Top Banner

of 38

Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

Apr 06, 2018

Download

Documents

Katherine Sauer
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    1/38

    Public Finance

    Dr. Katie Sauer

    Social Insurance

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    2/38

    Figure 12-1: Government Spending, 1953 & 2007

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    3/38

    Expected Value

    Expected value incorporates the probability of an

    occurrence of an event with its outcome.

    E[X] = p1X1 + p2X2 + + pnXn

    pi is the probability of an event

    Xi is the outcome associated with an event

    The probabilities must always sum to 1.

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    4/38

    Suppose that in a year, there is a

    0.1% chance that you will be involved in a caraccident resulting in $300,000 worth of damages

    and injuries

    10% chance that you will be involved in a caraccident resulting in $9000 worth of damages

    What is the expected value of the damages?

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    5/38

    E[Damages] = (0.001)(300,000)

    + (0.10)(9,000)+ (0.899)(0)

    E[Damages] = 300 + 900 + 0

    = 1200

    You should be willing to pay $1,200 per year for an

    insurance policy that covers all of your expenses.

    If your insurance company charges you $1,200, they are

    charging an actuarially fair price.

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    6/38

    Actuarially fair pricing means your insurance firm willearn zero expected profit.

    E[profit] = premium expected payout = 0

    = premium (probability of payout)(payout amount)

    Ex: E[profit] = 1200 (0.001)(300,000) (0.10)(9000)

    = 1200 300 900= 0

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    7/38

    Ex: You are playing roulette.

    - 38 pockets- choose red 16 pocket to bet $1 on

    - if the ball lands in red 16, win $35

    - if the ball lands in any other pocket, lose $1

    Calculate your expected value of a $1 bet.

    E[$1 bet on red 16] =

    = (1/38)(35) + (37/38)(-1)= 0.92 0.97

    = - 0.05

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    8/38

    Ex: Insurance

    Sams income is $50,000 per year.

    There is a 1% chance that Sam will get hit by a car next

    year, resulting in $20,000 in medical expenses.

    Sams utility function is U = C0.5 .

    Sam can buy insurance form cents per dollar of

    insurance coverage $b.

    Assume an actuarially fair policy.

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    9/38

    Sams expected utility function can be expressed as:

    E[U]=

    (0.99)(50,000 mb)0.5 + (0.01)(50,000 mb 20,000+b)0.5

    An actuarially fair policy means that the firm earns zero

    expected profit:

    E[] = mb (0.01)b = 0

    m = 0.01

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    10/38

    Substituting in form yields:

    E[U]

    =(0.99)(50,0000.01b)0.5 + (0.01)(30,000 0.01b +b)0.5

    Maximizing with respect to the level of insurance coverage

    yields:

    5.05.0 )99.0000,30(

    )00495.0(

    )01.0000,50(

    )00495.0(

    bbb

    EU

    !x

    x

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    11/38

    Set it equal to zero and solve forb.

    0)99.0000,30(

    )00495.0(

    )01.0000,50(

    )00495.0(5.05.0

    !

    bb

    bb 01.0000,5099.0000,30 !

    000,20!b

    It is optimal for Sam to buy $20,000 of coverage.

    He will fully insure against the risk.

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    12/38

    If Sam wants $20,000 of coverage, he pays a premium of:

    mb

    m20,000

    from earlier we found m = 0.01

    (0.01)(20,000)

    $200

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    13/38

    Calculate Sams Expected Utility:

    - found m and b

    E[U]=

    (0.99)(50,000 mb)0.5 + (0.01)(50,000 mb 20,000+b)0.5

    E[U]=

    (0.99)(50,000200)0.5 + (0.01)(50,000 20020,000+

    20,000)0.5

    E[U]= 220.93 + 2.23 = 223.16

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    14/38

    What if Sam had only partially insured?

    - paid $100 for $10,000 of coverage

    E[U]=(0.99)(50,000100)0.5 + (0.01)(50,000 10020,000+

    10,000)0.5

    E[U]= 221.15 + 1.99 = 223.14

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    15/38

    The Expected Utility Model

    Your utility takes the following form: U = C0.5

    You are hit by a car with probabilityp.

    If you get hit, your medical costs are .

    Your income is W, regardless of whether you get hit.

    You can buy insurance for a premium ofmper dollar of

    insurance coverage.

    Insurance will pay you $b if you are hit.

    Insurance is actuarially fair.

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    16/38

    Your expected utility can be written as:

    E[U] = (probability of not getting hit)(utility)

    + (probability of getting hit)(utility)

    E[U] = (1 p) (W mb)0.5 + (p)(W mb + b)0.5

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    17/38

    Actuarially fair policy:

    E[] = mbpb = 0

    mb is the amount they receive in premiumspb is the expected payout

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    18/38

    mbpb = 0

    Simplifying yields:

    mb = pb

    m = p

    For example, if the risk of payout is 10%, then the

    insurance firm will charge 10 cents per dollar ofcoverage.

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    19/38

    Substitute m = p into the expected utility.

