is covered

by b and the other effects are covered by a (and ). The impact of offshoring on

aggregate output-growth via channel (1) is given by:

ηg

Mg

ββ

η −=

∂∂

=1

)/(

.constag

YY& .

Furthermore, the impact of offshoring via the other channels is given by

βαβ

βα

βα

ηη −−−=

∂∂

−=

∂∂

=111

)/( *

.gg

gYY

constb

& (remember equation (34)). Hence,

we can be sure that the effect via channel (1) is weaker than the other effects

289

Page 300: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

provided that βα

ββ

αβ

β−−−

<− 111

, which is equivalent to βαα −−> 1 .

Remember that my production functions imply that α is the economy-wide

output-elasticity of capital and βα −−1 is the economy-wide output-elasticity of

labor. Hence, we can be sure that the growth effects of offshoring via channel (1)

are smaller than the other effects, if output-elasticity of capital is higher than

output-elasticity of labor. Note, however, that these calculations do not take

channel (3) into account. That is, the effects via channel (1) are even less

significant.

5. The effects of offshoring on structural change In this model structural change is caused by differences in TFP-growth across

sectors. The differences in TFP-growth are reflected by prices (see equation (25)).

The representative household responds to the changes in prices by changing the

demand-ratios across goods. Hence, producers must adapt production to changing

demand, which leads to factor reallocations across sectors, i.e. structural change.

(For detailed discussion see Ngai and Pissarides, 2007.) I analyze now how

offshoring affects these structural change patterns.

Equations (29)-(31) are relevant for analyzing the effects of offshoring on

structural change. They represent the sectoral employment shares when the

economy offshores. Since labor is normalized to unity in my model, these

equations also represent the sectoral employment. I compare now the structural

change patterns in an economy that offshores with the structural change patterns

in an economy that does not offshore (see Theorem 2), ceteris paribus. I analyze

in this section the structural change patterns when 0>− TI

I gpp& . (As noted in the

290

Page 301: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

previous section, the case 0<− TI

I gpp& in general cannot occur, since the country

could return the state of autarky if terms of trade develop unfavorably;

nevertheless, all the results for the case 0<− TI

I gpp& could be derived in the same

manner as in this section.)

We have to distinguish between “transitory effects” and “PBGP effects” of

offshoring with respect to structural change: Remember that we assume that in the

beginning the economy is in autarky and moves along the PBGP. Then opening of

borders occurs, which induces a transition to a new PBGP. The term “transitory

effects” denotes the factor reallocations which occur during this transition period

and which come to a halt when the economy is on the new PBGP. That is, as we

will see, some industry-employment-shares are constant in the old and in the new

PBGP; they only change during the transition period. The reallocations which are

associated with this change during the transition period are named transitory

effects. On the other hand, as we will see, when comparing the new and the old

PBGP the strength of the factor reallocation between some industries is not the

same in the old and the new PBGP. That is, offshoring induces a change in the

strength of structural change, when comparing the old and the new PBGP. This

effect of offshoring is named “PBGP effects”.

“Transitory effects” of offshoring: As just explained, this term stands for the

factor reallocations that are caused by offshoring and that take place only during

the transition period between two PBGPs. We have to distinguish between four

different “transitional effects”, which are explained in the following and

summarized in Theorem 5a:

291

Page 302: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Effect 1: Offshoring increases the exports-to-output ratio (E/Y), since the

economy has to “pay” for intermediate imports. This effect increases the

employment share of the exporting sector M (see equation (30); note that E/Y

is given by βϕ)1( − due to equation (23)). E/Y is constant along the PBGP

due to Theorem 1. Thus, the increase in exports is a transitional effect with

respect to structural change. That is, the changes in the employment share of

export-industries (which are a subsector of sector M) are accomplished during

the transition period.

Effect 2: Offshoring decreases the domestic-intermediates-to-output ratio

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

Yhp II , since some intermediates are imported from abroad. (Note that due

to equation (26) Yhp II is given by ϕβ when offshoring takes place; in the

case without offshoring, Yhp II is given by β (see Theorem 2 and equation

(26)). Thus, the domestic-intermediates-production-to-output ratio decreases

by βϕ)1( − due to offshoring.) This effect decreases the employment share of

sector I (via ϕβ ; see equation (31)), since intermediate industries are part of

sector I. Note again that this effect is transitional as well, since Yhp II is

constant along the PBGP (it is equal toϕβ ). That is, the decrease in the

domestic-intermediates-production-to-output ratio is accomplished during the

transition period.

Effect 3: It can be shown (see APPENDIX F) that the aggregate investment-

to-output ratio ( ) increases due to offshoring. This effect

increases the employment share of the sector M (see equation (30)), since

YKg /)( *+δ

292

Page 303: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

capital-producing industries are a part of sector M. Since is

constant along the PBGP (see Theorem 1), this effect is transitional, i.e. the

accompanying reallocations are accomplished during the transition period.

The increase in the aggregate investment-to-output ratio occurs, because of

the higher aggregate productivity-growth (see also the previous section).

YKg /)( *+δ

Effect 4: The aggregate output of our economy is consumed, exported, used as

capital-input and used as intermediate input (see equations (7), (10)-(12) and

(16)-(17)). Thus, the following relation must be true:

Yhp

YE

YKg

YC II++

++=

)(1*δ . (This equation is implied by equations (20)

and (26).) My explanations of Effects 1 and 2 imply that E/Y increases due to

offshoring by the same amount as Yhp II decreases due to offshoring. Thus,

YKg

YC )( *++

δ must be constant when comparing the PBGP without

offshoring to the PBGP with offshoring. This fact implies that the aggregate

consumption-to-output ratio (C/Y) must decrease due to offshoring during the

transition period, since Effect 3 implies that increases due to

offshoring. Note that, as just explained, the decrease in C/Y is caused only by

the increase in the investment-to-output ratio ( ) (and not by

exports or by domestic intermediate goods production). What are the

implications of the decrease in C/Y for structural change? Theorem 1 implies

that C/Y is constant along the PBGP. Thus, equations (29)-(31) imply that the

decrease in C/Y is in part a transitional effect (the change in C/Y is

accomplished during the transition period) which reduces the employment

shares in all sectors during the transition period, since all sectors feature

YKg /)( *+δ

YKg /)( *+δ

293

Page 304: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

consumption goods industries. However, ’s are not constant along the

PBGP (see equations (32)-(33)).

Xxi /

14 Hence, equations (29)-(31) imply that the

decrease in C/Y has also an PBGP-effect which will be discussed now.

“PBGP effects” of offshoring (for an explicit proof see Theorem 5b): The term

“PBGP effects” stands for the differences in strength of structural change when

comparing the old and the new PBGP. (Strength of structural change means the

amount of labor that is reallocated per unit of time. Hence, strength of structural

change can be measured by strength of changes in the employment shares.)

Hence, the PBGP-effects may the regarded as permanent or long-run effects of

offshoring on structural change. My discussion of Effects 1-4 above and

equations (29)-(31) imply that YC

Xxi ’s are the only terms, which determine the

strength of structural change along the PBGP. (YC

Xxi denotes the ratio of sectoral

consumption to aggregate output, since equation (28) implies that YCp

YC

Xx iii = .)

A decrease in C/Y (see Effect 4) decreases the strength of structural change (see

equations (29)-(31) and Theorem 5b below), which means that less labor is

reallocated across sectors over time. That is, offshoring causes a slowdown of

structural change (or in other words: structural change smoothing) in the long run.

(A discussion of the shape of the -curves can be found in APPENDIX B

and in the paper by Ngai and Pissarides, 2007.)

Xxi /

Now, let us summarize these results as follows:

14 Ie omit here the discussion of the shape of the -curves, since they are the same as in the model of Ngai and Pissarides (2007).

Xxi /

294

Page 305: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Theorem 5a: Offshoring leads to

• an increase in the exports-to-output ratio (E/Y) (i.e. offshoring has

a positive impact on the employment share of export industries

during the transition period)

• a decrease in the domestic-intermediates-production-to-output

ratio ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

Yhp II (i.e. offshoring has a negative impact on the

employment share of domestic intermediate industries during the

transition period)

• an increase in the investment-to-output ratio ( ) (i.e.

offshoring has a positive impact on the employment share on

investment-goods-industries during the transition period)

YKg /)( *+δ

• a decreases in the consumption-to-output ratio (C/Y) (i.e.

offshoring has a negative impact on the employment share of

consumption-goods-industries during the transition period).

Theorem 5b: Structural change along the PBGP is slowed down by offshoring.

That is, along the PBGP the changes in over time are weaker in an economy

that offshores in comparison to an economy that does not offshore, ceteris

paribus.

in

Proof: Since this Theorem is important, here is an explicit proof: Remember that

C, Y and K are constant along the PBGP. Hence, equations (29)-(31) imply that

the following relations are true along the PBGP:

(29a) dt

XxdYC

dtdn PP )/(

=

295

Page 306: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

(30a) dt

XxdYC

dtdn MM )/(

=

(31a) dt

XxdYC

dtdn II )/(

=

where t stands for time. Theorem 5a implies that C/Y declines due to offshoring.

Hence, equations (29a)-(31a) imply that the changes in over time are weaker

due to offshoring. Hence, since structural change stands for changes in over

time, structural change is slowed down by offshoring. Q.E.D.

in

in

Theorem 5c: The structural-change-slow-down from Theorem 5b is caused by the

offshoring-induced decline in the consumption-to-output ratio.

Proof: This Theorem is implied by the proof of Theorem 5b. Q.E.D.

Corollary: Because of the positive productivity effects of offshoring, consumption

becomes a (quantitatively) less important part of aggregate output (shift from

consumption-goods-production to investment-goods-production). Hence, the

changes in consumption demand patterns (which are the only determinant

of structural change along the PBGP) become less relevant for the reallocation of

factors across sectors. Therefore, offshoring causes a structural change

slowdown.

Xxi /

All explanations regarding the development of sectoral employment shares are

also true for the sectoral capital shares , intermediate input shares (see

equation (27)) and sectoral output shares

in

ik iz

YYp ii (see equations (29)-(31)).

296

Page 307: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

6. Discussion and implications In my analysis I have assumed that terms of trade are exogenous, since the

questions analyzed in my paper do not require endogenous terms of trade. As

mentioned in section 3 we know that, if offshoring takes place, terms of trade

must be such that 0>− TI

I gpp& , since otherwise the country would be better off

in autarky (i.e. offshoring would not take place). Furthermore, for 0>− TI

I gpp&

all my results are unambiguous. Hence, there is no need for endogenizing the

terms of trade. Nevertheless, it may be interesting to know the (endogenous)

terms of trade as function of deep parameters of the model. To derive the possible

range of the terms of trade I analyze the following example: I assume for the

moment that the foreign country (India) is the same as the domestic country

(USA) beside of the TFP in sector I. Let the TFP in sector I in India be .

Hence, due to equation (25) the price for the good I is given by

FIA

I

MI A

Ap = in the

USA and by FI

MFI A

Ap = in India. This implies that one of the countries will

offshore to the other country (and export M-goods) and that both countries will be

better off when trading, provided that and provided that T (i.e. the

reciprocal of the terms of trade) is somewhere between and (see also

Theorem 3). We know that T will be somewhere between and , since

otherwise both countries would be better off in autarky and in autarky both

countries would lose the gains from trade. (Remember that is not only an

indicator of technological differences between sectors, but also of the utility based

relative demand for the goods, see footnote 11).

FII AA ≠

Ip FIp

Ip FIp

ip

297

Page 308: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Although in the present model setting there seems to be no reason for negative

effects of offshoring for GDP-growth (i.e. terms of trade must always be such that

0>− TI

I gpp& ), it may be possible to construct cases where offshoring negatively

affects GDP-growth, i.e. 0<− TI

I gpp& . For example, assume that after the

departure from autarky the technology develops in such a manner that some

foreign intermediates, that cannot be produced at home, become essential for

state-of art production. In this case the state of art production process becomes

dependent on foreign resources (i.e. change from equation (6b) to (6a) becomes

impossible). The dependency on foreign resources would allow for unfavorable

terms of trade development (i.e. 0<− TI

I gpp& ) and hence for a GDP-growth

slowdown (see Theorem 3), since the foreign country has a better bargaining

position and can dictate the terms of trade. An intuitive example for this

argumentation may be mineral oil: Some industrialized countries do not have

(relevant) reserves of mineral oil at home. However, since they started importing

mineral oil in the early 20th century their technology developed such that mineral

oil is a key resource for the most products. Of course, the question here is whether

the development process in these countries would have been much slower, if they

never had started importing mineral oil (e.g. by researching right from the

beginning, i.e. in the early 20th century, for alternative non-oil-based

technologies). Hence, there is a trade-off between the losses from using

alternative technology (slower development) and the losses from offshoring-

dependency (weak bargaining position due to dependency). This trade-off would

have to be evaluated.

298

Page 309: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

My distinction between “transitional effects” and “PBGP effects” of offshoring

on structural change in the previous section implies that only the “PBGP effects”

constitute a permanent effect on structural change in the long run. The

“transitional effects” can be regarded as transitory effects of offshoring with

respect to structural change.

A further interpretation of the distinction between “transitional effects” and

“PBGP effects” might be that the effects of offshoring will impact the economy in

two phases: In this case the “transitional effects” might be regarded as phase-1-

effects and “PBGP effects” might be regarded as phase-2-effects. That is, when

offshoring starts (e.g. due to technological progress or due to opening of

international borders) the economy must go through phase 1 first. The

reallocations during this phase are described by Effects 1-4 in the previous

section: employment in domestic intermediate-inputs-industries decreases,

employment in exports-industries increases, employment in capital-producing

industries increases and employment in consumption-goods-industries decreases.

Note that all these effects imply that labor is reallocated from all sectors to the

capital-producing sector in phase 1. That is, in phase 1 there is a kind of

“manufacturing sector renaissance” (provided that we interpret the capital-

producing sector as the manufacturing sector; see also p.271 and footnote 10).

After this phase is accomplished, phase 2 starts where smoother structural change

prevails, as explained in the previous section.

Thus, overall, this interpretation implies that the economy faces a turbulent phase

1 (where strong labor reallocations take place) due to offshoring. This result

supports Blinder (2005, 2007a, 2007b) who emphasizes the possible negative

(transitory) effects of offshoring. He argues that the reallocations during the

transitory phase can cause high unemployment, since they require that the labor

299

Page 310: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

force changes its skill sets. This is especially true if the labor force has to be

reallocated across sectors rather than within sectors, since different skill sets are

required across sectors (for example, in the services sector soft skills are much

more important than in the manufacturing sector). My discussion of phase 1

implies that most of the labor force will have to be reallocated across sectors

during this phase, which implies that indeed high unemployment may arise in

reality. Furthermore, my discussion of phase 1 implies as well that unemployment

might be even higher than expected by now: Unemployment may not only arise in

the intermediates-industries, but also in the consumption-goods-industries (Effect

4).

A further interesting result from the previous section is that a sort of “partial

offshoring” occurs. That is, only a part of the intermediates-production is

offshored: the labor employed in the domestic intermediates production (ϕβ )

does not decrease in the long run, but is constant (see discussion of Effect 2), i.e.

the intermediates-production is not completely taken over by the foreign labor

force. This is consistent with the experience from manufacturing sector

offshoring: developed economies are still producing manufacturing goods.15 To

my knowledge, the only paper that models partial offshoring is the one by Choi

(2007), where partial offshoring occurs due to uncertainty. My results imply that

partial offshoring occurs even when there is no uncertainty, provided that foreign

intermediates are not perfect substitutes for domestic intermediates. In my model

this result comes from the fact that the relative extent of offshoring ( )

depends not only on price relations between domestic and foreign producers, but

also on quality of foreign products (indicated by

FI hh /

ϕ ); see also equation (26) and

discussion in section 2. 15 See, e.g. Blinder (2007b).

300

Page 311: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

7. Concluding remarks Overall, my model implies that the inclusion of capital and structural change

associated with Baumol’s cost disease is crucial for an adequate assessment of the

productivity effect of offshoring. Standard trade theory in general does not

include these factors. Hence, the decision on the overall effect of offshoring (i.e.

whether the negative terms-of-trade effect is stronger or weaker than the positive

productivity effect) may be biased in this literature. In all my results capital plays

the key role: capital accumulation does not only create additional growth by itself,

but also makes the existence of growth effects via Baumol’s cost disease possible

(if there was no capital in my model, offshoring would not have any effects on

GDP-growth via Baumol’s cost disease).

These effects are based on the mechanism that an offshoring-induced increase in

domestic productivity accelerates domestic capital-production. Therefore, the

effects, which are shown in my model, are weaker, if some capital-goods are

imported from abroad. (In this case domestic capital production is less relevant

for domestic aggregate dynamics.) Nevertheless, we know that every country

produces some capital goods at home; thus, the effects that are modeled in my

paper exist in reality. Furthermore, in the discussion about North-South-

offshoring16 the assumption that the North produces the largest part of its capital-

goods on its own seems to be plausible, since the South does not posses the

technology to produce the high-tech capital-goods of the North.

Of course, it can happen that the North loses some of its comparative advantage

in the capital-producing sector and starts importing (more of) capital goods from

abroad. In this case the North would lose some of the positive effects of

offshoring, which are modeled in my paper. That is, even if the North gains

16 North-South-offshoring means here offshoring between industrialized countries and less developed countries, which is in the focus of the actual offshoring debate.

301

Page 312: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

comparative advantage in some other sectors (which may ensure that the

offshoring-terms-of-trade develop favorably from the viewpoint of the North), the

loss of comparative advantage in the capital-producing sector (and allowing for

capital-goods-imports form abroad) means that the positive effects of offshoring

(via e.g. slowdown of Baumol’s cost disease, as modeled in my paper) do not

exist in the North any more. This argument is related to the debate about future

terms-of-trade development and the danger that the North loses some of its

comparative advantage (see e.g. Samuelson (2004)). However, my argument

brings another aspect to this debate. My results imply that it is important in which

sector the comparative advantage is lost: The manufacturing sector produces the

most of the capital goods. Hence, if the North loses its comparative advantage in

the manufacturing sector (and if it allows for capital-goods-imports), the North

loses its potential dynamic advantages from offshoring modeled in my paper.

That is, in this case, even if the offshoring-terms-of-trade are favourable (due to

gains in comparative advantage in other sectors), offshoring does not accelerate

domestic capital production (since capital is produced abroad) and, thus,

Baumol’s structural change patterns are not slowed down.

My results imply that offshoring has the potential to influence the long run

growth of industrialized economies (positively). Of course this influence persists

only as long as different countries use different technologies to produce similar

(not perfectly substitutable) goods.

My result regarding the (long-run) structural change slowdown associated with

offshoring implies that offshoring has an impact on the key feature of the modern

development process, namely the transition from a manufacturing economy to a

services economy. Hence, many topics associated with this transition (ranging

302

Page 313: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

from labor market policy to education-system-design) are influenced by

offshoring. Note that structural change arises in my model due to cross-sector

differences in TFP-growth. I focused on this structural change determinant, since

it has important implications for aggregate growth (via Baumol’s cost disease).

However, this is not the only structural change determinant studied in the

literature; e.g. Kongsamut et al. (2001) show that the consumption demand

patterns associated with non-homothetic preferences can cause structural change

as well. My model results imply that these structural change patterns are slowed

down by offshoring as well, since in my model the structural change slowdown

comes from a decrease in the importance of consumption demand patterns for

factor allocation.

I made several assumptions which are simplifying the model, but which are not

necessary for my key results: My subdivision of the economy into impersonal

services (which are offshored), personal services and manufacturing goods is not

necessary. Actually any sort of offshoring could be analyzed within my model.

Furthermore, manufacturing goods need not to be exported but other goods can be

exported. As discussed in the previous section, the terms-of-trade can be

endogenized in my model; however, endogenous terms of trade do not change my

key results.

If I used more complicated assumptions in my model (e.g. cross-sector

differences in output-elasticites of inputs), the effects, which are studied in my

model, would still exist, while the analysis would become much more

complicated (simulations would be necessary). However, I cannot exclude that

more complicated assumptions would yield additional growth-effects of

offshoring. Further research could focus on the study of the existence of such

effects.

303

Page 314: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Regarding further research the following points may be of interest as well:

First, as discussed in the previous section my model implies that offshoring could

theoretically have negative growth effects, provided that some kind of

dependency on foreign intermediates arises. Further research could try do develop

this argumentation further. However, as discussed in the previous section, this

case is difficult to analyze, since it requires comparing different paths of

technological development.

