Top Banner
January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy Process Discussion Paper No. 4 Environment Group Africa Region The World Bank
28

Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

Oct 02, 2018

Download

Documents

hoangthu
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

January 1999

Anders EkbomJan Bojö

Poverty and Environment:Evidence of Links and Integration into the

Country Assistance Strategy Process

Discussion Paper No. 4

Environment GroupAfrica Region

The World Bank

Page 2: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy Process

Anders EkbomJan Bojö

January 1999

Environment GroupAfrica RegionThe World Bank

Page 3: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

1

“Povertyii is a major cause and effect of global envi-ronmental problems” stated the influential Brundt-land Commission (WCED, 1987; p. 3) in a sen-tence that captures widely held beliefs: Poorpeople are often seen as compelled to exploittheir surrounding for short-term survival, andare assumed to be the ones most exposed to nat-ural resources degradationiii. Despite these intu-itively plausible statements, the debate on thecharacteristics of poverty-environment interac-tion has been likened to a puzzle (World Bank,1997), where we possess several pieces, haveidentified some crucial links and features, butstill lack the entire picture.

The aims of this paper are hence to (i) specifythe main hypotheses on how poverty and envi-ronment are linked, (ii) examine empirical evi-dence linked to each one of them, and (iii) pro-vide good examples of joint poverty-environment analyses in the World Bank’s Coun-try Assistance Strategies (CASs) and PovertyAssessments (PAs).

This report is a continuation of a previouslypublished Discussion Paper from the Environ-ment Group in the Africa Region of the WorldBank (No. 1) entitled Mainstreaming Environmentin Country Assistance Strategies (Ekbom and Bojö,1997). The previous study was based on a globalreview of 34 CASs which showed that CASscould substantially improve their analyses ofpoverty and environment. Our previous workhas been applied to many country contexts,where we have worked with EnvironmentGroup colleagues and other Country Team-

members to put lessons into practice. In theensuing debate, considerable interest wasexpressed to further elaborate the central themeof poverty-environment linkages; poverty allevi-ation being the generally accepted core of theWorld Bank’s work. This debate brought aboutthis paper.

The target group of the paper is primarilyWorld Bank staff involved in the CAS process,but we hope that a wider group of readers inter-ested in the general topics of poverty alleviationand environmentally sustainable development(ESD) will find something of interest.

The structure of the paper is as follows: Sec-tion 2 presents some arguments on how povertyand environment impact on each other, includ-ing key references and some empirical evidence.Section 3 presents some good examples fromexisting CASs and PAs of country-specific pov-erty-environment interactions. The section alsopresents some suggestions on how to address theissues jointly in the CAS process.

We see this document as a contribution to aprocess. Its effectiveness will mainly depend onits usefulness in successfully integrating povertyand environment in the CAS process. Ways toachieve this include working upstream in theCAS process, linking up early with povertyexperts in the Country Team and others insideand outside the Bank, identifying key areaswhere a joint poverty-environment approachwould be useful, and pursuing synergies andwin-win solutions by e.g. including poverty alle-viation components in Environmental Support

Introduction

1

Page 4: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

2

Programs or, conversely, including environmen-tal management components in poverty allevia-tion projects. Obviously, it is also useful to con-sult the poverty documents such as PovertyAssessments (PAs), Participatory PAs, and Liv-ing Standard Surveys to identify the entry pointsfor poverty-environment integrated work. In

cases with limited evidence of poverty-environ-ment links, further analysis may be necessary.The need for such analysis can be identifiedthrough Economic Sector Work (ESW) orthrough monitoring of selected performanceindicators and evaluation criteria which linkpoverty and environment.

Page 5: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

3

Below we specify a set of hypotheses (Hn) ofhow poverty and environment are linked, andexamine available empirical evidence.

H1. Poor people are the main victims of a bad environment

We will refer to this as the “victims” hypothesis,advanced by, for example, the influential Brundt-land Commission. Some common but generalobservations that underpin this hypothesis arethe following: Poor people are commonly boundto reside in areas with poor environmental qual-ity. Defining “the poorest” as the poorest 20 per-cent among the total population of all develop-ing countries, Leach and Mearns (1991) haveshown that 60 percent of them live in “ecologi-cally vulnerable areas”, including rural areas oflow agricultural potential and squatter settle-ments within urban areas.

Poor people lack resources to relocate fromthese areas and to adopt defensive measuresagainst negative exposure. Lower educationincreases their vulnerability to health risks. Theassociated political marginalization decreases theopportunities for environmental protection andprovision of basic services such as safe drinkingwater, access to clean air, functioning sewerageand waste collection. Urban squatters are com-monly exposed to polluted air, contaminatedwater, and hazardous and solid waste. Rural land-less people are forced for their survival to settle onmarginal lands, and cultivate poor soils. Whetherit is steep slopes, arid or semi-arid lands or river

deltas, they are all subject to aggravated risks suchas land slides, soil degradation, drought or floods.

The empirical example from Ghana in Box 1below brings out this hypothesis in statisticalnumbers.

In conclusion on this point, the results of thisstudy confirm the hypothesis that poor are victimsof a degraded environment, deprived of resourcesto escape the situation, and Songsore andMcGranahan (1993, p. 33) conclude that: “environ-mental risks go hand-in-hand with socio-economicdeprivation”. Turning this into a constructivepoint, the opportunities are there for “win-win”investments in a better environment for the poor.

H1a: Poor people are more vulnerable to loss of biolog-ical resources. An aspect of the “victims hypothe-sis” is that poor people are more directly depen-dent on biological resources for their livelihoodthan richer people. Loss of flora and fauna isthus relatively more costly to poorer segments ofsociety. Furthermore, poor people often are com-pelled to settle close to these resources com-monly found in open access areas, to beexploited at family-labor costs only.

People particularly dependent on biologicalresources include (i) small-scale farmers, whooften derive additional sources of income fromwild fruits, nuts, berries, herbs, medicinal plants,bushmeat and roots, (ii) trans-humant pastoral-ists, who derive essential nutrients from similarwild flora and fauna in marginal areas such asdrylands, and (iii) artisanal fishermen, who derivea variety of coastal and marine resources such asshells, seaweed, coral and fishes, which provide

Poverty-Environment Interactions

2

Page 6: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

4

food, building material, ornaments, cultural arti-facts and cash income. The case study in box 2looks more closely at the dependence on biologi-cal resources among different income segments.

In conclusion, this well-documented examplesuggests that (a) poor people may be relativelymore dependent on biological resources found oncommons, but (b) that better off people actuallyconsume a greater amount of them, in absoluteterms, per household. This lends some support tothe hypotheses as stated, but it complicates mat-ters somewhat. The policy implication is thatbiodiversity conservation might benefit the poor-est, but it could be a blunt instrument. To targetinterventions effectively, we need to know moreabout what specific resources the poor utilize themost, not only that they are biological resources.Particularly in cases where local resource usewould be limited, it is important to understandhow the local population is affected, and whatcompensation might be warranted.v

H1b: Extreme environmental stress can force thepoorest to migrate. Another corollary to the “vic-tims hypothesis” states that the poor, althoughless empowered to relocate from inhospitablesurroundings, are often forced to long-rangemigration due to environmental hardship. Their

choice of settlement will still be constrained, asindicated by the overall “victims” hypothesis,and the two hypotheses are mutually compati-ble. Natural and man-made disasters often forcethe poorest to temporarily or permanently leavetheir homestead to seek survival elsewhere. Theassociated environmental stress and resourcescarcity has resulted in widespread displacementof poor people. This resource-induced migrationhas become so pertinent that the victims havebeen labeled “environmental refugees” and sub-ject to specific assessment and action.

It should be recognized that migratory pat-terns are traditionally part of the coping mecha-nisms of, in particular, nomadic pastoralist soci-eties. In such cases, it could represent a well-established, risk-minimizing and functional rela-tionship with a fragile but dynamic environ-ment. This type of migration would not fallunder the definition of “environmental refugees”and is not our concern here.

In conclusion, while not all environmental ref-ugees are poor, and while many poor do notmigrate, it is evident that poor people have lessresources to adapt to inhospitable environ-ments, and are therefore forced to migrate insubstantial numbers, as Myers and Kent (1995)have documented.

Box 1: Environmental Risksand Living Standards in Ghana

In a study of 1000 randomly selected households in Accra, Ghana, Songsore and McGranahan (1993) ana-lyze the links between local environment, wealth and health. Wealth is measured in terms of possession ofcertain consumer durables and frequency of meat, poultry or fish consumption. The poorest and richest quin-tiles are singled out for comparison. The study focuses on diarrhea and respiratory diseases. Principal analyt-ical methods are bi-and multivariate regression analyses.

The poorest households show higher incidence of diarrhea, especially among children: 22% of the childrenin the poorest quintile, but only 9% in the richest were subject to diarrhea in the two weeks prior to the inter-view. The links between respiratory diseasesiv and wealth are weaker, but suggest a negative relationship forwomen and children. The poorest enjoy significantly less environmental services (safe water, sewerage). Theylack knowledge or means to efficiently prevent diseases, are exposed to more health hazards, and are subjectto more crowding, i.e. more people share pots, toilets, living room etc. Poverty is statistically related to higherprevalence of parasitic and diarrhea infections.

Specific explanations for some of the symptoms are that poor food handling, storage and hygiene practicestransmit diseases, especially parasitic and diarrhea infections. Here, local food vendors are a potential sourceof contaminated food; 61% of the poorest, but only 33% of the wealthiest households in Accra depend on foodvendors for daily intake. Water provided to poorer households is not safe and supply is often interrupted.

Some 83% of the richest, but only 3% of the poorest stored food in refrigerators. Similar disparities werereported for other hygiene practices (e.g. low frequency in hand washing prior to meals). Measures of crowd-ing indicated that 71% of the poorest households, but only 34% of the richest occupy less than 4m2 per personin the sleeping room. Likewise, 69% of the poorest, but only 12% of the richest share toilet with more than 10persons. Further, pests are also key transmitters of diseases. The poorest households reported a very highprevalence of flies (95%), cockroaches (66%), and rats (56%), respectively. The corresponding figures for thetop quintile were 22%, 30% and 15%.

Page 7: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

5

Box 3: Environmental Refugees

Myers and Kent’s (1995) comprehensive study“Environmental Exodus—An Emergent Crisis inthe Global Arena” indicates that there areapproximately 25 million environmental refu-gees in the world. For comparison, the numberof traditional (political and war) refugees areestimated at 22 million. The report defines “envi-ronmental refugees” as “…persons who can nolonger gain a secure livelihood in their tradi-tional homelands because of environmental fac-tors of unusual scope, notably drought, desertifi-cation, deforestation, soil erosion, watershortages and climate change, also natural disas-ters such as cyclones, storms and floods” (p. 19).

