Top Banner
Stabilization and Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University
32

Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Dec 26, 2015

Download

Documents

Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Stabilization and Fiscal Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: Consolidation:

The Case of IsraelThe Case of Israel

Efraim SadkaTel Aviv University

Page 2: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• Inflation is normally considered to be a monetary phenomenon.“Classical” Dichotomy between nominal and real variables.

• This may be true as long as fiscal policy is “within the ball park”.

• However: persistent, high public sector deficit (and persistent, high public expenditures) are doomed to lead to large current account deficits, a rising external debt, balance-of-payment crises, currency devaluation and spiraling inflation.The absence of budget discipline, coupled with an almost inevitable monetary accommodation, will eventually fuel an inflationary process that could run out of control.

1

Page 3: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Total Public Sector DeficitTotal Public Sector Deficit

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90

Per

cent

of

GD

P

2

Page 4: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Public Spending (% of GNP)Public Spending (% of GNP)

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91

Per

cent

of G

NP

Defense Other Total

3

Page 5: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

The Ratio of Public Debt to GNPThe Ratio of Public Debt to GNP

020406080

100

120140160180200

61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91

Per

cent

4

Page 6: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Annual Inflation Rates, 1960-89Annual Inflation Rates, 1960-89

050

100150200250300350400450500

Perc

ent p

er y

ear

5

Page 7: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• Israel managed to stabilize its economy in mid-1985.Before that several stabilization attempts were made. Most notable among them:

- “Five-Five Plan” (devaluation of five percent per month and increases of five percent per month in the controlled subsidized prices of basic necessities).- “Package Deals” (voluntary wage-price freezes).

• They all failed after a few months, because they failed to handle the real thing: the large public sector deficit (some even increased the deficit).

6

Page 8: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• The 1985 stabilization:

- Total and Immediate Elimination of the public sector deficit.

- This elimination was achieved mainly by “good” or “successful” cuts (Alberto Alesina and Roberto Perotti). Budget cuts can actually increase rather than decrease the Debt/GDP ratio, if they cause recession (lowering GDP, increasing transfer payments such as unemployment insurance, and reducing the revenues). “Good” cuts are those that rely on spending cuts (wage bill and transfer payments) rather than on tax increases; such fiscal adjustments are often associated (in the longer-run) with increases in growth, crowding in of private investments and reduction in unemployment.

7

Page 9: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

In the Israeli case, the fiscal adjustments consisted mainly of spending cuts (defense expenditures, subsidies, wage freeze in the public sector).Tax revenues rose too. The increase was caused mainly as a result of a lower inflation and by tightening the inflation-proofness of the income tax in the business sector – A unique Israeli feature (which is well worth elaboration; see below)

• The stabilization did not have a significant effect on unemployment.

8

Page 10: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Unemployment Rate, 1981-88Unemployment Rate, 1981-88

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988

Per

cent

9

Page 11: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• A perfectly synchronized monetary policy would have called for a discrete, one-shot “jump” in the money supply in order to accommodate the increased demand for money in the new environment of price stability, and then a slow growth of this supply.

In practice: tight monetary policy from the beginning, bringing about unprecedented high short-term interest rates.

10

Page 12: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

The Real Cost of Bank Credit, 1980-87The Real Cost of Bank Credit, 1980-87

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

80 81 82 83 84 85;1 85;2 86;1 86;2 87;1 87;2

Per

cen

t

11

Page 13: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• Traditionally, inflation is considered to induce automatic stabilizing effects. Israeli experience suggests quite the opposite:All in all, one should adopt the term “The Inflation Subsidy”. In fact, a key automatic Destabilizer, a major contributor to the spiraling inflationary process was the tax system, especially in the business sector.

12

Page 14: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• The features that are traditionally considered to be inflation-induced automatic stabilizers are:

(i) The real depreciation of money. However, like with any tax, the tax base (that is, money holdings) shrinks as the tax rate (that is, inflation) rises, so that tax revenues do not necessary rise. The Israeli experience: the so- called inflation tax can hardly generate one percent of GNP in revenues, no matter how high is the rate.

