Top Banner
European Journal of International Relations 1–26 © The Author(s) 2015 Reprints and permissions: sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/1354066114565721 ejt.sagepub.com E J R I Revolutions and international relations: Rediscovering the classical bourgeois revolutions Alexander Anievas University of Cambridge, UK Abstract In the modern era, revolutions have been central to the structure and dynamics of international affairs. They have always been international events: international in origin, ideology, process and effect, supercharging the rhythms and logics of any given international system. Yet, within the discipline of International Relations, the study of revolutions has remained something of a secondary subject. Not only have there been relatively few studies theoretically engaging with revolution and international relations, but the dominant theoretical frameworks in International Relations have largely bracketed out revolutions from their conceptions of international politics. Yet, if revolutions have been, in part, international in both cause and effect, thereby transcending the confines of ‘second-’ and ‘third-image’ conceptions of international relations, we require theoretical tools capable of capturing the sociological and geopolitical dimensions of these Janus-faced events without reducing one dimension to the other. Drawing on the theory of uneven and combined development, this article provides such a conception, organically uniting both ‘sociological’ and ‘geopolitical’ modes of explanation. It does so, in particular, by re-examining two of the key ‘classical’ bourgeois revolutions of the early-modern epoch: the English and French revolutions. Keywords Bourgeois revolutions, capitalism, critical theory, international system, Marxism, political economy Corresponding author: Alexander Anievas, University of Cambridge, The Alison Richard Building, 7 West Road, Cambridge, CB3 9DT, UK. Email: [email protected] 565721EJT 0 0 10.1177/1354066114565721European Journal of International RelationsAnievas research-article 2014 Original Article
26

Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Apr 26, 2023

Download

Documents

Mitch Green
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

European Journal of International Relations

1 –26© The Author(s) 2015

Reprints and permissions: sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav

DOI: 10.1177/1354066114565721ejt.sagepub.com

EJ RI

Revolutions and international relations: Rediscovering the classical bourgeois revolutions

Alexander AnievasUniversity of Cambridge, UK

AbstractIn the modern era, revolutions have been central to the structure and dynamics of international affairs. They have always been international events: international in origin, ideology, process and effect, supercharging the rhythms and logics of any given international system. Yet, within the discipline of International Relations, the study of revolutions has remained something of a secondary subject. Not only have there been relatively few studies theoretically engaging with revolution and international relations, but the dominant theoretical frameworks in International Relations have largely bracketed out revolutions from their conceptions of international politics. Yet, if revolutions have been, in part, international in both cause and effect, thereby transcending the confines of ‘second-’ and ‘third-image’ conceptions of international relations, we require theoretical tools capable of capturing the sociological and geopolitical dimensions of these Janus-faced events without reducing one dimension to the other. Drawing on the theory of uneven and combined development, this article provides such a conception, organically uniting both ‘sociological’ and ‘geopolitical’ modes of explanation. It does so, in particular, by re-examining two of the key ‘classical’ bourgeois revolutions of the early-modern epoch: the English and French revolutions.

KeywordsBourgeois revolutions, capitalism, critical theory, international system, Marxism, political economy

Corresponding author:Alexander Anievas, University of Cambridge, The Alison Richard Building, 7 West Road, Cambridge, CB3 9DT, UK. Email: [email protected]

565721 EJT0010.1177/1354066114565721European Journal of International RelationsAnievasresearch-article2014

Original Article

Page 2: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

2 European Journal of International Relations

Introduction

In Martin Wight’s (1966) classic Power Politics, he estimated that as of 1960, the period generally considered to span the history of modern international relations had witnessed ‘256 years of international revolution to 212 unrevolutionary’ years (Wight, 1966: 92). Since that time, the world has experienced a near-perpetual state of revolution, as exem-plified by the vast array of popular revolts, guerrilla wars and resistance movements emerging over the period. It would seem, then, that the default setting of modern interna-tional relations has been one of revolution: an epoch perhaps best understood as a series of continuing attempts to confront the challenges of social disorder and revolution wrought by the international expansion of capitalist relations: in short, an era of perma-nent counter-revolution from which the discipline of International Relations (IR) itself crystallized out of (cf. Van Pijl, 2014).

In the modern epoch, revolutions have been absolutely central to the changing struc-ture and dynamics of international affairs. They have always been international events: international in origin, ideology, process and effect, supercharging (both ideologically and politically) the rhythms and logics of any given international system. The co-consti-tutive nature of revolutions and international relations is well captured by Arno Mayer (2000: 534, 533), when he writes of how ‘at every point’ in a revolution’s development, ‘international politics impinges on’ its course, while the creation and consolidation of revolutionary states ‘perhaps best dramatizes the centrality of interstate relations and war’ to modern social development.

Yet, within the discipline of International Relations (IR), the study of revolutions has remained something of a secondary subject. Not only have there been relatively few stud-ies theoretically engaging with revolution and international relations, but the dominant theoretical frameworks — notably, realism, liberalism and constructivism — have largely bracketed-out revolutions from their conceptions of international politics (but see Armstrong, 1993; Halliday, 1999; Walt, 1997). In the extreme case of structural realism, revolutions have been altogether excluded from the study of international relations as they remain outside Kenneth Waltz’s discretely conceived international system, which abstracts from the sociological terrain (the so-called ‘domestic’) through which revolutions are sup-posedly formed.1 Hence, revolutions remain at the margins of the discipline, constituting ‘the great anomaly’, as Fred Halliday (2001: 693) put it, as they are continually viewed as ‘aberrations’ and/or ‘abnormalities’ to the regular anarchic dictates of the international system conceived as a realm of perennial great power struggles over the balance of power.

Yet, if revolutions are, in part, international in both cause and effect, transcending the confines of ‘second-’ and ‘third-image’ conceptions of international relations, we require theoretical tools capable of capturing the sociological and geopolitical dimensions of these Janus-faced events without reducing one dimension into the other. One might think that historical sociology, which has commonly pointed to ‘the international’ as a cause of revolutions (see, especially, Foran, 2005; Skocpol, 1979), would show us the way. Nonetheless, here too, ‘the international’ remains ‘powerfully acknowledged but analyti-cally unpenetrated’, leading to continual charges of ‘attaching an essentialized, Realist conception of the international onto historical sociology’ (Rosenberg, 2006: 310).

Page 3: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 3

What we need, then, is a theory of socio-historical development that organically fuses both sociological (‘internalist’) and geopolitical (‘externalist’) modes of explanation into a single unified theoretical apparatus. It is perhaps no surprise that the most attuned scholar of revolutions in IR, Fred Halliday (1999), would come to identify ‘uneven and combined development’ (U&CD) as one such possible theory. Nonetheless, within Halliday’s work, the concept remained something of an afterthought; Halliday never systematically integrated the concept into his theoretical understandings of revolutions, thus never realizing the potential of U&CD as a unified theory of socio-historical devel-opment. This task was left to one of Halliday’s students, Justin Rosenberg, who has sought to rework Trotsky’s concept as a historical sociological theory of ‘the interna-tional’ (Rosenberg, 2006). What Rosenberg has demonstrated is that the concept of U&CD uniquely interpolates a distinctly international dimension of causality as intrinsic to the historical process of development itself (Rosenberg, 2010). This then renders ‘the international’ historically and sociologically intelligible, overcoming both realist reifica-tions of the international system as an absolutely autonomous (‘supra-social’) sphere and classical sociology’s tendency to falsely subsume its distinctive causal dynamics and behavioural patterns to unisocietal abstractions.

Given U&CD’s origins as a theoretical tool to explain the Bolshevik Revolution (Trotsky, 1959 [1930]), it is, then, surprising that the theory has yet to be deployed in explaining these international dimensions of revolutions (but see Matin, 2013). This is the aim of the following article, which seeks to draw on and further develop the theory in explaining two key instances of ‘bourgeois revolution’, the English and French. In doing so, the article seeks to further tease out the theory’s implications for understanding pre-capitalist periods of international relations, as demonstrated in the English case, while remaining sufficiently attuned to the qualitative transformations that occurred over the capitalist epoch.

The article is developed in four movements. The first section reconsiders the con-cept of ‘bourgeois revolutions’ in terms of the effects of revolutions in creating and consolidating territorially demarcated sovereign centres of capital accumulation, rather than defining them in terms of their agents. This ‘consequentialist’ interpretation of bourgeois revolutions subverts revisionist and Political Marxist critiques of the con-cept while providing a more apposite framework to understand their differential effects in their domestic and international dimensions. The section then concludes by spelling out the main causal components of the theory of U&CD in explaining modern revolu-tions. The second section turns to examine the English Civil Wars of 1640–1651 and the Glorious Revolution of 1688–1689, highlighting the largely overlooked interna-tional origins and effects of the revolutions theoretically captured by the notion of U&CD. The third section analyses the French Revolution of 1789–1815, arguing that the revolution was, indeed, bourgeois and capitalist in both origin and outcome, subse-quently transforming the character and dynamics of the European international system over the Long Nineteenth Century. The conclusion then teases out the implications of the preceding theoretically informed empirical analysis for understanding the relation-ship between revolutions and the modern international system for both IR and Marxist theories.