Many of these refugees are located on theHorn of Africa and in the Sahelian region, but alarge portion also resides in the Indian sub-con-tinent, China, Mexico and Central America.Based on six regional case studies, the reportstates that “poverty, and especially absolutepoverty, works in conjunction with environmen-tal factors and population pressures to producesizable numbers of refugees who are driven byall three factors working in conjunction” (Ibid.,p. 49).

H1c: Inequality reinforces environmental pressure. Askewed distribution of wealth and income hasimplications for environmental pressure. Forexample, if small-scale farmers are compelled toutilize marginal areas because large-scale land-owners occupy the best agricultural land, the ineq-uitable land distribution may be an importantdriving force behind deforestation and land degra-dation. Along this line, Dasgupta and Mäler (1994)argue that poverty and many environmental prob-lems stem from, or are exacerbated by, inequality.They also emphasize that in the presence of ine-

Box 4: Inequality and the Environment

A notorious example of inequality and itseffect on environment and health is SouthAfrica’s former Homelands—one of the majorlegacies of Apartheid—where many of the blackAfricans reside. Due to crowding, poverty,neglect and past policies of institutionalizedinequity, they are now subject to extremely poorhealth and environmental conditions. Around1/3 of the children of the black majority sufferfrom chronic malnutrition, only around 25%have electricity and running water, and less than20% have modern sanitation. At the same timemost whites enjoy “first world” conditions in allrespects. Consequently, infant mortality rate isabout 7–13% for black Africans, but only 1.2%for whites, and whites live 11.5 years longer onaverage. (World Bank, 1994).

quality, many local common property manage-ment schemes break down. This, in turn, results innegative impacts on the most vulnerable.

A corollary to the hypothesis above is thataverage GDP growth does not by definitionimply simultaneous poverty alleviation andenvironmental improvements. The effect can infact be the opposite or mixed, if growth playsinto the hands of a privileged elite.

For a full account, the effects of economicgrowth on poverty and environment need to beevaluated at household level. The effect on indi-vidual household members of a deterioratingenvironment can vary widely. In particular, chil-dren are the most vulnerable to poverty andenvironmental degradation: for instance, chil-dren inhale greater quantities of air-borne pollut-ants relative to their body weight because of their

Box 2: Use of Biological Resourcesin Zimbabwe

A detailed survey in Zimbabwe of 213 rural households’ use of several hundred non-marketed (“wild” or“environmental”) goods collected at local commons, shows that these goods account for a substantial share ofpoor people’s household budgets, and a significantly larger share than in richer households. Value derivedfrom environmental goods constitute as much as 40% of the total household budget in the lowest incomequintile, but only 25% among the top quintile.

Ordinary Least Squares (OLS)- and Tobit-regressions show that all but one of the income elasticities for“wild” goods are positive but mostly low. This indicates that as incomes rise, the relative budget share of wildgoods decreases but—contrary to the H1a hypothesis—that total demand for wild goods increase, albeit at aslow pace. The study also identifies that the elasticities vary widely between individual species: increasingincomes result in substantially larger consumption of e.g. fish, game meat, and local pottery, moderateincrease of e.g. mice, and wild fruit, and decreased consumption of some e.g. household utensils. Hence,some wild goods are complements and some substitutes to purchased goods. Cavendish concludes that thecommon notion of a single poverty-environment relationship is not supported by his evidence.

Source: Cavendish (1997).

Page 8: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

6

higher activity levels; they contract diarrheamore frequently due to higher exposure to vec-tors; infants in particular are exposed to higherhealth risks as they have not fully developedtheir immune system. There is also a genderaspect to the poverty-environment linkage(Agarwal, 1997). Thus, it is imperative to developthe understanding of poverty-environment inter-actions among sub-sets of poor people.

H1d: Governmental policies can create or reinforce avicious circle of poverty-environment interaction.Governments do this through policy failures,including failure to address market failures,imposing negative externalities with particularlysevere impacts on the poor. Market failures areexemplified by missing or incomplete marketsfor environmental goods and services (cleanwater, air, biodiversity resources, wetlands etc.).In the context of this paper, policy failures can bedescribed as policy makers’ actions or failures toact, which results in environmental degradationor pollution. Examples include subsidies to pol-luting industries and tenure insecurity, whichencourage poor people to engage in non-sustain-able resource use. It also includes corruptioncontributing to environmental degradation: “Theexistence of large resource rents from harvestingmature timber has attracted politicians as well asbusinessmen to the opportunities of immediategain” (Repetto & Gillis, 1988, p. 388).

The example from Brazil in Box 5 belowdescribes how government policies have contrib-uted to environmental degradation in the Ama-zon and reduced the chances of the poor tobecome farmers, which have left many of themlandless or unemployed.

Structural Adjustment Policies (SAPs) pro-moted by IMF and the Bank represent a subset ofgovernmental policies. Their effects on socialwelfare and the environment have been subjectto much debate and some analysis (see e.g.Munasinghe and Cruz, 1995; Reed 1992, 1996).Few reliable empirical studies exist, mainly dueto insufficient environmental data fed into weakanalytical frameworks, difficulties in establishingthe counterfactual, and the fact that SAPs oftenare only partially implemented. Timing andsequencing often deviate from the original policypackage, which makes it difficult to disentanglethe (often lagged) effects. While the need foradjustment of economic policies in Sub-SaharanAfrica is clear and increasingly beyond contro-versy, analyses of SAPs have shown both posi-tive and negative impacts on the environment.

Box 5: Policy Failures,Environment and the Poor

Mahar (1988) and Binswanger (1989) analyzethe impact of Brazil’s government’s policies onthe forest resources of the Amazon region andconclude that they have contributed to large-scale deforestation. An area of more than600,000 km2 has been cleared, 80% of which hasoccurred since 1980. The government’s role inthis massive loss of natural capital has been oneof biasing the allocation of land and agriculturalcredits towards the rich, promoting environ-mentally hazardous road developments, conces-sioning settlements in ecologically sensitiveareas, and encouraging livestock developmentthrough grazing-area expansion.

Specific policy failures include substantialagricultural tax exemptions for large-scale farm-ers, public-land allocation rules of differingclaim security as well as land taxes which pro-vide incentives for land clearing and conversionto crop land or pasture, tax credit schemesfavoring livestock ranching on cleared forestland, and subsidized credits to corporate live-stock ranches.

A review of studies from ten countries (Bojö,1997) covers Côte d’Ivoire, Cameroon, Ghana,Mali, Mexico, Philippines, Tanzania, Thailand,Zambia, and Zimbabwe, which all have beensubject to structural adjustment programs(SAPs). The implementation of SAPs has beenerratic, which, compounded by insufficient dataand analytical methods, have made it difficult toidentify the specific effects of SAPs. However,the study of Thailand, based on an extensiveComputable General Equilibrium model of 90sectors and 5 policy scenarios, reports that SAPshave contributed to reduced pollution andresource depletion per unit of GDP, but due toeconomic growth they have also led to an overalldecline of environmental quality.

A result common to several of the studies inSub-Saharan Africa is that reduced subsidies onfertilizers and pesticides combined with cur-rency devaluation, reportedly have contributedto agricultural encroachment into forests andincreased timber exports. On the positive side,the increased costs have decreased the use of pol-luting agro-chemicals. A general conclusion fromthe studies is that SAPs have been necessary tobring fundamentals in order, but that there is aneed to deploy complementary measures to min-imize the negative environmental effects.

Page 9: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

7

Box 6: Structural Adjustment and the Environment

Holden (1997) analyzes the impact of Zam-bia’s SAPs on the Chitemene slash-and-burnshifting cultivation system, which requires largeamounts of woody biomass for crop production.The adjustment policies included (i) introduc-tion of a market-based exchange rate;(ii) removal of price controls, leading to regionaland local price differentiation, (iii) removal offood and fertilizer subsidies, leading to higherconsumer food prices and higher fertilizerprices for farmers, (iv) reduced governmentinvolvement in production and marketing, and(v) reduced government expenditure.

Based on Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) andTobit-regressions of cross-section data from1992/93, Holden concludes that removal of fer-tilizer and transport subsidies resulted in substi-tution from maize to local crops (such as fingermillet, groundnut, beans and cassava), expan-sion of shifting cultivation and thus increaseddeforestation. Deforestation has had limitednegative environmental impact, however,mainly because the miombo woodlands innorthern Zambia are still abundant, the biodi-versity value is relatively low, local externalitiessuch as soil erosion and water contamination arenot yet disturbing, and other use and non-usevalues of the forest resources are limited. Hence,the opportunity cost of burning the forest is stillsmall, but Holden cautions that if populationgrowth continues and current policies are pur-sued, deforestation may become a serious envi-ronmental and economic problem.vi

H2. Poor people are agents of environmental degradation

This hypothesis is not about “putting the blameon the poor,” but to state that the rural poor areoften compelled to exploit marginal areas, such assteep hillsides, or derive resources from protectedareas. Compounded by the impact of populationgrowth, they often lack the incentives or means tointensify their production and are forced toexploit new, fragile lands. The urban poor unwill-ingly contribute to a different kind of environ-mental degradation, resulting in poor health,which can further reduce income opportunities.

World Bank (1992, 1995) elaborate on some ofthe links between poverty and environment. It isstated that a declining natural resource base,largely caused by poor people deprived of access

Box 7: Poverty and Deforestation

Mexico lost some 19.2 million ha of forestbetween 1980 and 1990. Empirical evidencefrom the country indicate that poverty is associ-ated with higher levels of deforestation, and thatthe poorer municipalities lost a greater propor-tion of local forest resources during this period.(Deininger and Minten, 1996).

In a two-period Cobb-Douglas productionfunction model, Deininger and Minten estimatedeterminants of deforestation through Tobit-regressions applied to eight different agro-cli-matic regions. The socio-economic data is basedon the 1991 Agricultural census and the 1990Population census, which give information onmunicipality level. The bio-physical data con-sists of information on land use, soil type andvegetation cover. This data are based on satelliteimages of 22,000 sample plots, each 100m.x100m. in size, complemented by extensiveground truthing.

