Top Banner
Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120 Therefore, can consume (at extremes) 150 units of good 1, costing 0.8 per unit, or 120 units of “all other goods”/money or any combination along budget line
22

Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Mar 31, 2015

Download

Documents

Xiomara Arnell
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Questions 1 & 2• Individual A• Perfect 1:1 substitutes• x-axis: one particular good– p1 = 0.8

• y-axis: all other goods– money, given that p2 = 1

• M = 120• Therefore, can consume (at extremes) 150 units of

good 1, costing 0.8 per unit, or 120 units of “all other goods”/money– or any combination along budget line

Page 2: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Qgood

Qmoney

Purple lines – indifference curves

Budget constraint: M = 120, p1 = 0.8

Page 3: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Questions 3 & 4• Mostly the same as before• Individual A has perfect 1:1 substitutes as prefs• x-axis: one particular good– p1 = 1.2

• y-axis: all other goods– money, given that p2 = 1

• M = 120• Therefore, can consume (at extremes) 100 units of

good 1, costing 1.2 per unit, or 120 units of “all other goods”/money– or any combination along budget line

Page 4: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Qgood

Qmoney

Purple lines – indifference curves

Budget constraint: M = 120, p1 = 0.8

Budget constraint: M = 120, p1 = 1.2

Page 5: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Why is the new IC lower than the old IC?

• In general terms:– Increase in price of one good reduces feasible set

• Perfect substitute preferences imply all income is spent on one good (unless a = p1/p2 where 1:a is form of preferences)

• Shift in relative prices reduces consumption of good 1 => welfare effects will be negative

Page 6: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Compensating variation – new prices

• “This is the amount of money we need to give to the individual to restore him or her to the same level of happiness (the same indifference curve) as before the price rise.”

• Draw in parallel shift of new budget constraint until we hit the original indifference curve.

• What is the associated increase in income that this implies?

Page 7: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Qgood

Qmoney

Budget constraint: M = 120, p1 = 0.8

Budget constraint: M = 120, p1 = 1.2

30

Page 8: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Why is this less than the increased cost of the originally purchased bundle of goods?• “Originally the individual bought 150 units of the

good – costing 120 at the original price and 180 at the new price”

• Individual substitutes away from good 1 and purchases good 2.– Utility vs income, constrained to buy one bundle– Consider case where budget constraint shifted out

until it passes through original bundle of goods (Slutsky decomposition – Chapter 19.8)

• Pasty tax?

Page 9: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Question 5 – equivalent variation (old prices)

• Same problem as questions 1-4, only concentrating on equivalent variation rather than compensating variation.

• “Calculate the equivalent variation – this is the amount of money that we need to take away from Individual A at the original prices to have the same impact on his or her welfare as the price rise.”

• Draw in parallel shift of old budget constraint until we hit the new indifference curve.

• What is the associated decrease in income that this implies?

Page 10: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Qgood

Qmoney

24

Budget constraint: M = 120, p1 = 0.8

Budget constraint: M = 120, p1 = 1.2

Page 11: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Price

Q1

Area ≈ (1 - 0.8) * (120 + 0.5 * 30) ≈ 0.2 * 135 ≈ 276

Page 12: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

CV ≠ EV (generally...)

• Look at things from two different perspectives– CV – new price (old level of utility)– EV – old price (new level of utility)

• Rise in P– CV and EV both positive– Individual is better off at old price

• CV > EV and |CV| > |EV|

• Fall in P– CV and EV both negative– Individual is better off at new price

• CV > EV but |CV| < |EV|

Page 13: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

What about QLP / PS?

• Ignore possibility of corner solutions with QLP– shifting of budget constraint to calculate either CV

or EV will always produce same value (D Y).⊥

• PS always (well...) has corner solutions.– CV = EV = ΔCS if and only if p > a for both original

and new prices.• CV = EV = ΔCS = 0

– If p ≤ a for at least one price, we have different corner solutions (or multiple solutions if p = a).

Page 14: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Questions 8-9• Individual B• Perfect 1:1 complements• x-axis: one particular good– p1original = 0.8, then p1new = 1.2

• y-axis: all other goods– money, given that p2 = 1

• M = 120• Q consumed of either good = M/(p1 + p2)• At original prices, 120/(0.8 + 1) = 66.66...• At new prices, 120/(1.2 + 1) = 54.5454...

Page 15: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Qgood

Qmoney

Budget constraint: M = 120, p1 = 0.8

Budget constraint: M = 120, p1 = 1.2

Page 16: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Qgood

Qmoney

CV=26.66...

Page 17: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

CV = increased cost

• “Note that the compensating variation in this case is exactly equal to the increased cost of the originally purchased bundle of goods. (0.4 times 66.6666… equals 26.666….) Why?”

• Perfect complementarity means goods must be purchased in fixed proportions– Therefore no substitution effect– Total effect = income effect– CV uses new prices => CV = increased cost

Page 18: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Qgood

Qmoney

EV=21.818...

Page 19: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

EV < CV

• Perfect complements => no substitution effect, so move between same two bundles when measuring CV and EV.

• Always consume positive quantity of each good.

• Because price of one good changes, cost of purchasing must be lower with lower prices.

Page 20: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Price

Q1

Area ≈(1.2 - 0.8) * (54.54... + 0.5 * (66.66... - 54.54...)) ≈ 0.4 * (54.54... + 6.06...) ≈ 24.2

Change in surplus again between CV and EV

Page 21: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Question 10• Summed (“aggregate”) demand looks like this:

Page 22: Questions 1 & 2 Individual A Perfect 1:1 substitutes x-axis: one particular good – p 1 = 0.8 y-axis: all other goods – money, given that p 2 = 1 M = 120.

Question 10• Loss of surplus:

Area ≈(0.2)(54.54)+(0.2)(0.5)(60-54.54)+(0.2)(180)+(0.2)(0.5)(216.67-180)

≈ 51As before!

D for Perfect substitutes

D for Perfect complements