Second, as discussed in my paper, offshoring can increase GDP-growth via

structural change, since capital production becomes more important in

comparison to consumption goods production, where consumption goods

production (but not capital production) causes the growth slowdown associated

with Baumol’s cost disease. The question is whether the structural change

patterns associated with Baumol’s cost disease can also arise in the capital

producing sector. This would require, that different sorts of capital are produced

by different technology and that capital demand is price inelastic. If this is

possible, the offshoring-induced increase in capital production would also cause

by itself some growth effects via Baumol’s cost disease. Hence, the final effects

would depend on the relative strength of Baumol’s cost disease in the

consumption goods production in comparison to the capital goods production.

Third, unemployment could be explicitly analyzed in my model by assuming

some barriers to inter-sectoral reallocation of labor. This framework could be

used to analyze the effects of such barriers on the duration of the transition period

and on the growth rate of aggregates.

Fourth, there are of course several further potential impact channels of offshoring

on growth which I did not analyze in my model (e.g. offshoring could influence

304

Page 315: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

the endogenous technological progress). All these topics are left for further

research.

305

Page 316: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX A We know from equation (11) that is produced by sector I. Thus, the total factor

productivity (TFP) of -production is given by the TFP of sector I. It follows

from equation (4) that the TFP of sector I is given by . Thus, I can formulate

the following Theorem:

Ih

Ih

IA

Theorem A1: The TFP of the domestic intermediates-production ( ) is given by

.

Ih

IA

Equations (7), (8) and (18) imply

(A.1) Teh M

F =

We know from equation (10) that is produced by sector M. Thus, the TFP of

-production is given by the TFP of sector M. Thus, I can formulate the

following Theorem due to equation (4):

Me

Me

Theorem A2: The TFP of exports-production ( ) is given by . Me MA

It follows from equation (A.1) and Theorem A2:

Theorem A3: The implicit TFP of intermediates-imports ( ) is given by FhTAM .

Implicit TFP means here the TFP which is implied by the terms of trade and by

the TFP of the export sector.

Equation (6) and Theorems A1 and A3 imply that the implicit TFP of

intermediates-production (Z) is given by ϕ

ϕ−

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

1

TAA M

I . The growth-rate of this

term (i.e. the implicit TFP-growth-rate of Z-production) is given by

).)(1( TMI ggg −−+ ϕϕ This term is equal to , because of equations (25) and

(35). Q.E.D.

ηg

306

Page 317: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX B In the proof of Theorem 5b I have shown that the dynamics of the employment

shares along the PBGP are given by the following equations:

(B.1) dt

XxdYC

dtdn PP )/(

=

(B.2) dt

XxdYC

dtdn MM )/(

=

(B.3) dt

XxdYC

dtdn II )/(

=

Remember that C/Y is constant along the PBGP, due to Theorem 1b. Hence,

equations (B.1)-(B.3) imply that the dynamics of the employment shares are

determined by the dynamics of s. Xxi / ‘

Equations (32) and (33) imply

(B.4)

1

111

+⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= −− εεεε

ωω

ωω

M

P

P

M

I

P

P

I

P

AA

AAX

x

(B.5)

1

111

+⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= −− εεεε

ωω

ωω

I

M

M

I

P

M

M

P

M

AA

AAX

x

(B.6)

1

111

+⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= −− εεεε

ωω

ωω

M

I

I

M

P

I

I

P

I

AA

AAX

x

I analyze here two cases: (1) high-productivity-goods are offshored and (2) low-

productivity-goods are offshored (see also Definition 1).

Case (1): In this case the sectoral productivity ranking is as follows:

(B.7) IMP AAA << , IMP ggg <<

307

Page 318: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Hence, the sector P is a low-productivity-sector and sector I is a high-

productivity-sector. (B.4), (B.6) and (B.7) imply that 0)/(>

dtXxd P and

0)/(<

dtXxd I , provided that 1<ε . Hence, equations (B.1) and (B.3) imply that

the employment share of sector P increases and the employment share of sector I

decreases, provided that 1<ε . That is, factors are reallocated from high-

productivity-sector(s) to low-productivity-sector(s), provided that demand is

price-inelastic.

Case (2): In this case the sectoral productivity ranking is as follows:

(B.8) , MIP AAA << MIP ggg <<

In this case sector M has the highest TFP-growth rate and sector P has the lowest

TFP-growth rate. (B.4), (B.5) and (B.8) imply that 0)/(>

dtXxd P and

0)/(<

dtXxd M , provided that 1<ε . Hence equations (B.1) and (B.2) imply that

0>dt

dnP and 0<dt

dnM , provided that 1<ε . That is, again factors are reallocated

from the sector with the highest-TFP-growth rate to the sector with the lowest-

TFP-growth rate, provided that demand is price-inelastic.

308

Page 319: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX C In reality real GDP is calculated by using an average price as GDP-deflator; i.e. in

general a basket of all goods that have been produced is used as numéraire. (See

also Ngai and Pissarides (2007), p. 435, and Ngai and Pissarides (2004), p. 21.) In

my model I choose the manufacturing output as numéraire, since in this way I can

analyze equilibrium growth paths in the most convenient manner. Nevertheless, I

can calculate the real GDP by using an average price deflator as well. I use the

following compound deflator which may be regarded as the theoretical mirror

image of the deflators that are used to calculate real GDP in reality:

(C.1) ∑≡i

iN

Nii p

YYp

p

where and denote respectively the net-output of sector i and aggregate

net-output. are the prices of my model (where sector-M-output is numéraire).

“Net-output” means here gross-output minus real value of intermediates inputs

(which is equal to “real-value added”). Hence, is given by the following

relation:

NiY NY

ip

NiY

(C.2) HzYpYp iiiN

ii −≡

where H is the aggregate value of all intermediates that have been used for

production. Hence,

(C.3) FII ThhpH +≡

(Remember that, T is the price of foreign intermediates as e.g. defined in equation

(8)).

Hence,

(C.4) ∑≡i

NiiN YpY

309

Page 320: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

I use “net output”, since in reality GDP does not include intermediates production

in order to avoid “double counting of intermediates production”. (See, e.g.,

Landefeld et al. (2008) on intermediate inputs and GDP.)

Overall, my GDP-deflator (definition (C.1)) is simply a weighted-average of

prices, where I used net-output-shares as weights (and where prices are in

manufacturing terms). Thus, if we divide our aggregate net-output (which is

expressed in manufacturing terms) by this deflator we have a GDP-measure that

is similar to that used in reality.

(C.5) p

YGDP N≡

Note that instead of definition (C.1) I could use the following definition:

(C.6) ∑≡i

iiiA p

YYp

p

where not net-output-shares are used as weights, but output-shares. However, it

does not matter, i.e. in my model p and Ap are the same. (I omit here the proof,

since its trivial.)

By using equations (C.1)-(C.5) and (15),(19), (22) and (25)-(27) it can be shown

that

(C.7) ∑−

=−

i i

iM A

nA

Yp

YGDP )1()1( ββ Q.E.D.

Note that Y is given by equations (19) and (24). Furthermore the price index is

given by

(C.8) ∑=i i

iM A

nAp

310

Page 321: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

We can see that the real GDP is determined by factor-allocation across sectors

(where sectors differ by the productivity parameters ). Hence, structural change

(i.e. changes ) affect the growth rate of GDP.

iA

in

Now, I show that the impact of structural change on real GDP is negative.

(C.7), (C.8), (19) and (24) imply that the impact of structural change on GDP

depends only on the development of p . If I show that reallocation of factors

across sectors (i.e. changes in ) increases in p , we know that structural change

has a negative impact on real GDP-growth. To do so I derive the following total

differential of p :

(C.9) ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= ∑

ii

iM dn

AApd 1

Due to equation (14) the following relation must be true

(C.10) ∑ =i

idn 0

where I have calculated the total differential of equation (14).

Like in APPENDIX B I distinguish between two cases: (1) high-productivity-

goods are offshored and (2) low-productivity-goods are offshored (see also

Definition 1).

Case (1): In this case the relations between sectoral total-factor-

productivities are as follows:

(C.11) IMP AAA << , IMP ggg <<

By using equation (C.10), equation (C.9) can be reformulated as follows:

(C.12) II

MP

P

M dnAA

dnAA

pd ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−= 11

311

Page 322: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

In APPENDIX B I have shown that in this case the employment share of sector P

increases and the employment share of sector I decreases; hence

(C.13) 0,0 <> IP dndn

(C.11)-(C.13) imply that 0>pd

Case (2): In this case the relations between sectoral total-factor-

productivities are as follows:

(C.14) MIP AAA << , MIP ggg <<

By using equation (C.10), equation (C.9) can be reformulated as follows:

(C.15) MI

MP

I

M

P

M dnAA

dnAA

AA

pd ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−= 1

In APPENDIX B I have shown that in this case the employment share of sector P

increases and the employment share of sector M decreases; hence

(C.15) 0,0 <> MP dndn

(C.14)-(C.15) imply that 0>pd

Overall, I have shown that in both cases labor is reallocated from the low-

productivity-sector to the high-productivity sector. This reallocation process leads

to increases in p . Increases in p lead to decreases in real GDP (according to

equation (C.7)). Hence, structural change has a negative impact on real GDP-

growth. Furthermore, the stronger structural change is, the stronger is this

negative impact (where the strength of structural change is indicated by ’s).

Q.E.D.

idn

312

Page 323: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX D Following Steindel (1995), GDP measured by the fixed-weights method is given

in my model by ∑∑ −−=≡i

iiii

iiF nApKYpGDP 0110 ββ

βα

η (where I used the prices in

manufacturing terms in as fixed sector-weights; however, any other fixed

weights could be used here). This equation implies that effects (2) and (3) (and

(4)) do not offset each other regarding GDP-growth (since

0=t

∑∑ =i i

iiM

iiii A

nAAnAp 000 ). That is, changes in have an impact on the growth rate

of . Hence, my discussion in section 4.2 implies that in my model

offshoring influences -growth via channel (3).

in

FGDP

FGDP

I study the impacts of offshoring on chain-weighted GDP-growth in my model by

using the following example: Assume that we want to calculate the growth rate of

chain-weighted GDP between two points in time (e.g. 1=t and ). Define 2=t

∑∑ −−=≡i

iiii

ii nApKYpY 11111 ββ

βα

η and ∑∑ −−=≡i

iiii

ii nApKYpY 21122 ββ

βα

η , where

and denote respectively the prices of goods i in 1ip 2

ip 1=t and . Following

Steindel (1995), the growth rate of chain-weighted GDP between and

is given by:

2=t

1=t 2=t

(D.1)

⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜

++−

+−

=⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+≡

∑∑

∑∑

••

iiii

iiii

iiii

iiii

C

C

nAp

nAp

nAp

nApgg

YY

YY

GDPPDG

2

2

1

1

*2

2

1

1 )()(

21

1121

ηββ

βα&&&

Hence, we can see that factor reallocation (via ) has an impact on -

growth, i.e. the effects (2) and (3) (and (4)) do not offset each other regarding

in CGDP

313

Page 324: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

CGDP -growth. Thus, we know from the discussion in section 4.2 that offshoring

influences -growth via channel (3). CGDP

314

Page 325: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX E Assume that production functions are given by the following equation:

(4a) iZzKknAY iiiiiiiii ∀= −− ,)()()( 1 βαβα

This equation implies that input-elasticities of output differ across sectors.

Footnote 11 implies that the price of a good is given by:ii

MM

i

i

M

Mi Y

nnYp

βαβα

−−−−

=1

1 .

Hence, equations (14) and (17) imply that

(19b) ∑

−−−

−−=

Mii

i ii

i

MMM n

n

YY11

)1(βα

βα

Note that this equation can be restructured further (i.e. the growth path of

could be derived as function of exogenous parameters in the optimum); in this

respect see the paper by Kongsamut et al. (1997) and the paper by Acemoglu and

Guerrieri (2008) as well. However, for our purposes the function in (19b) is

sufficient: we can see now that the allocation of labor across sectors (via ) has

an impact on Y. That is, structural change has an impact o the growth-rate of Y,

i.e. the effects (2), (3) and (4) do not offset each other regarding Y-growth. Hence,

the discussion in section 4.2 implies that offshoring has a “final” impact on Y-

growth when output-elasticities differ across sectors.

MY

in

315

Page 326: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

APPENDIX F Theorem 1 and equation (21) imply that the following relation is true along the

PBGP:

(F.1) ρδα −−=KYg *

This equation can be rearranged as follows:

(F.2) ρδαδδ

+++

=+ *

** )()(

gg

YKg

The first derivative of ρδαδ

+++

*

* )(g

g with respect to is given by *g

(F.3) 0

)(

**

*

*

>++

=∂

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛++

+∂

ρδαρρδ

αδ

ggg

g

Equations (F.2) and (F.3) and Theorem 3 imply that offshoring increases

YKg )( *+δ provided that 0>− T

I

I gpp& . Q.E.D.

316

Page 327: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

LIST OF SYMBOLS of PART II of CHAPTER V iA Parameter indicating technology/productivity level of sector i.

(exogenous)

FIA Productivity parameter in sector I in the foreign country.

0iA Level of at initial point of time of the model. iA

C Aggregate consumption expenditures; index of overall consumption-

expenditures of the representative household

iC Consumption of subsector-i-output; indicates how much of the output of

subsector i is consumed.

E Aggregate exports.

GDP Real GDP.

CGDP Real GDP measured the chain-weights method.

FGDP Real GDP measured by the fixed weights method.

H Aggregate value of all intermediates that are used in production.

K Aggregate capital; i.e. the amount of capital that is used for production in

the whole economy.

T Ratio of exports to imports associated with offshoring.

U Life-time utility of the (representative) household.

X Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous model-parameters.)

Y Aggregate output; index of economy-wide output-volume.

iY Output of sector i.

1Y Y at t =1

2Y Y at t = 2.

NY Aggregate net-output. Aggregate output minus aggregate value of

intermediates.

317

Page 328: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

NiY Net-output of sector i. Value of (gross-)output of sector i minus value of

intermediate inputs that sector i uses.

Z Index of intermediate production. Indicates how much intermediate inputs

are used in the whole economy.

a Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

b Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

Me Export of sector-M-goods.

*g Growth rate of aggregates along the PBGP.

ig Growth rate of total factor-productivity in sector i.

Tg Growth rate of T.

ηg Growth rate of η .

Fh Intermediates produced abroad.

Ih Intermediates produced by sector I in the home country.

i Index denoting a sector.

ik Capital-share of sector i; indicates which share of aggregate capital (K) is

used in sector i.

in Employment-share of sector i; indicates which share of aggregate labor is

used in sector i.

0in Level of at initial point of time of the model. in

p Price-index (“deflator”).

318

Page 329: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

ip Relative price of good i, where good M is numéraire. Indicates how many

units of good M can be obtained for one unit of good i on the market.

0ip Level of at initial point of time of the model. ip

1ip at t = 1. ip

2ip at t = 2. ip

FIp (relative) price of I in the foreign country.

t Index denoting time.

(.)u Instantaneous utility-function.

ix Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous model-parameters; grows at

constant rate.)

iz Intermediate-share of subsector i; indicates which share of intermediate

input-index (Z) is used in sector i.

α Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to output-

elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

β Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to output-

elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

δ Depreciation rate on capital (K). (exogenous)

ε (relative) price elasticity of demand. (exogenous)

ρ Time-preference rate. (exogenous)

iω Parameter of the utility function; closely related to the utility of . iC

ϕ Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas-intermediate-index; indicates the elasticity

of Z with respect to . (exogenous) Ih

319

Page 330: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

320

Page 331: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

321

PART III of CHAPTER V

A PBGP-Framework for Analyzing the Impacts of Ageing on Structural Change and real GDP-growth

Ageing (i.e. an increase in the old-to-young-ratio) leads to demand-shifts (and

thus to factor-reallocation) across sectors, since demand-patterns differ across the

“old” and the “young”. As a result, ageing has an impact on GDP-growth and thus

on old-age-pension-to-output-ratios, depending on the technological attributes of

these sectors. This relationship is neglected by standard (one-sector-)frameworks.

I show in a theoretical model that a rich portfolio of parameters determines the

non-monotonous dynamics of this relationship, implying that the future

challenges by ageing may vary significantly across countries and across time.

Moreover, my model provides potential policy-channels for reducing the negative

impacts of ageing.

Again, I modify the reference-model from Section 1 of Chapter III to adapt it to

the topic that is analyzed. The resulting model is a multi-sector Ramsey-Cass-

Koopmans model. I will discuss these modifications in detail later; however, here

are some short explanations: For simplicity, I restrict the number of technologies

to only two. I introduce another preference-structure; especially, I introduce some

exogenous and income-independent demand shifts to model ageing-related

demand-shifts. Furthermore, I introduce some intermediate structures and use a

GDP-measure similar to the one used in essay on offshoring (PART II of Chapter

V). Note that I present here two models: In contrast to the complex version of my

ageing-model, the simpler version features identical capital-intensity across

sectors. This makes the model much simpler and maybe easier to understand.

However, the more complex version has much richer dynamics and implications.

Page 332: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

322

TABLE OF CONTENTS for PART III of CHAPTER V

1. Introduction .................................................................................................... 323

2. Model assumptions ......................................................................................... 330

2.1 Utility........................................................................................................ 330

2.2 Production................................................................................................. 333

2.3 Numéraire ................................................................................................. 335

2.4 Aggregates and sectors ............................................................................. 337

3. Model equilibrium .......................................................................................... 338

3.1 Optimality conditions ............................................................................... 338

3.2 Aggregates ................................................................................................ 339

3.3 Sectors ...................................................................................................... 342

4. Effects of ageing............................................................................................. 343

4.1 Partially Balanced Growth Path (PBGP) without ageing......................... 344

4.2 Ageing and cross-sector differences in TFP-growth ................................ 347

4.3 Ageing and cross-sector differences in input-elasticities ......................... 352

4.3.1 Productivity effect: Impacts and channels......................................... 353

4.3.2 Additional impacts on GDP: The price-effect................................... 359

4.3.2.1 Transitional effects of ageing on GDP ....................................... 359

4.3.2.2 PBGP-effects of ageing .............................................................. 366

4.3.3 Dynamic aspects ................................................................................ 367

5. Concluding remarks........................................................................................ 368

APPENDIX A..................................................................................................... 373

APPENDIX B..................................................................................................... 379

APPENDIX C..................................................................................................... 380

APPENDIX D..................................................................................................... 390

LIST OF SYMBOLS of PART III of CHAPTER V.......................................... 391

Page 333: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

323

1. Introduction Ageing, a term which in general refers to an increasing life span of an average

member of a society, is a recurrent topic on the economic agenda. It has already

had some major impacts on the economic environment (e.g. there have been some

major changes in the pension and health systems of some industrialized

economies) and it is regarded as one of the trends which (will) have major

impacts on economic and social structures in (industrialized) economies in

present and in the future. Hence, it is not surprising that there is a large body of

literature dealing with several aspects of ageing. (For an overview of models

dealing with ageing and economic growth see, e.g., Gruescu (2007); for a shorter

discussion of these growth-effects see, e.g., Mc Morrow and Röger (2003); an

overview of related empirical studies is provided by, e.g., Groezen et al. (2005).)

In this paper I focus on an impact channel of ageing which seems to be rarely

studied in this literature (at least there seems to be a shortage of theoretical

models that analyze the following relationship): I analyze the impacts of ageing-

induced demand-shifts on factor-allocation across technologically distinct sectors

and their consequences for GDP-growth and old-age-pension-to-output ratios.

The working hypothesis is the following: An increase in the relative share of the

“old” in an economy changes the structure of aggregate demand, since the “old”

have another structure of demand in comparison to the “young”. If there are some

differences in technologies between sectors that produce the goods for the old and

sectors that produce the goods for the young, there may arise some effects on

aggregate productivity growth and thus on GDP-growth and pension-to-output-

ratios. (I name this whole line of arguments “factor-allocation-effects of ageing”).

In other words, ageing-induced changes in aggregate demand may cause some

cross-technology factor-reallocation, hence causing changes in aggregate (or:

Page 334: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

324

average) productivity growth. Thus, the increasing old-age pension payments

(due to the increasing number of recipients) are confronted with changes in the

growth rate of the tax-base, which may require changes in the old-age-pension

system.

This line of arguments seems to be quite obvious, especially when thinking of

services, like health care services and geriatric nursing services: in general, the

“old” demand more of such services in comparison to the “young”; furthermore,

the “production process” of these services is regarded to be technologically

distinct (i.e. relatively labor-intensive) in comparison to e.g. manufacturing goods

(see also IMF (2004), chapter 3, and especially p. 159). However, there are also

some other differences in demand between the old and the young, e.g. the young

have a relatively larger demand for commodities and investment goods (e.g.

housing, car and furniture, i.e. things that the old may already have). Furthermore,

in general, the old seem to spend a larger share of budget on services (see

Groezen et al. (2005)).

