Top Banner
Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253–279 On strategic vertical foreign investment a, a ,b * Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaene a Department of Economics, Erasmus University, P .O. Box 1738, 3000 DR Rotterdam, The Netherlands b Tinbergen Institute, Rotterdam The Netherlands Received 30 April 1996; accepted 11 September 1997 Abstract We investigate the strategic incentives for vertical foreign direct investment by oligopolistic firms under exchange rate uncertainty. Domestic final good firms meet their input requirements either by investing abroad and producing directly through a subsidiary (intra-firm trade) or by buying from an oligopolistic market abroad (inter-firm trade). Firms undertaking vertical investment can bid up the input price faced by their rivals through strategic purchase. We demonstrate the possibility of vertical foreclosure, multiple equilib- ria, complementarity and bunching of investment decisions. Increase in the variability of exchange rate has positive effects on foreign direct investment and trade in the intermediate good; an appreciation of investor’s currency has similar effects. 1998 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. Keywords: Foreign direct investment; Vertical foreclosure; Exchange rate uncertainty JEL classification: D43; F2; F31 1. Introduction Foreign direct investment (FDI) has grown dramatically as a major form of international capital transfer over the last few decades. Between 1980 and 1990 world flows of FDI have approximately tripled. The emerging global economy is one increasingly dominated by multinational firms which currently account for * Corresponding author. Tel: 131-10-4081420; fax: 131-10-2121724; e-mail: [email protected] 0022-1996 / 98 / $ – see front matter 1998 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S0022-1996(97)00053-6
27

On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

Aug 02, 2020

Download

Documents

dariahiddleston
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253–279

On strategic vertical foreign investmenta , a ,b*Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaene

aDepartment of Economics, Erasmus University, P.O. Box 1738, 3000 DR Rotterdam,The Netherlands

bTinbergen Institute, Rotterdam The Netherlands

Received 30 April 1996; accepted 11 September 1997

Abstract

We investigate the strategic incentives for vertical foreign direct investment byoligopolistic firms under exchange rate uncertainty. Domestic final good firms meet theirinput requirements either by investing abroad and producing directly through a subsidiary(intra-firm trade) or by buying from an oligopolistic market abroad (inter-firm trade). Firmsundertaking vertical investment can bid up the input price faced by their rivals throughstrategic purchase. We demonstrate the possibility of vertical foreclosure, multiple equilib-ria, complementarity and bunching of investment decisions. Increase in the variability ofexchange rate has positive effects on foreign direct investment and trade in the intermediategood; an appreciation of investor’s currency has similar effects. 1998 Elsevier ScienceB.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Foreign direct investment; Vertical foreclosure; Exchange rate uncertainty

JEL classification: D43; F2; F31

1. Introduction

Foreign direct investment (FDI) has grown dramatically as a major form ofinternational capital transfer over the last few decades. Between 1980 and 1990world flows of FDI have approximately tripled. The emerging global economy isone increasingly dominated by multinational firms which currently account for

*Corresponding author. Tel: 131-10-4081420; fax: 131-10-2121724; e-mail: [email protected]

0022-1996/98/$ – see front matter 1998 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.PI I : S0022-1996( 97 )00053-6

Page 2: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

254 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

about one-third of world output. About one-third of world trade takes place in theform of intra-firm trade; intermediates and manufactured goods constitute themajor components of such trade flows (UNCTAD, 1994). Therefore, the questionof what determines the global expansion and the transboundary investmentbehaviour of enterprises assumes considerable significance.

One of the important features of FDI is that it is prominent in industries wherethe classical competitive paradigm fits least well. Old style multinationalspopulated and continue to dominate oligopolistic natural resource based industriessuch as oil and aluminium. Modern multinationals thrive in fast moving Schum-petarian sectors such as pharmaceutical and electronics. A large number ofempirical studies for several periods and host countries indicate a high correlation

1between seller concentration in a market and the flow of direct investment abroad.Not surprisingly therefore, a large part of the current literature on FDI has focusedon firms’ decisions to set up subsidiaries abroad as an intrinsic element of thecompetition for market share in oligopolistic industries.