(ii) with a progressive income tax, inflation increases real tax revenues, when income tax brackets are not indexed. However, it is naïve to believe that a government which fails to exercise a fiscal discipline can actually resist public pressure to index the income tax brackets, when inflation picks up.

13

Page 15: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• Against these two mild or altogether non-existent stabilizing effects there are two major destabilizing effects.

(i) First, there is the so-called “Tanzi effect”: Due to collection lags, defined as the time that elapses between the date when the tax liability accrues and the time when the tax payment is received by the government, inflation causes erosion of the Real tax revenues. In the Israeli case, this erosion reached 10% (!) of overall tax revenues.

(ii) Second, the Israeli experience suggests that inflation virtually demolishes the income tax base in the business sector:

14

Page 16: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

(a) (Nominal) capital gains are taxed upon realization while (nominal) interest is deductible on an accrual basis. This gives rise to a very simple, yet powerful tax-avoidance technique: use debt-finance to invest in fixed assets (equipment, real estate), to acquire new firms, etc.

Furthermore, as inflation rises, there arises a mounting pressure on the government to either lower the tax on nominal capital gains, or tax only the real part of capital gains; and the government sooner or later yields to such pressures. Needless to say, no such measures are applied with respect to the deductibility of nominal interest.

The outcome of such partial (unbalanced) tax adjustments for inflation – a further reduction in tax revenues from the business sector. It took a few years of high inflation until the government attempted to enact a comprehensive adjustment for inflation in the tax system; and this applied mainly to corporations only. 15

Page 17: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

(b) An example of a tax avoidance for self-employed (proprietorships): Revenues $200,000 Expenses $150,000 Taxable Income $ 50,000

The rate of exchange: $ 1 = NIS 1 at the beginning of the tax year $ 1 = NIS 2 at the end of the tax year

Now, if you can get the revenues at the beginning of the tax year and postpone payment of expenses to the end of the year then: Revenues NIS 200,000 Expenses NIS 300,000 Net Loss NIS 100,000

Why would your clients and suppliers agree to let you maneuver your revenues and expenses in this way? After all, you reduce your taxable income but theirs rise. However, they are indifferent, if they are non-profit organizations (including the government), or if they are corporations whose taxable income is calculated on a real basis, or if they are foreign entities, etc.

16

Page 18: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

(c) The outcome: A sharp decline in tax revenues from corporations and proprietorships. Also, the distribution of the tax burden shifted Dramatically. With price stability, the income tax burden was distributed as follows: Wage-Earners: 1/3 Corporations and Self-Employed: 2/3 As inflation picked up, the distribution of the tax burden shifted against wage-earners as follows:

Wage-Earners: 2/3Corporations and Self-employed: 1/3

Similarly, effective average tax rates on capital income:1980 1985 1990-4.4% -34.8% 34.5%

(The decline in the effective tax rate on capital income occurred even though the statutory corporate tax went down from 60% in 1980 to 40% in 1990)

• Indeed, the 1985 stabilization program was associated with an increase in tax revenues brought about by: (i) the automatic destabilizer feature of the tax system; (ii) changes in the tax laws aimed at providing a more comprehensive adjustment for inflation. 17

Page 19: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Effective Average Tax RatesEffective Average Tax Rates

-40

-30

-20

-10

0

10

20

30

40

1980 1985 1990Perc

ent

Consumption Labor Income Capital Income18

Page 20: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• Conclusion / Recommendation:

A nominal tax system acts as an automatic destabilizer; furthermore, governments tend to yield to public pressure and to provide some adjustments (relieves) for inflation; and partial adjustments might be worse than no adjustments at all.Therefore, fully adjust the income tax system for inflation (an inflation-proof tax system).An inflation-proof tax system is efficient, fair, equitable and does not act as an automatic destabilizer.

19

Page 21: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• The 1985 stabilization program managed to bring inflation down immediately to the 15-20% range. And gradually later to the high, single-digit range.