Empirical evidence on such differences in demand patterns between the old and

the young and their growing importance (not only for factor reallocation across

sectors) has been presented by, e.g., Börsch-Supan (1993, 2003), Fuchs (1998)

and Fougère et al. (2007). Furthermore, empirical evidence implies that there are

strong differences in technology across products/sectors (e.g. when comparing

services and manufactured products or health care services and commodities

production): Evidence on differences in TFP-growth across sectors/products has

been presented by, e.g., Baumol et al. (1985) and Bernard and Jones (1996).

Evidence on differences in capital intensities across sectors has been presented

by, e.g., Close and Schulenburger (1971), Kongsamut et al. (1997), Gollin (2002),

Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) and Valentinyi and Herrendorf (2008). Nordhaus

Page 335: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

325

(2008) presents some evidence on the relevance of cross-sector reallocations for

aggregate growth. Overall, this (partly indirect) evidence on factor-allocation-

effects of ageing seems to provide sufficient incentive to take a look at their

relevance from a theoretical perspective.

My model is related to the theoretical literature that postulates the importance of

cross-sector technology-differences for GDP-growth, e.g. Baumol (1967) and

Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008). Baumol (1967) claims that cross-sector

differences in (labor-)productivity-growth can cause (by themselves) a GDP-

growth-slowdown via relative price changes (“Baumol’s cost disease”). However,

Baumol (1967) does not analyze (ageing-induced) demand-shifts, and he makes

as well some simplifying assumptions (e.g. he excludes capital accumulation)

which may be not accurate for my goals as we will see later. Acemoglu and

Guerrieri (2008) show that cross-sector differences in capital-intensities have an

impact on aggregate growth. However, they as well do not include (ageing-

induced) demand-shifts into their analysis. Furthermore, Rausch (2006) provides

a two-sector Heckscher-Ohlin model with ageing, where ageing leads to an

increase in the savings rate, since the old have relatively larger amounts of assets.

He argues that ageing leads to changes in the relative sector-size (and thus in

GDP-growth), provided that sectors differ by capital intensity (see Rausch (2006),

pp. 20 ff.). He as well does not take account of the impacts of ageing-induced

demand-shifts.

To my knowledge, the model by Groezen et al. (2005) is the only one that

explicitly includes ageing-induced demand-shifts into analysis, where ageing is

incorporated into a two-sector overlapping-generations model. The old consume

the output of a sector that uses only labor as input. Furthermore, there is no

productivity growth in this sector. The young consume the output of a progressive

Page 336: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

326

sector that uses capital and labor as input factors. Furthermore, this sector

“produces” capital and endogenous technological progress which increases its

productivity with time. Groezen et al. (2005) show the importance of the elasticity

of substitution between capital and labor in the progressive sector. If this

elasticity is equal to unity, ageing has no impacts on growth in their model.

However, if this elasticity is greater (smaller) than unity, ageing has a negative

(positive) impact on growth.

I focus here on the pure factor-allocation-effects of ageing, i.e. I analyze the

impacts of ageing on GDP-growth and on the pension-to-output-ratios via factor

reallocation, ceteris paribus. That is, I do not try to analyze which endogenous

growth effects alternative allocations of factors may have (this question has

already been analyzed in part by Groezen et al. (2005)); hence, I keep the TFP-

growth-rates exogenous. Furthermore, I keep the elasticity of substitution

between capital and labor equal to unity, since, as just mentioned, the effects of

non-unitary substitution-elasticity have already been analyzed adequately by

Groezen et al. (2005). Moreover, I do not use an overlapping-generations model

but a Ramsey-model, since the effects of ageing in overlapping generations

models are well known from the previous literature; especially the reallocation

effects of ageing in an overlapping generations model are known from Groezen et

al. (2005). The Ramsey-model is analytically much more convenient regarding

the questions which are in my focus. In some respect, these simplifying

assumptions allow us to elaborate more exactly which (further/new) parameters

and technological specificities are relevant for the reallocation-effects of ageing,

i.e. I can model the sector that produces the goods for the old in a more realistic

way: its productivity increases due to technological progress and it uses capital,

labor and intermediates as inputs. My model is a sort of disaggregated Ramsey-

Page 337: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

327

model1 where the representative household(s) consume(s) two groups of goods:

“senior-goods” (i.e. goods that are primarily consumed by “older” people) and

“junior-goods” (i.e. goods that are primarily consumed by younger people).

Ageing (i.e. an increasing ratio of old-to-young) yields an increasing weight of

senior-needs in the aggregate utility function, hence leading to a demand-shift in

direction of senior-goods. I assume that the production of senior-goods and the

production of junior-goods differ by TFP-growth and by capital-intensity (i.e.

output-elasticity of inputs), according to the empirical evidence discussed above.

Moreover, I include intermediates production into the model; this allows for

linkages between senior- and junior-goods-production which have been stated to

be important by Fougère et al. (2007) and by Kuhn (2004).

In my model ageing has three effects regarding GDP-growth:

(1) The ageing-induced demand-shift alters the factor allocation across

technologically distinct sectors, which yields to a direct productivity effect

(average factor-productivities change).

(2) This productivity effect has also an impact on GDP-growth via capital

accumulation (change in the savings rate). This effect is similar to the effect of a

productivity-increase in the standard one-sector Ramsey-model: a change in

productivity leads to a change in the opportunity costs of consumption, since

return on savings depends on productivity of capital (remember that savings are

invested in capital). Note that the change in the savings rate in my model is not

the same as the ageing-induced savings-change in other ageing-models (e.g. in the

model by Rausch (2006)). In these models the effect of ageing on the savings rate

is modeled as a direct effect (“more saving for retirement”).

1 For discussion of the standard (one-sector) Ramsey-model, see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004).

Page 338: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

328

(3) Since the ageing-induced demand-shift leads to changes of sectoral output-

shares, the average price-index (which is the weighted average of sector prices)

changes as well. Hence, ageing leads to changes in the GDP-deflator (average

price index), which has an impact on the (real-)GDP as well.

If the change in GDP-growth is negative, there is additional upward-pressure on

the old-age-pension-to-output ratio. (Remember that upward pressure on the old-

age-pension-to-output-ratio comes from an increasing number of pension-

recipients as well).

I show that the strength and the direction of the factor-allocation-effects of ageing

depend on the combination of several parameters, including

• technology parameters, e.g. sectoral TFP-growth-rates and (initial) TFP-levels

as well as input-elasticities of sectoral production functions (including

intermediates-elasticities, which supports Fougère et al. (2007) and Kuhn

(2004)),

• parameters determining the savings rate (due to effect (2)), e.g. the time-

preference rate and

• population parameters (the old-to-young-ratio and the growth rate of working-

population).

Hence, the strength and direction of factor-allocation effects of ageing may vary

across countries according to their values of these parameters. Therefore, the fact

that empirical studies were not able to identify an unambiguous effect of ageing

on growth (see Groezen et al. (2005)) may come from the neglect of the

importance of cross-country differences in these parameters. Overall, my model

implies that the fact that capital intensity in the senior-sectors is relatively low is

not sufficient to constitute negative effects of ageing.

Page 339: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

329

In contrast to Groezen et al. (2005) I show that reallocation-effects of ageing

arise, even if the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor is equal to

unity and that the exact constellation of the parameters listed above determines

the direction of this effect. My results imply as well that the impact of ageing via

the savings rate, which is modeled by previous literature (e.g. by Rausch (2006)),

may be weakened or strengthened depending on the parameters listed above.

Furthermore, in contrast to the previous literature I show that the impacts of

ageing on GDP-growth may change over time, i.e. in the beginning ageing may

have a positive (negative) impact on GDP-growth and later the effect of ageing

may be negative (positive). Finally, my results imply that projections of future

GDP-growth and of future pension-system-challenges may be too optimistic. For

example, the paper by the Economic Policy Committee of the EU Commission

(2003) based on Mc Morrow and Röger (2003) (see there especially pp. 12 ff.)

does not include factor-reallocation-effects in its ageing-related projections.

Hence, the negative impacts of ageing may be stronger than expected by now and

the reforms of old-age-pension systems (and health-systems) may be too weak.

The rest of the paper is set up as follows: In sections 2 and 3 I present the

assumptions and the solution of my model. In section 4 I analyze the impacts of

ageing: first I describe the dynamics of the equilibrium without ageing (section

4.1); subsequently, I compare this equilibrium to the equilibrium with ageing,

where I present a simpler version of the model in section 4.2 (where only cross-

sector-differences in TFP-growth exist) and the more sophisticated version of the

model in section 4.3. Finally, I make some concluding remarks in section 5.

Page 340: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

330

2. Model assumptions

2.1 Utility I assume an economy where two groups of goods exist: “junior-goods” (goods

mi ,...1= ) and “senior-goods” (goods ),...1 nmi += . The representative household

consumes a mix of these goods and maximizes the following life-time utility

function (in the following I omit the time-indices):

(1) ∫∞

−=0

dtueU tρ

where

(2) SJ uNLu

NLu )1( −+=

(3) ⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−= ∏

=

m

iiiJ

iCu1

)(ln ωθ

(4) ⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−= ∏

+=

n

miiiS

iCu1

)(ln ωθ

(5a) ∑ ∑= +=

==m

i

n

miii

1 10,0 θθ

(5b) ∑ ∑= +=

==m

i

n

miii

1 1

1,1 ωω

(6) LNi gLLg

NNi ==∀<<

&&,,10 ω

where iC stands for consumption of good i and ρ is the time-preference rate. N

is an index of overall-population (including the young and the old) growing at

constant exogenous rate; L is an index of the young (working) population

growing at constant exogenous rate. Hence, the ratio NL / is an index of the

Page 341: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

331

share of the young as part of overall population, and a decreasing NL / can be

interpreted as ageing.

The utility function is based on the Stone-Geary-preferences, where the iθ s can

be respectively interpreted as the subsistence levels (if iθ > 0) or as levels of

home-production (if iθ < 0). The income-elasticity of demand differs across

goods; the price-elasticity of demand differs across goods as well and is not equal

to unity. (See also Kongsamut et al (1997, 2001) for the discussion of a similar

utility function.)

In fact this utility function introduces ageing induced demand shifts in the most

simple way. The utility function implies that ageing (a decreasing NL / ) makes

the consumption of senior-goods relatively more contributing to aggregate utility,

and, as we will see later, this leads to a shift of demand towards senior-goods. In

order to focus on the effects of ageing I introduce the restrictions (5a) and (5b). In

this way I ensure that there are no other shifts in demand between the junior and

senior sector, beside of those induced by ageing (a decreasing NL / ): Provided

that NL / is constant (no ageing), the demand for senior-goods and the demand

for junior-goods grow at the same rate, yielding no factor reallocations between

the senior- and the junior-sector. (Nevertheless, there are still demand shifts and

reallocations within these sectors, due to the iθ s.)

Alternatively, the functions Ju and Su could be assumed to be of type Cobb-

Douglas or CES. I chose Stone-Geary-preferences, since in this way I can add

additional sources of demand-shifts (others than ageing) by omitting the

restriction (5a) and (5b). This will be of importance later.

Note that there is a difference between demand-shifts, which are modeled in

standard structural change theory (e.g. in the paper by Kongsamut et al. (2001)),

Page 342: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

332

and ageing-induced demand shifts, which are modeled in my paper. In standard

structural change theory demand shifts are caused by differences in income-

elasticity of demand across goods. Hence, some repercussions arise: changes in

income -> demand shifts -> productivity impacts-> changes in income and so on.

This repercussion does not arise in my model. In my model the chain of impacts

is rather only in one direction: (income–independent) exogenous change in old-to-

young ratio -> demand shifts -> productivity impacts -> change in income. Of

course, one could postulate that changes in income are associated with changes in

old-to-young ratio to some extent (e.g. due to improvement in medicine or do to

some change in socio-cultural parameters which are associated with increasing

income). This would imply that changes in the old-to-young ratio are endogenous.

Although I believe that this is an interesting topic in general, a model with

endogenous old-to-young ratio would yield very similar results as the standard

structural change theory. The only difference would be that there is a further link

in the chain of impacts: income-change -> change in old-to-young ratio ->

demand shifts -> productivity impacts -> income-change and so on.

Therefore, we can summarize this discussion as follows: Ageing seems to cause

productivity-impacts via demand-shifts in two ways: On the one hand, it acts

similar like income-elasticity-differences across goods. This sort of impact is

modeled implicitly in standard structural change theory. On the other hand,

ageing acts like an exogenous shift in demand, which is income-independent.

This sort of impact is modeled in my paper. Hence, in my model I assume that

ageing arises due to some (from economist’s point of view) exogenous changes.

For example, some socio-cultural parameters change (e.g. change in religiosity,

emancipation) and/or some progress in medicine occurs independently of income

Page 343: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

333

level. Of course both factors depend on the income of a country to some extent;

however, they must have some income-independent timely component.

Note that I am not the only one that models ageing as exogenous shifts in

demand. For example, Groezen et al. (2005) models it in this way too. Overall,

there seems to be a research gap in this field, which may be interesting to fill.

2.2 Production According to the evidence discussed above, the senior-goods are not produced by

the same technology as junior-goods; the technologies differ by TFP-growth and

by output-elasticities of inputs (i.e. capital intensities differ between the senior-

and the junior-sector). Furthermore, I assume that only the young supply labor on

the market; hence L (and not N) is input in production:

(7) miZzKkLlAY iiii ,...1,)()()( == γβα

(8) nmiZzKkLlBY iiii ,...1,)()()( +== μνχ

(9) BA gBBg

AA

==&&

,

(10) 1;1;1,,,,,0 =++=++<< μνχγβαμνχγβα

where iY denotes the output of sector i; K denotes the aggregate stock of capital;

Z is an index of intermediate inputs; ii kl , and iz denote respectively the fraction

of labor, capital and intermediates devoted to sector i; A and B are exogenous

technology parameters, where I assume that TFP-growth differs between the

junior- and the senior-sector.

Page 344: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

334

I assume that each sector’s output is consumed and used as intermediate input

)( ih ; only sector-m-output is used as capital:

(11) mihCY iii ≠∀+= ,

(12) KKhCY mmm δ+++= &

where δ is the depreciation rate of capital. Provided that it is assumed that

senior-goods are rather services, the assumption that only the junior-sector

produces capital seems to be consistent with empirical evidence which states that

nearly all capital goods are produced by the manufacturing sector (see e.g.

Kongsamut et al. (1997, 2001)).

The intermediate-inputs-index )(Z is a Cobb-Douglas function of sectoral

intermediate outputs ( ih ):

(13) ∑∏==

=∀<<=n

iii

n

ii ihZ i

11

1,10,)( εεε

Note that it is important to assume intermediates production within this model. In

general we can assume that the old and the young consume many goods that are

nearly the same (however, the manner of consumption is quite different). For

example, the young and the old consume food. However, while probably many

young cook the food by themselves, some very old consume the food by being

served in retirement homes or hospitals. Hence, although the old and the young

eat similar things, the share of services is larger in the consumption of the old. If

we did not assume some intermediate linkages between the junior and senior

Page 345: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

335

consumption goods we would not take account for the fact that the old are the

same human beings as the young (i.e. having the same basic needs). For example,

the assumption that the old and the young consume different goods (that have no

intermediate linkages) would e.g. imply that the old do not eat food. It would not

be necessary to take account for these facts if intermediates production were

irrelevant for the ageing-effects. However, as we will see, the output-elasticites of

intermediate inputs determine among others the strength of the ageing impacts via

structural change. Hence, we have to include intermediate linkages between

senior-goods and junior-goods into my model.

All labor, capital and intermediate inputs are used in production, i.e.

(14) ∑∑∑===

===n

ii

n

ii

n

ii zkl

1111;1;1

2.3 Numéraire Let ip denote the price of good i. I choose the output of sector m as numéraire.

Hence,

(15a) 1=mp

It should be noted here that in reality real GDP is calculated by using an average

price as GDP-deflator; i.e. in general a basket of all goods that have been

produced is used as numéraire. (See also Ngai and Pissarides (2007), p. 435, and

Ngai and Pissarides (2004), p. 21.) I choose the manufacturing output as

numéraire, since in this way I can analyze the equilibrium growth paths in the

most convenient manner. Nevertheless, I will always calculate the GDP by using

Page 346: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

336

an average price deflator as well. I use the following compound deflator which

may be regarded as the theoretical mirror image of the deflators that are used to

calculate real GDP in reality:

(15b) ∑=

≡n

ii

N

Nii p

YYpp

1

where NiY and NY denote respectively the net-output of sector i and aggregate

net-output. “Net-output” means here gross-output minus real value of

intermediates inputs (which is equal to “real-value added”). Hence, NiY is given

by the following relation:

(15c) HzYpYp iiiN

ii −=

where H is the aggregate value of all intermediates that have been produced (see

later equation (18) as well). I use “net output”, since in reality GDP does not

include intermediates production in order to avoid “double counting of

intermediates production”. (See, e.g., Landefeld et al. (2008) on intermediate

inputs and GDP. Furthermore, the relationship between gross-output and net-

output in my model can be seen in equation (A.25) from APPENDIX A and

equations (16).)

Overall, my GDP-deflator (equation (15b)) is simply a weighted-average of

prices, where I used net-outputs as weights. If we divide our aggregate net-output

(expressed in manufacturing terms) by this deflator we have a GDP-measure that

is similar to that used in reality. However, all the issues regarding the choice of

the numéraire are irrelevant when looking at shares or ratios (since the changes

Page 347: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

337

in the numéraire of the numerator offset the changes in the (same) numéraire of

the denominator). For example, the capital-to-output ratio ( NYK / ) is the same

irrespective of the numéraire. (See also Ngai and Pissarides (2007), p. 435 and

Ngai and Pissarides (2004), p. 21.)

2.4 Aggregates and sectors I define aggregate (gross-)output (Y ), aggregate net-output ( NY ), real GDP

(GDP ), aggregate consumption expenditures (E) and aggregate value of

intermediate inputs ( H ) as follows:

(16a) ∑=

≡n

iiiYpY

1

(16b) HYYN −≡

(16c) p

YGDP N≡

(17) ∑=

≡n

iiiCpE

1

(18) ∑=

≡n

iiihpH

1

Throughout the paper I use aggregate net-output instead of aggregate (gross-

)output (Y), since in general GDP does not include intermediates. (In my model Y

is equal to the sum of investment, consumption and intermediates-value (H); see

equation (A.25) in APPENDIX A.)

The aggregate labor share of the junior-sector )( Jl and the aggregate labor share

of the senior-sector )( Sl are given by:

Page 348: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

338

(19) ∑∑+==

≡≡n

miiS

m

iiJ llll

11

The aggregate consumption expenditures on junior-goods ( JE ) and senior-goods

)( SE are given by:

(20) ∑∑+==

≡≡n

miiiS

m

iiiJ CpECpE

11

SE could also be interpreted as the budget devoted to the old. Throughout the

paper I assume that the aggregate budget is distributed across the old and the

young according to the representative household utility function (social welfare

function). That is, budgets are such to maximize social welfare.

3. Model equilibrium

3.1 Optimality conditions The model, as specified in the previous section, can be solved by maximizing life-

time utility (equations (1)-(6)) subject to equations (7)-(15a), e.g. by using a

Hamiltonian function. The intra- and intertemporal optimality conditions are

(where I assume that there is free mobility of factors across sectors):

(21) ihZ

ZzY

ZzYZzY

KkYKkY

LlYLlYp

im

m

ii

mm

ii

mm

ii

mmi ∀

∂∂

∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

=∂∂∂∂

= ,)()(/

)(/)(/)(/

)(/)(/

(22) iCuCup

m

ii ∀

∂∂∂∂

= ,/(.)/(.)

(23) ρδ −−∂∂

=−)( Kk

Yuu

m

m

m

m&

Page 349: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

339

where mm Cuu ∂∂≡ /(.) . The proof that these conditions are necessary and

sufficient conditions for an optimum is analogous to the corresponding proof in

the Kuznets-Kaldor-Puzzle essay (see there APPENDIX A).

By using equations (1)-(20) these optimality conditions (equations (21)-(23)) can

be transformed into the following equations (sections 3.2 and 3.3) describing the

aggregate and sectoral behavior of the economy (for a proof of these equations

see APPENDIX A):

3.2 Aggregates

(24) Kc

ggEKK G

Lc

mc

mˆ)

1(ˆˆ)(ˆ

−++−−+= − δβλαλ&

(25) c

ggKEE G

Lcc

m −−−−−= −−

ˆˆ

11 ρδβλ&

(26a) ανχβ

λαχββαλ−

−+−= − mc

mc vKY )()(ˆˆ

(26b) )(ˆˆm

cm

cN KY βλαλ += −

(26c)

αχγεμε

λαβανχβ

βνγεμε

λSS

cm

cSS

mK

ENL

+−

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −

−−+−

=−

1

ˆˆ

11

(26d) ανχβ

λαμχγβνγβμαλ−

−+−= − mc

mcKH )()(ˆˆ

(27) 1

2 )1()1()1()(ˆˆ−

−⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−

−−

−−++= Smmmc

mc pKPDG

ανχβμαβλβλαβλαλ

Page 350: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

340

where 1)1(1

)1(0 <

−−−+−

≡<μεεγγνεμεβ

SS

SSc , m

mm k

l≡λ , ∑

+=

≡n

miiS

1

εε , GGgG

&≡

SS

i

S

S

S n

iiBAG

μεεγγ

ε

εμνχεγ

με

εγγμ

βν

αχ

−−−

=

⎪⎭

⎪⎬⎫

⎪⎩

⎪⎨⎧

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛≡ ∏

)1(1

1

1

, and

[ ] )(1

)(1)()(

1

ˆαμγχεα

α

χεμγγαμγχεαανχβ

μαγχε

αμαναχ

λεγ

μγ

νβ

χα

−+−+−

−+−−

= ⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡ ∏

S

S

S

i

BAKp

m

n

iiS .