Recent theoretical models have emphasized the role of FDI as an instrumentused by exporting firms to protect and improve their market share abroad in the

2presence of trade barriers. While this covers a very important and growingcomponent of the total flow of actual FDI in the world, there is another importantcategory of foreign investment which is motivated by the desire of firms to acquiredirect control over the supply and manufacture of inputs upstream as well asdisposal of their output downstream. Such vertical investment enables firms toovercome the market power exercised by enterprises located in the upstream and

3downstream markets. The effect of such vertical foreign direct investment is notto reduce the volume of trade but rather increase the volume of intra-firm trade atthe cost of inter-firm trade.

Historically, international oil and mineral firms have concentrated on developingintegrated vertical structures and the tendency has continued to the present day.Thus, U.S. based oil companies remain unwilling to rely upon the upstream marketfor the bulk of their supplies. In the electronics industry, a large number of U.S.based firms such as IBM and Texas Instruments have chosen to manufacture aconsiderable part of their labour-intensive component needs directly within theirmultinational network rather than buy from independent suppliers. In the semi-conductor industry, the surge of FDI in South East Asia has largely concentratedon creating offshore assembly plants (Vernon, 1993). In general, the notabletendency among multinationals to increasingly locate various stages of production

1A detailed discussion is contained in Caves (1996).2See, among many others, Smith (1987); Horstmann and Markusen (1987); Motta (1992); Broll and

Zilcha (1992) and Goldberg and Kolstad (1995) consider the case of FDI in the presence of exchangerate uncertainty.

3They also enable firms to maintain quality of inputs, overcome uncertainties caused by informationasymmetry and maintain steady supply of inputs.

Page 3: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 255

in developed and developing countries that are liberalizing their trade (Markusen,1995), attests to the importance of vertical control and vertical integration asmotivations for FDI in the current world.

A fairly well established pattern that has been observed in the past few decadesis that rival firms in the same market tend to be bunched in their foreigninvestment decisions (see Vernon, 1993). Firms are observed to ‘‘imitate’’decisions of their rival firms to set up production subsidiaries in a particularregion. One of the important explanations offered for this has been strategiccompetition between noncollusive oligopolists. In a pioneering study of FDI by 23US multinationals over the period 1948–67, Knickerbocker (1973) found thatbunching of investment and imitative behaviour increased with seller concentrationup to a point and that bunching was most likely to occur in moderatelyconcentrated industries which, in turn, are most likely to exhibit the features of anoncollusive oligopoly. Less bunching occurs in industries where product differen-tiation and advertisement have reduced the cut and thrust of product marketoligopolistic rivalry. These conclusions have been supported by various otherstatistical and descriptive studies (see among others, Yu and Ito, 1988; Belderbos,1997).

The natural question which arises from these observations is the nature ofconditions under which oligopolistic rivalry leads to bunching of foreign invest-ment decisions and the factors which influence the extent of bunching. In recentyears, a number of theoretical models have been developed to study the possibilityof bunching or herding in investment decisions of competing firms. In theliterature on strategic FDI, the issue has been analyzed in models where FDI isundertaken by exporting firms to jump trade barriers. However, bunching ofinvestment decisions is also observed in industries where foreign investment isgeared towards creation of vertical subsidiaries undertaking production upstream

4or downstream.The purpose of this paper is to examine the strategic incentives of oligopolistic

firms to undertake upstream vertical FDI and directly produce their own inputrequirements in the presence of an upstream market from which firms can buytheir input at arm’s length prices. We are going to focus on two important factorswhich influence the incentive of firms to create vertical subsidiaries abroad—thelevel of existing concentration in the downstream market and the possibility of

4Following the threat posed by vertical integration of the Saudi and Venezuelan state owned oilcompanies, U.S. based oil companies have concentrated on creating, repairing and strengthening theirupstream links. In the 80’s, new upstream ties were being forged by Gulf Oil, Sun Oil, Citgo andTexaco. Vertical FDI in the semiconductor industry between 1964 and 1972 was characterized by abunching of investment in offshore assembly plants in South East Asia, essentially driven by theaggressive moves of firms in an increasingly competitive industry to compete on costs (Yoffie, 1993).In the last decade, there has been a huge surge of investment from developing East Asian countries toThailand and Indonesia setting up subsidiary manufacturing plants whose output is almost entirelyexported (Wells, 1993).