Page 4: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

4 European Journal of International Relations

Bourgeois revolutions and Uneven and combined development

Reconceptualising bourgeois revolutions: A consequentialist approach

Before providing a historical narrative and analysis of the ‘classical’ bourgeois revolu-tions, we must first define what we mean by ‘bourgeois revolution’. For many historians and social scientists, the concept has been shown to be both empirically and theoretically untenable. This has been the main finding of the ‘revisionist’ historiographies of the French and English Revolutions currently fashionable within the Anglo-Saxon academy. These were primarily initiated as a critique of the orthodox Marxist model of bourgeois revolution emerging during the interwar years and after. For the revisionists, the revolu-tions were not heralded by the ascendancy of a distinctly capitalist bourgeois class: during the revolutions, the bourgeoisie were not in the lead of political movements; after the revolutions, the bourgeoisies did not hold power and were often further removed from state control; and, finally, the revolutions did not result in the emergence or consoli-dation of capitalist states (cf. Davidson, 2012: ch. 15). More than anything else, the idea of the bourgeoisie as the primary agent in the making of the revolutions has taken the most sustained beating by revisionists.

While the bourgeoisie did, in fact, play some role in the classical revolutions, as exam-ined later, this agent-centred conceptualization of bourgeois revolutions is itself unneces-sary, if not unhelpful. Rather than looking at the intentions or composition of the agents involved in the making of revolutions, there is a veritable tradition of thinking (Marxist and non-Marxist) that conceptualizes revolutions in terms of their consequences (see Davidson, 2012: ch. 14). The most significant factor for this ‘consequentialist’ school of thought in classifying a revolution as ‘bourgeois’ is whether or not a revolution removed the socio-political and ideological ‘obstacles’ (notably, the pre-capitalist state) to the development and consolidation of capitalism by establishing the state as an autonomous site of capital accumulation.2 For, ‘[i]f the definition of a bourgeois revolution is restricted to the success-ful installation of a legal and political framework in which the free development of capital-ist property relations is assured’, Gareth Stedman Jones (1977: 86) writes, ‘there is then no necessary reason why a “bourgeois revolution” need be the direct work of a bourgeoisie’. Bourgeois revolutions are therefore best understood ‘not as revolutions consciously made by capitalist agents’, but in terms of their developmental outcomes: the effects that a revo-lution has in promoting and/or consolidating a distinctly capitalist form of state that will, in turn, benefit the capitalist class irrespective of the role that they may have played in such revolutions. Bourgeois revolutions thereby denote a socio-political transformation — ‘a change in state power, which is the precondition for large scale capital accumulation and the establishment of the bourgeoisie as the dominant class’ (Callinicos, 1989: 124).

Whether a revolution was the necessary condition to bring about capitalism or worked to facilitate an already-existing capitalism varied with each case, France largely being an example of the former and England the latter. The focus of the theory of bourgeois revo-lution is, then, not on the origins of capitalism as a socio-economic system, but on the elimination of the socio-political ‘barriers’ to ‘its continued existence and the overthrow of restrictions to its further expansion’ (Davidson, 2012: 420). Moreover, rather than viewing bourgeois revolutions as a single episode or event, more often than not they

Page 5: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 5

entailed much broader processes of long-term socio-political transformation, sometimes involving wars and foreign conquest. While these processes involved ‘episode[s] of con-vulsive political transformation, compressed in time and concentrated in target’ (Anderson, 1984: 112), it would be a mistake to identify bourgeois revolutions as solely comprised of such instances. While one must be cautious not to overstretch the concept to cover developmental tendencies more broadly, it does seem that the extended tempo-ralities of the English Civil Wars of 1640–1651 and Glorious Revolution of 1688–1689, as well as the French Revolution of 1787–1815, can all be conceived as bourgeois revo-lutions that were part and parcel of more general systemic crises taking national and international dimensions.

Furthermore, the evolving conditions of the international system, itself transformed by the ensuing revolutions, had a major causal impact on the timing, form and trajectory of these revolutions. Indeed, one might say that revolutions are almost universally inter-national in origin, dynamic and impact. Structural adaptation to geopolitical-military pressures has been a central causal component of modern revolutions, and their resulting effects upon the nature of the international system have been profound. Dramatically intensifying the competitive pressures of an increasingly capitalist international system and world economy, each successive capitalist revolution handed down the ‘geo-social’ conditions from which the next would emerge. The bourgeois revolutions were, Perry Anderson (1992: 116) writes, ‘historically interrelated, and the sequence of their con-nexions enters into the definition of their differences. Their order was constitutive of their structure’ [emphasis added].

Reconfiguring consequentialism through uneven and combined development

Rather than discounting different instances of revolution that failed to correspond to some ideal-type notion of bourgeois revolution, the approach outlined earlier opens the possibility for a more historically sensitive perspective, recognizing the inherently inter-connected, co-constitutive and variegated nature of revolutions. Nonetheless, a potential problem with contemporary applications of this ‘consequentialist’ approach has been their tendency to emphasize ‘developmental identity’ over ‘developmental difference’.3 In other words, in the shift to conceptualizing revolutions in terms of their social- systemic effects, some scholars have fallen into a problematic homogenization of revolu-tions in the modern epoch as almost universally capitalist (e.g. Callinicos, 1989; Davidson, 2012). The very different developmental outcomes of such revolutions in, say, North Vietnam (1945), China (1949) and Cuba (1959) are all conceived as establishing different forms of ‘bureaucratic state capitalism’ through ‘deflected permanent revolu-tions’ (Cliff, 1963) — the ‘modern version or functional equivalent’ of bourgeois revolu-tions (Davidson, 2012: 459). While it seems indisputable that such regimes increasingly incorporated features of capitalism over time, to conceive of these revolutions as ‘bour-geois’ or ‘capitalist’ is to stretch such concepts beyond breaking point.

In providing a more satisfactory and historically attuned consequentialist approach, it is therefore necessary to root it in a more robust conception of U&CD that adequately sensitizes our analysis to the vast qualitative differences between revolutions while

Page 6: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

6 European Journal of International Relations

uniquely incorporating a distinctly international dimension of causality into its basic conception of socio-historical development.4 For unevenness posits developmental vari-ations both within and between societies, along with the attendant spatial differentiations between them. The ‘force of uneven development’, Trotsky (1962 [1930/1906]: 131) wrote, ‘operates not only in the relations of countries to each other, but also in the mutual relationships of the various processes within one and the same country’. This conception of unevenness thus transverses the multiple spatial fields of social constitution and organization, breaking with any discretely conceived ‘inside–outside’ notions of the ‘national’ and ‘international’ (Walker, 1993) at the heart of disciplinary IR. As such, it prefigures the later shift to conceptions of social relations as ‘networks’ (Mann, 1986: 9–13) or ‘webs’ (McNeil and McNeil, 2003) without losing sight of their territorializa-tion in the modern epoch.

At the most abstract level, combination refers to the ways in which the internal rela-tions of any given society are determined by their relations with other developmentally differentiated societies, resulting in the intermingling and melding of ‘foreign’ and ‘native’ institutions and social structures within a single society. Although usually rooted in the interlacing and fusion of differentiated modes of production, the effects of a combined development suffuse every aspect of society (cf. Anievas and Nişancıoğlu, forthcoming). It is much more than a simple economic phenomenon, but instead cap-tures the totality of relations constitutive of a social order.

From the concepts of ‘unevenness’ and ‘combination’ follow a number of geo-social causal mechanisms embedding ‘the international’ into the heart of U&CD’s conception of development. These include: (1) the ‘whip of external necessity’ (the military- economic pressures generated by interstate competition among a plurality of unevenly developing societies); (2) the ‘privilege of historic backwardness’ (the opportunities opened up to later-developing states to adopt the most cutting-edge technologies, institu-tions and practices from the leading states in the international system); (3) the ‘contradic-tions of sociological amalgamation’ (the time-compressed character of this development taking inorganic, spasmodic and destabilizing forms, unhinging traditional social struc-tures in ways causally feeding back into the structures of the international system that produced them); and (4) processes of ‘substitutionism’,5 whereby later-developers, in attempting to developmentally supercharge their own societies, come to mobilize ‘replacement’ mechanisms for the various agents, institutions, technics and methods of earlier processes of development. As examined later, in both England and France, these mechanisms were at play in the making and effects of their respective revolutions.

Tying a ‘consequentialist’ understanding of revolutions to the theory of U&CD not only solves the difficulties of revisionist interpretations of bourgeois revolutions, but also the problematic relationship between IR and revolutions more generally. It does so, in particular, by specifying the distinctive causal dynamics and behavioural patterns of the international system effecting each and every revolution, while also theoretically capturing the differential agencies, methods and outcomes of revolutions, which explains the qualitative differences between revolutions as they co-constitutively interconnect in time and space: their sequentiality being constitutive of their structures, thereby elimi-nating the possibility of historical repetition and the utility of ‘ideal-types’. This then provides a theoretical explanation of why each bourgeois revolution was a ‘bastard birth’

Page 7: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 7

— an exception that proved the rule (Anderson, 1992: 116). It further explains the ‘dis-sonance’ between agents’ intentions and their effects: that is, how the consequences of a revolution often turn out to be capitalist irrespective of the agents’ original intentions as the systemic pressures and imperatives of ‘the international’6 decisively weigh on the outcomes of the revolution. We should therefore expect each revolution to diverge (in character, form and the agents involved) from previous revolutions: the sole criteria to judge whether they can be considered capitalist is whether they establish the state as a sovereign site of capital accumulation.

Rediscovering the British Revolution

The English Revolution in international context

The origins of the English Revolution, whether comprising the English Civil Wars of 1640–1651 or the entire period from 1640 to 1688, has produced an enormously rich and varied body of literature. With few exceptions,7 however, ‘virtually the whole of this literature’ has been ‘written as if England was not just an island, but was a closed entity, separate from the political, economic and intellectual world of the rest of Europe’ (Halliday, 1999: 185). Yet, the international structure and context of which England formed a part played a critical role in the causal and imaginative coordinates of its revo-lutionary experience. That the events of the English Revolution took place in an era of ‘general crisis’ riven by upheavals, rebellions and wars raging across Europe and beyond has scarcely been taken into account when explaining its causal sources.