Definition 1: NYandPDGYEK ˆˆ,ˆ,ˆ,ˆ stand for NYandGDPYEK ,,, expressed in

“labor-efficiency-units, i.e. cLG

YY−

≡1

1ˆ ,

cLG

KK−

≡1

1ˆ ,

cLG

EE−

≡1

1ˆ ,

cLG

GDPPDG−

≡1

and c

NN

LG

YY−

≡1

1ˆ .

Note that this definition of variables in efficiency units makes my discussion

about the equilibrium growth path easier later.

Proposition 1: Sp stands for the price of senior goods. Sp is given by:

[ ] )(1

)(1)()(

1

ˆαμγχεα

α

χεμγγαμγχεαανχβ

μαγχε

αμαναχ

λεγ

μγ

νβ

χα

−+−+−

−+−−

= ⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡ ∏

S

S

S

i

BAKp

m

n

iiS

Proof: Remember that senior goods are produced by the same production

functions; hence each senior good has the same price, Sp . The rest of the proof is

given in APPENDIX A. Q.E.D.

Page 351: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

341

We can see that (beside of the GDP-measure) the optimum aggregate structure of

this economy is quite similar to the optimum structure of the standard Ramsey-

model (or sometimes also named “Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans model”). (For

discussion of the standard Ramsey-model, see e.g. Barro and Sala-i-Martin

(2004).) For a given mλ , equations (24)-(26b) determine the equilibrium savings

rate of the model (optimal intertemporal allocation of factors), like in the normal

Ramsey-model. (In fact, for mλ = 1 equations (24)-(26b) are the same as the

corresponding equations of the standard Ramsey-model). Equation (26c)

determines mλ as function of cross-sectors demand patterns (see also later

equations (30) and (31)). mλ can be regarded as a productivity indicator of

aggregate production: it captures the changes in aggregate productivity that are

caused by factor-reallocations across technologically distinct sectors (junior and

senior sector), since mλ depends only on the allocation of labor across the junior

and senior sectors: ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+= SJm llβχανλ .2 Furthermore, equation (26c) determines

the mλ that is consistent with the efficient (intratemporal) allocation of factors

across sectors, since equation (26c) can be derived from equations (14) and (21)

(among others); see as well the derivations in APPENDIX A. (Equations (14)

state that all factors must be used in production, i.e. no factors are wasted;

equation (26c) requires that marginal rates of technical substitution are equal

across sectors, i.e. factors are efficiently allocated across sectors.)

2 This equation can be derived by using equation (A.23) from APPENDIX A and equations (14) and (19).

Page 352: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

342

3.3 Sectors

(28) )(

)()(ανχβ

λαχβνβαδε−

−+−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ +++= m

JJ

J YKK

YH

YEl

&

(29) αχ

ανχβλαχβνβαε

)()()(

−−+−

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ += m

SS

S YH

YEl

(30) NLEEJ =

(31) ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −=

NLEES 1

(32a) m

m

i

i

lk

lk

χβαν

= for nmi ,...1+=

(32b) im

mi l

lk

k = for mi ,...1=

(33a) m

m

i

i

lz

lz

χγαμ

= for nmi ,...1+=

(33b) im

mi l

lz

z = for mi ,...1=

where ∑=

≡m

iiJ

1

εε .

For a proof of these equations see APPENDIX B.

We can see that ageing (i.e. changes in L/N) leads to demand shifts between the

junior- and the senior-sector (equations (30) and (31)). These demand shifts lead

to changes in factor allocation between these two sectors (here shown by changes

in employment shares; see equations (28) and (29)). Further factor-reallocation

between the senior- and the junior-sector is caused by changes in aggregate

capital demand (since only the junior-sector produces capital) and by changes in

aggregate intermediates demand.

Page 353: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

343

Proposition 2: Capital intensity (intermediates-intensity) is lower in the senior

sector in comparison to the capital-intensity (intermediates intensity) in the junior

sector, provided that χβαν < ( )χγαμ < .

Proof: Since capital intensity in a subsector i is given by iLlKk

i

i ∀, , and

intermediates intensity in a subsector i is given by iLlZz

i

i ∀, , equations (32) and

(33) imply this proposition. Q.E.D.

4. Effects of ageing To study the effects of ageing I compare the economy without ageing (L/N =

constant) to the economy with ageing (L/N decreases), ceteris paribus. In all the

following argumentation, ageing (i.e. a change in L/N or a change in N

LN − )

means that Ng changes and not Lg . That is, I assume that L is independent of

ageing (i.e. it grows at constant rate Lg irrespective of whether ageing takes place

or not). In this way I can clearly distinguish between growth-effects of ageing via

factor-reallocation (which are in the focus of my paper) and growth effects of

changes in labor supply (i.e. changes in the growth rate of L). The latter are well

known from standard (one-sector) models.

(Working)Definition 2: Ageing stands for an increase in N/L, where Lg is

constant.

Page 354: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

344

In the next section (4.1) I discuss the equilibrium without ageing. In section 4.2, I

analyze the effects of ageing in a simpler version of my model, where only cross-

sector-differences in TFP-growth are allowed for. In section 4.3 the effects of

ageing are analyzed in the general version of the model, where it is allowed for

cross-sector differences in input-elasticities as well.

4.1 Partially Balanced Growth Path (PBGP) without ageing In this subsection I assume that there is no ageing, i.e. L/N = constant.

Definition 3: A “partially balanced growth path” (“PBGP”) is an equilibrium

growth path where NYYEK ˆ ,ˆ,ˆ,ˆ and mλ are constant.

The name “partially balanced growth path” reflects the fact that along the PBGP

some variables ( NYEKY and ,, ) behave as if they were on a balanced growth

path (steady state), while the other variables (e.g. GDP) do not behave in this

manner, i.e. they grow at non-constant rates, as we will see soon. (This concept is

similar to the concept of “aggregate balanced growth”, which is used by Ngai and

Pissarides (2007).)

Lemma 1: There exists a unique PBGP of the dynamic equation system (24)-(26),

provided that L/N is constant.

Proof: It can be seen at first sight that equations (24)-(26) imply that there is an

equilibrium growth path where NYYEK ˆ ,ˆ,ˆ,ˆ and mλ are constant, provided that

L/N is constant. Q.E.D.

Page 355: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

345

Lemma 2: Along the PBGP, the growth rate of the variables NYEKY and ,, is

given by

(34) .)1(

)1(* constgggg LSS

BSAS =++−+−

=χγεαμε

γεμε

(where L/N is constant).

Proof: This lemma is implied by Definitions 1 and 3. Q.E.D.

Lemma 3: Along the PBGP, factors are not shifted between the senior- and the

junior-sector, i.e. Jl and Sl are constant, (where L/N is constant).

Proof: This lemma is implied by equations (28)-(31), by Definitions 1 and 3 and

by Lemma 2. Q.E.D.

Definition 4: An asterisk (*) denotes the PBGP-value of the corresponding

variable.

Now, I derive the PBGP-values of variables as functions of exogenous

parameters:

Lemma 4: Along the PBGP, the variables PDGYYEK Nˆ,ˆ ,ˆ,ˆ,ˆ and mλ are given

by the following functions of exogenous model parameters (where L/N is

constant)

(35a) *11

*ˆm

csK λ−=

(35b) *11

1*ˆm

ccc

ssE λρα −− +=

(35c) ανχβ

λαχββα−

−+−= −

*1* )()(ˆ mc

c vsY

Page 356: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

346

(35d) )(ˆ *1*m

cc

N sY βλα += −

(35e) s

NLN

NLN

S

S

m

βρανχβεμαχγα

ανχβεμβνγβ

βαλ

−−+−+

−−−−+

=)()(

)()(*

(35f) 1

***2*1* )1()1()1()(ˆ−

−⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−

−−

−−++= Smmmc

c

psPDGανχβμαβλβλαβλα

where

(35g)

[ ] )(1

)(1)()(

11

1

*

αμγχεα

α

χεμγγαμγχεαανχβ

μαγχε

αμαναχ

εγμγ

νβ

χα

−+−+−

−+−

= ⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛= ∏

S

S

S

i

BAsp c

n

iiS

(35h)

cg

gs

GL −+++

1ρδ

β .

Proof: To determine the PBGP-values of NYYEK ˆ ,ˆ,ˆ,ˆ and mλ we have to set

0ˆ =K& and 0ˆ =E& (because of Definition 3). Then equations (24)-(27) imply

Lemma 4. Remember that in this section L/N is constant. Q.E.D.

Lemma 5: The young-to-old ratio (NL ) has an impact on the PBGP-levels of

aggregate variables ***** ˆ,ˆ ,ˆ,ˆ,ˆ PDGYYEK N and *mλ (where L/N is constant).

Proof: This lemma is implied by equations (35). Q.E.D..

Lemma 6: *ˆPDG does not grow at constant rate along the PBGP (even when N/L

is constant).

Page 357: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

347

Proof: This lemma is implied by (35f). Note that equation (35g) implies that *Sp

is not constant along the PBGP. Q.E.D.

Lemma 6 shows a quite convenient feature of my model: we can study the rich

dynamics of the GDP (where the reallocation-effects of ageing cause unbalanced-

growth of GDP) while the other variables are on a (partially) balanced growth

path (partial steady state). This fact makes it possible to analyze the impacts of

ageing without simulations.

Lemma 7a: A saddle-path, along which the economy converges to the PBGP,

exists in the neighbourhood of the PBGP of the dynamic equation system (24)-

(26).

Lemma 7b: If intermediates are omitted (i.e. if 0== μγ ), the PBGP of the

dynamic equation system (24)-(26) is locally stable.

Proof: see APPENDIX C.

Corollary 1: Even if the initial capital level is not given by equation (35a), the

economy (which is described by the aggregate equation system (24)-(26))

converges to the PBGP, provided that L/N is constant.

Proof: This corollary follows from Lemmas 1, 4 and 7. Q.E.D.

4.2 Ageing and cross-sector differences in TFP-growth In this subsection I provide a simpler version of my model, which is helpful to

understand the general mechanism which leads to the reallocation effects of

Page 358: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

348

ageing. I assume now that input-elasticities are equal across sectors, i.e.

νβχα == , and thus μγ = . Furthermore, I assume that ageing takes place.

Lemma 8: If νβχα == , and thus μγ = , equations (24)-(35) become:

(24)’ Kc

ggEKK G

Lc ˆ)

1(ˆˆ)(ˆ

−++−−+= δβα&

(25)’ c

ggK

EE G

Lc

−−−−−= −

ˆˆ

1 ρδβ&

(26a)’ cKY ˆˆ =

(26b)’ )(ˆˆ βα += cN KY

(26c)’ 1=mλ

(26d)’ YYYH Nˆˆˆˆ γ=−=

(27)’ 1

1)(ˆˆ−

⎥⎦⎤

⎢⎣⎡ −++=

BBAlKPDG S

c βα

(28)’ ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ +++=

YKK

YH

NL

YEl JJ

δε&

(29)' ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+⎟

⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −= SS Y

HNL

YEl ε1

(34)' LBSAS g

ggg +

+−=

αγεγε )1(*

(35a)’ csK −= 11

(35b)’ ccc

ssE −− += 11

1*ˆ ρα

(35c)’ cc

sY −= 1*ˆ

(35d)' )(ˆ 1* βα += −cc

N sY

Page 359: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

349

(35f)' 1

1* 1)(1)(ˆ−

⎭⎬⎫

⎩⎨⎧

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+⎟

⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −+

−++= S

cc

NLs

BBAsPDG γεραβα

where 10 <+

=<βα

βc , βαβα

εε

βα εγ+−−

=

+

⎪⎭

⎪⎬⎫

⎪⎩

⎪⎨⎧

⎥⎦⎤

⎢⎣⎡≡ ∏

1

1

1 n

ii

i

S

ABAG .

Proof: The proof is quite straight-forward. Therefore, I omit it here. Note that

following steps are necessary to obtain equation (27)’: By inserting equation

(26c) into equation (27). the following equation can be obtained:

[ ] 1

2 )1)(1(/1

)/ˆ/(ˆ/)()(ˆˆ−

−⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−−

+−−−

−++= SSS

cmS

mmc

mc pKENLNKPDG μ

αχγεμελγεβλαβλαλ

This term can be reformulated by using the other equations to obtain

[ ][ ] 1)/1(ˆ/ˆ/)(1)(ˆˆ −

−−+−+= BAYENLNKPDG Sc γεβα . Then, by using

equations (26d)’ and (29)’, equation (27)’ can be derived. Q.E.D..

Lemma 9: If input-elasticities are equal across sectors, there exists a unique

PBGP, irrespective of whether ageing takes place or not, and irrespective of the

rate of ageing.

Proof: Lemma 8 implies that equations (24)’-(26)’ apply here. The proof of

Lemma 9 can be seen directly from equations (24)’-(26c)’, which are nearly the

same as in the standard one-sector Ramsey model. Since equations (24)’-(26)’

are not dependent on L/N, the existence of the PBGP is not affected by changes in

L/N. Q.E.D.

Lemma 10: If input-elasticities are equal across sectors, the growth rate of the

variables NYEKY and ,,, is given by equation (34)’ along the PBGP.

Page 360: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

350

Proof: This lemma is implied by Lemma 8 and Definitions 1 and 3. Q.E.D.

Lemma 11: If input elasticities are equal across sectors, the PBGP is globally

saddle-path stable, irrespective of whether ageing takes place or not.

Proof: Lemma 8 implies that equations (24)’-(26)’ apply. Equations (24)’ and

(25)’ are the same as in the standard Ramsey-model regarding all relevant

features. Therefore, the aggregate system of my model behaves like the standard

Ramsey-model, i.e. it is globally saddle-path stable. (See also Ngai and Pissarides

(2007) on the stability of such frameworks.). Since equations (24)’-(26)’ are

independent of L/N, ageing has no impact on the stability of the PBGP. Q.E.D.

Corollary 2: When input-elasticities are equal across sectors, ageing is irrelevant

regarding the development of the variables NYandEKY ,,, in my model: Neither

the PBGP-growth rate *g nor the PBGP-levels **** ˆ andˆ,ˆ,ˆNYYEK are affected

by (the level or the growth rate of) L/N. A change in L/N does not induce a

deviation from the (initial) PBGP with respect to NYandEKY ,,, .

Proof: This corollary is implied by Lemmas 8-10 and equations (35). Q.E.D.

Now we take a look at the disaggregated variables of the economy.

Theorem 1: If input-elasticities are equal across sectors, ageing shifts demand

from the junior-sectors to the senior-sectors along the PBGP. That is, decreases

in L/N lead to decreases in EEJ / and increases in EES / .

Page 361: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

351

Proof: This theorem is implied by equations (30) and (31). Remember that, as

argued in section 2, the choice of the numéraire is irrelevant when looking at

shares or ratios. Q.E.D.

Theorem 2: If input-elasticities are equal across sectors, ageing reallocates

factors from the junior-sectors to the senior-sectors along the PBGP; i.e.

decreases in L/N lead to decreases in Jl and increases in Sl .

Proof: This theorem is implied by Lemma 8 and equations (28)’ and (29)’.

Q.E.D.

Theorem 3: If input elasticities are equal across sectors, ageing reduces the

growth rate of GDP along the PBGP, provided that the TFP-growth rate (and the

TFP-level) is lower in the senior sector in comparison to the junior sector. That

is, a decreasing L/N causes a reduction of the GDP-growth rate, provided that

A>B and BA gg > .

Proof: This theorem is implied by Lemma 8 and equation (35f)’. Q.E.D.

Corollary 3: If input-elasticities are equal across sectors, ageing shifts demand

from the junior-sectors to the senior-sector. These demand shift cause factor

reallocation from the junior-sector to the senior-sector. This reallocation process

reduces the growth rate of GDP provided that the senior-sector has a relatively

low TFP(growth-rate) in comparison to the senior sector.

Proof: This corollary is implied by Theorems 1-3. Q.E.D.

Page 362: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

352

Hence, whether ageing increases or decreases the GDP-growth-rate depends only

on the TFP-relation between the junior and senior sectors. The factors, which

determine the strength of the ageing-impact, are analyzed in the next section.

As argued in section 2, the choice of the numéraire is irrelevant when looking at

shares or ratios. Hence, we can analyze the senior-goods-consumption-to-output

ratio ( NS YE / ) without worrying about numéraire choice. The share of senior-

budget in aggregate output ( NS YE / ) increases at the same rate as the old-to-

young ratio (see equation (31) and remember that along the PBGP E and NY grow

at the same rate).

All the results from this section are valid for the case that the budget devoted to

seniors (e.g. old age pensions) develops according to the social welfare function

(representative household utility function). If however political issues led to a

reduction of old age pensions, the ageing-impacts would be weaker. We will

discuss this case later.

4.3 Ageing and cross-sector differences in input-elasticities Now let us assume that input-elasticities differ across sectors, i.e. νβχα ≠≠ ,

and μγ ≠ . (The TFP-growth rates differ across sectors as well.) Furthermore, in

this paper I analyze only the case where the capital intensity in the senior sector is

lower in comparison to the junior sector (i.e. χβαν < ), since this case is in

general assumed in the literature (see also Proposition 2). I assume that initially

the economy is in the equilibrium described in section 4.1 with L/N = constant. In

sections 4.3.1 and 4.3.2 I analyze what happens if there is a one time decrease in

Page 363: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

353

L/N (according to Definition 2). (After this decrease L/N is constant again.) In

section 4.3.3 I generalize my results to the case where L/N increases

consecutively. Furthermore, in section 4.3.1 I analyze the effects of ageing on net-

output and on the pension-to-output ratio and I derive the impact channels,

whereas in section 4.3.2 I look at the differences in this analysis when my GDP-

measure is taken into account.

4.3.1 Productivity effect: Impacts and channels In this subsection the term “aggregates” refers only to EYY N ,, and K but not to

GDP.

Lemma 12: A one time decrease in L/N leads to a change of the PBGP. That is,

the economy leaves the old PBGP and there is a transition period where the

economy converges to the new PBGP. The growth rate of aggregates ( *g ) is the

same along the old and the new PBGP.

Proof: Remember that I assume here again that the input-elasticities differ across

sectors; hence equations (24)-(35) apply here. Equations (35) imply that there

must be a transition period, since the old and the new PBGP require different

equilibrium capital levels; i.e. *K depends on L/N. (That is, the capital level that

exists when the decrease in L/N occurs, is not the same as the capital level that

brings the economy directly on the new PBGP; we know from the discussion of

the standard one-sector Ramsey-model that this induces a transition period, where

the economy is converging to the new PBGP.) Furthermore, Lemma 7 and

Corollary 1 imply that the economy will converge to the new PBGP (provided

that the decrease in L/N is not too strong). Equation (34) implies that the growth

Page 364: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

354

rate of aggregates ( *g ) is the same along the old and the new PBGP, since *g

does not depend on L/N. Q.E.D.

Lemma 13: A one-time decrease in L/N reduces the growth rate of aggregates

during the transition period between the old and the new PBGP. That is, the

growth-rate of aggregates ( NYandEK ,, ) during the transition period is lower

in comparison to the growth rate of aggregates along the (old and new) PBGP

( *g ).

Proof: To prove this lemma we need the following derivatives of equations (35).

(Note that my key results would not change, if I calculated here elasticities

instead of derivatives.)

(36a) 0ˆ

11

*

*

>=∂∂ −c

m

sKλ

(36b) 0ˆ

11

*

*

>=∂∂ −c

m

sE ρλ

(36c) ανχβαχβ

λ −−

=∂∂ − )(ˆ

1*

*c

c

m

sY

(36d) 0ˆ

1*

*

>=∂∂ −c

c

m

N sY βλ

(36e) 0

)()(

)()()( 2

*

<

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡ −−+−+

−++−+−−=

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −∂

sN

LN

ss

NLN

S

SSm

βρανχβεμαχγα

βρεμβγνρεμαχγα

βαανχβ

λ

Page 365: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

355

From these equations we can see that a one-time decrease in L/N leads to a

decrease in *mλ . The decrease in *

mλ leads to a decrease in *** ˆ and ,ˆ,ˆNYEK .3

Hence, the values of *** ˆ and ,ˆ,ˆNYEK along the new PBGP are lower in

comparison to those of the old PBGP. Therefore, we can conclude that

*** ˆ and ,ˆ,ˆNYEK decrease during the transition period. Hence, the growth rate of

aggregates ( NYEK and , ) during the transition period is lower than *g .

