Top Banner
On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012
47

On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

Dec 30, 2015

Download

Documents

Anissa Lee
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

On The Mathematics of Income Inequality

Klaus Volpert Villanova University

Sep. 19, 2013

Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012

Page 2: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

In 2010, hedge fund manager John Paulson took home

$5 Billion.

Stunning income differences

Page 3: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

In 2010, hedge fund manager John Paulson took home

$5 Billion.

That would be the combined income of 50,000 professors -

Stunning income differences

Page 4: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

In 2010, hedge fund manager John Paulson took home

$5 Billion.

That would be the combined income of 50,000 professors - if we made an average of $100,000.

That’s more than all the math professors in the US combined

Stunning income differences

Page 5: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

On the other hand, there is no doubt that one could find 50,000 of the world's poor whose combined wealth is less than each one of ours.

Page 6: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

On the other hand, there is no doubt that one could find 50,000 of the world's poor whose combined wealth is less than each one of ours.

Does it have to be that way?

Page 7: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

Total Equality is not possible

Page 8: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

Even if we could distribute all wealth equally, inequality would return in an instant.

Total Equality is not possible

Page 9: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

Even if we could distribute all wealth equally, inequality would return in an instant.

For one man would take his money to the bank, and one man would take it to the bar.

Herr Procher (my 10th grade English teacher)

Total Equality is not possible

Page 10: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

Inequality might be inevitable,it might be stunning, But it is not static!

Inequality varies a great deal from country to country. Even within the same country it can change dramatically over time!

Page 11: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

Q: What do you think: over the last 100 years, has inequality in the US increased or decreased?

Page 12: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

Q: What do you think: over the last 100 years, has inequality in the US increased or decreased?

Data by Thomas Piketty and Emanuel Saez

1913

1916

1919

1922

1925

1928

1931

1934

1937

1940

1943

1946

1949

1952

1955

1958

1961

1964

1967

1970

1973

1976

1979

1982

1985

1988

1991

1994

1997

2000

2003

2006

2009

2012

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20Share of total income (in percent) of top 1% Earners in the US, 1913-2012

Page 13: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

A better measure than the top 1%-index:The Lorenz Curve and the Gini-Index

L(x)= share of total income earned by all households combined that are poorer than the xth percentile.

e.g., L(.4)=.1 means that the poorest 40% of the population have a share of 10% of the total income.

The curve has two anchors: (0,0) and (1,1)

0.1

Page 14: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

If income was perfectly evenly distributed, then L(x)=x, and the graph would be a straight line

Perfect equality

The Lorenz Curve and the Gini-Index

Page 15: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

The Lorenz Curve and the Gini-Index

If one household received all the income, and no one else received anything, the curve would look like this

Perfect inequality

Page 16: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

The Lorenz Curve and the Gini-Index

Realistic curves are somewhere in between.

The closer to the diagonal the more equally distributed the income.

Page 17: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

The Lorenz Curve and the Gini-Index

The Gini-Index is the ratio of the area between the line of equality and L(x),and the entire area under the line of equality(which is ½).So, 1

0

2 ( )G x L x dx Perfect Equality → G=0Perfect Inequality → G=1

Page 18: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

11 2 32

0 0

12 2( )

2 3 3

x xG x x dx

2Example: If ( ) , thenL x x

Page 19: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

11 2 32

0 0

12 2( )

2 3 3

x xG x x dx

2Example: If ( ) , thenL x x

So the Gini-index is a summary measure,giving weight to the poor as to the wealthy

Page 20: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

11 2 32

0 0

12 2( )

2 3 3

x xG x x dx

2Example: If ( ) , thenL x x

So the Gini-index is a summary measure,giving weight to the poor and to the wealthy

This allows us to make comparisons between countries, as well as look at trends over time.

Page 21: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

The Gini-Index for various Countries:(according to data from the World Bank and CIA)

Page 22: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

The Gini-Index for various Countries:(according to data from the World Bank and CIA)

Country Gini-Index

Sweden .230

Germany .270

Egypt .344

Russia .420

China .480

Brazil .519

South Africa .650

Page 23: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

The Gini-Index for various Countries:(according to data from the World Bank and CIA)

Country Gini-Index

Sweden .230

Germany .270

Egypt .344

Russia .420

China .480

Brazil .519

South Africa .650

Discussion: there are several reasons why one must take these numbers with a grain of salt. . . (what are the basic economic units? What constitutes income? What about adjustments for cost of living? Etc.)Still. Overall the comparative impression is correct.

Page 24: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

What about the US?Here are Some Raw Data from the Census Bureau:

Quintile Lorenz value

.2 .04

.4 .148

.6 .321

.8 .563

1 1

US-Income Data 1967:Published by the Census Bureau

How can we calculate the Gini-index from these Quintiles??

Page 25: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

Connect the Dots??

Quintile Lorenz value

.2 .04

.4 .148

.6 .321

.8 .563

1 1

US-Income Data 1967:Published by the Census Bureau

Page 26: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

Connect the Dots??

Quintile Lorenz value

.2 .04

.4 .148

.6 .321

.8 .563

1 1

US-Income Data 1967:Published by the Census Bureau

This would clearly underestimate the area and the Gini-Index.How can we do better??