    E[U] = (1 p) (W mb)0.5 + (p) (W mb + b)0.5

    E[U] = (1 p) (W pb)0.5 + (p) (W pb + b)0.5

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    20/38

    Now, maximize the expected utility by choice of

    coverage (b).

    5.05.0 )(

    )5.0)(1(

    )(

    )5.0)(1(

    bpbW

    pp

    pbW

    pp

    b

    EU

    !

    x

    x

    H

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    21/38

    Set equal to zero and solve forb.

    0)(

    )5.0)(1(

    )(

    )5.0)(1(5.05.0

    !

    bpbW

    pp

    pbW

    pp

    H

    5.05.0 )(

    )5.0)(1(

    )(

    )5.0)(1(

    bpbW

    pp

    pbW

    pp

    !

    H

    5.05.0 )()( pbWbpbW ! H

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    22/38

    ? A ? A25.025.0

    )()( pbWbpbW! H

    pbWbpbW ! H

    H!b

    The optimal amount of coverage to buy is the amountthat exactly offsets the medical costs.

    - full insurance

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    23/38

    Expected Utility Theory tells us that with actuarially fair

    pricing, individuals will want to fully insure themselves

    to equalize consumption in all states of the world.

    People differ in their taste for risk.

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    24/38

    Given that it is theoretically optimal to have full

    insurance, why have Social Insurance?

    Asymmetric Information &Adverse Selection

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    25/38

    Suppose there are 100 careless insurance consumers

    who dont pay attention when crossing the street.

    5% chance of getting hit by a car$30,000 medical bills

    Suppose there are 100 careful insurance customers

    who always look both ways.

    0.5% chance of getting hit by a car

    $30,000 medical bills

    The insurance firm doesnt know who is careless and

    who is careful.

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    26/38

    Strategy 1: Ask each person if they are careful or not.

    Everyone will say they are careful.

    actuarially fair premium = (0.005)(30,000)

    = $150

    Total premiums = 200 x 150 = 30,000

    E[profit] = 30,000 (0.005)(30,000)(100)

    (0.05)(30,000)(100)

    = 30,000 15,000 150,000= 30,000 165,000

    The firm will lose money, so will not offer any insurance.

    - market failure

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    27/38

    Strategy 2: Offer a pooled rate.

    Divide the expected payout by the number of

    people and charge that amount to everyone

    165,000 / 200

    = $825

    Now, the careful consumers may choose not

    to purchase the insurance.

    Collect premiums from the careless:

    100 x $825

    = $82,500

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    28/38

    Pay out:

    (0.05)(100)($30,000)

    = $150,000

    The insurance firm will still lose money.

    The careful consumers will not be able to

    purchase their optimal amount of insurance.- market failure

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    29/38

    OvercomingAsymmetric Information

    1. Risk Premiums

    Many people are risk averse and are willing to pay more

    than the actuarially fair price for insurance.

    If our careful consumers are risk averse, they may

    be willing to pay $825 - $150 = $675 in a risk

    premium.

    Wed then have a pooling equilibrium.

    - all fully insure, which is optimal

    - not priced fairly for all

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    30/38

    2. Separate Products at Separate Prices

    - try to get customers to reveal information

    Option 1: $30,000 of coverage for $1,500

    (0.05)(30,000) = 1,500

    Option 2: $10,000 of coverage for $50

    (0.005)(10,000) = 50

    Likely that the careless would choose option 1 and the

    careful would choose option 2.

    This is called a separating equilibrium.

    - not optimal for the careful (market failure)

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    31/38

    Government Involvement Rationale:

    - asymmetric information / adverse selection

    - externalities

    - uninsured motorists

    - administrative costs

    - economies of scale

    - redistribution- tax low-risk to subsidize high-risk

    - paternalism

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    32/38

    Social Insurance vs Self-Insurance

    Suppose you are unemployed. Forms of self-insurance to

    get you through:

    - personal savings

    - borrow- money from other members of household

    - money from extended family, friends, church

    Suppose you can receive Unemployment Insurance.The UI Replacement Rate is the ratio of UI

    benefits to pre-unemployment earnings.

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    33/38

    UI replacement rate and the drop in consumption

    (a) No savings, credit cards, money from friends

    - at 0% UI replacement rate, consumption falls 100%

    - at 100% UI replacement rate, consumption falls 0%

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    34/38

    (b) Some savings, credit cards, money from friends

    - at 0% UI replacement rate, consumption falls 50%

    - at 100% UI replacement rate, consumption falls 0%

    - use UI instead of private funds

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    35/38

    (c) full private source of funds

    - at 0% UI replacement rate, consumption falls 0%

    - at 100% UI replacement rate, consumption falls 0%

    - use UI instead of private funds

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    36/38

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    37/38

    The Consumption-Smoothing Role of Social Insurance

    When events are predictable, social insurance plays a

    smaller consumption-smoothing role.

    When events are less costly, social insurance plays a

    smaller consumption-smoothing role.

  • 8/3/2019 Pub Econ Lecture 12 Social Insurance

    38/38

    Optimal Social Insurance Systems:

    should partially, not completely insure people against

    adverse events.

    Benefits: consumption smoothing

    Costs: moral hazard