This international context of English events was hardly lost on contemporaries (cf. Scott, 2000: 141–142). In 1649, Robert Mentet de Salmonet, a Scottish exile living in France, prefaced his account of the English Revolution by noting that Europe was passing through an ‘Iron Age’ marked by ‘Desolation of Countries commonly attending War’, an era ‘famous for the great and strange revolutions that have happen’d in it’, with ‘revolts … frequent both in East and West’ (Mentet de Salmonet, 1739: 2). Similarly, in January 1643, a protestant preacher, Jeremiah Whitaker, warned the House of Commons: ‘These days are a days of shaking … and this shaking is universal: the Palatinate, Bohemia, Germany, Catalonia, Portugal, Ireland, England’ (quoted in Trevor-Roper, 2011 [1965]: 59). The crisis that beset the English state was European, if not global, in nature and scope (see Parker, 2008). The socio-economic, ideological and political roots of both the long-term (structural) and immediate (conjunctural) causes of the British Revolution, through all its phases (1640–1642, 1688 and 1745), were, then, decisively international. How are we to understand the interaction of international and domestic conditions leading to the English Revolution?

The notion that the domestic situation of the Stuart monarchy was reasonably stable — a key tenet of revisionist historiography (cf. Russell, 1990) — seems gravely mis-placed when taking into account the broader European maelstrom of the era, of which England was hardly immune. Over the 16th and 17th centuries, English society under-went rapid socio-economic and demographic change, leading to a prolonged period of economic instability and heightened social tensions. Surveying the state of the English agrarian economy during this period, Peter Bowden (1990: 41) concludes that the

Page 8: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

8 European Journal of International Relations

1620s–1640s were times of ‘extreme hardship in England … probably the most terrible years through which the country has ever passed’. This was a period marked by intense social unrest and class conflict (a persistent ‘crisis of order’, as David Underwood (1996: 61) describes the years between 1560 and 1640), escalating to the point where ‘contem-poraries were conscious of a threat of popular revolt’ (Hill, 1981: 115; cf. Carlin, 1999; Manning, 1991).

The immediate events leading to the English Civil War are well known (cf. Carlin, 1999). In 1640, under the military pressure of an advancing Scottish force, King Charles I reconvened Parliament for the first time since its disbandment 11 years earlier. For much of his reign, Charles I had been attempting to strengthen obedience and loyalty to the Crown by building up a monarchical absolutism stylized on the Catholic monarchies of the continent, with comparable (though in no way analogous) counter-reformation policies. This was seen as an imperative given the military ineffectuality and weaknesses of the monarchy on display in the wars of the 1620s, which imperilled the domestic legitimacy of the Stuart state. Through these wars, the fierce political and religious con-flicts engulfing the European continent were incorporated into the domestic political structures of England. ‘The polarization of English politics by 1629–30’, L.J. Reeve (2003: 220) writes, ‘can be seen as one aspect of the polarization of international politics under the pressure of war’.

It had become increasingly clear that, on a geopolitical scale, the Stuart state was sim-ply no match for its Catholic absolutist rivals. It was in this sense that England’s ‘failure in war in Europe established the context for rebellion and civil war at home’ (Scott, 2000: 55, 114). The historical unevenness of state-building in Europe, affecting a particular ‘whip of external necessity’, was thus crucial to the outbreak of the English Civil Wars. Far from having ‘no influence on the English social revolution and relatively little influ-ence on the English political revolution’ (Teschke, 2003: 194, fn. 16), international mili-tary pressures were decisive in the making of the English Revolution. The Thirty Years’ War was itself further rooted in this overall unevenness of social development on the European continent: an ‘example of two civilizations in ideological conflict’ wherein the ‘political fronts and coalitions of power’ in the war reflected deep developmental differ-ences among the states involved (Polišenský, 1971: 9; cf. Davidson, 2012: 565–574). Generally speaking, the war pitted the least developed (in feudal terms) areas of Europe, which had nonetheless begun to make the first strides towards capitalism — particularly, the Netherlands, England and Bohemia — against the most developed and wealthiest regions, where feudalism was most entrenched — notably, the Spanish and Holy Roman Empires (Davidson, 2012: 570). The ‘general crisis’ of the 17th century in Europe (Hobsbawm, 1954) was thereby rooted in the protracted, uneven transition from feudal-ism to capitalism, finding its material bases in the intensified class conflicts over the dis-tribution of income explaining the ‘system-wide attempts at geopolitical accumulation in the form of the Wars of Religion and the Thirty Years’ War’ (Teschke, 2003: 170).

The failed attempts at absolutist state-building during the Tudor period (particularly between 1529 and 1547), and Elizabeth’s abandonment of all ambitions to develop a continental-style monarchy, had left the monarchy painfully dependent upon Parliament for raising the revenues required for waging war (Scott, 2000: 68–72; Stone, 1972: 60–64). In terms of military and fiscal effectiveness, the Stuart state was relatively

Page 9: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 9

‘backward’ in comparison to its continental competitors. The centralizing attempts by the Stuart monarchs, first James I and then Charles I, had brought them into direct conflict with England’s powerful landed classes dominating Parliament, as the latter had to assent to new taxes or give up control over fiscal policy. This was a landlord class that had become increasingly capitalist-oriented over the preceding century, as they ‘gradually gave up the magnate form of politico-military organization, commercialized their rela-tionships with their tenants, rationalized their estates, and made use of — but avoided dependence upon — the court’ (Brenner, 1989: 302; cf. Stone, 1965).

The conflicts between Crown and Parliament over war-funding had been a major reason for Charles I’s initial dismissal of Parliament in 1629. One conclusion from the 1625–1629 years was that war was impossible without state reform and that a financially exhausted government required peace in order to do so. The reprise from war was, how-ever, fatefully interrupted by the Scottish Rebellion of 1637–1640 sparked by Charles I’s attempt to impose Anglican services on the Presbyterian Church of Scotland. With the Scottish invasion of 1640, the military conflict in Europe moved back to England. As Scott (2000: 141) notes:

A catholicising king, associated with Spain and catholic Ireland, found himself divided from his English and Scots protestant subjects. This was one military outcome of the ideological impact made upon the Stuart kingdoms by the Thirty Years’ War. In the period 1637–40, then, the military struggle between reformation and counter-reformation moved to British soil. That it was not followed by continental European military intervention was a consequence only of the exhaustion of the great powers after more than two decades of war.

The European upheaval of the Thirty Years’ War consequently formed the immediate geopolitical context for the English Civil Wars and eventual collapse of Charles I’s mon-archy. It was against this international background that such widespread English fears of ‘popery’ must be understood as Catholic Spain spearheaded the counter-reformation across Europe. The majority of parliamentary oppositionists, particularly the ‘new mer-chants’ involved in the American colonial trades, were ‘militantly anti-Spanish’ in their foreign policy orientations (Brenner, 1993: 245–255). The ideological (if not military) threats of the European Catholic powers were seen as clear and present dangers.

The reconvening of Parliament unleashed a storm of political controversies as the parliamentarians sought to reassert their political power against an increasingly ‘popish’ and autocratic Crown, while Charles I sought to defend his perceived monarchical right to rule without undue parliamentary interference. The Irish Rebellion of October 1641 added further fuel to the fire as it now raised the question of who (Parliament or Crown) would control the English armed forces to suppress the rebellion. The eventual outcome of these insoluble conflicts between Crown and Parliament, representing two fundamentally differ-ent conceptions of sovereignty, was the outbreak of the Civil War in the summer of 1642.

Social forces in the making of the British Revolution

In examining the character of class conflicts in the making of this first ‘stage’ in the English Revolution, traditional social explanations have focused on the role of the rising

Page 10: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

10 European Journal of International Relations

gentry — conceived as an emerging bourgeois class — as the key social force in the making of the ‘Great Revolution’ of 1640 (see Hill, 1940; Tawney, 1941). The two sides in the Civil War, parliamentary forces and royalists, are thus considered agents of two opposing classes representing antagonistic modes of production: a rising capitalism and a declining feudalism. The traditional interpretation has not fared well with more con-temporary historiographical accounts and has been largely abandoned (see Brenner, 1993: 638–644; Carlin, 1999: chs 3, 4). One problem with this interpretation has been the difficulty in identifying the continuing existence of a distinctly feudal class to which the ascendant capitalist bourgeoisie was opposed since, by the time of the English Civil Wars, the ruling landed classes were, according to Robert Brenner (1993: 642), ‘by and large … capitalist, in the sense of depending on commercial farmers paying competitive rents, rather than one that was sharply divided into advanced and backward sectors’. For the ‘revisionists’ and their Political Marxist counterparts, pre-revolutionary English soci-ety is thus conceived as fully capitalist, calling into question any classification of the years between 1640 and 1688 as inaugurating a bourgeois revolution (cf. Lacher, 2006: 77; Teschke, 2003: 165–167; Wood, 1999: 63).

Yet, the extent of Brenner’s and other revisionists’ depiction of such a thoroughgoing capitalist transformation of pre-revolutionary English society remains open to much debate. As Henry Heller (2011: 120–121) has pointed out, the nobility in North-Western England remained an outpost of feudal reaction and royalist stronghold throughout the period. Using Brenner’s own conception of capitalism as existing with the full commodi-fication of labour-power, Robert Albritton (1993) has similarly argued that English agri-culture could not be considered completely capitalist in the early 17th century. Moreover, if we are to take quantitative measures regarding the extent of proletarianization in England from the mid- to late 16th century, it would appear that English society was only slightly more advanced than the European continent (compare figures in Tilly, 1984: 35–36; Whittle, 2001: 227–231).