Page 4: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

256 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

5strategic vertical foreclosure. The former determines, among other things, thedifference between the arm’s length market price and the unit cost of productionthrough a subsidiary. The latter enables firms which undertake vertical FDI toindulge in strategic manipulations of the downstream market which hurt rival firmsthat rely on the open market for their input needs. The particular form of verticalforeclosure we consider in this model is, in fact, the simplest one—subsidiariescan choose to purchase from the downstream market, if they so wish, thus bidding

6up the input price faced by rival firms.7The existing literature on vertical integration and foreclosure largely confines

attention to outcomes of competition and contracting in vertical markets with agiven number of vertically integrated firms. In our model, the number of verticallyintegrated firms is determined endogenously. This allows us to study thepossibility of bunching in vertical investment as a strategic outcome. It is worthemphasizing that there are no externalities, informational or technological,between investing firms. Any complementarity in investment decisions emergesendogenously from strategic interaction in upstream and downstream markets.This distinguishes our work from most of the ‘‘macro coordination’’ literaturewhere technological and/or demand complementarities are assumed to begin with

8in order to generate complementarity in investment.An important factor affecting firms’ foreign investment decisions is volatility in

the major currencies of the world as illustrated by the behaviour of the U.S. dollarin the 80’s and the 90’s. Such fluctuations give rise to both ‘‘level’’ and ‘‘risk’’effects. Exchange rate movements affect the relative cost of import of intermediategoods obtained through inter-firm trade vis-a-vis intra-firm trade. This drawsattention to the pricing policies of producers (exchange rate pass-through) invertically related markets and investment decisions in response to exchange ratemovements. Further, long term investment is clearly affected by the futurevariability of exchange rate shocks. Central to the issue, here, is the popularconjecture that the floating exchange rate regime has led to a decrease in the

9volume of FDI by multinational firms. This view has been repeatedly put forwardby various international organizations and governments (see for example, UN-

5In addition to these factors, the literature refers to the role of informational asymmetry andexternalities as important factors which make firms invest downstream when their rivals do.

6The literature contains numerous references to threats of other kinds of vertical foreclosure as beingimportant to the foreign investment decisions of firms e.g. cutting off or creating impediments tosources of supply through direct vertical restraints and contracts. See, among others, Rosengren andMeehan (1994) and Mullin and Mullin (1996) for recent case studies of vertical foreclosure andantitrust complaints.

7See, among others, Grossman and Hart (1986); Salinger (1988); Hart and Tirole (1990); Ordover etal. (1990); Bolton and Whinston (1991); Schrader and Martin (1995).

8See, for example, Murphy et al. (1989) and the survey by Matsuyama (1995).9A related issue is the conjectured negative effect of exchange rate variability on international trade

flows. The numerous empirical investigations into this issue have, on the whole, yielded no conclusiveevidence about such relationship. Recent theoretical models have offered several explanations for thisempirical ambiguity (see, for example, Dellas and Zilberfarb, 1993, and references contained therein).

Page 5: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 257

CTAD, 1993, pp. 224, Table XI.2). This paper examines the theoretical premisesof such conjecture in the context of vertical FDI.

The specific model we analyze is as follows. There is a given number of firmswhich operate in an oligopolistic downstream (or final good) market and meet theirintermediate good requirements through import. These firms have the option ofeither investing abroad (by incurring a fixed cost) and importing their inputsthrough intra-firm trade at transfer prices, or of not investing and importing theirinput requirements at arm’s length prices. In both cases, they are affected byexchange rate movements. The market for the intermediate good abroad is also anoligopoly. Firms investing upstream can bid up the input price faced by their rivalswhich do not invest, through strategic purchase. We assume that the marketdemand for the final good is linear and that production technology at both final andintermediate stages exhibit constant returns. All firms are risk-neutral expectedprofit maximizers. After investment decisions are made, exchange rate uncertaintyis resolved and the firms strategically determine their net supply in each marketthey participate in.