The study shows that the massive forest lossprimarily is driven by smallholders’ need foragricultural land, and secondarily driven bycommercial interests. Regression analyses ofdeforestation rate yield positive, statistically sig-nificant coefficients for (a proxy variable of)poverty.

to other resources, exacerbates the conditions ofthe poor by limiting their already restricted pro-duction possibilities. This applies in particular torural water, soils and energy. One of the basicforces behind the vicious circle between povertyand environment is thus suggested to be thatpoverty limits people’s options and inducesthem to deplete resources faster than is compati-ble with long-term sustainability. Hence the poorthemselves will aggravate the process of envi-ronmental degradation.

Dasgupta (1993) describes how closely depen-dent poor people are on their surrounding envi-ronmental resource base for their livelihood, andhow poverty can be a driving force to environ-mental degradation. Based on theory and someempirical evidence he argues that poverty is botha cause and effect of resource degradation or lackof access to resources, including natural capital.To exemplify the above arguments he describeshow poor nomadic dryland herdsmen often areexcluded from formal credit, capital and insur-ance markets and are forced to invest their capi-tal in cattle, resulting in non-sustainable herdsizes and overgrazing.

Page 10: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

8

Plausible explanations to the hypothesis thatthe poor are agents of environmental degrada-tion are that (i) poor people have shorter timehorizon and (ii) higher risk-aversion and a pro-pensity to use implicit, higher discount rates,which leads us to specify the following sub-hypothesis:vii

H2a: Poor people have shorter time horizons, whichexacerbates environmental degradation. Allegedly,poverty often results in myopic production andconsumption decisions, and precludes longerterm investments in preservation and accumula-tion of natural capital (Holden et. al., 1996;Prakash, 1997). Consequently, poor people’s lim-ited economic options and low savings ratescause them to deplete and degrade their immedi-ate environment (soils, forest, fisheries), andimpose externalities on future generations.

However, Ostrom (1990), Rhoades (1988),Prakash (1997), Jodha (1986), and Bromley (1992)support the alternative hypothesis by suggestingthat poverty does not necessarily imply shorttime horizons and environmental degradation.They argue that locally designed and governedresource management institutions provide resil-ience towards risks and exogenous shocks, andfacilitate sustainable use over time. Accordingly,poor people do not inherently have relativelyshorter time-horizons. They are forced to dimin-ish their time horizon only when subject to exter-nal shocks or extreme events, it is argued.Prakash (1997, p. 7) summarizes: “…it is not shorttime-horizons so much as exogenous factors and mis-guided policy and administrative mechanisms that areprimarily responsible for the environmental degrada-tion attributed to the poor.”

Ostrom observes that neither the state nor themarket has been uniformly successful inenabling individuals to sustain long-term, pro-ductive use of natural resource systems in manylocations. Instead, communities of individualshave relied on institutions resembling neither thestate nor the market to govern resource systemswith considerable degrees of success over longperiods of time. Long-time neighbors, driven bymaintaining their reputation as reliable membersof the community and recognizing the need forsustained future resource availability, expect alsotheir offspring to be subject similar conditions.Hence, people have developed, independent ofthe market and the State, sustainable CPR man-agement institutions, which facilitate access toessential resources across time.

Box 8: Time Horizon and the Environment

Ostrom (1990) shows how poor people indeedcan utilize fragile ecosystems and common-poolresources sustainably over long time periods,even centuries in some cases, if some specificconditions or, in her terminology, “design princi-ples” are fulfilled. Her global review draws onevidence from cases such as communally man-aged high mountain meadows and forests inSwitzerland and Japan, basin water resources insouth-western USA, and irrigation-waterschemes in Spain and the Philippines.

Based on the empirical survey, the conditionsshe identifies as essential for long-term, sustain-able management of common pool resources(CPRs) are: First, the geographical boundaries ofthe CPR must be clearly defined. Second, appro-priation of CPRs, provision rules for CPRs andthe local socio-economic and environmentalconditions must be congruent and coherent.Third, consensus-like collective-choice arrange-ments for managing the CPRs must exist; inother words, most individuals who are affectedby the operational rules can participate in modi-fying them. Fourth, adequate monitoring of theuse of the resource must be developed and func-tion over time, i.e. monitors who actively auditCPRs and the appropriators are accountable tothe appropriators or are the appropriators. Fifth,graduated sanctions must be imposed on thoseviolating the rules. The sanctions are preferablyassessed by other appropriators, by officialsaccountable to the appropriators, or both. Sixth,cost-efficient conflict-resolution mechanisms(e.g. low-cost local courts) must be developedand utilized. Seventh, stakeholders’ rights toorganize themselves in CPR-managementschemes must obtain (at least minimal) recogni-tion by the Government. Eighth, based on thesubsidiarity principle, the above design princi-ples should be coherently tied together locally,regionally and nationally, and implemented (in“nested enterprises”) at the lowest appropriatelevel of decision making.

In conclusion on this point, we can observethat poor people, under certain conditions, enterinto activities of a long-term, sustainable nature.Again, we are led to search behind the hypothe-sis to explain particular behavior, and Ostrom’s“design principles” point in a very interestingand plausible direction.

H2b: Poverty increases risk-aversion and discountrates, aggravating environmental pressure. It is often

Page 11: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

9

assumed that poorer people have higher dis-count rates than richer people. For example, theWorld Bank’s Forestry Policy (1991, p. 11) citeshigh private discount rates, especially amongpoor people who depends on the forests, as adriving force behind deforestation.

Pearce and Warford (1993) identify a viciouscircle between poverty, high discount rates andenvironmental degradation by arguing that:“High discount rates are one cause of environmentaldegradation because they encourage individuals to optfor short-term measures that satisfy immediate needsor wants and to ignore more environmentally appro-priate practices such as planting trees. In turn, thisenvironmental degradation leads to the poverty thatcauses high discount rates” (p. 72). They also arguethat poverty-induced high discount rates notonly delay pay-offs and prevent investments inphysical and natural capital, but also discourageinvestments in human-capital such as children’sschooling. This would be particularly pertinentwhere mortality is high and prospects for formalemployment limited. While higher discountrates among the poor could be explained by sim-ple lack of resources which creates an urgentneed for immediate gains, there is also the factthat poor people often have to borrow in infor-mal, high-interest rate markets, as documentedby Leach and Mearns (1991).

Rhoades (1988) describes how poor farmersrespond to enhanced levels of risk of crop failureby diversifying land allocation and scatteringparcels over a larger area in consent with otherfarmers. By cultivating lands of different soiltypes, quality and altitude, they manage toreduce their risks from pest or climate variabilityin a cost-effective way.

These results have important policy implica-tions. For instance, farmers with differing levelsof wealth would have different willingness andability to undertake long-term investments. Forinstance, a flat (uniform) subsidy of e.g. soil con-servation to individual farmers would inducesome (presumably the rich) to act on the incen-tive whereas others (the poor) would fail to act,due mainly to poor people’s lower valuation offuture benefits. Although poor people often havelower opportunity costs, and thus would beexpected to invest in labor-intensive activities,their limited ability to await distant, uncertainbenefits—driven by high discount rates—wouldcounteract such behavior.

Even if it is plausible that poorer people havehigher discount rates, the problem remains thatthis would deter them not only from conserva-tion investments, but also from investments witha detrimental environmental impact. The sameargument can be advanced with regard to risk-aversion; it deters people from behavior that

Box 9: Poverty, Risk-aversionand Discount Rate

In a study of 240 households in the semi-arid, tropical rural areas of India, Binswanger (1980) uses anexperimental, sequential gambling approach with real pay-offs to identify attitudes toward risk. The house-holds in the sample are predominantly poor, but with considerable variation. He finds that relatively poorerpeople tend to be slightly more risk-averse. Although the estimated coefficients are largely consistent for thepoverty variables (salary, assets and net transfers) across all sub-sets (villages) of respondents, the results arein several instances not statistically significant. The study does not extend to capture environmental impactsof differing risk aversion at different poverty levels. Without explicitly translating his findings into implica-tions on discount rate, Binswanger (1982) summarizes in a discussion paper based on broader empirical evi-dence: “Farmers in developing countries are almost universally risk averse when confronted with prospectswith significant outcomes.“ and …“every local measure of risk aversion on a utility function would differaccording to wealth unless very restrictive utility functions are chosen.” [p. 392].

Based on an empirical assessment of farmers’ discount rates in Costa Rica and a review of 14 other empiri-cal studies, Cuesta et. al. (1997) conclude that “[T]here is some evidence of declining discount rates withincreasing income, time frame, and size of investment” (p. 3). They show that several analytical methods canbeen used to measure individuals’ real rate of time preference: e.g. experimental games-approaches usingbinary choice, actual asset-choice models based on loans and land transactions, utility maximization modelsreflecting valuation of inter-temporal cost-benefit streams, and Contingent Valuation (CV) using willingness-to-pay (WTP).

In their study they apply CV and asset-choice models to reveal the real discount rate among 292 CostaRican small- and large-scale farmers. When faced with questions on past and expected price changes, andtheir WTP for certain farm technology, 95% of the farmers show real discount rates in an interval from 15.1%to 21.9%. The results show a negative relationship between income and real discount rate.

Page 12: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

10

could be both environmentally benign, or envi-ronmentally detrimental. While the tendency toa lower investment level with higher interestrates is ambiguous in terms of environmentalimpacts, we can postulate (cf. Pearce, et al. 1990)that higher interest rates makes it rational:

(i) to more quickly exploit exhaustibleresources (e.g. mineral deposits), as movingincome forward in time is more importantthe higher the discount rate, and

(ii) to maintain a smaller stock of renewableresources (e.g. timber, soil organic matter),as the relative return of these (generally)decline with size and the opportunity cost ishigher the higher the discount rate.

While sometimes tempered by the increasedcapital cost in a high interest rate economy, theseforces do point in the direction of higher envi-ronmental pressure. When capital costs are low,the incentive would be for poor people toquickly exploit what is immediately available.

H3. Higher incomes increase some environmental pressure

A feature of the H2 hypothesis above is that pov-erty is assumed to increase pressure on local nat-ural resources. But this observation immediatelyinvites the counter-hypothesis that high incomeearners tend to put relatively more stress on thenational and global environment, e.g. emissionof greenhouse gases, ozone-depleting CFCs, etc.This brings us to H3, which is not merely thecounter-hypothesis of H2, but an argument aboutthe relationship between environmental degra-dation in poor versus rich economies. Hence, thedebate is much more macro-oriented in this case.

Examples when higher incomes at some levelsmay increase environmental pressure include airpollution from a larger pool of motor vehicles,waste generation from greater consumption ingeneral, and carbon emission from increased useof fossil fuels.