In short, the feudal ‘remnants’ of English society had yet to be fully washed away by the building capitalist tide in the period preceding the revolution. It would therefore be more accurate to characterize English society over the 15th to 17th centuries as a com-bined form of development wherein feudalism and capitalism coexisted, interacted and fused in various ways, with the latter progressively coming to predominate in the imme-diate pre-1640 period in ways facilitating the conditions for revolution (cf. Anievas and Nişancıoğlu, forthcoming: ch. 6). Important to note here is how these processes of socio-economic change assisting the development of capitalism over the period were very much ‘a result and part of an international process, involving foreign trade, changes in intra-European relations following on from the discovery of the Americas, and the rivalry of rising mercantile powers in Europe’ (Halliday, 1999: 187; cf. Anievas and Nişancıoğlu, forthcoming: chs 3–6).

With this said, there nonetheless remain other problems with the traditional interpre-tations, not the least of which is the fact that capitalists could be found, as R.H. Tawney admitted, ‘on both sides’ of the contending parties (quoted in Davidson, 2012: 353; cf. Tawney, 1941: 18). While disagreeing with Brenner’s (1993) characterization of pre-1640 English society as fully capitalist, his alternative social interpretation is, indeed, a powerful one. Particularly useful is Brenner’s account of the political role played by

Page 11: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 11

different segments of capitalists comprising the London merchant community during the Civil Wars. Specifically, Brenner delineates two distinct factions of merchant capital: one dominant faction centred around the City, tied to the East India Company and import-ing from the Levant; and a second faction of ‘new merchants’ coming from outside the City and connected to the American colonial trades. While the former faction relied heavily on the Crown for politically protected trade routes and monopolies, the latter was much less dependent on the state, given their socio-economic backgrounds, as they were excluded from government-sanctioned charter companies. It was this second faction of colonial merchants — whom had begun the process of subsuming labour to capital (cf. Anievas and Nişancıoğlu, forthcoming: ch. 5) — that would come to play a leading role in supporting Oliver Cromwell and the Independents during the revolution. These merchants ‘stood at the head of the City popular movement and played a critical role in connecting that movement to the national parliamentary opposition’, of which many formed a crucial part of its leadership (Brenner, 1993: 317, 244).

The majority of parliamentary oppositionists were not, however, seeking a revolution, but sought instead to roll back Charles’s absolutist state-building drive. Yet, once war broke out, the intervention of social forces from below (the ‘middling sort’ comprised of wage-labouring peasants, craftsmen, artisans and independent small producers) pushed parliamentary leaders in a more radical direction while driving much of the nobility and gentry into the Royalist camp (Carlin, 1999: 162; Manning, 1991: chs 1–5). While the parliamentary opposition never embraced the radical demands of the London crowds and other sections of the ‘middling sort’, they nonetheless utilized the mass movement as a vehicle to victory, which they secured in December 1648 through Cromwell’s New Model Army. In an early case of substitutionism, it was this New Model Army that acted as a surrogate for a capitalist class that, although economically dominant, was not yet politically capable of assuming leadership in the new state, while also functioning as a key agent of capital accumulation alongside the bourgeois classes (Davidson, 2012: 573). After the execution of Charles I, the monarchy was overthrown and the republican Commonwealth of England declared.

Although the war had ended, the mass radicalism that it had unleashed did not. The need to restore social order was foremost in the minds of the conservative landowning gentry. Initially fearful of the Republic, the landed classes nonetheless (partially) recon-ciled themselves to Cromwell’s protectorate as it proved itself an effective bulwark against radicalism and a protector of private property. However, when Cromwell’s suc-cessors proved themselves incapable of providing effective central government, the gen-try ‘panicked, fearing as they had in the early 1650s that a social revolution would occur unless effective central government was restored without delay’ (Coward, 1992: 217). The result was the restoration of the Stuart monarchy, with Charles II taking the crown in 1660. The restoration was not, however, a return to the status quo of pre-revolution times, but rather continued the reforms of the post-revolutionary period.

Under the ‘whip of external necessity’ represented by the Anglo-Dutch wars of 1665–1667 and 1672–1674, and later during the Anglo-French wars of 1689–1714, the English-cum-British state underwent a number of dramatic transformations, leading to the emergence of a modern fiscal-military state capable of harnessing vast resources in waging war. Indeed, the period witnessed a process of English state-building characterized

Page 12: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

12 European Journal of International Relations

by the assimilation of the most advanced fiscal, military and administrative practices developed by the Dutch (Scott, 2000: 397–404). In this sense, the British state enjoyed a certain ‘privilege of backwardness’ in comparison to its chief Dutch competitor. Yet, for the English monarchy, it was the continental monarchies that remained the chief geopoliti-cal models of emulation. When Charles II’s successor, James II, sought to repeat his father’s effort to build an absolutist regime, he was overthrown in the Glorious Revolution of 1688 and replaced by the invading forces of William of Orange from the Netherlands (see Pincus, 2009). The primary aim of the Dutch invasion was to co-opt England to the Dutch-led war against the French, to which William was successful. Once again, European geopolitics decisively intervened in (re)shaping English state–society relations.

The sum result of the socio-economic and political changes taking place over the revolutionary epoch of 1640 to 1688 was the establishment of a form of state conducive to the maximization of capitalist development:

what emerged [from the revolution] was a state in which the administrative organs that most impeded capitalist development had been abolished … in which the executive was subordinated to the men of property, deprived of control over the judiciary, and yet strengthened in external relations by a powerful navy and the Navigation Act; in which local government was safely and cheaply in the hands of the natural ruler, and discipline was imposed on the lower orders by a Church safely subordinated to Parliament. (Hill, 1985: 117)

Nonetheless, the revolutionary process was not yet complete as the newly capitalist English state still faced internal and external systemic threats. Abroad, the single greatest counter-revolutionary threat to England was the French absolutist state. At home, the counter-revolutionary threat lay in Scotland, which, in contrast to the maturing capitalist order in England, remained an outpost of feudal reaction. After the Union of 1707, this systemic unevenness of development between the two hitherto separate monarchies was transformed into a unique pattern of combined development, juxtaposing and fusing the most ‘archaic’ and ‘advanced’ social relations in contradictory and explosive ways.8

Within the British state, a ruling class of feudal lords persisted in the Scottish coun-tryside, drawing their wealth in the form of feudal rents, while, in England, the landed ruling classes were now predominately capitalist. At the same time, after the 1707 Union, Scottish industries began to rapidly assimilate the most highly advanced English tech-nologies and organizational methods, experiencing the kinds of ‘contradictions of socio-logical amalgamation’ that would come to characterize future combined forms of capitalist development (see Davidson, 2003).

However, as long as feudalism existed in Scotland, the consolidation of capitalism in Britain remained perilously incomplete, liable to systemic reversal. The Union was cor-rectly perceived by the Scottish Jacobite lords as a threat to their socio-economic status and territorial privileges and they would come to gamble on counter-revolution as a means to preserve themselves as the ruling class. The final episode came in 1745 when nearly the whole of the English army was sent to Belgium to fight France during the War of Austrian Succession, providing the Jacobites with the opportunity to overthrow the Hanover monarchy. The Jacobite uprising was crushed, leading to the enactment of a number of legislative acts (notably, the Tenures Abolition Act and Disarming Act of 1746

Page 13: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 13

and Heritable Jurisdictions Act of 1747) signalling the end of feudalism in Scotland and thus the culmination of the British bourgeois revolution (Davidson, 2003: ch. 6).

The year 1789 in the history of uneven and combined development

Capitalism and the absolutist state in France

If the English case of bourgeois revolution represents an instance where an already-existing capitalist order was consolidated by the overthrow of the socio-political condi-tions obstructing its advancement, the French Revolution signifies a very different case: one where the dominance of the capitalist production mode was a consequence of the revolutionary settlement. This is not to argue that capitalist relations were entirely absent from pre-revolutionary France, nor that the absolutist state was entirely detrimental to capitalist development. Indeed, the notion of the fundamentally non-capitalist nature of French absolutism has become something of a cardinal tenet among many revisionists and Political Marxists (see, e.g., Brenner, 1985; Comninel, 1987; Lacher, 2006: 73–76; Mooers, 1991: 45–102; Taylor, 1967; Teschke, 2003: 167–188; Wood, 1999: 79–80, 103–105). For the latter, absolutist France is conceived as the non-modern Other to the impeccably ‘pristine’ capitalist England.

Positing the ‘radically non-capitalist’ (Lacher, 2006: 77) nature of French absolutism, Political Marxists have accepted the main findings of the revisionist historiography of the French Revolution: though the leaders of the French Revolution may have been bour-geois, they were emphatically not capitalist and the socio-economic order resulting from the revolutionary settlement ‘entrenched rather than removed pre-capitalist forms’ (Wood, 1999: 121). What is more, the entire theoretical edifice of Marx and Engels’s conception of bourgeois revolutions is questioned, given that they are alleged to have ‘uncritically accepted the liberal theory of bourgeois revolution in their early works’ (Teschke, 2003: 165; cf. Brenner, 1989; Comninel, 1987: 53–76, 104–178; Lacher, 2006: 77; Wood, 1999: 62–63). On both empirical and theoretical grounds, then, the idea of a bourgeois revolution in France is refuted and, more generally, the concept is relegated to the dustbin of history (see Teschke, 2005).