The main result of this paper is that, for a large class of environments, thestrategic incentive to invest may increase as more and more rival firms invest; inother words, vertical investment decisions may exhibit strategic complementarity.This is a consequence of strategic purchase by investing firms in order to raise theinput price faced by their rivals thus magnifying the relative disadvantage of notinvesting. This motivation for strategic investment becomes dominant when theintermediate market is more ‘‘competitive’’ in terms of the number of foreignproducers active in the market. In such situations, there are typically multipleequilibria: some equilibria involve many firms investing and others involve veryfew firms investing, sometimes, all or none. In other words, we can observebunching in investment decisions; competing firms invest upstream because theirrivals do. A small decrease in the fixed cost of investment can trigger a big jumpin the volume of investment.

Another interesting result we derive is that the reduced form expected gain frominvestment is a strictly convex function of the uncertain exchange rate. Therefore,an increase in foreign exchange variability (more precisely, a second-orderdecrease in the distribution of the exchange rate) has a positive effect on verticalforeign direct investment and the flow of international trade. To the extent thatstrategic control of vertical production is a motive for foreign investment, ourresults indicate there is a theoretical basis for increased volatility of exchange rateshaving a positive effect on FDI. As for the effect of a change in the level ofexchange rate, a depreciation of the investor’s currency increases both the effectivearm’s length price at which a unit of the intermediate good can be bought in themarket and the unit cost of producing the good directly through a subsidiary;however, demand for the input also changes which affects the arm’s length price.We show that the net effect is always a reduction in the incentive to undertakeFDI.

The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we lay out the general

Page 6: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

258 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

framework, describe the extensive form of the game as well as the solutionconcept. In Section 3, we derive the equilibrium in the final and intermediate goodmarkets following any profile of investment decisions by domestic firms. InSection 4, we consider the reduced form foreign investment game where firmssimultaneously decide whether or not to invest, prior to the resolution of exchangerate uncertainty, and characterize the equilibria of this game. In particular, wederive our main results about the strategic incentive to invest and analyze theeffects of decline in investment barriers. In Section 5, we outline the effects ofchange in exchange rate level and volatility on investment. We conclude in Section6. Appendix A contains a glossary of symbols.

2. The model

We analyze the issue of vertical foreign investment in the context of markets intwo countries—which we shall call ‘‘domestic’’ and ‘‘foreign’’. A homogenousfinal good is produced by N firms (N $ 1) in the domestic economy by using ahomogenous intermediate good as input. The demand curve for the final good islinear; in particular, the inverse demand function is given by:

p 5 a 2 bQ, a . 0, b . 0, Q , (a /b)

5 0, Q $ (a /b) (1)

where p denotes the price and Q is the total output /quantity demanded in the finalgood market. We assume that the input must be imported by domestic firms from

10the foreign economy and that the final good is produced and consumed in the11domestic market only. Further, apart from the domestic final good producers

mentioned above, there are no other firms which demand the intermediate goodproduced in the foreign market. Assume that production of one unit of the final

12 *good requires only one unit of the imported intermediate good. There are mexisting foreign firms (indexed by k) which produce the intermediate good abroad

*at a unit foreign currency cost c .Final good firms have the option of making vertical foreign investment in order

10This could reflect a situation where production of the input requires some foreign country specificfactor which is nontradeable or, more simply, the unit cost of producing the input domestically isrelatively very high (for example higher than the largest possible domestic currency cost of importing itat monopoly price from abroad).

11Allowing export of final output would make the revenue side subject to exchange rate variability;in this paper we wish to confine ourselves to the effect of exchange rate fluctuations on theimport / input supply side.

12This is a simplifying assumption which is representative of the technology of trading houses, forexample, but can be easily generalized to any constant factor requirement technology. Allowing forpossibility of factor substitution would complicate the analysis without adding to the basic story.