Some of these results are corroborated byWorld Development Report (World Bank, 1992),which presents positive exponential relation-ships between per capita income, and CO2 emis-sions and municipal waste per capita, respec-tively. However, emission of some pollutants(notably sulfur dioxide) initially go up and thendecrease with rising incomes. This bell-shapedpattern of increasing followed by decreasingenvironmental impact with rising income is oftencalled the “Environmental Kuznets-curve”.viii

Box 10: High Incomeand High Levels of Pollution

By using a large cross-national data set, basedon 95 indicators, Easterly (1997) attempts toanswer the question: will rising income overtime for a given country translate into increasingquality of life? Data was collected for the years1960, 1970, 1980 and 1990. The methodology isbased on linear or non-linear econometric esti-mation of the pooled data, where each indicatoris regressed against the logarithm of the per cap-ita income. Environment is one of the indicators.Easterly identifies several strongly positive rela-tionships between per capita income and emis-sion of some pollutants, for example CO2, NO2and SO2 in tons per capita, and wastepaper pro-duction in tons per 1000 inhabitants.

Shafik and Bandyopadhyay (ibid., p. 11) iden-tify, based on cross-country regression analysesfrom the 1980s, empirical evidence of an environ-mental Kuznets-curve for urban concentrationsof sulfur dioxide (SO2). Initially, the SO2 levelsamount to less than 10 micro grams per m3 of airat per capita income-levels around US$100. Theythen increase exponentially with income andpeak at 50 micro grams at US$2000 per capita,and then decline dramatically as incomes con-tinue to increase to again achieve very low SO2levels, but only at per capita incomes aroundUS$20,000-30,000.

In conclusion, it should however be noted thatin cases where environmental Kuznets curves doexist, they may very well be influenced by poli-cies, and should not be taken as an excuse for alaissez-faire attitude. It is not a given that one“must wait” for a certain income level before tak-ing measures to mitigate environmental loss.

Furthermore, despite real decline in emissionor effluent levels, environmental pressure is stillpositive and may be cumulative. This may havea lagged but irreversible impact on flora, faunaand ecosystem functions, for example in terms ofspecies loss. Therefore, flow indicators of envi-ronmental pressure are not sufficient in diagnos-ing the level of environmental degradation.

H4. Incomplete property rights reinforce the vicious poverty-environment circle

The rural poor are normally the ones with leastsecure rights to their assets, and are often com-pelled to exploit open access resources for sur-

Page 13: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

11

vival. The World Bank’s Forest Policy (1991, p. 11)specifically cites “weak property rights in manyforest and wooded areas” as a driving forcebehind deforestation. In urban areas, the poor—commonly squatters and migrants—often lacktenure over their land and homestead. Poor pro-vision of public infrastructure investments insewage, garbage collection and safe water supplyare at times justified on grounds of the illegalnature of (urban) settlements. Incomplete prop-erty rights, compounded by the lack of publicinvestment and poverty reduce the individual’sincentive for, and capacity to engage in, localenvironmental management. Tangible effects ofthese conditions in urban areas include poorerhealth, in particular increased incidence of intes-tinal infections and other communicable diseases.

In summary, there are studies that support thehypothesis that tenure security (perceived ratherthan formal) is correlated with the quality ofenvironmental management. A cautionary noteis in order when drawing the policy conclusionsfrom this evidence. The case described belowbrings out the lesson that merely privatizing therights, which is sometimes advocated by the“tragedy of the commons” school (Hardin, 1968)in the name of environmental protection, can bea counter-productive strategy.

There are alternatives to privatization thatdeserve consideration. Ostrom (1990) reviewshundreds of robust schemes, in which predomi-nantly poor communities have established self-governing systems to manage Common Pool

Resources (CPRs) such as fisheries, grazinglands, fresh-water supplies and village forests. Inmost cases the schemes have sustained change,without involvement of the government or mar-ket transactions, over decades or even centuries.Based on the survey, the eight design principlesshe identifies which facilitate sustainable man-agement of common pool resources are:(i) clearly defined property boundaries, (ii) con-gruence between appropriation of the CPRs,their provision rules and the local conditions,(iii) consensus-like collective-choice arrange-ments for using the CPRs, (iv) adequate monitor-ing, (v) graduated sanctions of violators,(vi) conflict-resolution mechanisms, (vii) at leastminimal recognition by the government of stake-holders’ rights to organize themselves in CPRmanagement, and (viii) nested enterprises (i.e.principles (i)–(vii) coherently implementedlocally, nationally or regionally).

H5. Population pressure exacerbates both poverty and environmental degradation

It is often asserted that population growth orhigh population density impacts negatively onthe environment, and this, in turn, exacerbatespoverty. Most of SSA experiences unsurpassedrates of population growth, and there is a crucialnexus of interaction between population growth,poverty and environmental degradation (Cleaverand Schreiber, 1994). But the actual, location-spe-cific links can vary.

Box 11: Rising Income and Afforestation in Peninsular Malaysia

Between 1966 and 1981, Peninsular Malaysia lost about 236,000 hectares of forest each year and its total for-est area fell from 9.65 to 6.82 million hectares. Rubber and oil palm plantations replaced much of the forestlost. However, by the late 1980s the rate of conversion slowed, as industrialization and urbanization causedthe rural labor market to tighten and agricultural returns to fall. The area in agriculture grew 520,000 hectaresin the seven years between 1974 and 1981, but only 160,000 hectares in the nine years that followed.

Based on a regression analysis of the region’s 65 districts, Vincent and Ali (1998) found that deforestationrates increased as per capita incomes rose until districts reached an average income of 1,100 Malaysian Ring-git, after which they fell sharply. By 1987, practically all of Peninsular Malaysia’s districts had income levelshigher than that. Not only did deforestation rates fall, but farmers also left significant areas ’idle’ and allowedthem to begin to revert to secondary forest. As rural youth moved to the cities to obtain manufacturing andpublic sector jobs and the farm population aged, farmers apparently decided to take more marginal farmlands out of production.

Using a global pooled cross-section and time-series data set between 1961–88, Cropper and Griffiths (1994)identify a similar inverted U-relationship between deforestation rates and income in Africa and Latin Amer-ica. The Kuznets curve’s theoretically estimated turning point occurs at a per capita income of US$4,760 forAfrica, and US$5,420 for Latin America. Since these incomes are rarely obtained throughout most of theseregions (i.e. most of the observations occur to the left of the curve’s global maximum), the deforestation curveis currently leveling off as income increases. The same results could not be obtained for Asia, due mainly tothe region’s massive effort at afforestation and the data set’s blunt definition of forest (no distinction betweenforest plantations and natural forests), the authors conclude.

Page 14: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

12

Box 12: Property Rights and the Environment

Saxena (1988) shows in a detailed study offorests with different property rights in UttarPradesh, India, how tree cover had degraded to10% on forest lands owned by the RevenueDepartment, 50% in forests owned by the ForestDepartment, and 70% in forests owned andmanaged by local communities and village for-est councils. The study concludes that the levelof effective enforcement of property rights wascrucial in explaining the level of degradation.

Hoy and Jimenez (1996) analyze the impact ofincomplete property rights on urban environ-ments in Indonesia. Given variable propertyrights, they estimate in a probit model determi-nants to the probability that households invest inlocal public goods, specifically the households’propensity to purchase garbage collection ser-vices. Among other results they “…find strongsupport for the hypothesis that reduced tenuresecurity significantly reduces the level of localpublic goods”, and that “…going from squatter tomoderate [tenure] security increases the probabil-ity of garbage collection by 32%, while going fromsquatter to high security raises the probability by44%” (p. 16). They also report an independent, sta-tistically significant positive relationship betweenhousehold income and the probability that house-holds purchase garbage collection services.

Southgate, Sierra and Brown (1989) empiri-cally estimate the causes of tropical deforestationin Ecuador. Based on data from eastern Ecua-dor’s twenty cantons and statistical OrdinaryLeast Squares (OLS)-regressions to explain defor-estation, they come to the conclusion that it isnegatively correlated with land tenure security.

There are several driving forces behind thepopulation-poverty-environment nexus. Al-though many poor people are old people or sin-gle mothers, many poor households are poorbecause they are large, and large because theyare poor. Poor parents tend to produce manychildren to secure income at old age, and pro-vide labor to collect essential goods such aswater, firewood and fodder. Children also playan important role in attending grazing animals,do other household chores and earn incomes bye.g. selling crops or other household produce.Further, poorer households are large due to lackof knowledge or means to sufficiently protectthemselves against unwanted pregnancies.Family size is also determined by social normsand cultural traditions. In some societies adultsare also expected to have many children as asign of wealth or fertility, or both.

Box 13: Privatization of Common Property Resources in India

Jodha (1986) shows that Common PropertyResources (CPRs) provide a significant contribu-tion towards employment and income genera-tion for the rural poor in India. Based on datafrom 80 villages in 21 districts in dry regions ofseven states in India, he shows that the depen-dence of richer households on CPRs is muchless. Further, the area of CPRs has decreaseddramatically during the last three decades, rang-ing between 26–63% in the studied districts.

Privatization of CPRs was introduced to sup-port the poor, but the result was the reverse: 49–86% of the privatized CPR areas ended up inhands of non-poor, and CPRs held by poor wereeventually sold to richer people to facilitateshort-term survival. Jodha concludes: “Thus therural poor collectively lost a significant part ofthe source of their sustenance through thedecline of CPRs. This loss does not seem to becompensated by privatized CPR lands given to(or retained by) them. The situation calls forgreater attention to CPRs as a part of the anti-poverty strategy” (Ibid., p. 1169).

Mink (1993), for instance, argues how thepoor’s living environment—characterized bylow quality and access to water—poor sanitationand polluted in-door air, and production prac-tices impact negatively on themselves and oth-ers. It is among others manifested in loweredhousehold productivity, which further exacer-bates the environmental degradation and pro-vides incentives for households to raise largefamilies. This would further contribute to pau-perism in an adverse, dynamic pattern. Minkmakes the case that alleviating poverty is a win-win strategy with respect to population growth,the economy and the environment.

Lacking the means to move to a better envi-ronment, large households suffer from their own(and others’) resource degradation. The mutualinterdependence between these factors sets off anegative spiral: the poorer a household is, themore children are needed to secure current andfuture livelihood. The larger the family is, themore resources it needs. The higher the resourcedemand, the larger the pressure on the scarce orfragile surrounding natural-resource base. Themore degraded or depleted the environment, themore children it has to have to secure old ageand provide essential goods and services. The

Page 15: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

13

more time spent on collection, less time is avail-able for education and human-resource develop-ment. Less time for education will perpetuatepoverty into next generation.