(Remember that Definitions 1 and 3 and Lemma 2 imply the following: if

*** ˆ and ˆ,ˆNYEK are constant, aggregates ( NYEK and , ) grow at the constant rate

*g ; hence, if *** ˆ and ˆ,ˆNYEK decrease, the growth rate of NYEK and , is lower

than *g . Note that this argumentation works, since “efficiency units” are the same

along the old and the new PBGP: I express the variables in efficiency units (see

Definition 1) as follows: e.g. cLG

YY−

≡1

1ˆ ; since cLG −1

1

does not change due to

ageing, efficiency units are the same along the old and the new PBGP.) Q.E.D.

I will discuss the intuition behind this lemma soon; at first I postulate two lemmas

which are helpful to understand Lemma 13.

Lemma 14: A one-time decrease in L/N shifts demand from the junior-sector to

the senior-sector. That is, along the new PBGP EES is higher (

EEJ is lower) in

comparison to the EES (

EEJ ) of the old PBGP.

3 Note that the effects of ageing on aggregate gross-output Y may be positive or negative depending on the sign of the term αχ − . This reflects the fact that depending on the input-elasticities ageing can lead to an increase in intermediates production that is stronger than the decrease in net-output and vice versa.

Page 366: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

356

Proof: This lemma is implied by equations (30) and (31). Q.E.D.

Lemma 15: A one-time decrease in L/N leads to factor reallocation from the

junior-sector to the senior-sector. That is, along the new PBGP Sl is higher in

comparison to the Sl of the old PBGP.

Proof: By using equation (A.23) from APPENDIX A; it can be shown that the

employment share along the PBGP is given by ανχβ

χβλ−

−= )1( **mSl . Since

equation (36e) implies that 01

*

<⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −∂

NL

mλ , a decrease in L/N leads to a decrease in

*

mλ . Therefore, *Sl increases due to a decrease in L/N. (Remember that I assume

that 0>−ανχβ .) Q.E.D.

Now, I discuss the intuition behind Lemma 13: We know that output is produced

by using labor and capital. Ageing shifts demand (and thus production factors)

towards senior-sectors (as implied by Lemmas 14 and 15). The key feature of the

senior-sectors is that capital is less productivity-enhancing in comparison to the

(junior-sectors). This is reflected by the fact that optimal capital intensity in the

senior-sector is lower in comparison to the junior-sector (see Proposition 2).

Hence, the ageing-induced (one-time) demand-shift implies that aggregate capital

becomes less productive when looking at the economy-wide-averages. Therefore,

at the aggregate level a one-time decrease in L/N acts similarly like a negative

Page 367: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

357

productivity-shock (a decrease in the productivity of capital).4 This leads to the

negative impacts on aggregate net-output-growth, aggregate capital-growth and

aggregate consumption-expenditures-growth (and of course, the savings rate

decreases, since savings which are invested in capital become less rentable, i.e.

the opportunity costs of consumption decrease). This adjustment-process occurs

during the transition period. Since a one-time productivity-level-shock has no

impacts on productivity-growth rates, the economy converges to a growth path

(PBGP) where the growth rate is the same as before. (Remember that steady state

growth rates are determined only by productivity-growth and not by productivity-

levels within the standard (one-sector) Ramsey-model; in this respect my

aggregate model is the same as the standard Ramsey model.)

A further interesting question is about the effects of ageing on the senior-budget-

to-the-net-output-ratio ( NS YE / ). Equations (31), (35b) and (35d) imply the

following derivative (consider also equation (36e)):

(37) 01)(ˆ

ˆ)ˆ/ˆ(2*

*

*

***

>⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

−++

+−

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −∂

∂−=

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −∂

∂c

ggsN

LN

NLNY

E

NLN

YE GL

m

m

N

NS δβλααλ

Hence, we can see that ageing increases the senior-budget-to-output-ratio. The

first term on the right-hand-side of equation (37) may be regarded as the direct

effect of ageing (i.e. an increase in the old-to-young ratio, increases the share of

the seniors in the overall consumption-to-output-share).5 The second term may be

4 This fact is reflected by the ageing-induced decrease in *

mλ , which is implied by equation (36e);

as discussed in section three *mλ can be interpreted as a productivity indicator, which reflects the

aggregate impacts of cross-sector factor-reallocation. 5 since **** /*/)(/ NNS YENLNYE −= .

Page 368: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

358

regarded as an indirect effect: the increase in the old-to-young ratio leads to an

increase in the overall consumption-to-output-share6 (i.e. as noted above the

savings-rate decreases due to lower productivity level).

We can see from equations (36) and (37) that a rich “portfolio” of parameters

determines the strength of the impact of ageing. (Note that this portfolio would

not change, if I calculated elasticities instead of derivatives in equations (36) and

(37).) These parameters are:

a) technology parameters: input-elasticities of sectoral production functions

(including labor, capital and intermediates elasticities), TFP-growth-rates (via

Gg ) and the depreciation rate

b) time preference rate

c) old-to-young ratio and the growth rate of labor.

The reason for the fact that so many parameters determine the impact of ageing is

the following: The demand-shift across technologically distinct sectors makes it

necessary to change the (average) aggregate structure of the economy, especially

the ratios between aggregate capital, labor and aggregate intermediates. The

sectoral technology parameters (especially the input-elasticities) determine how

strong this change has to be. Furthermore, since changes in capital in general

require an adjustment of the savings rate (*

*

ˆˆ

1YE

− ), all the variables which

determine the savings rate come into account, especially the parameters captured

by the auxiliary variable s; see equations (35), e.g. the time-preference rate. The

parameters, which determine the savings rate, contain all those variables which

6 since ( ) ( ) 01)(/)(/)(

)ˆ/ˆ(2*

***

>⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

−++

+−∂∂

−=−∂

∂c

ggs

NLNNLNYE G

Lm

mN δβλααλ

.

Page 369: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

359

are already known to determine the savings-rate of the standard Ramsey-model

(see the auxiliary variable s). However, my model provides a sector foundation of

those parameters: especially, Gg and c are assumed to be exogenous in the

standard Ramsey-model, while in my model these two variables are functions of

sectoral parameters.

4.3.2 Additional impacts on GDP: The price-effect Remember that I have shown in the previous section that a one-time increase in

L/N leads to a transition from the old PBGP to a new PBGP. Due to this fact, the

effect of ageing on real GDP-growth can be divided into transitional effects and

PBGP-effects. Transitional effects have an impact on the real GDP-growth-rate

during the transition between two PBGP’s, while PBGP-effects of ageing have an

impact on the growth rate along the new (PBGP). In fact I have shown that the

effects from the previous section are transitional. In this section I will introduce a

new effect, which affects real GDP-growth (but not the growth rate of other

aggregate variables). I name this effect price effect, and I show that this effect is

not only transitional.

4.3.2.1 Transitional effects of ageing on GDP To show these facts we have to calculate the derivative of equation (35f):

(38)

⎥⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢⎢

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+

−−

−−−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−+

+′

=⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −∂

++−

4444 84444 76444 8444 7644 844 76 )(

**

)(

*

)(

*2*

*1* 1)1()1()()(

)(ˆ

χανχβγμ

χανββα

βλαλβ S

SSm

mc

c

lplp

s

NLN

PDG

Page 370: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

360

where ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −∂

∂≡′

NLN

mm

** )( λλ , )1(1)1(1 *

*

**

Sm

m pp −+−

−−

−=βλαλ

ανχβμαβ and

ανχβχβλ−

−= )1( **mSl .

and where *Sp is given by equation (35g).

(For an explicit proof see APPENDIX D.) A “(+)” (a “(-)”) above a term denotes

that this term is positive (negative).

Theorem 4: A one-time decrease in L/N has a negative impact on the growth rate

of GDP during the transition between the old and the new PBGP, provided that

senior goods are “more expensive” in comparison to junior-goods; i.e. provided

that 1* >Sp , where *Sp is given by equation (35g).

Proof: This theorem is implied by equation (38). If 1* >Sp , an increase in the

old-to-young-ratio has a negative impact on the *ˆPDG -level (and hence a

negative impact on the GDP-growth-rate during the transition period; see also the

argumentation in the proof of Lemma 13). Note that *Sp is always positive and

determined by exogenous parameters. Furthermore, note that the relative price of

senior goods is given by *Sp (see proposition 1) and the price of junior goods is

given by 1. The latter comes from the fact that sector m is numéraire (see

equation (15a)) and belongs to the junior-sector and all junior sub-sectors have

identical production functions (see also equations (A.5) and (A.6) in APPENDIX

A). Q.E.D.

Page 371: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

361

If 1* <Sp , the effect of an increase in the old-to-young ratio may be positive or

negative, depending on the parameter constellation, where the effect can be

positive provided that *Sp is relatively small (i.e. relatively close to zero). To

isolate a set of parameter-values, which ensures that the GDP-effect of ageing is

positive when *Sp is relatively close to zero, we have to calculate the limit-value

of the term within the squared brackets of equation (38), i.e.

(39)

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

−−−

+=

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+

−−

−−−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−+

*

***

0

)(2)()(

1)1)(1(lim

S

SSSp

l

lplS

ανχβαναβχβα

χανχβγμ

χανββα

where ανχβ

χβλ−

−= )1( **mSl .

If (39) is negative, equation (38) implies that for small values of *Sp the effect of

ageing is positive regarding GDP-growth. Equation (39) implies that, e.g., αβ <

is a stronger than necessary condition for this. (Remember that I assume that

χβαν < .)

Now, the question is which parameter constellations ensure that *Sp is relatively

small.

Lemma 16: In the limit 1* >Sp ( )1* <Sp , provided that the growth rate of labor-

augmenting technological progress in the junior-sector is higher (lower) in

comparison to the growth rate of labor-augmenting technological progress in the

senior-sector, i.e. provided that BA ggχα11

> ( BA ggχα11

< ).

Page 372: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

362

Proof: We know from equation (35g) that the actual level of *Sp is determined

by a time-variant term )/( αχ BA and by a constant term

( ανχβμαγχ

εαμαναχ

εγμγ

νβ

χα −

=⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ ∏ sn

ii

i

1

). αχ BA / approaches infinity (zero),

provided that BA ggχα11

> ( BA ggχα11

< ). Thus, in the limit *Sp approaches

infinity (zero) as well, i.e. *Sp becomes larger (smaller) than 1. Q.E.D.

Hence, depending on the parameter setting, several cases can exist: (1) *Sp can

be relatively close to zero in the beginning, but approach to infinity with time; (2)

*Sp can be relatively close to zero in the beginning and approach to zero with

time; (3) *Sp can be relatively large in the beginning but approach to zero with

time; (4) *Sp can be relatively large in the beginning and approach to infinity

with time.

These cases and the discussion above (about equations (35g) and (38)) imply that

ageing may have positive and negative impacts on GDP-growth (during the

transition period) depending on the exact constellation of parameters from

equations (35g) and (38). Moreover, the effect of ageing may change with time

(in cases (1) and (3)), i.e. in the beginning the effect on GDP-growth may be

positive (negative) but later negative (positive).

Nevertheless, in the limit only the term αχ BA / (together with equation (38))

determines whether a future increase in the old-to-young ratio leads to an increase

or to a decrease in GDP(-growth). Hence, from the today’s point of view the

growth rate of this term (namely BA gg αχ − ) is deciding for the question about

Page 373: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

363

the (distant) future impacts of ageing: If 0>− BA gg αχ (or: BA ggχα11

> ) we

know that *Sp approaches infinity. Hence, we know that sooner or later ageing

will have negative (transitional) effects on GDP-growth. Otherwise, if

0<− BA gg αχ (or: BA ggχα11

< ) we know that sooner or later ageing could

have positive (transitional) effects on GDP-growth. This seems to be a quite

convenient rule of thumb. Especially, since in this way the effects of ageing are

related to two quite comprehensible and estimable parameters: in fact the

production functions, which I assumed, imply that Agα1 and Bg

χ1 are the

growth rates or labor-augmenting technological progress in the senior sector and

junior sector respectively. Nevertheless, this is only a rule of thumb, since the

other variables from equation (35g) may be dominant for a long period of time, if

BA gg αχ − is not very large (i.e. if αχ BA / changes slowly).

Theorem 5: In the limit, a one-time decrease in L/N has a negative impact on the

growth rate of GDP during the transition between the old and the new PBGP,

provided that the growth rate of labor-augmenting technological progress in the

junior-sector is higher in comparison to the growth rate of labor-augmenting

technological progress in the senior-sector, i.e. provided that BA ggχα11

> .

Proof: This theorem is implied by Theorem 4 and Lemma 16. Q.E.D.

To understand why it is important for the GDP-effects of ageing whether *Sp <1

or >1, we have to remember that I have shown in the proof of Theorem 4 that *Sp

Page 374: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

364

is the price of senior-sector-goods and that the price of junior-sector-goods is

equal to unity. Hence, *Sp <1 (>1) means that senior-goods are less (more)

expensive than junior-goods. Furthermore, with respect to GDP-growth ageing

has two types of effects:

a) The “productivity effect” has already been discussed in section 4.3.1. I stated

there that ageing acts like a negative productivity shock, i.e. it leads to a

decrease in net-output ( NY ), provided that capital intensity in the senior sector

is lower in comparison to the junior-sector. This effect affects the GDP

measure, since p

YGDP N≡ (see equation (16c)).

b) “Price effect”: Remember that we divide our net-output ( NY ) by the price-

index ( )p to obtain GDP. Hence, the changes in p have an impact on GDP

as well. Ageing leads to changes in p , since the ageing-induced demand-shift

leads to changes in output-shares, which have been used to weight the prices

of the price index (see equation (15b)). Hence, if the price of the senior sector

is lower (higher) in comparison to the price of the junior-sector, ageing

induced demand-shifts lead to a decrease (increase) of p (since the relatively

inexpensive senior-goods become a stronger weight in p ). The price effect

increases (decreases) GDP, provided that the senior-sector price ( *Sp ) is

lower (higher) in comparison to the junior-sector price ( = 1).

Hence, if *Sp >1, both effects (the productivity effect and the price effect) point to

the same direction, i.e. GDP-growth decreases. On the other hand, if *Sp <1, the

productivity effect has a negative impact on GDP-growth, but the price effect

increases GDP-growth. Hence, it is deciding which of those effects is stronger.

Page 375: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

365

Summary: If the model parameters (from equation (35g)) are such that the price

of senior-sector-goods is relatively low, ageing may have positive transitional

impacts on GDP. For example, if parameters from equation (35g) are such that

*Sp is close to zero and if αβ < , ageing has a (temporary) positive effect on

GDP-growth, since in this case the positive price effect is stronger than the

negative productivity effect. However, whether the transitional effects of a future

decrease in L/N will be positive depends on the growth rate of αχ BA / (which

determines the growth rate of the senior-goods-price, and hence the price effect).

On the other hand, if the model parameters are such that the price of the senior

sector ( *Sp ) is higher than the price of the junior sector ( =1), ageing has a

negative transitional impact on GDP-growth, since the productivity effect and the

price effect point to the same direction. Whether future ageing will have negative

(transitional) effects in this case depends on the development of the term αχ BA /

(and on the parameters of equation (35g)). Equations (35g) and (38) imply that

the parameter-portfolio, which determines the strength and direction of the

ageing-impact, comprises:

a) sectoral labor-, capital- and intermediates-elasticities of output

( iεμνχγβα ,,,,,, )

b) the parameters, which determine in neoclassical growth models the steady-

state savings rate (e.g. the time-preference rate, depreciation rate) (via parameter

“s” in equation (35g))

c) the relative level and growth rate of labor-augmenting technological

progress in junior-sector in comparison to the senior sector (via the term αχ BA / )

Page 376: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

366

d) population-parameters (the old-to-young ratio (N

LN −) via *

Sl and the

growth-rate of labor ( Lg ) via parameter “s”).

4.3.2.2 PBGP-effects of ageing In this subsection I show that ageing has not only transitional effects on GDP, but

it affects the growth rate of GDP along the PBGP.

Theorem 6: A one-time decrease in L/N reduces (increases) the PBGP-growth

rate of GDP, provided that the growth rate of labor-augmenting technological

progress in the junior-sector is higher (lower) in comparison to the growth rate of

labor-augmenting technological progress in the senior-sector, i.e. provided that

BA ggχα11

> ( BA ggχα11

< ). That is, the growth rate of GDP along the new

PBGP is lower (higher) in comparison to the growth rate of GDP along the old

PBGP, provided that BA ggχα11

> ( BA ggχα11

< ).

Proof: PDG ˆ along the PBGP is given by equation (35f). Along the PBGP all

terms of equation (35f) are constant beside of *Sp , which is given by equation

(35g). Therefore, we obtain the following growth-rate:

)1()1()1(

)1()1(

ˆˆ

***

**

*

*

Smm

Sm

p

p

PDGPDG

−−−

−−+

−−

−−=

ανχβμαβλβλα

ανχβμαβλ &&

Calculating the derivative of this growth rate implies:

Page 377: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

367

(40) 2***

***

*

)1()1()1(

)1()/(

ˆˆ

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−

−−

−−+

+−−

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛∂

∂=

⎟⎟

⎜⎜

⎛∂

Smm

Sm

pp

NLNL

PDGPDG

ανχβμαβλβλα

βαανχβμαβλ

&

&

Equation (36e) implies that ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛∂

NLm

*λ >0. Furthermore, remember that I assume

0>−ανχβ .

Equation (35g) implies *Sp& > 0 , if BA gg

χα11

> , and *Sp& < 0, if BA gg

χα11

< .

Hence, equation (40) is positive (negative), if BA ggχα11

> ( BA ggχα11

< ). That

is, a decrease in L/N has a negative (positive) impact on the GDP-growth rate

along the PBGP, provided that BA ggχα11

> ( BA ggχα11

< ). Q.E.D.

4.3.3 Dynamic aspects By now, in this section I have analyzed the impacts of a one-time increase in the

old-to-young ratio. If ageing is not regarded as a one-time increase but as a

sequence of (discrete) increases in the old-to-young ratio, my results still remain

applicable: Since I have shown in Lemma 7 (Corollary 1) that the PBGP is

saddle-path-stable, the economy will be on the converging path. The qualitative

results remain the same. The overall magnitude of the change in the macro-

variables (e.g. in GDP) is determined by the sum of the changes in the old-to-

young-ratio (overall-change in the old-to-young ratio). Only the period of change

(the transition period) is more prolonged, since the overall change is dispersed

over a sequence (i.e. the economy cannot reach the “final” PBGP before the

sequence is finished).

Page 378: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

368

5. Concluding remarks In this paper I have specified how ageing affects the GDP-growth rate and the

pension-to-GDP-ratio via factor-allocation effects. In comparison to the previous

literature I have shown that ageing affects these variables along additional

channels, for example:

• in contrast to Groezen et al. (2005), ageing-impacts arise in my model

despite of the fact that the elasticity of substitution between capital and labour is

equal to unity;

• in section 4.3.2 I introduced the “price effect”.

Moreover, my model adds new determinants of the ageing-impact (e.g. the fact

that capital-intensity in the senior sectors is lower in comparison to that of the

junior-sector does not necessarily lead to negative impacts of ageing, but a rich

portfolio of technology and preference parameters determines these ageing-

impacts in my model). Furthermore, in contrast to the previous literature, I have

shown (in section 4.3.2) that the ageing-effects may be non-monotonous over

time. Hence, the strength of the ageing impact (and the necessary reforms of

pension systems) may vary widely across countries and across time, depending on

the parameters derived in my model.

This non-monotonousity comes from the fact that although the senior sector has

relatively low capital intensity, the price of senior-goods needs not necessarily

being higher than the price of junior-goods. Hence, the positive “price effect” of

ageing can overweight the negative “productivity effect” of ageing; however, if

the growth rate of labor augmenting technological progress is relatively high in

the junior sectors, the senior goods must become more expensive than junior

Page 379: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

369

goods at some point of time, i.e. the price effect becomes negative as well. (See

the following explanations and the explanations on pp.28-31.)

As shown in section 4.3.2, despite of its “complexity” my model provides quite

easily interpretable results which can be used in empirical research and policy

making:

(1) The present and past effects of ageing via structural change can be analyzed

by assessing the (market) prices of senior-goods and junior-goods. In fact my

model implies that ageing has a negative impact on real GDP-growth via

structural change, if senior goods are “more expensive” than junior goods.