Here, we leave aside the exegetical question as to whether Marx and Engels’s concep-tion of bourgeois revolutions reflects an uncritically digested liberal theory of socio-political change9 and instead concentrate on the empirical foundations of revisionist and Political Marxist claims regarding the fundamentally non-capitalist nature of French absolutism. On closer inspection, it would seem that such arguments are based upon an overly static conception of French development during the pre-revolutionary period. Indeed, a number of recent works on the French economy during the period have offered a more rounded picture of its development (cf. Chevet, 2009; Heller, 2000, 2002, 2009a, 2009b; Hoffman, 1996; Horn, 2006, 2010; Lemarchand, 1990). As Henry Heller (2000, 2009a) has shown, capitalist social forces were already making themselves felt in late 16th-century France, particularly through the effects of the Wars of Religion (1562–1598), which, despite the general economic decline during the wars, acted as a long-term stimulus to technological and economic innovations during the reign of Henry IV. The Wars of

Page 14: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

14 European Journal of International Relations

Religion also hastened the process of primitive accumulation taking place in the French countryside, where poorer peasants were uprooted from the land, resulting in widespread proletarianization and the revaluation of land as capital. Consequently, by the 17th cen-tury, nearly three-quarters of the peasantry were deprived of the necessary means of production (land) to support themselves. Furthermore, by the beginning of the century, estimates show that as much as 22% of the rural workforce in France was engaged in industry (Heller, 2000: 257).

Accompanying this process of primitive accumulation was an increasing differentia-tion among the peasantry between a mass of wage-labourers and a nascent rural bour-geoisie (Ado, 1990; Lemarchand, 1990). At the same time, feudal rights over the management, sale and acquisition of property were increasingly weakened as peasants became more or less able to dispose of their property on the market (Heller, 2009a: 41–42, 44; cf. Heller, 2000). This process of primitive accumulation would continue over the 18th century as peasant proprietorship steadily declined, particularly in the last decades of the ancien régime, as the French countryside emerged as a region of significant capi-talist experimentations (see Vardi, 1993). In a recent study, Gérard Béaur concluded that up to 90% of the rural population in 18th-century France did not have enough land to support themselves, with about 20% being completely landless (cited in Heller, 2009b: 47). Hence, by the early 18th century, the ‘availability of growing pools of cheap wage-labour became a structural feature of the French economy’ (Heller, 2009a: 55, emphasis added). Alongside this increasing mass of market-dependent wage-labourers, 18th- century France also witnessed the emergence of a sizeable capitalist bourgeoisie primar-ily made up of merchants, artisans, shopkeepers and the paysannerie marchande. On Colin Jones’s (1998: 165) calculations, the French bourgeoisie grew over the century from approximately 700,000–800,000 individuals in 1700 to about 2.3 million in 1789, making up nearly 10% of the population. Citing the spread of commercialization in pre-revolutionary France, Jones (1998: 174) argues that France witnessed the relative ‘bour-geoisification’ of the Old Regime as the tastes and attitudes of the bourgeoisie permeated French society, ‘challenging the former hegemony of the aristocracy’ (Lewis, 1999: 15). As even the revisionist historian William Doyle (1989: 22–23) notes:

the relative weight of the bourgeoisie in society was increasing ever more rapidly than their numbers. Their share of national wealth was enormous. Most industrial and all commercial capital, amounting to almost a fifth of all French private wealth, was bourgeois owned.

One might criticize the use of the term ‘bourgeoisie’ here as conflating it with a distinctly capitalist class, instead of viewing it as a non-capitalist bourgeoisie, as the term was used in the 18th century to refer to town-dwellers or anyone holding non-noble status. However, as noted, a growing fraction of this broader bourgeoisie derived their incomes from the exploitation of wage-labour. While a non-capitalist bourgeoisie surely existed in pre-revolutionary France, much of this bourgeoisie was decisively transformed in a capitalist direction over the 17th and 18th centuries. It was during this period that France underwent an era of dramatic socio-economic development, characterized by substantial growth in manufacturing and agriculture, making the country arguably the ‘strongest economy in continental Europe’ (Heller, 2009b: 14).

Page 15: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 15

Statistical indexes confirm the vibrant and dynamic nature of French economic devel-opment during the period. French industrial output grew on an annual basis by 1.9% between 1701–1710 and 1781–1790, as compared with 1.1% in Britain. By the begin-ning of the 18th century, industry made up about a quarter of France’s total output, as compared with a third in Britain. By 1780, industry accounted for two-thirds in both countries. Further, by 1789, the iron industry in France was significantly larger than in Britain, producing nearly two-and-a-half times the tonnage. Overall, France’s manufac-turing output was approximately three times as great as Britain’s in 1789 (Duplessis, 1997: 242; Horn, 2006: 89). Moreover, the increase in industrial output per head in France during the 18th century was likely faster than that in Britain (Milward and Saull, 2013: 31). From 1715 to 1785, the British economy grew by about 50%, as compared with the expansion of the French economy by nearly 100%, while the annual average growth of the French economy between 1701–1710 and 1781–1790 was 1%, as com-pared with 0.7% for Britain (Heller, 2009b: 40). Between 1716–1720 and 1784–1788, France’s external commerce multiplied by a factor of three, against a British expansion of 2.4. As such, by the end of the 1780s, France had become the largest trading power in Europe, with a total value of long-distance trade equalling £25 million, trumping Britain, whose trade amounted to £20 million (Daudin, 2004: 144).

Despite this impressive growth over the 18th century, and while leading in certain economic sectors over Britain, the French economy did nonetheless remain relatively ‘backward’ as compared with its chief economic and geopolitical competitor. Like its English predecessor, France reaped a certain ‘privilege of backwardness’, adopting numerous technological innovations from its more advanced British competitor (see Heller, 2009b: 38–39; Horn, 2010: 88–92). Yet, as demonstrated, absolutist France was far from the developmental ‘dead-end’ (Teschke, 2003: 192) that revisionists have made it out to be.

Nevertheless, capitalist relations were not yet dominant in pre-revolutionary France as feudal methods of extra-economic exploitation remained salient. Despite the develop-ment of a substantial bourgeoisie, the aristocracy continued to dominate — if not monop-olize — political power, with the nobles occupying most key positions in the army, navy and judiciary (Lewis, 1999: 14). The growing socio-economic weight of French capital-ists had not yet been transformed into direct political power. How, then, might we con-ceptualize the pre-revolutionary French social structure?

Some historians have conceived of French absolutism as a ‘transitional’ social forma-tion, amalgamating features of both feudalism and capitalism. Such was the view of Perry Anderson, who described the absolutist states of Western Europe as ‘a complex of feudal and capitalist modes of production, with a gradually rising urban bourgeois and a growing primitive accumulation of capital, on an international scale’ (Anderson, 1974: 428–429). Similarly, Neil Davidson (2012: 587) speaks of the ‘transitional, combined nature of the [pre-1789] French economy’ [emphasis in original].

French absolutism represented a distinctive form of combined development, albeit one dominated by its feudal aspects. The absolutist state denoted a transfigured form of the separation of the political and the economic that characterized the emergence of capi-talism in England. Despite the growing significance of capitalist relations in town and country, which witnessed the divorcing of the producers from direct relations of personal

Page 16: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

16 European Journal of International Relations

domination and dependency characteristic of feudalism, the state remained a locus of economic dependency through the sale of venal offices.10 Absolutist France was thus marked by what Kamran Matin (2013: 204) has described as ‘personal independence based upon dependence mediated by the state’ [emphasis in original],11 where differen-tial access to the state apparatus was a key source of conflict. The particular ‘contradic-tions of sociological amalgamation’ engendered by this pattern of U&CD in France, in turn, witnessed ‘the precarious compromise between the building of a modern state and the preservation of principles of social organization inherited from feudal times’ (Furet, 1981: 110). It was not simply that feudal and capitalist relations coexisted in pre-revolu-tionary France, but that they were ‘inextricably interlaced in the society of the Old Regime forming a conflictual unity’ in which ‘[m]ixed forms of property and hybrid social groups played an important role on the eve of the revolution [emphasis added]’ (Ado, 1990: 364).

The origins of the bourgeois revolution in France

If Political Marxists are incorrect in their characterizations of the French absolutist state as radically non-capitalist, they are on more solid ground in foregrounding the role of international rivalries in precipitating the revolutionary crisis. As Colin Mooers (1991: 93–94) writes:

It was through state military competition that the backwardness of French productive relations was initially, and disastrously, demonstrated. The coercive force of England’s more advanced system of social relations was experienced by France in a succession of military defeats and the ultimate bankruptcy of the absolutist state.

It was this ‘whip of external necessity’, represented by the internationally mediated mod-ernizing challenge of capitalist Britain, that occasioned the revolutionary crisis in France. In this sense, the British Revolution of the previous century had laid down the ‘geo-social’ conditions for the French Revolution as the international terrain on which France had to compete in the 18th century had been radically transformed by the social order inaugurated by the British Revolution. The differential developmental trajectories between Britain and France (uneven development) and their attendant geopolitical and sociological consequences (combined development) were thus critical to the making of the French Revolution.