Boserup (1965, 1986), however, has become theprincipal representative of the contesting view.She argues that resource scarcity and populationgrowth jointly induce technological change,innovation and intensification, which does notnecessarily impact negatively on the environ-ment. Hence, poverty and population growthbecome positive agents of change in a dynamicinterplay, which often results in introduction ofmore efficient production techniques.

In fact, empirical studies of the population-poverty-environment links indicate validity ofeach of the contesting views, as shown in box14.ix Hence, it might very well be, as argued byHeath and Binswanger (1996), that the final out-come can go either way and is essentially drivenby policy; i.e. whether growing population pres-sures induce positive or negative environmentalchange is ultimately and fundamentally drivenby the overall policy framework.

In a summary view, Prakash (1997) who exem-plifies Boserup’s school of thought, states thatbased on empirical studies in Kenya (Tiffen et.al., 1993; Bradley, 1991; Ferguson-Bison, 1992)and the Himalayas (Ives and Messerli, 1989),…”there is no fundamental relationship between

population density and environmental degrada-tion. The assumption that high population den-sity will necessarily cause greater anthropogenicdegradation is exceptionally difficult to justifygiven the available evidence.” [p. 12].

Based on the above arguments and empiricalevidence, it seems clear that it is not possible, apriori, to say that population growth or highdensity will result in environmental degradation.Clearly, population growth plays a crucial role indetermining the quality and stock of natural cap-ital, but in many instances it is not the root causeof environmental degradation. Rather thanembarking on massive population-control pro-grams, underlying policy and market failuresshould be scrutinized and corrected first andforemost. Good economic policies, secure tenurerights, political stability and a dynamic economycan all contribute to alleviate the pressures frompopulation. Again, this reinforces the comple-mentarity between different types of operations.

Much of this complementarity appears obvi-ous: market-oriented reforms that stimulateurban job growth can attract surplus labor out ofa sensitive forest zone, and so forth. However,one type of complementarity that has been givenlittle notice is one between community-basedpopulation control and environmental manage-ment (CBPE) activities. The interesting researchby Population Plan International (Engelman,

Box 14: Population and the Environment

Pearce and Warford (1993) argue that there is strong evidence of negative environmental impacts ofincreasing populations. They exemplify by referring to the strong negative relationship identified betweenforest coverage and population density in 72 tropical countries.

Cropper and Griffiths (1994) state that: “…there is no question that population growth contributes to envi-ronmental degradation…” (p. 250). They confirm this by estimating statistically the impact of increasing pop-ulation pressure (defined as the rural population density), population growth rate and increased per-capitaincome on deforestation, respectively. They use data from 64 developing countries between 1961–1988. Theirresults indicate that population pressure as well as population growth are generally positively correlatedwith deforestation. In Africa, for instance, the deforestation rate would increase 0.33% as population-densityincreases with one person per 10 hectares. These effects are to some extent offset by increasing GDP andGDP/capita.

Filmer and Pritchett (1997) assess the existence of a vicious circle between environmental degradation andfertility. Based on data from Pakistan, they conclude that (i) firewood availability seems to be negatively cor-related with fertility, and (ii) households living far from firewood have more children. Filmer and Pritchettalso present a model of population-forest cover interaction. It identifies distinct stages (or phases) across time,in which population and forest cover alternately correlate positively or negatively depending on the popula-tion growth. They cautiously conclude: “A claim that these results confirm the existence of a vicious circlebetween environmental degradation and demand for children is clearly far too strong. The results, however,are supportive of the notion that there is a stage in time in the relationship between environmental degrada-tion, fertility, and land ownership rights during which children are in relatively high demand” (p. 31).

Page 16: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

14

1998) provides a synthesis of the experience sofar. From a population perspective, the experi-ence of several NGOs suggest that this approachto linking conservation and reproductive healthactivities, at the request of community members,can reduce costs for family planning servicedelivery in remote areas by taking advantage ofpersonnel and networks already developed forconservation work. From the environmental per-spective, women who manage the timing ofchildbearing may be better able to manage com-peting tasks, including the local naturalresources, Engelman argues.

Concluding Note

We close this section by noting that the literatureis richer in general assertions than in rigorous

empirical evidence. Where evidence is available,it often points in the direction of multi-causalchains, where the influence of a single factor(tenure security, population growth etc.) is verydifficult to ascertain. Nevertheless, we have gonebeyond the simplified statements in our hypoth-eses and discovered a diverse set of conditionsthat will increase the probabilities of support orrejection of the hypothesis at hand. While, “itdepends” is not a very forceful conclusion, it is auseful one, if we know something about “what itdepends on.”

We do conclude that “the poor as victims”hypothesis of environmental degradation appearsquite plausible, and that it does open up anagenda of potential win-win operations that com-bine poverty alleviation with environmental man-agement measures.

Page 17: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

15

Poverty is a frequently discussed topic in CASs.However, the sample of 34 CASs reviewed inEkbom and Bojö (1997) shows that it is rather sel-dom analyzed jointly with environmental degra-dation. Poverty and environment are usuallytreated in separate sections, specifying separateactivities, use separate evaluation criteria andindicators, and refer to different analytical back-ground documents: Poverty Assessments andLiving Standard Surveys address poverty, andNational and Local Environmental Action Plansand Country Environmental Strategy papersaddress the environment.

There are however some good examples ofjoint analysis. Below we present some of themfrom existing CASs and PAs. The structure fol-lows the hypotheses presented in section 2. Morefrequent analyses of this kind would greatlyenhance the understanding and policy formula-tion of the inter-related problems of poverty andenvironment.

H1. Poor people are the main victims of a bad environment

The Brazil CAS capture the links between pov-erty and environment aptly: “Since the poor tendto reside in the most polluted neighborhoods, they alsosuffer most from health damages and reduced qualityof life caused by pollution” (p. 7). “About 20 millionBrazilians lack safe drinking water and 40 millionhave inadequate sanitation services. These are twoservices where expansion of service is closely con-nected to improving living standards and reducing

poverty, and where weaknesses have led to high envi-ronmental pollution and increasing costs in main-taining health standards in drinking water. Onlyabout 20 percent of collected sewage is treated. Fur-thermore, these weaknesses disproportionately affectthe poor. About 92 percent of the urban populationwithout public sewerage services are poor” (p. 55).

The Senegal Poverty Assessment elaborateson several of the hypotheses, among them theobservation that the poor occupy unhealthy sur-roundings: “In spite of better standards of living inurban areas on average, a substantial number of poorlive in the “quartiers flottantes” or squatter area inperi-urban Dakar. Dakar serves as a magnet for thehandicapped, orphans, and destitute who seek ser-vices, special care, or income from begging. Increasingrates of rural to urban migration (and migration fromneighboring countries) appear to contribute to theproblems of these squatter neighborhoods which havepoor or nonexistent sanitation, often house up to 8people in a room measuring 1.5 to 2 square meters,lack water or electricity, and are characterized byhousing made of discarded metal or cardboard. Suchenvironments become breeding grounds for increasesin disease” (p. 13).

The issue of environmental refugees, whereenvironmental stress force the poorest to tempo-rarily or permanently leave their homestead toseek survival elsewhere, is addressed in somePoverty Assessments. The Kenya PA exemplifiesby stating that: “emigration from the better endowedhighlands to semi-arid districts, such as Machakos,Kitui and Kajiado, in search of land, has been a majorphenomenon in Kenya in the last two decades or so.

Synthesizing Poverty and Environment in CASs

3

Page 18: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

16

Without this population movement, the incidence ofpoverty in the better endowed areas would have prob-ably been higher. However, this migration in search ofland has had the effect of displacing nomadic tribeswho historically used the land and watering holes fortheir cattle” (p. 19).

The Niger PA states that “Migration is wide-spread: it is a survival strategy for individuals andhouseholds in difficulty, a relief mechanism for house-holds and communities and a possibility of enrich-ment—but also of impoverishment; the poor migrateto look for food and work within Niger or to a neigh-boring country (usually Nigeria), often returning tothe village during the period of cultivation. Some“come back only with an illness”, AIDS or venerealdisease. Migration of an entire family is a sign ofgreat distress. These migrants attach themselves tourban relatives and increase the masses of unem-ployed” (p. 30).

On the argument that governmental policiescreate or reinforce a vicious circle of poverty-environment interaction with specifically severeimpact on poor people, the Senegal PovertyAssessment describes that: “Poor incentives in themarket for charcoal only serve to accelerate erosion ofsoil and forests. …charcoal prices are not set to reflectthe full economic cost, and the permits are grantedaccording to the amount of charcoal produced ratherthan the number of trees cut thus providing no incen-tive to manufacture the charcoal more efficiently.….the revenues from the licensing system are con-trolled by the Forestry Service, and not by the localpopulation. Local participation is thus essentially lim-ited to serving as labor for cutting trees (a commonactivity of the poor). Thus rural communities have lit-tle incentive to protect this resource, and substantialincentive to cultivate land even if not optimal for thesoil, simply to prevent the land from being harvestedby an outsider. This, in combination with nationalenergy policies that keep tariffs on alternatives tocharcoal such as petroleum high (largely to reap taxrevenue), also serve to accelerate deforestation rates”(p. 29–30).

H2. The poor are agents of environmental degradation

The Brazil CAS states: “…the increasing demand ofgrowing urban population for sanitation and trans-port services remains unsatisfied, thereby generatinga cycle of urban pollution, health problems, and lowerquality of life for the population at large” (p. 7).

Implicitly addressing inequality as a trigger-ing factor to environmental degradation caused

by poor people, the Philippines CAS describeshow the upland areas are rapidly being popu-lated due to lowland poverty and marginaliza-tion of small-scale farmers. The combination ofpoverty-driven lowland-to-upland migration,inadequate farming techniques and extensivedeforestation, cause detrimental on-site anddown-stream effects in terms of soil erosion,reducing agricultural productivity, and siltationof vital infrastructure such as irrigation, hydro-electric, and municipal water installations.

The Madagascar CAS poses yet another goodexample, and stresses the need to address thecomplex interactions between poverty, unem-ployment, high population growth and environ-mental degradation through an integrated eco-nomic development strategy. It emphasizesspecifically the issue of inequality by stating that“poverty and population growth are the principalcauses of environmental damage, that environmentaldegradation leads to lower crop yields and infrastruc-ture deterioration, and that rapid economic growth isessential to break this vicious circle”, but that ….”thestructure of growth is as important to ensure thateconomic benefits are distributed equitably, and thatdevelopment must foster the use of the most abundantresource of the poor-labor” (p. 7–8).