(Otherwise, if senior goods are cheaper, the effects of ageing can be positive or

negative, depending on the exact model parameters which will be discussed in the

following.) In contrast to Groezen et al. (2005), my model does not imply that

low capital-intensity in the senior sector is sufficient to constitute negative effects

of ageing. That is, lower capital-intensity in the senior sector does not necessarily

imply that senior goods are more expensive in comparison to junior goods. The

reason is that TFP-plays a role for the effects of ageing as well: for example high

TFP may offset the negative effects of low capital intensity.

(2) For the discussion about the future effects of ageing we have to know which

parameters determine the development of relative prices of senior and junior

sector. Only in this way we can asses whether it makes sense to assume that in

future ageing will have negative impacts on real GDP-growth via structural

change. My results imply that in the limit (or: in the very long run) ageing has

negative impacts on real GDP-growth, provided that the growth rate of labor-

augmenting technological progress is lower in the senior sector in comparison to

the junior-sector. In this case sooner or later senior goods become more expensive

in comparison to junior goods. Hence, when discussing the future effects of

Page 380: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

370

ageing it is important to know about the development of labor-augmenting

technological progress in the senior and junior sector. However, as mentioned in

section 4.3.2, this is only a rule of thumb, since “sooner or later” is a quite vague

concept. That is, the exact parameter restrictions (which were derived in section

4.3.2) may be the key determinant of the ageing impact for a very long period of

time.

(3) The portfolio of parameters, which determine the effects of ageing via

structural change, which has been derived in section 4.3.2, provides a range of

policies to counteract the negative impacts of ageing on real GDP-growth. My

model can help to isolate more or less efficient policies: For example, equation

(40) implies that the relative price of senior goods can be influenced by policies

that have an impact on

• the savings rate (via s in equation (40)),

• the sectoral output-elasticities of inputs,

• the growth rate of working population (via s),

• and the sectoral levels and rates of labor-augmenting technological

progress.

For example, policies, which influence the savings rate, seem to be not effective

in the very long run, since (as just explained) in the very long run the impacts of

labor-augmenting technological progress are dominant regarding the development

of the relative price of senior goods price. On the other hand, e.g., policies that

increase the birth rate seem to be relatively effective: they do not only decrease

the old-to-young ratio directly (hence reducing the rate of ageing) but they also

reduce the relative price of senior goods (via Lg from s in equation (40)).

Page 381: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

371

Throughout the paper I assumed that parameter restrictions (5a,b) hold. In fact,

these restrictions ensure that there are no other sources of demand-shifts between

the senior and junior sector beside of that caused by ageing. However, the impact

of social welfare parameters (especially, the question how the utility of the old

and the young is weighted in a society) may be captured by deviation from these

restrictions. The question is whether pension systems (and private “savings-for-

retirement”-behavior) change systematically (i.e. whether the weight is shifted to

the old or to the young) with an increasing income. The answer to this question

has an impact on the strength of the ageing-impacts. This fact could be modeled

by a departure from the restrictions (5a,b). Furthermore, it should be mentioned

here that if fewer budgets were devoted to the old (i.e. if SE was restricted

exogenously, e.g. by an “inefficient” pension system), the ageing impacts would

be weaker. However, from the social welfare point of view this would be

suboptimal (i.e. the social welfare would be suboptimal). These facts may as well

have some explanatory power regarding differences in the strength of ageing

impacts across countries.

In section 4.3 I modeled ageing like a shock (or series of shocks) and not like a

smooth and perfectly foresighted process. The difference between these two

approaches is that the latter is more difficult to model (I could not rely on the

PBGP-results) and I would have to use simulations. Furthermore, if perfectly

foresighted the effects of ageing would be smoother, i.e. dispersed over a longer

period (i.e. even before the increase in the old-to-young ratio the effects of ageing

would show up), which would affect my results quantitatively but not

qualitatively (i.e. the impact channels would be the same). Furthermore, it should

be questioned whether it makes sense to model ageing like a smooth perfectly

foresighted process, especially when taking into account irrational or bounded

Page 382: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

372

rational behavior of households in reality. Last but not least, since my model is

rather aimed to postulate some crude qualitative macroeconomic relationships

between economic parameters and variables, the question whether ageing is

modeled as a series of shocks or as a perfectly foresighted smooth process seems

to be less relevant.

Overall, my results imply that for assessing (the future) growth-impacts of ageing

some further empirical research is necessary to estimate the exact technological

properties of the junior and senior sector. Especially, it seems to be necessary to

link the data on demand-differences across the old and the young with the data on

technological properties of the sectors. Only in this way a general conclusion can

be drawn about the past and future strength of the ageing impacts. Furthermore,

the discussion about whether the senior sector needs necessarily having a lower

growth rate of labor-augmenting technological progress in future seems to be

interesting regarding the effects of ageing.

Last not least, as mentioned in Section 2.1, it could be interesting to endogenize

the population development (e.g. old-to-young ratio as a function of income) and

to analyze what factor reallocation impacts arise in such a model.

Analyzing these questions is left for further research.

Page 383: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

373

APPENDIX A Inserting equations (7) and (8) into equation (21) yields:

(A.1) im

mi l

lk

k = and im

mi l

lz

z = , for mi ,...1=

(A.2) im

mi l

lk

kβν

χα

= and im

mi l

lz

zγμ

χα

= , for nmi ,...1+=

Inserting equations (A.1) and (A.2) into equation (7) yields

(A.3) miLAlY mmii ,...1for, == γβζκ

(A.4) nmiLBlY mmii ,...1for, +== μνζϑκ

where LlZz

m

mm ≡ζ ,

μν

γμ

χα

βν

χαϑ ⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡ and

LlKk

m

mm ≡κ .

Inserting equations (A.3) and (A.4) into equation (21) yields:

(A.5) mipi ,...1for ,1 ==

(A.6) nmipBAp Smmi ,...1for,1

+=≡= −− μγνβ ζκϑχ

α

It follows from equations (15a) and (21) that ihZhZ

pm

ii ∀

∂∂∂∂

= ,//

, which implies

that

(A.7) ip

hh

im

mii ∀= ,1ε

ε

Inserting equation (A.7) into equation (18) yields:

(A.8) m

mhH

ε=

Inserting equations (A.7), (A.5) and (A.6) into equation (13) yields:

(A.9) ∏=

−− ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛=

n

immi

S

i

ABHZ

1

εγμβνε ζϑκ

αχε

Page 384: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

374

where ∑+=

≡n

miiS

1εε

Inserting equations (A.3) and (A.5) into equation (21) yields for mi =

(A.10) HZ

ZzLAl

m

mmmγβζκ

γ=1

Solving this equation for H yields:

(A.11) γβζκγ mmm

m ALzl

H =

Inserting equation (A.9) into equation (A.10) yields

(A.12) ψκζ mm D=

where γεμγ

ενββψ

−−+−−

≡S

S

)(1)(

and

SS

i

Sn

iiA

BADμεεγ

ε

εμν

εχγαμ

χβαν

αχγ

−−−

= ⎪⎭

⎪⎬⎫

⎪⎩

⎪⎨⎧

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡ ∏

)1(11

1

.

Inserting equations (A.1) and (A.2) into equation (14) yields (remember: it

follows from equation (14) that ∑∑+==

−=n

mii

m

ii ll

111 ):

(A.13) 1

111

+=⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−=∑ β

νχαn

mi m

mi k

ll

(A.14) ∑+=

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−=

n

mii

m

m lzl

111

γμ

χα

It follows from equations (1)-(6) and (22) that

(A.15a) ( ) miforCC immm

ii ,...1=+−= θθ

ωω

(A.15b) nmiforp

CN

LNC ii

mm

m

ii ,...1+=+

−−= θ

θωω

Inserting equations (A.15), (A.5) and (A.6) into equation (17) yields

Page 385: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

375

(A.16) m

mmCLNE

ωθ−

=

Inserting equations (2)-(6) and (A.3) into equation (23) yields due to equation

(A.16):

(A.17) ρδζκβ γβ −−= −mmA

EE 1&

Inserting equations (A.3)-(A.6) into equation (16a) yields (remember:

∑∑+==

−=n

mii

m

ii ll

111 ):

(A.18) ⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−= ∑

+=

n

miimm lALY

111

χαζκ γβ

Inserting equation (A.13) into equation (A.18) yields:

(A.19) ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+=

m

mmm k

lbaALY γβζκ

where

χβανχα

−−≡

1

11a and

χβανχα

−≡

1

1b

Inserting first equation (A.14) and then equation (A.13) into equation (A.11)

yields:

(A.20) ⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+=

m

mmm k

lddALH 21γβζκγ

where

χβανχγαμ

−−≡

1

111d and

χβανχγαμ

−≡

1

12d .

It follows from equation (A.4) that

(A.21) μν ζϑκ mm

ii BL

Yl = for nmi ,...1+= .

Page 386: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

376

Inserting first equation (11), then equations (A.15) and (A.6) and finally equation

(A.19) into equation (A.21) yields

(A.22) Yph

BLYC

NLNl ii

mm

imm

m

ii ~~ α

χζϑκ

θθωω

αχ

μν ++−−

= for nmi ,...1+=

where

m

m

klba

YY+

≡~ .

It follows from equation (A.13) that

(A.23) ∑+=

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−=

n

miim l

111

χβανλ

where m

mm k

l≡λ

Inserting first equation (A.22), then equations (A.16) and (A.7) and finally

equation (A.8) into equation (A.23) yields after some algebra (remember that

∑+=

=n

mii

10θ ):

(A.24) ⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ +

−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−= S

m

mm Y

HYE

NLN

klba ε

αχ

χβανλ 11

where m

mm k

l≡λ .

Equations (11), (12), (16a), (17), (18) and (15a) imply:

(A.25) HEKKY +++= δ&

Inserting equation (A.12) into equation (A.19) yields

(A.26) ( ) ccm

cm KLbaGY −− += 1λλ

where μεεγγνεμεβ

SS

SSc−−−+−

≡)1(1

)1( ,

Page 387: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

377

SS

i

Sn

iiA

BAAGμεεγ

γ

ε

εμν

εχγαμ

χβαν

αχγ

−−−

= ⎪⎭

⎪⎬⎫

⎪⎩

⎪⎨⎧

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡ ∏

)1(1

1

, and m

mm k

l≡λ .

Inserting equation (A.12) into equation (A.17) yields

(A.27) ρδλβ −−= −−− cccm LKG

EE 111&

Inserting equation (A.19) into equation (A.20) yields equation

(A.28)

m

m

m

m

klba

kldd

YH+

+=

21

γ

Equations (A.24)-(A.28) can be transformed into equations (24), (25),

(26a,b,d) and (26c). Q.E.D.

Now I only have to derive equation (27). By using equations (14), (15c), (16a),

(A.5) and (A.6) equation (15b) can be transformed as follows:

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎝

⎛−−−= ∑ ∑

+= +=

n

mi

n

miiSiSN

N

zHpYpYY

p1 1

)1(1

where Sp is given by equation (A.6). Now, inserting equations (A.2), (A.4) and

(A.6) yields:

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−−=

m

mmmSSN

N lzHLAlpY

Yp

ß

γμζκ

χα γ)1(1 .

where Sl is given by equation (19). Inserting equations (16b), (A.14), (A.19) and

(A.20) yields

( )⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜

−−

+−

+−−= μ

χγμαχγλ

λχα

S

m

mNSS

l

ddbaY

Ylpp1

1)1(1 21

Page 388: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

378

where

χβανχα

−−≡

1

11a ,

χβανχα

−≡

1

1b ,

χβανχγαμ

−−≡

1

111d and

χβανχγαμ

−≡

1

12d . Now,

inserting equations (26a,b) and (A.23) yields

(A.29)

( )

m

Smm pp

βλαανχβμαβλβλα

+−−

−−−+=

1)1)(1(

where Sp is given by equation (A.6). Inserting equation (A.12) into (A.6) yields

after some algebra:

(A.30)

[ ] )(1

)(1)()(

1

ˆαμγχεα

α

χεμγγαμγχεαανχβ

μαγχε

αμαναχ

λεγ

μγ

νβ

χα

−+−+−

−+−−

= ⎥⎥⎥

⎢⎢⎢

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛≡ ∏

S

S

S

i

BAKp

m

n

iiS

(Hint: the following equations may be useful for obtaining (A.30): 1=++ γβα

and 1=++ μνχ ; these equations imply among others that

ανβχβμγννβ −=−+− and μαγχγνμβμγ −=−+− .)

The rest of the proof is quite simple: equation (27) can be obtained by

dividing the net-output (equation (26b)) by the price-index (equation (A.29)),

where Sp is given by equation (A.30). Q.E.D.

Page 389: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

379

APPENDIX B Equations (A.7), (A.8), (A.16) and (A.22) from APPENDIX A and equations

(5a,b) and (19) imply equation (29).

Equation (28) can be derived in the same way as equation (29).

Equations (A.5), (A.6), (A.15a,b), (A.16) from APPENDIX A and equations

(5a,b) and (20) imply equations (30) and (31).

For a proof of equations (32) and (33) see APPENDIX A equations (A.1) and

(A.2).

Page 390: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

380

APPENDIX C First, I show by using linear approximation that the saddle-path-feature of the

PBGP is given (Lemma 7a). Then I prove local stability by using a phase diagram

(Lemma 7b).

Existence of a saddle-path (Lemma 7a)

The study of local stability of the PBGP is analogous to the proof by Acemoglu

and Guerrieri (2008) (see there for details and see also Acemoglu (2009), pp. 269-

273, 926).

First, I have to show that the determinant of the Jacobian of the differential

equation system (24)-(25) (where mλ is given by equation (26c)) is different from

zero when evaluated at the PBGP (i.e. for *** ,ˆ,ˆmEK λ from equations (35a,b,e)).

This implies that this differential equation system is hyperbolic and can be

linearly approximated around *** ,ˆ,ˆmEK λ (Grobman-Hartman-Theorem; see as

well Acemoglu (2009), p. 926, and Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008)). The

determinant of the Jacobian is given by:

(C.1) EK

KE

EE

KK

EE

KE

EK

KK

J ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

ˆˆ

∂∂

∂∂

−∂∂

∂∂

=

∂∂

∂∂

∂∂

∂∂

=&&&&

&&

&&

The derivatives of equations (24)-(25) are given by:

Page 391: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

381

(C.2)

EcKE

cggK

EE

KKcKcE

KE

EccK

EK

cgg

KccKKc

KK

mcm

cGL

ccm

mcm

ccm

c

mcm

cm

c

GL

mcm

cm

ccm

cm

c

ˆ)1(ˆˆ1

ˆˆˆ

ˆˆ)1(ˆ)1(ˆ

ˆˆ

1ˆ))1((ˆˆˆ

1ˆ))1((ˆ)(ˆˆˆ

111

112

1

111

∂∂

−+⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

−−−−−=

∂∂

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

∂∂

−+−=∂∂

−∂∂

−+−=∂∂

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

−++−

∂∂

−+−++=∂∂

−−−−

−−−−

−−−

−−−−−−

λλβρδβλ

λλλβ

λβλαλ

δλβλαλβλαλ

&

&

&

&

where the derivatives of equation (26c) are given by

(C.3)

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ −−⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −++⎟

⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −+

−−

=∂∂

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ −−⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −++⎟

⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −+

−−

−=∂∂

−+

cm

cSS

cm

cm

cm

cSS

c

cm

m

KEc

NLN

KEc

NLN

K

KEc

NLN

KNLN

E

1

1

1

1

1

ˆˆ

111

ˆˆ

ˆ

ˆˆ

111

ˆˆ

λαβανχβ

ααμχγε

ααμχγε

λαβανχβ

λ

λαβανχβ

ααμχγε

ααμχγε

λαβ

ανχβλ

Inserting the derivatives (C.2) and (C.3) into (C.1) and inserting the PBGP-values

from equations (35a,b,e) yields after some algebra the following value of the

determinant of the Jacobian evaluated at the PBGP:

(C.4)

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ −−⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −++⎟

⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −+

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛

−+++⎟

⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −+

−−+

−−−

−=

cm

cSS

GLS

KEc

NLN

cgg

LNN

KE

NLNc

J

1**

*1

*

*

*

)()ˆ(

ˆ111

11ˆ

ˆ)1(

λαβανχβ

ααμχγε

ααμχγε

ρδααμχγε

ανχβαρ

αανχβ

We can see that the determinant evaluated at PBGP is different form zero. Hence,

the PBGP is hyperbolic. Furthermore, we can be sure that 0* <J , provided that

Page 392: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

382

0>−ανχβ . Since I assume in my paper that the capital intensity in the senior-

sector is lower in comparison to the junior sector, the relation 0>−ανχβ holds

(see section 4.3).

Our differential equation system consists of two differential equations ((24) and

(25)) and of two variables ( E and K ), where we have one state and one control-

variable. Hence, saddle-path-stability of the PBGP requires that there exist one

negative (and one positive) eigenvalue of the differential equation system when

evaluated at PBGP (see also Acemoglu and Guerrieri (2008) and Acemoglu

(2009), pp. 269-273). Since 0* <J we can be sure that this is the case. ( 0* <J

can exist only if one eigenvalue is positive and the other eigenvalue is negative. If

both eigenvalues were negative or if both eigenvalues were positive, the

determinant *J would be positive.) Therefore, in the neighborhood of the PBGP

there is a saddle-path, along which the economy converges to the PBGP. Q.E.D.

Local stability (Lemma 7b)

In the following, I omit intermediates for simplicity, i.e. I set 0== μγ .

Furthermore, as noted above I study here only the case 0>−ανχβ (see also

section 4.3). Since αχανχβ −=− if 0== μγ , I can say as well that I study

here only the case 0>−αχ . Note, however, that the qualitative stability results

for the other case (i.e. 0<−αχ ) are the same.

To show the stability-features of the PBGP, the three-dimensional system (C.1)-

(C.3) has to be transformed into a two dimensional system, in order to allow me

using a phase-diagram. By defining the variable m

κˆ

≡ , the system (24)-(25)-

(26c) can be reformulated as follows (after some algebra):

Page 393: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

383

(C.5) ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

+++−= −

βρδβκ β

1ˆˆ

1 GL

ggEE&

(C.6)

β

ββ

κβχα

ρκαβ

χακβ

δκ

κκ

EN

LNN

LNEgg GL

ˆ1

)1

( 11

−−+

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ −−−−

−++−

=

−−

&

I can focus attention on showing that the stationary point of this differential

equation system is stable: The discussion in section 4.1 (Definition 3 and Lemmas

1-4) implies that κ and E are jointly in steady state only if K , E and mλ are

jointly in steady state and that K , E and mλ are jointly in steady state only if κ

and E are jointly in steady state. Therefore, the proof of stability of the stationary

point of system (C.5)-(C.6) implies stability of the stationary point of system

(24)-(25)-(26c). Hence, in the following I will prove stability of the stationary

point of system (C.5)-(C.6).

It follows from equations (C.5) and (C.6) that the steady-state-loci of the two

variables are given by

(C.5a)

β

βρδ

βκ

⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜

−+++

==

11

*

1

:0ˆˆ

GL

ggEE&

(C.6a) κκω

αβχαρ

βδκ

κκ

β

β

κ−

= −−

−++−

==1

1

0

1

)1

(ˆ:0

n

GL

ggE &

&

Now, I could depict the differential equation system (C.5)-(C.6) in the phase

space ( κ,E ). Before doing so, I show that not the whole phase space ( κ,E ) is

economically meaningful. The economically meaningful phase-space is restricted

Page 394: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

384

by three curves ( 321 ,, tt RRR ), as shown in the following figure and as derived

below:

Figure C.1: Relevant space of the phase diagram

Only the space below the 1R -line is economically meaningful, since the

employment-share of at least one sub-sector i is negative in the space above the

1R -line. This can be seen from the following fact:

As shown in APPENDIX A (see there equation (A.23)), the following relation is

true

(C.7) ∑+=

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ −−=

n

miim l

11

χβανχβλ

Note that αχανχβ −=− when 0== μγ .

Since, il cannot be negative (hence , 101

≤≤ ∑+=

n

miil ) this equation implies that

(C.8) χβαν

<m

m

kl

κ

E

1R

30=tR

20=tR

Page 395: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

385

Inserting equation (26c) into this relation yields

(C.9) βκχα

LNNER−

<ˆ:1 (remember that 0== μγ ).

Hence, the space above 1R is not feasible. When the economy reaches a point on

1R , no labor is used in sub-sectors i=1,…m. If I impose Inada-conditions on the

production functions, as usual, this means that the output of sub-sectors i=1,…m

is equal to zero, which means that the consumption of these sectors is equal to

zero. Our utility function implies that life-time utility is infinitely negative in this

case. Hence, the household prefers not to be at the 1R -curve.