Throughout the 18th century, British power had been steadily increasing, buoyed by the country’s predominance in American trade and markets. Those states that held colo-nies or access to the Atlantic system were provided significant economic-cum-military advantages. In this sense, the European balance of power of the 18th century was built on the pedestal of the Atlantic slave trade. As French Secretary of State (1761–1766) César Gabriel de Choiseul put it:

in the present state of Europe it is colonies, trade and in consequence sea power, which must determine the balance of power upon the continent. The House of Austria, Russia, the King of Prussia are only powers of the second rank, as are all those which cannot go to war unless subsidized by the trading powers. (Quoted in Kennedy, 1989: 147)

Page 17: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 17

A central aim of French foreign policy was, then, as Foreign Minister Vergennes stated, to ‘reduce England to a position of equality … to take from her a share of her strength, her monopoly of American trade and markets’ (quoted in Stone, 2004: 19). It was with this aim in mind that the French regime would embroil itself in a series of costly colonial wars, particularly the Seven Years’ War (1754–1763) and the American War of Independence (1778–1783), which would ultimately bankrupt the regime. This geopo-litically driven bankruptcy was the immediate ‘trigger’ for the revolutionary crisis of 1787–1788, when, having borrowed until no more money was forthcoming, the new comptrôleur-général, Calone, sought to implement a radical programme of reforms — taxes on all landowners irrespective of rank and the creation of new provincial assem-blies — which provoked the political crisis leading to the monarchy’s downfall (Lewis, 1999: 21–22). The state’s fiscal crisis not only came to increasingly loosen the ideologi-cal and political cohesion of the French ruling classes, but also translated into an ‘unbear-able’ tax burden on the peasantry (Matin, 2013: 51), fuelling widespread social discontent and rebellion in the countryside (Lewis, 1999: 60).

The economic crisis affecting France at the time was, however, of a more general nature. Signs of economic troubles had emerged in several key economic sectors as early as the 1760s. According to some, ‘the economic slowdown marked the exhaustion of further possibilities for accumulation within the system’ (Heller, 2009b: 67; cf. Lemarchand, 1990). Further industrial development was blocked owing to a shortage of capital; stagnation had become apparent in various branches of industry, reflecting insuf-ficient demand at home in a time of growing protectionism; the agricultural economy was affected by severe grain shortages in 1788–1789; and manufacturing was further weakened by the Treaty of Eden of 1786, lowering tariffs between France and Britain (Heller, 2009b: 67–71). The second half of the 18th century was also marked by a nota-ble escalation in urban violence and peasant conflict: nearly three-quarters of the 4400 recorded collective protests in the years 1720–1788 occurred after 1765, mostly in the form of food riots and anti-seigneurialism (McPhee, 2002: 33). These were, in part, a consequence of the increasing burden of taxes on the labouring classes (Lewis, 1999: 60). The nobility were also further squeezing the peasantry by usurping communal rights and increasing feudal charges on their tenants (Heller, 2009b: 69). In short, the Old Regime was in crisis.

Decisive in the immediate conjuncture of revolution, the role of ‘the international’ in the long-term (structural) origins of the revolution was also significant as 18th-century France witnessed a series of geopolitically induced social transformations, preparing the conditions for the regime’s eventual collapse. Over the 17th and 18th centuries, the French regime gradually shifted from a relatively defensive foreign policy posture vis-a-vis the Habsburgs to a more expansionist foreign policy on the continent and over-seas. The domestic effects of this transformation in France’s foreign relations were decisive in laying the conditions for the 1789 revolution. Bailey Stone (2004: 260) lists the key developments emerging from this ‘dynamic interplay between international and domestic forces’ as including ‘the proliferation of venal offices, the deepening divisions within the army, the gradual reduction of social-status-related tax exemptions, and the growing constitutional confrontation between the crown and the tax-resisting parlements of the realm’. These changes, wrought by the attempt to uphold French

Page 18: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

18 European Journal of International Relations

absolutism in a changing international context, increasingly came into conflict with the social and ideological basis of the ancien régime — upholding noble privilege and the monarchical state.

In order to fund the Bourbon monarchy’s belligerent foreign policy, the French state sold off enormous numbers of noble titles and even more offices conferring nobility or enhanced social status. Scholars have estimated that as many as 10,000 people were ennobled over the century: ‘Multiplied by five for the families who inherited noble status from their newly ennobled heads, this gives a minimum total of 32,500 or a maxi-mum of 50,000 new nobles during the eighteenth century’ (Stone, 2004: 42). The pur-chase of ennobling offices thereby acted as a key means of bourgeois infiltration into French society’s elite ranks, ‘into its central and provincial administration, its financial apparatus, its judiciary, and its armed forces’ (Stone, 2004: 42). The overall effect was to decisively increase the weight of the bourgeoisie within France’s political order as the ‘government was driven by geostrategic and derivative fiscal necessity to encourage the assimilation of “new” civilian officeholding (or “robe”) nobility to older military (or “sword”) noblesse, and of wealthy bourgeoisie to recent “robe” nobility’ (Stone, 2004: 42). ‘In this sense’, Stone (2004: 42) concludes, ‘the crown was indeed an agent of social evolution … of the metamorphosis of exclusive nobility into more inclusive “notability”’.

Yet, despite the mass of office sales to replenish the state’s ailing finances, it was actu-ally becoming more difficult for the bourgeoisie to become nobles as increases in offices failed to keep pace with the dramatic expansion of the bourgeoisie over the 18th century (cf. Doyle, 1984; Lucas, 1973). Moreover, intensified competition and increased office prices meant that a more aspirant bourgeoisie than ever were failing to purchase their way up the social ladder, consequently fuelling bourgeois resentment against the old order (Doyle, 1984: 858). The traditional means of social promotion were therefore con-tracting in the final years of the Old Regime. It was hardly surprising, then, that when the Estates General met in May–June 1789, the bourgeoisie of the Third Estate was over-whelmingly in favour of a single chamber that it would dominate.

The ensuing revolution sparked by the geopolitically induced bankruptcy of the state would see the bourgeoisie act as a chief leader of the revolutionary movement through-out its phases. Reviewing the social backgrounds of those who held office during the revolution, Lynn Hunt (1984: 117) writes:

The revolutionary political class can be termed ‘bourgeois’ both in terms of social position and of class consciousness. The revolutionary officials were the owners of the means of production; they were either merchants with capital, professionals with skills, artisans with their own shops, or more rarely, peasants with land…. The ‘consciousness’ of the revolutionary elite can be labelled insofar as it was distinctly anti-feudal, anti-aristocratic, and anti-absolutist.

The bourgeois revolution in France was, indeed, exceptional for the leadership role that the bourgeois played in it. Yet, the bourgeoisie had not originally sought to overthrow the ancien régime, but instead to merely reform the state. It was only under the pressure of counter-revolution from both within and without and popular pressures from below — especially through the intervention of the peasantry — that the bourgeoisie were driven,

Page 19: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 19

particularly under the Jacobins, to smash the old order (Callinicos, 1989: 146–147; Hobsbawm, 1996: 60–62; Soboul, 1998: 32).

However, was the socio-political order established by the revolution conducive to capitalist development? A main argument against the notion of a French bourgeois revo-lution is that the post-revolutionary regime was actually antithetical to capitalist mod-ernization. If bourgeois revolutions are to be understood in terms of their outcomes, an anti-capitalist revolutionary settlement would surely pose a problem. According to George Comninel (1987: 202), the French Revolution:

did very little in the way of transforming the essential social relations of production … it did not produce capitalist society. Instead, the Revolution further entrenched small-scale peasant production, and with it the extraction of agrarian surplus through rent, mortgages, etc.

What are we to make of such arguments?First, to judge the essential character of a revolution, one must look at its conse-

quences in its temporal totality (i.e. 1789–1815). The issue is not whether capitalist con-ditions were immediately established, but whether the outcome of the revolution was conducive to capitalist development in the medium to long term. From this perspective, it seems indisputable that the revolution established the socio-political conditions for capitalist development. As Albert Soboul (1998: 32) writes:

By wiping the slate clean of all feudal vestiges, by liberating the peasants of seigniorial rights and ecclesiastical tithes, and to a certain degree from community constraints, by destroying the trade monopolies and unifying the national market, the French Revolution marked a decisive stage on the path to capitalism. Suppressing feudal landed property, it even freed small direct producers, making possible the differentiation of the peasant mass and its polarization between capital and wage labor. This led to entirely new relations of production; capital, once under feudal domination, was able to make the value of work mercenary. In this way, the autonomy of capitalist production was finally assured in the agricultural domain as well as the industrial sector.

Further, in an early instance of what can be retrospectively understood as a state capital-ist form of substitutionism, the Committee of Public Safety nationalized the existing armouries and built a massive new armaments manufacturer in Paris (employing over 5000 wage-labourers) and more elsewhere. The majority of furnaces and forges (over a thousand) were confiscated from the ecclesiastics and nobles by the state and rented out and operated by the so-called maîtres de forges, who were bourgeois in origin. Under the Directory and later Napoleon, these industries were then sold off to these same individu-als, who came to rapidly centralize ownership and control over the 1789–1815 period. ‘The stage was set for a future transformation of this industry — key to the development of nineteenth century industrial capitalism — under the auspices of the maîtres de forges who now operated these means of production as their private property’ (Davidson, 2012: 532; cf. Heller, 2009b: 90, 96, 103).