Few, if any, CASs and PAs elaborate on theissue whether poor people have shorter timehorizons, are risk averse or have higher dis-count rates, and how that would link to resourceuse and environmental quality. Although the dis-cussion in the Senegal Poverty Assessment doesnot substantially address short- vs. long-terminvestments, it touches upon the poor’s con-strained time horizon by stating that: “…recentsurveys show that obtaining food and seeds are ofgreater concern to farmers….. These trends illustratethe current constraints faced by the rural poor—theneed to choose between long-term investment ininputs versus immediate necessities, as well as thedecline in cash income” (p. 29).

H3. Higher incomes increase some environmental pressure

Interestingly enough, we note that very fewCASs in our sample pay particular attention tothe impact of economic growth on the naturalresource base, pollution levels or the environ-mental sustainability of that growth in the longrun. Admittedly, this is not a serious issue insome of the world’s poorest countries, but in agrowing number of developing countries eco-

Page 19: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

17

nomic growth is major contributing factor to nat-ural resource depletion and pollution.

The Indonesia CASs (1995, 1997) pursue theissue of growth and environment, and providearguably the best examples: “Environmental qual-ity and sustainability are an integral part of Indone-sian government’s stated development concerns. Thegrowing attention to these issues in the Government’sdevelopment strategy reflects an increased awarenessof the costs and risks of the worsening environmentalconditions due to past growth, and the potential forcontinued environmental degradation in the future”(1995, p. 8). Further: “In spite of rapid growth …,Indonesia’s competitive position in low-skilled laborand resource intensive industries is now beingeroded…[due to] environmental degradation in areassuch as forestry and large-scale mining” (1997, p. 7)“[T]he negative externalities of rapid growth have tobe captured and mitigated through comprehensiveinstitutional and regulatory structures” (1997, p. 23).

It is explained that Indonesia’s historically laxpolicies on natural resource extraction, particu-larly in the forestry sector, facilitated growth, butalso caused a “first generation” of green environ-mental problems such as soil erosion. Thegrowth initiated significant socio-economic tran-sitions, including rural-urban migration andmassive industrialization, which facilitated sus-tained economic growth, but also gave rise to a“second generation” of new, primarily brownenvironmental problems: water contamination,solid and hazardous waste, urban and industrialair pollution, etc.

H4. Incomplete property rights reinforce the vicious poverty-environment circle

On the complex issue of property rights, theSenegal Poverty Assessment writes: “The currentincentive system governing land and natural resourceuse states that land not under cultivation can be“leased” by the state to outsiders or others, withoutnecessarily requiring permission from the local popu-lation. This practice only compounds the incentive tomaximize land use, and creates a disincentive toplanting forests, thus contributing to problems of soildegradation” (p. vi).

H5. Population pressure exacerbates both poverty and environmental degradation

The Senegal Poverty Assessment elaborates onhow poverty interacts, in a vicious circle, withenvironmental degradation and population

growth: “…In order to preserve the long-term natu-ral resource base (and income base) in the rural sector,progress is urgently needed in controlling populationpressure, and in implementing an incentive structureconducive to sound and locally-driven naturalresource management. The collision course betweenmanaging the meager resource base, providing forfood needs, and supporting a growing population isnow at a critical stage. As can be seen …decliningavailability of arable land lies at the heart of this colli-sion, and is being driven over the long-term by popu-lation growth, the increased demand for food produc-tion for an increasingly urbanized population, anddeclining rainfall patterns” (p. 29).

The Burkina Faso CAS asserts in many sec-tions that there is a vicious interaction betweenpopulation growth, poverty and environmentaldegradation, and that “regionally, there is a strongcorrelation between rainfall patterns, soil degrada-tion, and the incidence of poverty” (p. 3). It empha-sizes that environmental conservation and natu-ral resource management are critical to povertyalleviation and economic growth, and that manyactivities, detrimental to the environment (min-ing of agricultural and forest lands), are indeedpoverty driven.

Concluding Note

Even though several poverty assessments dealwith issues relating to environment, the focus isoften too narrow. To exemplify, the Senegal Pov-erty Assessment analyzes health issues verywell in a traditional sense. However, someaspects remain unexplained, for instance thelarge differences in health expenditures betweenurban and rural citizens in Senegal: “it would beworthwhile to examine through rapid qualitativeassessment why poor rural households spend so littleon health care compared to their urban counterparts(e.g. because of income constraints, because healthservices are simply not available, because of lowdemand for modern health care, or because of theavailability of low-priced generic drugs throughhealth posts…”(p. 36).

Here, as in many cases, the environmentaldimension of the issue is overlooked. While wedo not know the specific answer regarding Sene-gal, the importance of access to biologicalresources (“wild” or “environmental” goods),biological diversity and poor people’s depen-dence on, and use of, it for good health is notconsidered. The option many rural poor have of

Page 20: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

18

obtaining traditional medicines and many otheressential goods and services from local naturalresources, can provide an important additionalpiece in the puzzle of understanding poverty-environment links.

Our review shows that few CASs elaborate onthe poverty-environment links, and we havefound few examples of good PAs in this respect.As pointed out in many studies, there is anurgent need to enhance the understanding ofhow poor people depend on, interact with andutilize their local environment for survival. Forinstance, poor people’s survival mechanismsdeveloped in their inter-play with biologicaldiversity and common property resources areonly superficially understood.

As some of the empirical evidence corroboratesthe fact that poverty and environment are pro-foundly linked and do indeed impact on eachother through various means—it is also critical toidentify and systematically use appropriate indi-cators to enhance our knowledge in this realm.Ideally, these indicators should encompass bothpoverty and environment, and should capture themechanisms through which they are linked.

What might those indicators look like? Jodha(1991) has suggested a large set of indicators cov-ering major agro-ecological zones and the urbanenvironment, many of which are relevant alsofrom a poverty perspective. Similarly, the WorldBank-report Expanding the Measure of Wealth:Indicators of Sustainable Development (1997) sug-gests e.g. soil-related land quality indicators for

pressure, state and response, indicators of mate-rial flows, soil-nutrient balances as well as the-matic environmental indicators used by progres-sive governments. The 1998 World DevelopmentIndicators-report (World Bank, 1998a) and WorldResources 1998–99 by World Resources Institute(1998) present real data on some useful environ-mental indicators, which however are somewhatlimited due to lack of coverage and reliability.

One promising attempt (World Bank, 1998b) isthe joint project developed between the Bank,UNEP and regional institutions, where prelimi-nary indicators of environmental sustainabilityin Central America’s rural areas have been sug-gested. At present the indicators are preliminaryand the project is in a development stage. Theapproach, where pressure, state, impact andresponse have been used as points of departure,is however promising. Some of these and otherindicators are presented in Appendix 1.

To understand the interplay between the localenvironment and poverty, one would have to relatethe data gathered in a particular context to socio-economic data from the same area. This wouldallow us to answer important questions like:

• to what extent are different income categoriesaffected by natural resource degradation?

• to what extent are different income catego-ries affected by pollution?

The answers could then guide targeted effortsto mitigate environmental pressures that havethe greatest effects on the poorest people.

Page 21: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

19

Agarwal, Bina, 1997; Gender, Environment, andPoverty Interlinks: Regional Variations and Tempo-ral Shifts in Rural India, 1971–91, World Devel-opment, Vol. 25, No. 1, pp. 23–52, Elsevier Sci-ence Ltd, U.K.

Binswanger, Hans P., 1980; Attitudes toward Risk:Experimental Measurement in Rural India,pp. 395–407 in American Journal of Agricul-tural Economics, Vol. 62, No. 1

Binswanger, Hans P., 1982; Empirical EstimationAnd Use Of Risk Preferences: Discussion”,pp. 391–393 in American Journal of Agricul-tural Economics, Vol. 64, No. 2

Binswanger, Hans P., 1989; Brazilian Policies thatEncourage Deforestation in Brazil, EnvironmentDepartment Working Paper No. 16, WorldBank. Washington D.C.

Bojö, Jan, Karl-Göran Mäler, and Lena Unemo,1992; Environment and Development: an Eco-nomic Approach, [2nd ed.] Kluwer AcademicPublishers, The Netherlands.

Bojö, Jan, 1997; Structural Adjustment and theEnvironment: A Review of Studies with Emphasison Sub-Saharan Africa in Forum for Develop-ment Studies [Ed. Olav Stokke], No. 1, 1997,Norwegian Institute of International Affairs,Flekkefjord.

Boserup, Ester, 1965; The Conditions of Agricul-tural Growth, Allen and Unwin, London.

Boserup, Ester, 1986; Shifts in the Determinants ofFertility in the Developing World: Environmental,

Technical, Economic and Cultural Factors in TheState of Population Theory (pp. 239–255) byColeman and Schofield [Eds.], Blackwell,Oxford.

Bradley, Phil, 1991; Woodfuel, Women and Woodlots(Volume 1), MacMillan Press Ltd., London.

Bromley, Daniel, 1992; Making the Commons Work:Theory, Practice and Policy, Institute for Contem-porary Studies Press, San Francisco.

Cavendish, William, 1997; The Complexity of theCommons: Environmental resource demands inRural Zimbabwe, mimeo [processed], Centre forthe Study of African Economies, Oxford Uni-versity, Oxford

Cropper M. and C. Griffiths, 1994; The Interactionof Population Growth and Environmental Quality,American Economic Review, Papers and Pro-ceedings Edition, vol. 84, no. 2, pp. 250–254.

Cuesta, Mauricio, Gerald Carlson, and ErnstLutz, 1997; An Empirical Assessment of Farmers’Discount Rates in Costa Rica, EnvironmentDepartment, World Bank. Washington D.C.

Dasgupta, Partha, 1995; Population, Poverty AndLocal Environment, Scientific American, 272(2),pp. 26–31.

Dasgupta, Partha, and Karl-Göran Mäler, 1994;Poverty, Institutions, and the Environmental-Resource Base, World Bank. Washington D.C.

Easterly, William, 1997; Life During Growth: a com-pendium of political, social and environmentalindicators of what gets better and what gets worse

References

Page 22: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

20

from low to high income, Working paper no. 17,Policy Research Department, World Bank.Washington D.C.

Ekbom, Anders, and Jan Bojö, 1997; Mainstream-ing Environment in Country Assistance Strategies,Discussion Paper No. 1, Environment Group,Africa Region, World Bank. Washington D.C.