• Price stability (price increases at annual rates of 1-3%) was achieved in the second half on the last decade, but at a real cost of a long period of economic slowdown and rising unemployment that started in 1996 and were aggravated by the eruption of the Intifada in the last quarter of 2000.

20

Page 22: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• Cost of living adjustments (COLA) to wages are very useful at a time of disinflation. Their absence in Israel in recent years induced wage contracts based on official inflation targets. When these targets were consistently (some may say deliberately) missed from below, real wages rose and, consequently, unemployment rose too.

Bringing down the annual inflation rate to the 1-3% range in the second half of the last decade imposed a fairly high economic toll.

21

Page 23: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Rate of Inflation – Target and ActualRate of Inflation – Target and Actual

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

Target Upper Bound Target Lower Bound Actual22

Page 24: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Change in Real WageChange in Real Wage

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

Per

cent

Public Private Average

23

Page 25: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Unemployment Rate, 1995-2001Unemployment Rate, 1995-2001

012345

6789

10

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

Per

cent

24

Page 26: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• “There is a time for everything and a reason for every activity under haven: … a time to tear down and a time to build … a time to tear and a time to mend” (Ecclesiastes)

With a totally irresponsible government, one should emphasize almost exclusively just one thing: fiscal discipline, without any “if”, “but”, etc.

25

Page 27: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Nowadays, we should make two reservations:• First, it is important not to conduct pro-cyclical

fiscal policy. One should look at the “cyclically adjusted” budget deficit. One measure, suggested by Blanchard, would be to calculate what the budget balance would be in a certain year, if unemployment had not changed from the preceding years.That is, we eliminate from the budget balance changes in taxes and transfers induced by changes in unemployment with unchanged tax-transfers laws.

26

Page 28: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• Second, it is important to emphasize that fiscal policy cannot be judged on the basis of just one variable: the budget balance. One should also look at the levels of expenditures and taxes and their composition.

Of particular interest is the level of public investment. Maintaining balanced budget by depressing public investment is a bad policy prescription. It has a negative effect on total factor productivity, labor productivity and economic growth in the long-run.

27

Page 29: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Accumulated Investment Gap in Accumulated Investment Gap in Roads and Rails (in the 90s)Roads and Rails (in the 90s)

1.42%= Average Investment in the Western Countries, 1991-95

YearInvestment in IsraelYearly gap in investment between Israel and the

Western Countries %)of GDP()in Billion Shekel,

1999 prices(

19900.47%1.30.95%

19910.62%1.80.80%

19920.71%2.20.71%

19930.90%2.80.52%

19940.88%3.00.54%

19950.83%3.00.59%

19960.92%3.50.50%

19970.81%3.20.61%

19980.99%4.00.43%

19990.79%3.20.63%

Total6.30%

417.4 GDP in 1999 (in Billion of Shekels)26.3 Accumulated investment gap in roads and rails in the 90s 28

Page 30: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Traffic Density over TimeTraffic Density over Time

0

50

100

150

200

250

1985

=10

0

29

Page 31: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

Traffic Density IndexTraffic Density Index**

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

Israel

Portu

gal

Italy

UK

Average

Germ

any

Neth

erland

s

Czeck

R.

Japan

Sw

itzerland

Den

mark

Fran

ce

Sw

eden

Sp

ain

Fin

land

* Adjusted number of kilometers traveled per one kilometer of road, 199630

Page 32: Stabilization and Fiscal Consolidation: The Case of Israel Efraim Sadka Tel Aviv University.

• Perhaps, fiscal discipline should be examined in terms of public saving rather than in terms of the budget balance (public saving is public balance, minus public investment.)Long-term public investment may be properly financed by debt. Such a practice may indeed increase the “gross” public debt, but such an increase is accompanied by an increase in the stock of public capital, so that “net” public debt does not rise.Furthermore, a shift from debt-financed to tax-financed public investments imposes an undue, heavy burden on the transition generation. This generation must pay taxes to finance both the debt-financed public investments carried out in the past and the new tax-financed public investments.

31