Second, the revisionist view that the agrarian settlement established by the revolution, which entrenched a smallholding peasantry supposedly retarding agricultural innova-tion, has been forcefully challenged by more recent studies (see Chevet, 2009; Heller,

Page 20: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

20 European Journal of International Relations

2009b: 99–103; McPhee, 1989). Comninel’s and others’ conclusions regarding the detri-mental effect of small-scale peasant production on capitalist development essentially assimilates the road taken by French agrarian capitalism to the large-scale capitalist ten-ant farming of the English model. Yet, this merely reproduces the kind of unilinear con-ceptions of socio-historical development characteristic of modernization theories, whereby the ‘raison d’etre of agrarian society should have been to increase productivity along English lines’ (McPhee, 1989: 1280). According to Anatolii Ado, if the rapid development of agrarian capitalism was inhibited during the 19th century, it was an effect of the persistence of large property and the burden of rent, not small peasant prop-erty. Hence, ‘the popular revolution of the petty producers ought to be seen as an essen-tial element of the capitalist dynamic characteristic of this upheaval’ (Heller, 2009b: 103). As Peter McPhee (1989: 1276) concludes:

the economic, social, and ultimately political changes in the French countryside in the nineteenth century are best understood as a slow extension of ‘simple commodity production’, that ‘historical premis’ of capitalism, whose full capacity as the ‘really revolutionising path’ was limited by the ‘retrograde’ effects of large property rented in small holding.

Although French agriculture lagged behind Britain’s throughout the 19th century, this should not be interpreted as a denial of its capitalist character. For the outcome of the revolution’s agrarian settlement ‘undoubtedly benefitted the “really existing” capitalist class in France as opposed to some ideal construct derived from comparison with England’ (Callinicos, 1989: 151). Moreover, one would expect that the path of French capitalist development would diverge from that of England as the international condi-tions of its emergence had been dramatically transformed. Indeed, one of the key reasons why French industrialization, like much of the European continent, diverged from the British path was due to the more serious revolutionary threat emanating from below (Horn, 2010). While deviating from the British model, France was, in fact, compara-tively successful in its industrial drive as ‘industry grew relatively rapidly in the period 1815 to 1850 when the era of war ended’ (Horn, 2010: 99; cf. Horn, 2006).

The international effects of the French Revolution were no less profound as the revo-lution and Napoleonic Wars decisively transformed the 19th-century geopolitical order and, consequently, the form that subsequent bourgeois revolutions would take. Regarding the former, Metternich’s ‘Concert of Europe’ inaugurating the so-called ‘Hundred Years Peace’ was conceived as a conscious reaction to the revolutionary forces unleashed by 1789 as conservative European state managers sought to balance against both states in the international system and radical social forces at home (see Halperin, 2004). The radi-calization of the French Revolution was also viewed by the European ruling classes as a warning sign of things to come, while inhibiting the bourgeoisie to play their ‘assigned’ revolutionary roles lest the ‘underclasses’ got out of hand, as witnessed in the revolutions of 1848–1849.

Subsequent revolutions in Europe and beyond would thus come to take the form of ‘revolutions from above’, or what Gramsci called ‘passive revolutions’: largely elite-driven affairs limiting the popular participation of the subaltern classes — as exemplified in the Italian, German and Japanese revolutionary experiences of the late 19th century

Page 21: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 21

— and involving ‘molecular’ processes of transformation, ‘progressively modify[ing] the pre-existing composition of forces’ in the ruling classes’ ‘gradual but continuous absorption of its ‘“antithesis”’ (the proletariat) (Gramsci, 1971: 58, 109). The European ruling classes had learned the lessons of the French bourgeoisie, heeding Bismarck’s advice of 1866 that ‘[i]f revolution there is to be, let us rather undertake it than undergo it’ (quoted in Gall, 1986: 305). Under the transformed ‘geo-social’ milieu handed down by the experience of 1789, passive revolutions would become the primary means through which later-developing states would achieve their own bourgeois revolutions. Such revo-lutions can be thus conceived as organically emerging from the transfigured world- historical conditions unleashed by the ‘Great Transformation’ and its political conse-quences, heralding a particularly intense form of U&CD generalized through the rise of a distinctly capitalist world economy (see Allinson and Anievas, 2010).

Conclusion

As this article has shown, international relations have been causally decisive in the ori-gins, dynamics and outcomes of revolutions. In turn, revolutions have been essential features in the development and reproduction of geopolitical orders, instilling them with distinct social logics and purposes. International relations have, then, been concerned not only with the problems of war and peace, but, fundamentally tied to these, with ‘the management of change in domestic political orders’ (Rosenberg, 1994: 35). Only by grasping revolutions in these international dimensions can one begin to fully understand their world-historical meanings.

The re-conceptualization of bourgeois revolutions offered in this article has important implications for both Marxist and IR theory. Regarding the former, it means a fundamen-tal rethinking of historical materialism’s basic theoretical premises as it necessitates the incorporation of a distinctly ‘international’ dimension of social development and repro-duction into its guiding ‘general abstractions’. This can be seen to represent (in Lakatosian terms) a ‘progressive problem-shift’ within the historical materialist research programme, introducing and ‘stretching’ an auxiliary theory consistent with the ‘hard-core’ premises of that programme. Rather than protecting these hard-core premises by limiting their explanatory scope (‘monster-barring’) or identifying anomalies as exceptions or patholo-gies, the theory of U&CD aims to magnify the explanatory power of the original research programme (cf. Anievas, 2014: ch. 2).

For IR theory, the preceding analysis challenges the persistent theoretical separation of the ‘inside’ and ‘outside’ dimensions of social reality (Walker, 1993) at the heart of mainstream IR. Capturing the fused linkages between revolutions and ‘the international’ requires a fundamental rethinking of some of the core categories of IR theory itself, such as the ‘balance of power’, as their empirical referents necessarily cut across and inter-connect with both ‘second-’ and ‘third-’level images of international relations, thereby scrambling their hitherto assumed meanings. This not only means dispensing with the ‘national-territorial totality’ (Halliday, 1994: 78) as the primary ontological unit of analy-sis, but also requires the development of theoretical concepts capable of capturing the multiple, interconnected spatial fields of social constitution and organization. Rather than beginning with analytically distinct conceptualizations of discrete spheres of

Page 22: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

22 European Journal of International Relations

domestic and international politics that only subsequently interact, IR theory needs to be reconstructed upon the foundations of wider macro-processes of socio-historical change, as captured by U&CD. Only in these ways can we then begin to understand the intercon-nections between revolutions and international relations as organically emerging from a unified process of world-historical development.

Acknowledgements

Thanks to Pepijn Brandon, Henry Heller, Kamran Matin and Kerem Nişancıoğlu for comments on earlier drafts. Usual disclaimers apply.

Funding

I would like to acknowledge the generous funding and support provided by the Leverhulme Trust.

Notes

1. However, see Stephen Walt’s (1997) attempt to fit revolutions within the system-level frame-work of neorealism, the result of which is the usual ‘external interaction’ model whereby processes occurring at discretely conceived levels of analysis (revolutions in the ‘domestic’; wars in the ‘international’) are theorized as externally interacting in a way that leaves the basic ontological assumptions of the theory intact.

2. For our purposes here, capitalism may be defined as a historically distinct mode of production characterized by the systemization of competitive accumulation primarily (but not exclu-sively) based on the exploitation of wage-labour (cf. Anievas and Nişancıoğlu, forthcoming).

3. I owe this formulation to one of the peer reviewers. 4. This approach partially compliments Kamran Matin’s (2013: 48, ch. 3) reformulation of bour-

geois revolutions from the perspective of U&CD while nonetheless maintaining the conse-quentialist approach that he criticizes.

5. On processes of substitutionism being intrinsic to combined development, see Matin (2013: 19).

6. In order to avoid structural realist (mis)conceptions of ‘the international’ as an absolutely autonomous, supra-social sphere of geopolitical interaction, the concepts of ‘the interna-tional’ and ‘international system’ as used here neither to denote a permanent state of anarchy nor necessarily imply competition between discretely conceived political units in which the autonomous logic of this competition dictates their strategies. I must thank one of the peer reviewers for pushing me to clarify this important point.

7. Most notably, Scott (2000). 8. The analysis here is somewhat reminiscent of Gramsci’s (1994: ch. 4) discussion of the

‘Southern Question’ in Italy. 9. For a systematic refutation of this argument, see Davidson (2012: 133–180).10. Offices sold by the state to raise additional taxes.11. Here, Matin (2013) is describing the ‘rentier state’ of the Pahlavi dynasty in Iran.

References

Ado A (1990) The role of the French Revolution in the transition from feudalism to capitalism. Science & Society 54(3): 361–366.

Albritton R (1993) Did agrarian capitalism exist? Journal of Peasant Studies 20(3): 419–441.Allinson JC and Anievas A (2010) The uneven and combined development of the Meiji Restoration:

A passive revolutionary road to capitalist modernity. Capital & Class 34(3): 469–490.

Page 23: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 23

Anderson P (1974) Lineages of the Absolutist State. London: New Left Books.Anderson P (1984) Modernity and revolution. New Left Review 1(144): 96–113.Anderson P (1992) English Questions. London: Verso.Anievas A (2014) Capital, the State, and War: Class Conflict and Geopolitics in the Thirty Years’

Crisis, 1914–1945. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Anievas A and Nişancıoğlu K (forthcoming) How the West Came to Rule: The Geopolitical

Origins of Capitalism. London: Pluto.Armstrong D (1993) Revolution and World Order: The Revolutionary State in International

Society. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Bowden PJ (1990) Agricultural prices, farm profits and rents: 1500–1640. In: Bowden PJ (ed.)

Economic Change: Wages, Profits and Rents. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Brenner R (1985) Agrarian class structure and economic development in pre-industrial Europe.

In: Aston TH and Philpin CHE (eds) The Brenner Debate: Agrarian Class Structure and Economic Development in Pre-Industrial Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Brenner R (1989) Bourgeois revolution and the transition to capitalism. In: Beier AL, Cannadine D and Rosenheim JM (eds) The First Modern Society. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Brenner R (1993) Merchants and Revolution: Commercial Change, Political Conflict, and London’s Overseas Traders, 1550–1653. London: Verso.