Engelman, R., 1998; Plan & Conserve: A SourceBook on Linking Population and EnvironmentalServices in Communities. Population Plan Inter-national, Washington, D.C.

English J., Mary Tiffen, and Michael Mortimore,1994; Land Resource Management in MachakosDistrict, Kenya 1930–1990, World Bank. Wash-ington D.C.

Ferguson-Bison, D., 1992; Rational Land Manage-ment in the Face of Demographic Pressure: Obsta-cles and Opportunities for Rural Men and Women,Ambio 21 (1): 90–94.

Filmer, Deon, and Lant Pritchett, 1996; Environ-mental degradation and the Demand for Children:Searching for the Vicious circle, Working paperno. 12, Policy Research Department, WorldBank. Washington D.C.

Green, Cynthia P. [Ed.], 1993; Sustainable Develop-ment: Population and the Environment, Academyfor Educational Development, Washington D.C.

Hardin, Garrett, 1968; The Tragedy of the Com-mons, in Science, Vol. 162, pp: 1243–48.

Heath, John, and Hans Binswanger, 1996; NaturalResource Degradation Effects Of Poverty And Pop-ulation Growth Are Largely Policy Induced: TheCase Of Colombia in Journal of Environmentand Development Economics, Vol. 1: pp. 65–83.

Holden, Stein, Bekele Shiferaw, and Mette Wik,1996; Poverty, Market Imperfections, and TimePreferences: of Relevance for Environmental Pol-icy?, Discussion paper #D-26/1996, Depart-ment of Economics and Social Sciences, Agri-cultural University of Norway.

Holden, Stein T., 1997; Adjustment Policies, PeasantHousehold Resource Allocation and Deforestationin Northern Zambia: an Overview and some PolicyConclusions in Forum for Development Studies[Ed. Olav Stokke], No. 1, 1997, NorwegianInstitute of International Affairs, Flekkefjord.

Hoy, Michael, and Emmanuel Jimenez, 1996; TheImpact on the Urban Environment of Incomplete

Property Rights, Working paper no. 14, PolicyResearch Department, World Bank. Washing-ton D.C.

International Journal of Ecological Economics,1998; Special Issue: The ‘Environmental KuznetsCurve’ (Vol. 25, Nr. 2), International Society ofEcological Economics.

Ives, J., and B. Messerli, 1989; The HimalayanDilemma: Reconciling Development and Conserva-tion, Routledge/United Nations University,London.

Jodha, N.S., 1986; Common Property Resources andRural Poor in Dry Regions of India, Economic &Political Weekly, Vol. 21 (27): 1169–81

Journal of Environment and Development Eco-nomics, 1997; Special Issue: The ‘EnvironmentalKuznets Curve’ (Vol. 2, Issue 4), CambridgeUniversity Press, Cambridge, UK.

Kramer, R.A., N. Sharma, and M. Munasinghe,1995; Valuing Tropical Forests: Methodolgoy andCase Study of Madagascar, Environment PaperNo. 13, World Bank. Washington D.C.

Leach, Melissa, and Robin Mearns, 1991; Povertyand Environment in Developing Countries: AnOverview Study. Insitute of Development Stud-ies, Sussex, UK. Processed.

Lopez, Ramon, 1997; Where Development Can orCannot Go—The Role of Poverty and Environ-ment, World Bank, Washington D.C.

Mahar, Dennis, 1988; Government Policies andDeforestation in Brazil’s Amazon Region, Envi-ronment Department Working Paper No. 7,World Bank. Washington D.C.

Mink, S., 1993; Poverty, Population and the Envi-ronment, Discussion paper no. 189, WorldBank, Washington D.C.

Munasinghe, M., and W. Cruz, 1995. Economy-wide Policies and the Environment, Lessons fromExperience, Environment paper No. 9, WorldBank. Washington D.C.

Myers, Norman, and Jennifer Kent, 1995; Environ-mental Exodus—An Emergent Crisis in the GlobalArena, Climate Institute, Washington D.C.

Ostrom, Elinor, 1990; Governing the Commons: theEvolution of Institutions for Collective Actions,Cambridge University Press, New York.

Pearce, David, E. Barbier, and A. Markandya, 1990;Sustainable Development: Economics and Environ-ment in the Third World. Edward Elgar, London.

Page 23: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

21

Pearce, David W., and Jeremy J. Warford, 1993;World Without End—Economics, Environmentand Sustainable Development, Oxford UniversityPress, New York

Prakash, Sanjev, 1997; Poverty and EnvironmentLinkages in Mountains and Uplands: Reflectionson the “Poverty Trap” thesis, CREED Workingpaper Series No 12, IIED, London.

Ravallion, Martin, 1992; Poverty Comparisons: Aguide to Concepts and Methods, Living StandardsMeasurement Study Working paper, No 88,Poverty Analysis and Policy Division, WorldBank. Washington D.C.

Ravallion, Martin, 1998; Poverty Lines in Theoryand Practice, Living Standards MeasurementStudy Working paper, No 133, DevelopmentResearch Group, Development EconomicsDepartment, World Bank. Washington D.C.

Reed, David, [Ed.], 1992; Structural Adjustmentand the Environment, Earthscan PublicationsLtd., London.

Reed, David, [Ed.], 1996; Structural Adjustment,the Environment, and Sustainable Development,Earthscan Publications Ltd., London.

Repetto, Robert, and M. Gillis [Eds.], 1988; PublicPolicies and the Misuse of Forest Resources, Cam-bridge University Press.

Rhoades, Robert, 1988; Thinking Like a Mountain,Newsletter of the Information Centre for LowExternal Input Agriculture, 4(1): 3–5, Leusden,The Netherlands.

Saxena, N.C., 1988; Social Forestry in U.P. Hills,International Centre for Integrated MountainDevelopment, Kathmandu.

Sida, 1991; Poverty, Environment and Develop-ment—Proposals for Action, Stockholm

Segnestam, Mats, 1996; Poverty and Environment,Task force on Poverty Reduction: Workingpaper 10, Sida, Stockholm

Songsore, Jacob, and Gordon McGranahan, 1993;Environment, Wealth and Health: Towards an

analysis of intra-urban differentials within theGreater Accra Metropolitan Area, Ghana, Envi-ronment and Urbanization, 5(2):10–34.

Southgate, Douglas, Rodrigo Sierra, andLawrence Brown, 1989; The Causes of TropicalDeforestation in Ecuador: A Statistical Analysis,LEEC Paper 89-09, IIED/UCL London Envi-ronmental Economics Centre.

Tiffen, Mary, Michael Mortimore, and FrancisGichuki, 1994; More People, Less Erosion, Envi-ronmental Recovery in Kenya, John Wiley andSons, New York.

Vincent, Jeffrey, and Rozali Mohamed Ali, 1998;Environment and Development in a Resource-Rich Economy, Malaysia Under the New Eco-nomic Policy, Harvard Institute for Interna-tional Development.

World Bank, 1991; The Forest Sector: A World BankPolicy Paper. Washington, D.C.

World Bank, 1992; World Development Report1992—Development and the Environment, OxfordUniversity Press, New York.

World Bank, 1994; Reducing Poverty in SouthAfrica: Options for Equitable and SustainableGrowth, Southern Africa Department, Wash-ington D.C.

World Bank, 1996; Toward Environmentally Sus-tainable Development in Sub-Saharan Africa: AWorld Bank Agenda, Africa Region, TechnicalDepartment, Washington D.C.

World Bank, 1997; Expanding the Measure ofWealth: Indicators of Sustainable Development,ESD Series No. 17, Washington D.C.

World Bank, 1998a; 1998 World Development Indi-cators, Washington D.C.

World Bank, 1998b; Project Summary: Indicators ofRural Sustainability: An Outlook for CentralAmerica (processed), Washington D.C.

World Resources Institute, 1998; World Resources1998–99, Oxford University Press, New York.

Page 24: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

22

Variable Pressure State Impact Response

1. Population •Population growth (% rural, urban)

•Population density (p/ha)•Population size (#)

•Population distribution (% rural, urban)

•Fertility rate (%)•Population projections

2. Socio-economic development

•GNP per capita ($US)•GNP distribution (%)•Production structure (%)•Unemployment rate (%)

•Employment structure (%)•Income Gini Coefficient•Rural population w. service

access (%)•School enrollment rate (%)•Rural literacy (%, by sex)•Natural capital/cap. ($US,

%)•Daily Caloric intake/cap.•Agriculture labor force (%)•Life expectancy (yrs.)

•Infant mortality rate (x1000 births)

•Rural poor (%)•Malnourished children (%)•Minors in labor force

(urban, rural; % of total)

•% of GNP to Education•% of GNP to Health•% of population

immunized•% of women w. family-

planning access•Participation in

agreements, treaties

3. Land use •Pesticide use t/ha)•Fertilizer use (t/ha)•Agricult. land per capita

(ha)•Irrigated land (% of crop

land•Crop prices ($US)•Input prices ($US)•Grain-fed livestock (%)•Land concentr. (Gini coeff.)•Drug cultivation areas (ha)•Charcoal production (m3/

cap)•Fuel production (m3/cap)•Annual wood production

(m3)•Deforestation (ha/yr.)•Livestock population (#)•Land-use changes (ha)

Cereal production (t)•Cereal yields (t/ha)•Roots, tuber production (t)•Roots, tuber yields (t/ha)•Food-consumption change

(%)•Agriculture as % of GNP•Cropland area (ha)•Centers of crop prod’n (ha)•Wood reserve/production

ratio•Forest area (ha)•Pasture area (ha)•Land use/cover area (ha)•Land use index (pot./act.)•Net primary productivity

(t/ha)

•Erosion rates (t/ha)•Soil degradation index•Cropland affected by pest

and disease (%)•Food export/import ratio•Nutrient balance•Soil organic matter•Soil loss volume (t)•Soil compaction•Wood scarcity (% of pop.)•Forest fragmentation (ha)•Carrying-capacity index

(AU/ha)•Erosion-affected area (ha)•Desertific.-affected area

(ha)•Salinization-affected area

(ha)

•Agriculture land needed to feed projected population (ha)

•Agriculture research/training expenditures ($US)

•Potential agriculture yields•Forest action plans•Annual reforest. (ha)•Reforest./deforest.-ratio•Deforestation projections

(ha/yr)•Restored/rehabilitated

surfaces (ha)•Land-use proj. (ha)