Page 7: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 259

to set up subsidiary units in the foreign economy which can directly produce theintermediate good for own use or for sale to other users. Let f .0 denote the fixedcost of setting up such a subsidiary unit, measured in domestic currency. Thedomestic resource cost of importing the intermediate good, whether from ownsubsidiary or from other suppliers, depends on the exchange rate, defined as

˜domestic price of the foreign currency and denoted by e. Final good firms face˜uncertainty about e when they make vertical investment decisions. All firms are

risk-neutral, maximize expected net profit and have rational expectations.The market evolves in two stages; decisions made in the first stage being

irreversible and fully observable in the second stage. First, N domestic final goodfirms decide simultaneously on whether or not to make vertical foreign invest-ments in intermediate production. Once firms have decided on vertical investment,uncertainty about the exchange rate is resolved. In the second stage, firmsoperating in both domestic final good as well as foreign intermediate good marketsmake their supply decisions rationally. Producers of the intermediate good,

*consisting of the preexisting m foreign firms as well as newly set-up subsidiaries,anticipate the derived demand for the intermediate good and determine their netsupply. Each of them holds Cournot conjecture about the decisions of otherproducers in the intermediate good market. Subsidiaries of investing firms can bidup the market price of the intermediate good by actually buying some amount ofthe intermediate good, even though they can produce it at a unit cost less than themarket price. This has the effect of raising the input cost of rival noninvesting

13firms. The derived demand for intermediates from the final good marketemanates entirely from noninvesting domestic firms and these firms act asprice-taking buyers in the intermediate good market. The net supply decisions ofthe foreign firms and the subsidiaries, together with the derived demand function,determine the market price for the intermediate good. This price is anticipated byfirms in the final good market where, again, each firm determines its final outputholding Cournot conjecture about the behaviour of the other firms in the samemarket. Firms from each country evaluate their net profit in terms of their owncurrency. A final good firm which invests and its subsidiary maximize the sum oftheir profits in both markets (evaluated in domestic currency).

We solve the model by backward induction. First, we consider the final andintermediate good markets and determine the equilibrium in these markets for anygiven profile of investment decisions and for any specific realization of theexchange rate. This allows us to determine the expected net profit for each finalgood firm corresponding to any profile of investment decisions across the N firms.Next, we consider the reduced form game where each firm decides whether or notto make vertical foreign investment; the payoff to each firm is its expected profit,

13The literature on vertical foreclosure contains models where such input cost raising is pursued byoligopolistic vertically integrated downstream firms (see Salop and Scheffman, 1983, 1987; Schraderand Martin, 1995).

Page 8: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

260 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

net of any fixed cost of investment. The Nash equilibrium of this reduced formgame determines the solution of the model; in particular, the number of investingfirms.

Suppose that firms have made their vertical investment decisions and that a˜particular value of e is realized. Let m denote the number of final good firms

(indexed by i) which invest, 0#m#N. Thus there are (N2m) noninvesting firms(indexed by j). In the next section, we work out the market equilibrium for each

˜value of m50, 1,...,N and each possible realization of e.

3. Equilibrium in goods markets

˜Let e denote a specific realization of e. Fix e and m. We now proceed to derivethe equilibrium outcome in stage 2. Let q and r be respectively (investing) firmi j

i’s and (noninvesting) firm j’s final good production, so that:

m N2mO q 1 O r 5 Qi ji51 j51

*Let p denote the anticipated market price of the intermediate good in foreigncurrency. The anticipated profit (in domestic currency) of a final good firm j whichproduces output r , is given by:j

*P 5 r (a 2 bQ 2 ep ) j 5 1, 2,...,N 2 m (2)j j

On the other hand, an investing firm i has to take into account its revenues andcosts in both the final and the intermediate good markets. As stated in the previoussection, such a firm and its subsidiary have identical objective functions. Let xi

denote the net purchase of the intermediate good by a subsidiary of firm i. Itsanticipated domestic currency profit from combined participation in the down-stream and upstream markets is given by:

* * *P 5 q (a 2 bQ 2 ec ) 2 x (ep 2 ec ) i 5 1, 2,...,m; m $ 1 (3)i i i

When x is positive, the subsidiary of firm i actually buys a strictly positivei

amount of the intermediate good in the foreign market. Then, out of the total input14need q which is imported from its subsidiary, a quantity (q 2x )$0 is internallyi i i