Carlin N (1999) The Causes of the English Civil War. Oxford: Blackwell.Callinicos A (1989) Bourgeois revolutions and historical materialism. International Socialism

2(43): 113–171.Chevet J-M (2009) Reconsidering a rural myth: Peasant France and capitalist Britain. In: Broad

J (ed.) A Common Agricultural Heritage? Revising French and British Rural Divergence. Exeter: British Agricultural History Society.

Cliff T (1963) Deflected permanent revolution. International Socialism 1(12): 1–18.Comninel GC (1987) Rethinking the French Revolution: Marxism and the Revisionist Challenge.

London: Verso.Coward B (1992) The experience of the gentry, 1640–1660. In: Richardson RC (ed.) Town and

Countryside in the English Revolution. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Daudin G (2004) Profitability of slave and long-distance trading in context: The case of eight-

eenth-century France. The Journal of Economic History 64(1): 144–171.Davidson N (2003) Discovering the Scottish Revolution, 1692–1746. London: Pluto.Davidson N (2012) How Revolutionary were the Bourgeois Revolutions? Chicago, IL: Haymarket

Press.Doyle W (1984) The price of offices in pre-revolutionary France. Historical Journal 27(4):

831–860.Doyle W (1989) The Oxford History of the French Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Duplessis R (1997) Transitions to Capitalism in Early Modern Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press.Foran J (2005) Taking Power: On the Origins of Third World Revolutions. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press.Furet F (1981) Interpreting the French Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Gall L (1986) Bismarck: The White Revolutionary, 1851–1871, Volume 1. London: Allen and

Unwin.Gramsci A (1971) Selections from the Prison Notebooks. London: Lawrence and Wishart.Gramsci A (1994) Pre-Prison Writings. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Halliday F (1994) Rethinking International Relations. London: PalgraveHalliday F (1999) Revolution and World Politics: The Rise and Fall of the Sixth Great Power.

Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

Page 24: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

24 European Journal of International Relations

Halliday F (2001) The great anomaly. Review of International Studies 27(4): 693–699.Halperin S (2004) War and Social Change in Europe: The Great Transformation Revisited.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Heller H (2000) Primitive accumulation and technical innovation in the French Wars of Religion.

History and Technology 16(3): 243–262.Heller H (2002) Labour, Science, and Technology in France, 1500–1620. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press.Heller H (2009a) The longue durée of the French bourgeoisie. Historical Materialism 17(1):

31–59.Heller H (2009b) The Bourgeois Revolution in France. Oxford: Berghahn Book.Heller H (2011) The Birth of Capitalism. London: Pluto.Hill C (1940) The English Revolution 1640: Three Essays. London: Lawrence & Wishart.Hill C (1981) Parliament and people in seventeenth-century England. Past & Present 92:

100–124.Hill C (1985) The Collected Essays of Christopher Hill: Writing and Revolution in 17th Century

England, Volume 1. Brighton: Harvester Press.Hobsbawm E (1954) The general crisis of the European economy in the seventeenth century. Past

& Present 5: 33–53.Hobsbawm E (1996) The Age of Revolution, 1789–1848. New York, NY: Vintage Books.Hoffman PT (1996) Growth in a Traditional Society: The French Countryside, 1450–1815.

Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Horn J (2006) The Path Not Taken: French Industrialization in the Age of Revolution, 1750–1830.

Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Horn J (2010) Avoiding revolution: The French path to industrialization. In: Horn J, Rosenband

LN and Smith MR (eds) Reconceptualizing the Industrial Revolutions. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Hunt L (1984) Politics, Culture, and Class in the French Revolution. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

Jones C (1998) Bourgeois revolution revived: 1789 and social change. In: Kates G (ed.) The French Revolution: Recent Debates & New Controversies. London: Routledge.

Jones GS (1977) Society and politics at the beginning of the world economy. Cambridge Journal of Economics 1: 77–92.

Kennedy P (1989) The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers. London: Fontana.Lacher H (2006) Beyond Globalization: Capitalism, Territoriality and the International Relations

of Modernity. London: Routledge.Lemarchand G (1990) France on the eve of the revolution: A society in crisis or a crisis of politics?

Science & Society 54(3): 266–287.Lewis G (1999) The French Revolution: Rethinking the Debate. London: Routledge.Lucas C (1973) Nobles, bourgeois and the origins of the French Revolution. Past & Present 60:

84–126.McNeil JR and McNeil WH (2003) The Human Web. London: W.W. Norton.McPhee P (1989) The French Revolution, peasants, and capitalism. American Historical Review

94(5): 1265–1280.McPhee P (2002) The French Revolution, 1789–1799. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Mann M (1986) The Sources of Social Power: A History of Power from the Beginning to AD 1760,

Volume 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Manning B (1991) The English People and the English Revolution. London: Bookmarks.Matin K (2013) Recasting Iranian Modernity: International Relations and Social Change. London:

Routledge.

Page 25: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

Anievas 25

Mayer A (2000) The Furies: Violence and Terror in the French and Russian Revolutions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Mentet de Salmonet R (1739) The History of the Troubles of Great-Britain. London: Oliver Payne.Milward AS and Saul SB (2013) The Economic Development of Continental Europe, 1780–1870.

London: Routledge.Mooers C (1991) The Making of Bourgeois Europe: Absolutism, Revolution, and the Rise of

Capitalism in England, France, and Germany. London: Verso.Parker G (2008) Crisis and catastrophe: The global crisis of the seventeenth century reconsidered.

American Historical Review 113(4): 1053–1079.Pincus S (2009) 1688: The First Modern Revolution. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Polišenský JV (1971) The Thirty Years’ War. London: B.T. Batsford.Reeve LJ (2003) Charles I and the Road to Personal Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University

Press.Rosenberg J (1994) The Empire of Civil Society. London: Verso.Rosenberg J (2006) Why is there no international historical sociology? European Journal of

International Relations 12(3): 307–340.Rosenberg J (2010) Basic problems in the theory of uneven and combined development, part

II: Unevenness and political multiplicity. Cambridge Review of International Affairs 23(1): 165–189.

Russell C (1990) The Causes of the English Civil War. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Scott J (2000) England’s Troubles: Seventeenth-Century English Political Instability in European

Context. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Skocpol T (1979) States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia and

China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Soboul A (1998) The French Revolution in the history of the contemporary world. In: Kates G

(ed.) The French Revolution: Recent Debates & New Controversies. London: Routledge.Stone B (2004) Reinterpreting the French Revolution: A Global-Historical Perspective.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Stone L (1965) The Crisis of the Aristocracy 1558–1641. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Stone L (1972) The Causes of the English Revolution 1529–1642. New York, NY: Harper & Row.Tawney RW (1941) The rise of the gentry, 1558–1640. Economic History Review 11: 1–38.Taylor GV (1967) Noncapitalist wealth and the origins of the French Revolution. American

Historical Review 72(4): 469–496.Teschke B (2003) Myth of 1648: Class, Geopolitics and the Making of Modern International

Relations. London: Verso.Teschke B (2005) Bourgeois revolution, state formation and the absence of the international.

Historical Materialism 13(2): 3–26.Tilly C (1984) Demographic origins of the European proletariat. In: Levine D (ed.) Proletarianization

and Family History. Orlando, FL: Academic Press.Trevor-Roper HR (2011 [1965]) The general crisis of the seventeenth century. In: Aston TR (ed.)

Crisis in Europe: 1560–1660. London: Routledge.Trotsky L (1959 [1930]) History of the Russian Revolution. Garden City, NY: Doubleday.Trotsky L (1962 [1930/1906]) The Permanent Revolution and Results and Prospects. London: Labor.Underwood D (1996) A Freeborn People: Politics and the Nation in Seventeenth Century England.

Oxford: Clarendon Press.Van Pijl K (2014) The Discipline of Western Supremacy: Modes of Foreign Relations and Political

Economy, Volume III. London: Pluto.Vardi L (1993) The Land and the Loom: Peasants and Profit in Northern France, 1680–1800.

Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

Page 26: Revolutions and International Relations: Rediscovering the Classical Bourgeois Revolutions

26 European Journal of International Relations

Walker RBJ (1993) Inside/Outside: International Relations as Political Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Walt SM (1997) Revolution and War. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Whittle J (2001) The Development of Agrarian Capitalism: Land and Labour in Norfolk, 1440–1580.

Oxford: Oxford University Press.Wight M (1966) Power Politics. London: Allen & Unwin.Wood EM (1999) The Origin of Capitalism: A Longer View. London: Pluto.

Author biography

Alexander Anievas is an Early Career Leverhulme Fellow at the Department of Politics and International Studies, University of Cambridge, UK. He is the author of Capital, the State, and War: Class Conflict and Geopolitics in the Thirty Years’ Crisis, 1914–1945 (University of Michigan Press, 2014) and co-author (with Kerem Nişancıoğlu) of How the West Came to Rule: The Geopolitical Origins of Capitalism (Pluto Press, forthcoming). He has co-edited volumes on The Longue Durée of the Far-Right: An International Historical Sociology (Routledge, 2015), with Richard Saull, Neil Davidson and Adam Fabry, and Race and Racism in International Relations: Confronting the Global Colour Line (Routledge, 2015), with Nivi Manchanda and Robbie Shilliam, and is the editor of Cataclysm 1914: The First World War and the Making of Modern World Politics (Brill Press, 2015). He is also an editorial member of the journal Historical Materialism: Research in Critical Marxist Theory.