4. Biodiversity •Non domesticated land (ha)

•Species extinction rates•Conservation condition•Species (#) used in

agriculture

•% of natural areas•Threatened species (% of

total)•Endemic species (% of

total)•Threatened plants taxones

(#)•Biodiversity distinctives•Major habitat type

•Conservation state •Protected areas•Biodiversity inventories•Participation in

agreements, treaties•Ecoregions needed for

representation in bio-regions

Appendix 1. Selected Environmental Indicators

Page 25: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

23

Tropical drylands•sheet erosion, wind erosion•lowered water tables, groundwater salinisation•growth of inferior annuals, thorny and woody shrubs (i.e. reduced availability of useful biomass)•declining crop productivity•declining availability of common property resources

Mountain areas•increased landslips, gully erosion, terrace abandonment•decline in species diversity in pastures and forests•substitution of cattle by sheep and goats, increased seasonal migration•substitution of deep-rooted crops by shallow-rooted ones•persistent decline in agricultural productivity•increased distance and time involved in gathering fodder and fuelwood•reduced fallowing, intercropping and crop diversification

Tropical moist forests•declining species diversity, decline in forest area•reduction in length and deterioration of vegetation, composition of fallows•decline in useful species present in bush and fallow•gully erosion

Tropical wetlands•decline in useful macrophytes through eutrophication, chemical pollution and presence of metals•soil drying and compaction

Irrigated lands•waterlogging, salinisation•mining of productive soil components (organic matter, available macro-, micro-nutrients)

Rainfed cropland•sheet and gully erosion, declining crop productivity•increased yield variability/ increasing rainfall variability•increasing crop disease and pest damage•reduced fallowing, intercropping and crop diversification

Urban areas•Increased presence in human environment of health damaging pollutants and micro-organisms•increased presence of toxic wastes in air and water•declining availability of clean drinking water•decreased quality and increased overcrowding of housing

Source: Leach and Mearns (1991) adapted from Jodha (1991)

5. Water and Coastal resources

•Population in coastal areas (#)

•Marine and continental catch (t/yr)

•Coast-tourist arrivals (p/km of coast line)

•Water consumption (m3/cap.)

•Annual water withdrawal (% of total)

•Mangrove, coral reef area (ha)

•Annual internal renewable water resources (m3/cap.)

•Sectoral withdrawals

•Mangrove, coral reef/coast line-ratio

•BOD and COD in water (mg/l)

•Pesticide, fertilizer concentration in water (mg/l)

•Participation in agreements, treaties

•Protected coastal areas (ha)•Waters treated (%)•Rural population w. safe-

water access (%)

6. Energy and Atmosphere

•Fuel, wood consumption (m3/cap.)

•Hydro-power generation (total and % of capacity)

•Energy consumption (J/cap.)

•Global warming net emissions (t CO2 eq. C)

•Net emissions due to land use change (% of total)

Hydro-power potential (G/h/yr)

•Installed hydro-power capacity (G)

•Energy reserves (tep)•Dam efficiency (Kw/ha)•Emissions (tC/cap.)•Agriculture emissions (% of

total)•Livestock emissions (% of

total)

•Traditional fuels (% of total requirements)

•Bio-energy potential (t)•Participation in

agreements, treaties

7. Natural events •Frequency of natural disasters (#/yr)

•Population affected by natural disasters

•Financial losses due to natural disasters ($US)

•Lives lost due to natural disasters (#)

•National plans against destruction of natural disasters

Source: World Bank, 1998b.

Variable Pressure State Impact Response

Page 26: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

24

i. There are other arguments pertaining to theefforts to curb population growth, such as publichealth aspects. These are valid, but outside of thescope of this publication.

ii. The concept of “poverty” has been given sev-eral definitions. The most central concept is thepoverty line, where the Absolute Poverty Line(APL) is the minimum level of expendituredeemed necessary to satisfy individual’s require-ment of food and some non-food necessities. Thehead count ratio measures the proportion of peo-ple (or households) whose adjusted equivalentincome is below the poverty line. The Food Pov-erty Line is the minimum expenditure necessaryfor satisfying food needs only. Depth of poverty,often labeled the Poverty Gap Index, is the dif-ference between the absolute poverty line andthe average consumption expenditure of thepoor, expressed as a percentage of the APL. TheGini Coefficient is a summary measure of inequal-ity in the distribution of expenditure (for furtherreference, see e.g. Ravallion, 1992, 1998). Anotherset of definitions are derived in ParticipatoryPoverty Assessments and based on local peo-ple’s perceptions and characteristics of that soci-ety’s poor. For the purposes of this paper, wehave to accept the fact that different sources usedwill be based on different definitions of poverty.We do not believe that this ambiguity shouldstand in the way of a search a synthesis of empir-ical lessons.

iii. The World Development Report on poverty(World Bank, 1990) argues that poverty is an

important determinant and effect of environ-mental degradation, and that investing in theenvironment is often a win-win solution withrespect to poverty reduction. The reverse mayalso be true. The report describes how rural poorare marginalized or forced to intensify theirresource use resulting in environmental degra-dation, which in turn exacerbates the poverty.Lopez (1997) argue that there might be a virtuousor vicious cycle of interaction between popula-tion growth, environment, poverty and institu-tions. The final outcome is crucially determinedby policies, he argues. Sida (1991) and Segnestam(1996) adhere generally to these views but alsoemphasize, inter alia, (i) the extremely high com-plexity of the issue, (ii) the importance of under-standing these processes as well as the localsocio-economic and ecological context, and(iii) that pursuit of economic-growth policies andpoverty-reduction policies without due attentionpaid at their environmental consequences entailserious inherent risks to the sustainability of thevery same policies.

iv. This could be related to the type of cookingfuel used; e.g. fuelwood as opposed to kerosene,liquefied petroleum gas (LPG) or electricity.

v. See for example Kramer et. al. (1995) for acarefully conducted study to assess the compen-sation needs of local villagers in the vicinity of anational park in Madagascar.

vi. A word of caution in the interpretation of thisstudy is in order. The comprehensive impact of

End Notes

Page 27: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

25

the policy reforms must be taken into accountwhen evaluating the impact, not only theremoval of certain subsidies. Thus, it would beenlightening to also include in the evaluation theimpact of changed incentives on the output sideand other relevant reforms pertaining to theprofitability of Zambian small-holder’s agricul-tural production, as well as other exogenouscauses of their purported behavioral change.

This is justified based on the argument that it isnot the removal of fertilizer subsidies that hasmade maize less profitable than other crops,increased slash-and-burn cultivation and trig-gered substitution towards environmentallymalign local crops, but rather elimination of thepan-territorial pre-planting prices offered tofarmers, which amounted to a transport subsidyto their maize production (and marketing) inremote areas. It is doubtful whether maize farm-ers in the relevant areas received or used muchfertilizer even when it was subsidized. More-over, the analysis gives no guidance as towhether the changed input and output pricesprovided, on balance, improved or worsenedterms-of-trade for most of the affected farmers.Further, we do not know whether changes in for-est cover were (also) due to exogenous causessuch as population growth, in-migration, orabnormal climate during the survey period.

vii. While it may be difficult to separate the timehorizon impacts from the discount rate impactby merely observing behavior, they are concep-tually different factors. Time horizon refers to thefact that some costs or benefits may not enter atall into the calculation. An example would be afarmer clearing a plot of land with the perspec-tive of harvesting for three seasons, and then tomove on. Another would be a farmer within arotational 5 or 7-year system, as traditionallypracticed in parts of Ethiopia and Eritrea. Whilesocial forces are still at work to define acceptablebehavior, such a system does provide a definitetime horizon for investment decisions.

Discount rate refers to the conceptually distinctcase of weighing future cost and benefits, perhapsover a considerable time horizon. It is oftendivided into individual or social discount rates.Individual or private discount rates are primarilydetermined by individual pure time preference(“impatience” or individuals’ premium fordelayed pay-off), risk and uncertainty. Social dis-count rates are either determined by the social

time preference rate (STPR) or social opportunitycost of capital (SOC). STPR is based on the elas-ticity of marginal utility of income (or consump-tion) multiplied by income growth per capitaplus the social rate of time preference (“impa-tience”). SOC is based on marginal productivityof capital.

It has been debated whether society and thesocial discount rate should reflect “impatience”by simply aggregating all individuals’ pure timepreference into the STRP and hence place differ-ent values for nominally identical costs or bene-fits incurred across time. Based on the goal ofsustainable development and inter-generationalequity, we argue that no such distinction can bejustified. Society has a responsibility, which goesbeyond individual preferences of the currentgeneration, to also include future generations.Society’s discounting also includes an element ofrisk and uncertainty, which are normally identi-fied by multiplying (a distribution of) probabili-ties with utilities of various outcomes.

High discount rate are generally caused by (fearof) economic and social instability, and high realinterest rates in credit markets. A further compli-cation is the separation between risk-aversion and“pure” discount rates. Conceptually, one can sep-arate the valuation of future costs and benefits attheir expected values from the consideration ofvariance around those expected values. In prac-tice, the distinction becomes blurred, and we havefound it difficult to separate the two elementswhen interpreting empirical studies. Hence, thosetwo factors have been lumped together. For a dis-cussion see e.g. Bojö, Mäler and Unemo (1992,pp. 65–71); Pearce and Warford (1993, pp. 65–80).

viii. The term stems from the seminal work ofSimon Kuznets, primarily in the 1950s, on therelationship between income distribution andincome level. The debate about this curveapplied to the environmental domain hasbecome quite lively, and recent issues of the Jour-nal of Environment and Development Econom-ics (1997) and International Journal of EcologicalEconomics (1998) are entirely devoted to thistheme, with articles covering indicators pertain-ing to air and water pollution, inequality, defor-estation, trade, energy and traffic volumes.

ix. In addition to the studies presented in box 14,Cleaver and Schreiber (1994) find that the defor-estation rate correlates positively with the total

Page 28: Poverty and Environment - Newcastle University · January 1999 Anders Ekbom Jan Bojö Poverty and Environment: Evidence of Links and Integration into the Country Assistance Strategy

26

fertility rate in a cross-section of 38 countries inSub-Saharan Africa. However, they also reportthat the econometrically estimated effect of pop-ulation pressure (cultivated area per person) ondeforestation, having pooled the cross-countrysample, yield statistically non-significant coeffi-

cients. In the simple cross-country sample, popu-lation pressure had the expected negative signon the coefficient, but it is very small and not sta-tistically significant. Cleaver and Schreiber con-clude that “the result is therefore ambiguous andunconfirmed” (p. 72).