Now I turn to the 2tR and 3

tR -curves. I have to take account of the non-negativity-

constraints on consumption ( iCi ∀> 0 ), since our Stone-Geary-type utility

function can give rise to negative consumption. By using equations (A.6), (A.15)

and (A.16) from APPENDIX A and Definition 1 the non-negativity-constraints

( iCi ∀> 0 ) can be transformed as follows (remember that I assume here

0== μγ ):

(C.10) miLA

LNE

i

i ,...11ˆ1 =

−>

αωθ

(C.11) nmiLBA

LNNE v

i

i ,...111ˆ2 +=⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

−> −− β

αβν

χ

κνβ

χβαν

ωθ

This set of constraints implies that at any point of time only two constraints are

binding, namely those with respectively the largest i

i

ωθ− . Hence, the set (C.10),

(C.11) can be reduced to the following set:

(C.12) αω

θ1

2 1ˆ:LA

LNER

j

jt

−>

Page 396: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

386

where mii

i

j

j ,...1=−>

−ωθ

ωθ

and mj ≤≤1 .

(C.13) βαβν

χ

κνβ

χβαν

ωθ

−−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−

−> v

x

xt

LBALN

NER 11ˆ: 23

where nmii

i

x

x ,...1+=−

>−

ωθ

ωθ

and nxm ≤≤+1

These constraints are time-dependent. It depends upon the parameter setting

whether 2tR or whether 3

tR is binding at a point of time. In Figure C.1 I have

depicted examples for these constraints for the initial state of the system. Only the

space above the constraints is economically meaningful, since below the

constraints the consumption of at least one good is negative. Last not least, note

that equations (C.12)/(C.13) imply that the 2tR -curve and the 3

tR -curve converge

to the axes of the phase-diagram as time approaches infinity.

Now, I depict the differential equation system (C.5)-(C.6) in the phase space

( κ,E ).

Page 397: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

387

Figure C.2: The differential equation system (C.5)-(C.6) in the phase-space for

0>−=− αχανχβ

Note that I have depicted here only the relevant (or: binding) parts of the

restriction-set of Figure C.1 as a bold line R.

The phase diagram implies that there must be a saddle-path along which the

system converges to the stationary point S (where S is actually the PBGP). The

length of the saddle-path is restricted by the restrictions of the meaningful space

321 ,, tt RRR (bold line). In other words, only if the initial κ ( 0κ ) is somewhere

between 0κ and κ , the economy can be on the saddle-path. Therefore, the

system can be only locally saddle-path stable. Now, I have to show that the

system will be on the saddle-path if κκκ << 00 . Furthermore, I have to discuss

what happens if 0κ is not within this range.

Every trajectory, which starts above the saddle-path or left from 0κ , reaches the

1R -curve in finite time. As discussed above, the life-time utility becomes

infinitely negative if the household reaches the 1R -curve. These arguments imply

κ

E

0=κ&

0ˆ =E&

S

saddle-path

κ0κ

R

Page 398: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

388

that the representative household will never choose to start above the saddle path

if κκκ << 00 , since all the trajectories above the saddle-path lead to a state

where life-time-utility is infinitely negative.

Furthermore, all initial points that are situated below the saddle-path or right from

κ converge to the point T. If the system reaches one of the constraints ( 32 , tt RR )

during this convergence process, it moves along the binding constraint towards T.

However, the transversality condition is violated in T. Therefore, T is not an

equilibrium. To see that the transversality condition is violated in T consider the

following facts: The transversality condition in my model requires that

01

lim 1 >−

−−−−

∞→ βδβκ β G

Lt

gg , which is equivalent to:

β

βδ

βκ

∞→

⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜

−++

<

11

1

limG

Lt gg

. However, equation (C.6a) implies that in point T in

Figure C.2

β

βδ

κ

⎟⎟⎟⎟

⎜⎜⎜⎜

−++

=

11

1

1G

Lgg

. Hence, the transversality condition is

violated if the system converges to point T.

Overall, we know that, if κκκ << 00 , the household always decides to be on the

saddle-path. Hence, we know that for κκκ << 00 the economy converges to the

PBGP. In this sense, the PBGP is locally stable (within the range κκκ << 00 ).

If the initial capital is to small ( 00 κκ < ), the economy converges to a state

where some existence minima are not satisfied (curve 1R ) and thus utility

becomes infinitely negative. This may be interpreted as a development trap. On

the other hand, if initial capital-level is too large ( κκ >0 ), all trajectories violate

Page 399: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

389

the transversality condition. Therefore, in this case, the representative

household must waste a part of its initial capital to come into the feasible area

( κκκ << 00 ).

Q.E.D.

Page 400: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

390

APPENDIX D Due to equation (16c) we know that

(D.1) *

**

**

*

p

Y

NLN

pp

NLN

Y

NLN

GDP

NN

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −∂

∂−

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −∂

=⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −∂

Equation (38) can be obtained by inserting equation (A.29) from APPENDIX A

and equation (35d) into equation (D.1). Hints: Equation (A.30) from APPENDIX

A and equation (35a) imply that 0*

=⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −∂

NLN

pS . Furthermore, I used equation

(A.23) to transform *mλ into *

Sl .

Page 401: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

391

LIST OF SYMBOLS of PART III of CHAPTER V * Denotes the PBGP-value of the corresponding variable.

^ Implies that the variable is expressed in “labor-efficiency units” (see

Definition 1).

A Parameter indicating technology/productivity level of junior-goods.

(exogenous)

B Parameter indicating technology/productivity level of senior-goods.

(exogenous)

iC Consumption of sector-i-output; indicates how much of the output of

sector i is consumed.

D Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous model-parameters; growing

at constant rate.)

E Aggregate consumption expenditures; index of overall consumption-

expenditures of the representative household.

JE Consumption expenditures on junior goods.

SE Consumption expenditures on senior goods.

G Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous model-parameters; growing

at constant rate.)

GDP Real GDP.

H Aggregate intermediate output; index of the value of all intermediates

produced in the economy

J Determinant of the Jacobian matrix.

K Aggregate capital; i.e. the amount of capital that is used for production in

the whole economy.

L Index of working population (economy-wide labor-input). (exogenous)

Page 402: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

392

N Index of overall-population. (exogenous)

1R Function restricting the economically meaningful space in the phase-

diagram.

2tR Function restricting the economically meaningful space in the phase-

diagram.

3tR Function restricting the economically meaningful space in the phase-

diagram.

R Set of binding parts of functions restricting the meaningful space in the

phase-diagram

U Life-time utility of the (representative) household.

Y Aggregate output; index of economy-wide output-volume.

Y~ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

iY Output of sector i.

NY Aggregate net-output. Aggregate output minus aggregate value of

intermediates.

NiY Net-output of sector i. Value of (gross-)output of sector i minus value of

intermediate inputs that sector i uses.

Z Index of intermediate production. Indicates how much intermediate inputs

are used in the whole economy.

a Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

b Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

Page 403: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

393

c Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

1d Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

2d Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

*g Growth rate of aggregates along the PBGP.

Ag Growth rate of A. (exogenous)

Bg Growth rate of B. (exogenous)

Gg Growth rate of G.

Lg Growth rate of L. (exogenous).

Ng Growth rate of N. (exogenous)

ih Intermediates produced by subsector i; indicates how much output of

subsector i is used as intermediate in the whole economy.

i Index denoting a sector.

ik Capital-share of sector i; indicates which share of aggregate capital (K) is

used in sector i.

il Employment-share of sector i; indicates which share of aggregate labor (L)

is used in sector i.

Jl Employment share of the junior sectors.

Sl Employment share of the senior sectors.

m Index-number limiting the range of sectors that belong to the junior-sector.

n Number of sectors.

p Price-index (“deflator”).

Page 404: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

394

ip Relative price of sector i. (Sector m is numéraire.)

Sp Relative price of senior goods. (Sector m is numéraire.)

s Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

t Index denoting time.

u Instantaneous utility-function.

Ju Instantaneous utility index, closely related to the utility of junior goods.

mu First derivative of u with respect to mC .

Su Instantaneous utility index, closely related to the utility of senior goods.

iz Intermediate-share of sector i; indicates which share of intermediate input-

index (Z) is used in sector i.

α Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to output-

elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

β Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to output-

elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

γ Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to output-

elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

δ Depreciation rate on capital (K). (exogenous)

iε Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas-intermediate-index; indicates the elasticity

of Z with respect to ih . (exogenous)

Jε Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

Page 405: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

395

Sε Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

iθ Parameter of the utility function; closely related to the utility of iC . May

be interpreted as minimum consumption regarding good i (e.g. subsistence

level), if positive. May be interpreted as “natural” endowment of good i, if

negative. (exogenous)

ϑ Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

κ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

κ Upper level of κ , which separates the phase-diagram into a convergent

and divergent section.

0κ Lower level of κ , which separates the phase-diagram into a convergent

and divergent section at the initial point of time.

0κ Level of κ at the initial point of time of the model.

mκ Capital-intensity in sector m.

mλ Auxiliary variable. (Function of other model-variables.)

μ Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to output-

elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

ν Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to output-

elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

ρ Time-preference rate. (exogenous)

mζ Intermediate-intensity in sector m.

χ Parameter of the Cobb-Douglas production function; is equal to output-

elasticity of the corresponding input. (exogenous)

Page 406: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

396

ψ Auxiliary parameter. (Function of exogenous and constant model-

parameters.)

iω Parameter of the utility function; closely related to the utility of iC .

(exogenous)

Page 407: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

CHAPTER VI

Summary

My work is about using the methods of the PBGP-school for modelling structural

change and economic growth. Broadly speaking, this new school of structural

change can be characterized upon two attributes (a mathematical one and a

theoretical one): (1) The concept of “partially balanced growth” is used to study

the differential-equation-systems of the theoretical models. (2) The modelling

framework may be regarded as “neoclassical” in many ways.

I have explained in Chapter IV that there is a large body of literature on

structural change consisting of several schools, dealing with several aspects of

structural change and using different approaches and methods. After elaborating

the features of these schools in Chapter IV, I have decided to focus on the New

School of Structural Change (or: PBGP-School of Structural Change).

I decided for this school, since it seemed to me very promising: It allows me to

study structural change in analytically-solvable frameworks, while including

some important aspects of the neoclassical growth-school (e.g. capital

accumulation). Furthermore, since the PBGP-school is very familiar with

neoclassical mainstream assumptions, I hoped that I can draw references to the

mainstream.

After elaborating the mathematical and modelling prerequisites of the PBGP-

method in Chapters II and III, I searched for several open questions in growth

theory associated with structural change. From all the open questions that I have

found, three questions seemed important and feasible to me: the Kuznets-Kaldor-

Puzzle, dynamic effects of offshoring associated with structural change and the

397

Page 408: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

growth effects of ageing via structural change. I have studied these topics by

using the PBGP-method in Chapter V.

The elaboration of the mathematical prerequisites of the PBGP-school

(Chapter II) has shown that from the mathematical point view there are three

main challenges in using the PBGP-method:

1.) A partially balanced growth path exists only in very “rare” cases. Therefore, it

is difficult to find (meaningful) economic assumptions that yield differential

equation systems where partially balanced growth paths exist.

2.) Since the assumptions of the PBGP-school are based on neoclassical growth

theory, the solution of PBGP-models requires the solution of optimal control

problems. In continuous time these problems can be solved by using the

Hamiltonian. However, due to the high dimension of multi-sector differential

equation systems, proving the sufficiency of Hamiltonian optimality conditions

becomes very difficult, especially calculating the determinant of the Hessian for

proving concavity of the Hamiltonian.

3.) The proof of the stability of a partially balanced growth path as well as the

study of transitional dynamics are relatively difficult in the PBGP-school. The

problem is that the differential equation systems of the PBGP-school are (at least)

three-dimensional. Therefore, it is necessary to find (adequate) transformations of

the three-dimensional differential equation systems into two-dimensional ones to

be able to use a phase diagram. This is often difficult (at least for me).

Note that these problems do not arise in other structural change-schools, since

other structural change schools do not require proving the existence and stability

of a PBGP.

398

Page 409: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Nevertheless, I believe that the models of Chapter V have shown that the three

mathematical problems of the PBGP-school can be solved sometimes: at least I

have managed it to solve them in my models of Chapter V.

The elaboration of the modelling-foundations of the PBGP-school in Chapter

III has shown that from the theoretical point of view there is always one

challenge to the PBGP-school: The existence of a PBGP requires usage of knife-

edge parameter restrictions. It is quite difficult to find a theoretical rationale for

these knife-edge restrictions. In Part I of Chapter V, I have searched for such a

theoretical rationale. Exactly speaking, I have argued that independency between

preferences and technologies may explain (in part) these knife-edge conditions.

Furthermore, the discussion in Chapter IV implies that structural-change-theorists

(and growth theorists) have always used some knife-edge conditions to simplify

the analysis.

Now, the last question is about the general conclusion from my work: What is

the general value of the PBGP-method? I have discussed this question

throughout my work.

In Sections 6, 7 and 8 of Chapter I, I have explained that the PBGP-method

seems to be very useful for studying structural-change-topics that require the

inclusion of capital into analysis. In contrast to the PBGP-method, the traditional

methods of structural-change-modelling require simulations to include capital (or

even they omit capital). The price that we have to pay for this advantage of the

PBGP-method is: PBGP-models may not be regarded as descriptive, i.e. they

depict only some of the many channels along which structural change affects

aggregate growth. This is due to the necessity to use knife-edge conditions to

generate PBGPs. However, the discussion in Chapter IV (especially Section 3)

399

Page 410: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

has shown that structural-change-theoreticians (and growth-theoreticians in

general) have always used some knife-edge conditions to increase the

“understandability” of their models.

The discussion in Sections 2 and 3 of Chapter II has shown that it is quite

difficult to analyse differential equation systems of multi-sector models in

general. In Chapter III, I have provided an example, explaining the difficulties

of understanding the dynamics of a multi-sector model (when capital is included

into analysis). Furthermore, I have demonstrated there how the PBGP-method

resolves these challenges by using knife-edge conditions.

Last not least, as I hope, the essays from Chapter V have shown as well that the

PBGP-method is valuable. Although the essays seem complicated, they are

actually not: Remember that all the topics/channels are in general that

complicated that only few intuitive results could be obtained without using the

PBGP-method. Normally, simulations would be necessary to get a notion of

ruling dynamics. Hence, the PBGP-method seems to be a valuable method for

deriving impact-channels and theories of structural change, i.e. for

“understanding” structural change.

In fact, my evaluation of the PBGP-method must depend on the topic-related

insights that are provided by my Chapter-V-models as well. I believe that there

are relevant/interesting insights (however, you have your own opinion on this, I

guess):

In the essay on the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle I have shown by using the PBGP-

method that the assumption of independency between preferences and

technologies may solve the Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle. The Kuznets-Kaldor-puzzle

is one of the most important/essential empirical observations regarding the

relationship between structural change and aggregate development. I have also

400

Page 411: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

tried to develop a method for assessing the degree of independency in reality and

applied it to the data of the United States.

In the essay on Offshoring I used the PBGP-method to point to the existence of an

impact channel of offshoring on real GDP-growth, which has been neglected in

the literature. Especially, I argued that offshoring slows structural change down

(in the long run) and thus reduces the negative impacts of structural change on

real-GDP-growth (via Baumol’s cost disease).

The essay on population ageing shows that the factor-reallocation effects of

ageing can be analysed by using the PBGP-method in a quite convenient way. I

hope this essay has improved the insights into structural change, which is induced

by ageing, and into the parameters, which are of importance for the relationship

between ageing and real-GDP-growth.

It seems to me that there are always new topics that could be studied by using the

PBGP-method. In fact, the most topics that are associated with structural change

could be analysed by using (some extension of) the models from Chapter V.

Last not least, as mentioned in the beginning of Chapter V, I believe that the

mathematical models, which I have presented in my work, are quite valuable on

their own, since they can be reinterpreted to analyse some new topics associated

with structural change. Remember that I have discussed in Chapters II and III that

it is very difficult to find assumptions that ensure the existence of a PBGP and

that it is even more difficult to find assumptions that additionally make the proof

of sufficiency of Hamiltonian conditions and global stability of the PBGP feasible

(when all structural change determinants are included into analysis). In fact, I

have done all this work and my models are “convenient” mathematical a-priori-

solutions, which can be adapted/reintepreted to analyse some new economic

401

Page 412: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

questions associated with structural change, without having trouble with proving

sufficiency and stability of optimal solutions.

To conclude: I believe that my research has shown that the PBGP-method is a

valuable tool for the “modern structural-change-theorist”. Of course, the PBGP-

method is only one tool among several tools for structural change modelling. That

is, the PBGP-method completes the set of traditional methods (traditional

structural change theory and simulation-based models).

I am very grateful to Prof. Wagner for supervising this work.

402

Page 413: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

REFERENCES Acemogly, D. (2009). “Introduction to Modern Economic Growth”, Princeton:

Princeton University Press.

Acemoglu, D., Guerrieri, V. (2008). “Capital Deepening and Non-Balanced

Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy, 116(3): 467-498.

Aghion, P., Howitt, P. (1998). “Endogenous Growth Theory”, Cambridge,

Mass.: MIT Press.

Amiti, M., Wei, S.-J. (2005). “Service Offshoring, Productivity, and

Employment: Evidence from the United States”, IMF working paper No.

WP/05/238.

Amiti, M., Wei, S.-J. (2006). “Service Offshoring and Productivity: Evidence

from the United States.” NBER working paper No. 11926.

Andersen, E.S. (2001). “Satiation in an Evolutionary Model of Structural

Economic Dynamics”, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11: 143–164.

Appelbaum, E., Schettkat, R. (1999). “Are Prices Unimportant? The Changing

Structure of the Industrialized Economies”, Journal of Post Keynesian

Economics, 21(3): 387-398.

Aaronson, D., Rissman, E.R., Sullivan, D.G. (2004). “Can Sectoral

Reallocation Explain the Jobless Recovery?”, Economic Perspectives (Federal

Reserve Bank of Chicago), 2Q/2004: 36-49.

Bah, E.M. (2007). “A Three-Sector Model of Structural Transformation and

Economic Development”, MPRA Paper No. 10654.

Baldwin, R., Robert-Nicoud, F. (2007). “Offshoring: General Equilibrium

Effects on Wages, Production and Trade”, NBER working paper No. 12991.

403

Page 414: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Barro, R.J., Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004). “Economic Growth”, 2nd edition,

Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Barry, F., Walsh, F. (2008). “Gains and Losses from Sectoral Relocation: A

Review of Theory and Empirics“,Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 19:

4–16.

Baumol, W.J. (1967). “Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy

of Urban Crisis”, American Economic Review, 57(3): 415-426.

Baumol, W.J., Batey Blackman, S.A., Wolf, E.N. (1985). “Unbalanced Growth

Revisited: Asymptotic Stagnancy and New Evidence”, American Economic

Review, 57(3): 415-426.

Beißinger, T. (2000). “Technischer Fortschritt als Ursache sektoralen Wandels“,

WiSt Heft 1 Januar 2000.

Benhabib, J., Nishimura, K. (1979). “The Hopf Bifurcation and the Existence

and Stability of Closed Orbits in Multisector Models of Optimal Growth”, Journal

of Economic Theory, 21: 421–444.

Bernard, A.B., Jones, C.I. (1996). “Comparing Apples to Oranges: Productivity

Convergence and Measurement across Industries and Countries”, American

Economic Review, 86(5): 1216-1238.

Berthélmy, J.C., Söderling, L. (1999). “The Role of Capital Accumulation,

Adjustment and Structural Change for Economic Take-off: Empirical Evidence

from African Growth Episodes”, OECD Development Centre Working Paper No.

150.

Bhagwati, J., Panagariya, A., Srinivasan, T.N. (2004). “The Muddles over

Outsourcing”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18: 93-114.

404

Page 415: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Blinder, A. (2005). “Fear of Offshoring”, CEPS working paper No. 119.

Blinder, A. (2007a). “How Many U.S. Jobs Might Be Offshorable?”, CEPS

working paper No. 142.

Blinder, A. (2007b). “Offshoring: Big Deal or Business as Usual?”, CEPS

working paper, No. 149.

Boldrin, M. (1988). “Paths of Optimal Accumulation in Two-sector Models”,

UCLA Dept. of Economics Working Paper No. 464.

Börsch-Supan A. (1993). “Aging in Germany and the United States:

International Comparisons”, NBER Working Paper 4530.

Börsch-Supan A. (2003). “Labor Market Effects of Population Aging”, LABOR,

17(Special Issue): 5-44.

Boppart, T. (2010). Engel's law and directed technical change. Available on the

web at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/37242

Broadberry, S.N. (1997). “The Long Run Growth and Productivity Performance

of the United Kingdom”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 44(4): 403-424.

Broadberry, S.N. (1998). “How Did the United States and Germany Overtake

Britain? A Sectoral Analysis of Comparative Productivity Levels, 1870-1990”,

The Journal of Economic History, 58(2): 375-407.