Page 27: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

A First Model for the Lorenz Curve: ( ) pL x x

Matched with real income data, however, no power function fits the whole population very well: Quintile Lorenz

value

.2 .04

.4 .148

.6 .321

.8 .563

1 1

US-Income Data 1967:Published by the Census Bureau

2.287( )L x xBest fit:

Page 28: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

However!

( ) pL x cx

If we only try to match the bottom 60%, then it does fit well!

We’ll come back to that. . . . Quintile Lorenz

value

.2 .04

.4 .148

.6 .321

.8 .563

1 1

US-Income Data 1967:Published by the Census Bureau

1.90849 ( ) .L x xBest fit:

Page 29: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

A Second Model for the Lorenz Curve: A Quintic Polynomial:

2 3 4 5( )L x ax bx cx dx ex

A quintic polynomial fits much better:

Quintile Lorenz value

.2 .04

.4 .148

.6 .321

.8 .563

1 1

US-Income Data 1967:Published by the Census Bureau

2 3 4 5( ) .13 .23 3.9 5.8 2.99L x x x x x x

Page 30: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

A Second Model for the Lorenz Curve: A Quintic Polynomial:

2 3 4 5( )L x ax bx cx dx ex

A quintic polynomial fits much better:

Quintile Lorenz value

.2 .04

.4 .148

.6 .321

.8 .563

1 1

US-Income Data 1967:Published by the Census Bureau

2 3 4 5( ) .13 .23 3.9 5.8 2.99L x x x x x x

2 Problems: (a) We calculate G=.391, while the official number is G=.397 (b) The coefficients tell us nothing.

Q: Can we come up with a function that has some economic meaning?

Page 31: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

The rich don’t feel so rich. . .The self-similarity phenomenon:

In 2007: (according to data from Saez and Piketty)

• The top 10.0% received 48% of total US income• The top 1.0% received 24%• The top .1% received 12%• The top .01% received 6%

The inequality repeats among the rich: no matter how rich you are, there are always some who are far richer,in a very peculiar and predictable pattern.

Q: what function for L(x) would describe such a pattern?

Page 32: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

( ) 1 (1 ) , 0 1qL x x q

Here is a family of such functions.q=1 → total equalityq=0 → total inequality

This family of functions is known as Pareto distributions

Page 33: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

These functions have this remarkable property:The Gini-index among the top x percent is the same as in the whole population, for any x.

= =

The Principle of Self-Similarity `to the right`

This can be called a (one-sided) `scale-invariance’,also known as the `Pareto Principle’.

Page 34: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

This function works great for the top 5%:

Page 35: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

but, alas, even this model does not fit very well for the whole population:

So what to do? We have a model that fits very well at the top, and, remember, we have a model that fits very well at the bottom. . . Let’s take another look at ( ) pL x x

Page 36: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

exhibits the opposite phenomenon:

Self-similarity to the left:The inequality repeats among the poor

( ) pL x x

The Gini-Index among the whole population is the same as the Gini-Index restricted to just the poorest 50%, say. Or the poorest 20%. Or the poorest 2%. Etc.

So one model works well at the top, one at the bottom, so for the whole population we try a hybrid model, that asymptotically equals the two separate models at either end:

Page 37: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

The Hybrid Model:

( ) (1 (1 ) )p qL x x x

Note: asymptotically we have

1as 0, ( ) px L x qx as 1, ( ) (1 (1 ) )qx L x x

Empirically, the model fits amazingly well:

Page 38: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

.7438 .6823( ) (1 (1 ) )L x x x

With this model, G=.395.Official value: G=.3971967

Sum of Squares of Residuals: 0.00001989

( ) (1 (1 ) )p qL x x x

Page 39: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

.7987 .5608( ) (1 (1 ) )L x x x

With this model, G=.468Official value: G=.466Quintic model: G=.45720082008

Sum of Squares of Residuals: 0.00000396

( ) (1 (1 ) )p qL x x x

Page 40: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

We matched this model to every year 1967-2010.Each time the predicted Gini-index, based on just 4 data points each year, is within 0.25% of the official Gini-Index computed by the Census bureau from a full set of raw data.

The Trend 1967-2010

Notice that the latest (2012) Gini-Index for the US is

approximately .477

Page 41: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

.7987 .5608( ) (1 (1 ) )L x x x

20082008

Notice:p and q are economically meaningful:

and

are the limits of the Gini-Index at the low and high end respectively

( ) (1 (1 ) )p qL x x x

Page 42: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

1967-2010: The Trends in and

Inequality among the poor has slightly increased

Inequality among the rich has increased significantly

Page 43: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

It is easy to forget among all the models and data, that there are real people affected by poverty and inequality.

Concluding Thought

Page 44: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

It is easy to forget among all the models and data, that there are real people affected by poverty and inequality.

When we think of inequality, do we think of him or her?

Concluding Thought

Is our thinking, our respect, our care, as skewed as the Lorenz curve?

Page 45: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

So I would like to finish with a quote from a girl at a school in South Africa that is under the care of the Augustinian Mission, which in turn is connected to Villanova University

Concluding Thought

Page 46: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

AndileStudent, St. Leo’s School, Durban, South Africa

Page 47: On The Mathematics of Income Inequality Klaus Volpert Villanova University Sep. 19, 2013 Published in American Mathematical Monthly, Dec 2012.

“I am somebody. I may be poor, but I am somebody. I maybe make mistakes, but I am somebody.”

AndileStudent, St. Leo’s School, Durban, South Africa