Broadberry, S.N, Irwin, D.A. (2006). “Labor Productivity in the United States

and the United Kingdom during the Nineteenth Century”, Explorations in

Economic History, 43: 257–279.

Buera, F.J., Kaboski, J.P. (2009a). “Can Traditional Theories of Structural

Change Fit the Data?”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(2-3):

469-477.

405

Page 416: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Buera, F.J., Kaboski, J.P. (2009b). “The Rise of the Service Economy”, NBER

Working Paper No. 14822.

Caselli, F., Coleman, W.J.II. (2001). “The U.S. Structural Transformation and

Regional Convergence: A Reinterpretation“, Journal of Political Economy,

109(3): 584-616.

Cass, D. (1965). “Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital

Accumulation”, Review of Economic Studies, 32(3): 233-240.

Chiang, A.C. (1984). “Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics”,

Singapore: McGraw-Hill.

Choi, E.K. (2007). “To outsource or not to outsource in an integrated world”,

International Review of Economics & Finance, 16: 521-527.

Clark, C. (1957). “The Conditions of Economic Progress”, 3rd edition. London:

Macmillan.

Close, F.A., Shulenburger, D.E. (1971). “Labor’s Share by Sector and Industry,

1948-1965”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 24(4): 588-602.

Curtis, D.C.A., Murthy, K.S.R. (1998). “Economic Growth and Restructuring:

A Test of Unbalanced Growth Models – 1977-1992”, Applied Economics Letters,

5: 777-780.

de la Fuente, A. (2000). “Mathematical Methods and Models for Economists”,

New York: Cambridge University Press.

Desai, A.M., Foley, F.C., Hines Jr., J.R. (2005). “Foreign Direct Investment and

Domestic Economic Activity”, NBER working paper No. 11717.

406

Page 417: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Disney, R., Haskel, J., Heden, Y. (2003). “Restructuring and Productivity

Growth in UK Manufacturing“, The Economic Journal, 113: 666–694.

Dowrick, S., Gemmel, N. (1991). “Industrialisation, Catching up and Economic

Growth: A Comparative Study across the World’s Capitalist Economies”, The

Economic Journal, 101: 263-275.

Duarte, M., Restuccia, D. (2010). “The Role of the Structural Transformation in

Aggregate Productivity“,The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(1): 129-173.

Echevarria, C. (1997). “Changes in Sectoral Composition Associated with

Economic Growth”, International Economic Review, 38: 431–452.

Echevarria, C. (2000). “Non-homothetic Preferences and Growth”, Journal of

International Trade and Economic Development, 9(2): 151-171.

Economic Policy Committee of the EU Commission (2003). “The Impact of

Ageing Populations on Public Finances: Overview of Analysis Carried out at EU

Level and Proposals for a Future Work Programme”, EPC/ECFIN/435/03 final.

Elfring, T. (1989). “New Evidence on the Expansion of Service Employment in

Advanced Economies“, Review of Income and Wealth, 35(4): 409-440.

Fagerberg, J. (2000). “Technological Progress, Structural Change and

Productivity Growth: A Comparative Study“, Structural Change and Economic

Dynamics, 11: 393–411.

Fisher, A.G.B. (1939). “Production, primary, secondary and tertiary”, The

Economic Record, 15: 24–38.

Fisher, A.G.B. (1952). “A note on tertiary production”, Economic Journal, 62:

820–834.

407

Page 418: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Fixler, D.J., Siegel, D. (1999). „Outsourcing and Productivity Growth in

Services”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 10(2): 177-194.

Foellmi, R., Zweimueller, J. (2008). “Structural change, Engel's consumption

cycles and Kaldor's Facts of Economic Growth”, Journal of Monetary Economics,

55(7): 1317-1328.

Foster, L., Haltiwanger, J., Krizan, C.J. (1998). „Aggregate Productivity

Growth: Lessons from Microeconomic Evidence“, NBER Working Paper 6803.

Fougère M., Mercenier J., Mérette, M. (2007). “A Sectoral and Occupational

Analysis of Population Ageing in Canada Using a Dynamic CGE Overlapping

Generations Model”, Economic Modelling, 24(4): 690-711.

Fourastié, J. (1969). „Die Große Hoffnung des Zwanzigsten Jahrhunderts“, 2nd

edition, Köln: Bund-Verlag.

Fuchs, V.R. (1998). “Provide, Provide: The Economics of Aging”, NBER

Working Paper 6642.

Gandolfo, G. (1996). “Economic Dynamics”, 3rd edition, Heidelberg: Springer.

Garner, C.A. (2004). “Offshoring in the Service Sector: Economic Impact and

Policy Issues”, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, 3rd

Quarter.

Girma, S., Gorg, H. (2004). “Outsourcing, Foreign Ownership and Productivity:

Evidence from UK establishment level data”, Review of International Economics,

12: 817-832.

Gollin, D. (2002). “Getting Income Shares Right”, Journal of Political Economy,

110(2), 458-474.

408

Page 419: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Gollin, D., Parente, S., Rogerson, R. (2002). “The Role of Agriculture in

Development”, AEA Papers and Proceedings, 92(2): 160-164.

Gollin, D., Parente, S.L., Rogerson, R. (2007). “The Food Problem and the

Evolution of International Income Levels”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 54:

1230–1255.

Goodwin, R.M., Punzo, L.F. (1987). “The Dynamics of a Capitalist Economy. A

Multisectoral Approach”, Oxford: Polity Press.

Greenhalg, C., Gregory, M. (2001). “Structural Change and the Eemergence of

the New Service Economy”, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 63

(special issue): 629-646.

Greenwood, J., Uysal, G. (2005). “New Goods and the Transition to a New

Economy”, Journal of Economic Growth, 10: 99–134.

Groezen van, B., Meijdam, L., Verbon, H.A.A. (2005). “Serving the Old:

Ageing and Economic Growth”, Oxford Economic Papers, 57(4): 647-663.

Grossman, G.M., Helpman, E. (1991). “Innovation and Growth in the Global

Economy”, Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press.

Grossman, G.M., Helpman, E. (2005). “Outsourcing in a Global Economy”,

Review of Economic Studies, 72: 135-159.

Gruescu, S. (2007). “Population Ageing and Economic Growth”, Physica.

Heidelberg.

Gualerzi, D. (2001). “Consumption and Growth: Recovery and Structural

Change in the US Economy”, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

Gundlach, E. (1994). “Demand Bias as an Explanation for Structural Change”,

Kyklos, 47(2): 249-267.

409

Page 420: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Hahn, W. (1967). “Stability of Motion”, Berlin: Springer.

Hanson, G.H., Mataloni Jr., R.J, Slaughter, M.J. (2003). “Expansion Abroad

and the Domestic Operations of U.S. Multinational Firms.” mimeo. Available on

the web at:

http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/matthew.slaughter/working_papers/

MNE%20Links%200903.pdf

Harris, D.J. (1982). “Structural Change and Economic Growth A Review

Article”, Contributions to Political Economy, 1: 25-45.

Hsieh, C.T., Klenow, P.J. (2007). “Relative Prices and Relative Prosperity”,

American Economic Review, 97(3): 562-585.

International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2004). “World Economic Outlook: The

Global Demographic Transition. Chapter III: How Will Demographic Change

Affect the Global Economy?”, Available on the web at:

http://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/weo/2004/02/pdf/chapter3.pdf

Irwin, D. (2005). “Comments on James Markusen”, in: Brookings Trade Forum

on “Offshoring White-Collar Work”.

Jensen, J.B., Kletzer, L.G. (2006). „Tradable Services: Understanding the Scope

and Impact of Services Offshoring”, in:. Brookings Trade Forum on “Offshoring

White-Collar Work”.

Jensen, B.S., Larsen, M.E. (2004). “General Equilibrium Dynamics of Multi-

Sector Growth Models“, Journal of Economics, Suppl. 10: 17-56.

Kaganovich, M. (1998). “Sustained Endogenous Growth with Decreasing

Returns and Heterogeneous Capital“, Journal of Economic Dynamics and

Control, 22: 1575-1603.

410

Page 421: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Kamien, M.I., Schwartz, N.L. (2000). “Dynamic Optimization”, 2nd edition,

Amsterdam: Elsevier.

Klevorick, A.K., Levin, R.C., Nelson, R.R., Winter, S.G. (1995). “On the

Sources and Significance of Interindustry Differences in Technological

Opportunities”, Research Policy 24: 185-205.

Kongsamut, P., Rebelo, S., Xie, D. (1997). „Beyond Balanced Growth“, NBER

Working Paper, 6159.

Kongsamut, P., Rebelo, S., Xie, D. (2001). „Beyond Balanced Growth”, Review

of Economic Studies, 68(4): 869-882.

Krüger, J.J. (2008). “Productivity and Structural Change: A Review of the

Literature”, Journal of Economic Surveys, 22(2): 330–363.

Kuhn, P. (2003). “Effects of Population Ageing on Labour Market Flows in

Canada: Analytical Issues and Research Priorities”, HRDC-IC Working Paper A-

02.

Kuznets, S. (1976). “Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure and Spread”, 7th

edition, New Haven: Yale University Press.

Laitner, J. (2000). “Structural Change and Economic Growth”, Review of

Economic Studies, 67: 545-561.

Landefeld, J.S., Seskin, E.P., Fraumeni, B.M. (2008). “Taking the Pulse of the

Economy: Measuring GDP”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 22(2): 193-216.

Landesmann, M.A., Stehrer, R. (2006). “Goodwin’s Structural Economic

Dynamics: Modelling Schumpeterian and Keynesian Insights”, Structural Change

and Economic Dynamics, 17: 501–524.

411

Page 422: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Maddison, A. (1980). “Economic Growth and Structural Change in the

Advanced Countries”, in: L. Irving and J.W. Wheeler (Eds.), Western Economies

in Transition: Structural Change and Adjustment Policies in Industrial Countries

(pp. 41–65). London: Croom Helm.

Maddison, A. (1987). “Growth and Slowdown in Advanced Capitalist

Economies: Techniques of Quantitative Assessment”, Journal of Economic

Literature, 25: 649-698.

Mankiw, G.N., Swagel, P. (2006). “The Politics and Economics of Offshore

Outsourcing”, NBER working paper No. 12398.

Mann, C.L. (2004). “Globalization of IT Services and White Collar Jobs: The

Next Wave of Productivity Growth”, International Economics Policy Briefs, 3-11.

Institute of International Economics.

Malinvaud, E. (1995). “Luigi Pasinetti's Structural Economic Dynamics: A

Review Essay”, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 5: 59-69.

Marin, D. (2006). “A New International Division of Labor in Europe:

Outsourcing and Offshoring to Eastern Europe”, Journal of the European

Economic Association, 4: 612-622.

Matsuyama, K. (2009). “Structural Change in an Interdependent World: A

Global View of Manufacturing Decline”, Journal of European Economic

Association, 7(2-3): 478-486.

Maußner, A., Klump, R. (1996). “Wachstumstheorie”, Berlin, Heidelberg:

Springer.

Mc Morrow, K., Röger, W. (2003). “Economic and Financial Market

Consequences of Ageing Populations”, European Commission Economic Paper

182.

412

Page 423: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Meckl, J. (2002). “Structural Change and Generalized Balanced Growth”,

Journal of Economics, 77(3): 241-266.

Messina, J. (2003). “Sectoral Structure and Entry Regulations“, IZA Discussion

Paper No. 747.

Metcalfe, J.S., Foster, J. Ramlogan, R. (2006). “Adaptive Economic Growth“,

Cambridge Journal of Economics, 30: 7–32.

Mickiewicz, T., Zalewska, A. (2001). “Deindustrialsation and Structural Change

during the Post-Communist Transition”, William Davidson Institute Working

Paper No. 383.

Milberg, W., Mahoney, M., Schneider, M., von Arnim, R. (2006). “Dynamic

Gains from U.S. Services Offshoring: A Critical View”, SCEPA working paper

No. 2006-4.

Montobbio, F. (2002). “An Evolutionary Model of Industrial Growth and

Structural Change”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 13: 387–414.

Nayak, P., Mishra, S.K. (2009). “Structural Change in Meghalaya: Theory and

Evidence”, MPRA Paper No. 15728.

Ngai, R.L., Pissarides, C.A. (2004). “Structural Change in a Multi-Sector Model

of Growth”, CEP Discussion Paper, 627.

Ngai, R.L., Pissarides, C.A. (2007). “Structural Change in a Multisector Model

of Growth”, American Economic Review, 97(1): 429-443.

Ngai, L.R., Pissarides, C.A. (2008). “Trends in Hours and Economic Growth”,

Review of Economic Dynamics, 11: 239–256.

Nordhaus, W.D. (2008). “Baumol's Diseases: A Macroeconomic Perspective”,

The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 8(1) (Contributions), Article 9.

413

Page 424: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Notarangelo, M. (1999). “Unbalanced Growth: A Case of Structural Dynamics“,

Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 10: 209–223.

Olsen, K.B. (2006). “Productivity Impacts of Offshoring and Outsourcing: A

Review”, OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2006/1,

OECD Publishing.

Oulton, N. (2001). “Must the Growth Rate Decline? Baumol’s Unbalanced

Growth Revisited”, Oxford Economic Papers, 53: 605–627.

Oxley, L. (1994). “Conitegration, Causality and Wagner’s Law: A Test for

Britain 1870-1913”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 41(3): 286-298.

Pasinetti, L. (1981). “Structural Change and Economic Growth: A Theoretical

Essay on the Dynamics of the Wealth of Nations”, Cambridge, Mass.: Cambridge

University Press.

Pasinetti, L. (1988). “Vorlesungen zur Theorie der Produktion”, Marburg:

Metropolis.

Pasinetti, L. (1993). “Structural Economic Dynamics: A theory of the Economic

Consequences of Human Learning”, Cambridge, Mass.: Cambridge University

Press.

Pavitt, K. (1985). “Sectoral Patterns of Technical Change: Towards a Taxonomy

and a Theory”, Research Policy, 13: 343-373.

Penderer, M. (2003). “Industrial Structure and Aggregate Growth“, Structural

Change and Economic Dynamics, 14: 427-448.

Poirson, H. (2000). “The Impact of Intersectoral Labor Reallocation on

Economic Growth”, IMF Working Paper No. WP/00/104.

414

Page 425: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Pugno, M. (2006). “The Service Paradox and Endogenous Economic Growth“,

Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 17: 99–115.

Punzo, L.F. (2006). “Towards a Disequilibrium Theory of Structural Dynamics

Goodwin’s Contribution”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 17: 382–

399.

Raiser, M., Schaffer, M, Schuchhardt, J. (2003). “Benchmarking Structural

Change in Transition”, IZA Discussion Paper No. 727.

Rausch, S. (2006). “Aging, Trade and Welfare in a Heckscher-Ohlin Model with

Overlapping Generations”, Available on the web at:

http://www.rwi-

essen.de/pls/portal30/docs/FOLDER/RGS/RESEARCH/PUBLICATIONS/RAUS

CH_AGING,+TRADE+AND+WELFARE_ABSTRACT.PDF

Restuccia, D., Yang, D.T., Zhua, X. (2008). “Agriculture and Aggregate

Productivity: A Quantitative Cross-Country Analysis”, Journal of Monetary

Economics, 55: 234–250.

Robinson, S. (1971). “Sources of Growth in Less Developed Countries: A Cross-

Section Study”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85(3): 391-408.

Rodríguez-Clare, A. (2007). “Offshoring in a Ricardian World”, NBER working

paper No. 13203.

Rogerson, R. (2008). “Structural Transformation and the Deterioration of

European Labor Market Outcomes“, Journal of Political Economy, 116(2): 235-

259.

Romer, P.M. (1990). “Endogenous Technological Change”, Journal of Political

Economy, 98(5): S71-S102.

415

Page 426: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Rommelfanger, H. (2006). “Mathematik für Wirtschaftswissenschaftler, Band 3:

Differenzengleichungen, Differentialgleichungen, Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie,

Stochastische Prozesse”, Heidelberg: Elsevier, Spektrum.

Rowthorn, R., Ramaswamy, R. (1999). “Growth, Trade, and

Deindustrialization”, IMF Working Paper No. WP/98/60.

Samuelson, P. (1948). “Some Implications of "Linearity"”, The Review of

Economic Studies, 15(2): 88-90.

Samuelson, P. (2004). “Where Ricardo and Mill Rebut and Confirm Arguments

of Mainstream Economists Supporting Globalization”, Journal of Economic

Perspectives, 18: 135-146.

Sasaki, H. (2007). “The Rise of Service Employment and its Impact on

Aggregate Productivity Growth“, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 18:

438–459.

Saviotti, P.P., Pyka, A. (2004). “Economic Development by the Creation of New

Sectors”, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14: 1–35.

Schettkat, R., Yocarini, L. (2006). “The Shift to Services Employment: A

Review of the Literature”, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 17(2):

127–147.

Simpson, H. (2009). “Productivity in Public Services”, Journal of Economic

Surveys, 23(2): 250–276.

Steindel, C. (1995). “Chain-weighting: The New Approach to Measuring GDP”,

Current Issues in Economics and Finance (Federal Reserve Bank of New York),

1(9).

416

Page 427: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Takahashi, H. (2008). “Optimal Balanced Growth in a General Multi-Sector

Endogenous Growth Model with Constant Returns”, Economic Theory, 37: 31–

49.

Takahashi, H. (1992). “The von Neuman Facet and a Global Asymptotic

Stability”, Annals of Operations Research, 37:273-282.

Temple, J. (2001). “Structural Change and Europe’s Golden Age“, CEPR

(International Macroeconomics) Working Paper No. 2861.

United Nations (2006). “Structural Change and Economic Growth“, World

Economic and Social Survey 2006, Chapter 2: 29-51.

United States Government Accountability Office (GAO) (2005). “Offshoring

of Services: An Overview of the Issues”, Report to Congressional Committees,

November 2005.

Uzawa, H. (1964). “Optimal Growth in a Two-Sector Model of Capital

Accumulation”, The Review of Economic Studies, 31(1): 1-24.

Valentinyi, A., Herrendorf, B. (2008). “Measuring factor income shares at the

sectoral level”, Review of Economic Dynamics, 11(4): 820-835.

Van Welsum, D., Vickery, G. (2005). “Potential Offshoring of ICT-intensive

using Occupations”, OECD. Available on the web at:

http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/35/11/34682317.pdf

Vogt, W. (1973). “Seminar Politische Ökonomie“, Frankfurt a.M.: Suhrkamp.

Wagner, H. (1997). “Wachstum und Entwicklung – Theorie der

Entwicklungspolitik”, 2nd edition, München: Oldenburg.

Wolfe, M. (1955). “The concept of economic sectors”, Quarterly Journal of

Economics, 69(3): 402–420.

417

Page 428: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Zuleta, H., Young, A.T. (2007). “Labor’s Shares – Aggregate and Industry:

Accounting for Both in a Model of Unbalanced Growth with Induced

Innovation”, University of Rosario Working Paper (Economics), No. 10-2007.

418

Page 429: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Curriculum Vitae (Lebenslauf) March 2011 (März 2011)

Name (Name): Denis Stijepic Date of Birth (Geburtsdatum): 27th November1981 (27. November 1981) Place of Birth (Geburtsort): Doboj, Jugoslavia (Doboj, Jugoslawien) Education (Bildungsweg): 2001

Higher education entrance qualification, academic high school in Wallduern, Germany; Grade: 1.2 (Allgemeine Hochschulreife, wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Gymnasium in Walldürn; Notendurchschnitt: 1,2)

2006 Master degree in economics, J.W. Goethe-University in Frankfurt am Main, Germany; Grade: 1.5 (Diplom Volkswirt, J.W. Goethe-Universitaet in Frankfurt am Main; Gesamtnote: sehr gut (1,5))

Occupation (Beruflicher Werdegang): Since 2007 research assistant, Chair of Macroeconomics, University in

Hagen (Seit 2007 wissenschaftlicher Mitarbeiter am Lehrstuhl für

Makroökonomie, FernUniversität in Hagen)

Page 430: Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within … · Structural Change and Economic Growth: Analysis within the “Partially Balanced Growth-Framework” ... An unbalanced

Erklärung laut §6(8) der Promotionsordnung

Hiermit versichere ich, dass ich die vorliegende Dissertation selbständig und ohne unerlaubte Hilfe angefertigt und andere als die in der Dissertation angegebenen Hilfsmittel nicht benutzt habe. Insbesondere habe ich nicht die Hilfe einer Promotionsberaterin/eines Promotionsberaters in Anspruch genommen. Alle Stellen, die wörtlich oder sinngemäß aus veröffentlichten oder nicht veröffentlichten Schriften entnommen sind, habe ich als solche kenntlich gemacht.

Denis Stijepic