*produced by the subsidiary (and imported at transfer price ec in terms ofdomestic currency), while an amount x is bought by the subsidiary from thei

* *intermediate good market at price p (imported at arm’s length price ep in termsof domestic currency). Being a net buyer of the intermediate good, the investingfirm (or, equivalently, its subsidiary) earns a negative profit upstream in order to

14It can be checked that x never exceeds q in equilibrium.i i

Page 9: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 261

gain strategic advantage by pushing up the market price of the intermediate goodfaced by its noninvesting rivals. When x is negative, firm i’s subsidiary actuallyi

sells on the intermediate good market and its total production is (q 2x ).q .i i i

*Lastly, a foreign intermediate good firm k produces output q which leads tok

anticipated profit (in foreign currency):

* * * * *P 5 q [ p 2 c ], k 5 1,...,m (4)k k

The expressions (2)–(4) define the profit for each type of firm.In the final good market, firms i and j simultaneously choose q and r (for giveni j

*anticipated p ). Imposing symmetry within each group of domestic firms (q 5q,i

;i; r 5r, ; j), we obtain the Cournot–Nash equilibrium:j

1]]] * * *q 5 [a 2 ec 1 (N 2 m)(ep 2 ec )] (5)b(N 1 1)

1]]] * * *r 5 [a 2 ec 2 (m 1 1)(ep 2 ec )] (6)b(N 1 1)

with final good price:

1]]] * *p 5 (a 1 (N 2 m)ep 1 mec ) (7)(N 1 1)

It is clear from (7) that an increase in m is always associated with a decrease in pand, hence, from (1) with an increase in Q. This is because, as more firms investupstream, these final good firms are able to produce their output at lower marginalcost. As in other standard Cournot competition models (Dornbusch, 1987), thedecline in the weighted marginal cost of production across the industry is passedon to consumers in the form of lower price, greater consumption and increasedconsumer surplus. Increase in the final good output implies a direct increase in the

15volume of international trade of the intermediate good. Profits are given by:

2 * *P 5 bq 2 x (ep 2 ec ) (8)i i

2P 5 br (9)j

Now, consider the intermediate good market abroad. As assumed earlier, themarket demand for intermediate good is generated by noninvesting firms, whichact as price-taking buyers in this market. Premultiplying (6) by (N2m), we can

15Vertical foreign investment also changes the composition of trade. Trade in the intermediate goodis equal to Q5m(q2x)1(mx1(N2m)r) for x$0; it is equal to Q5mq1(N2m)r for x,0. In bothexpressions, the first term reflects intra-firm trade, the second arm’s length trade. Hence, besidesincreasing Q, an increase in m increases the proportion of the former at the expense of the latter.

Page 10: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

262 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

obtain the total derived demand for the intermediate good. The inverse demand forthe intermediate good is then given by:

1 b(N 1 1)Q*]]] ]]]]* * *p 5 c 1 a 2 ec 2 (10)F Ge(m 1 1) (N 2 m)

*where Q is the total quantity of the intermediate good demanded. Given this,foreign producers of intermediates and investing domestic firms simultaneously

*choose their actions: foreign firms choose the quantity q $0 they wish to supplyk

and the subsidiaries of investing firms decide on x . The total output available fori

satisfaction of intermediate good demand (by noninvesting final good firms) is:

m m** *Q 5O q 2O x (11)k i

k51 i51

*A foreign producer k sets q so as to maximize its foreign currency profit given byk

(4), while the subsidiary of investing firm i sets x so as to maximize its reducedi

form profit given by (3). Using (10) and (11), the best response of firm k satisfies:

b(N 1 1)]]]* * *a 2 ec 1 (mx 2 (m 1 1)q ) 5 0 (12)(N 2 m)

* *where symmetry is imposed (q 5q , ;k; x 5x, ;i). From (9), (10) and (11), wek i

can calculate the net reduced profit of firm i from any choice of x . The besti

response for firm i satisfies (imposing symmetry of actions chosen):

2]]] * * *(a 2 ec 1 bmx 2 bm q )F G(m 1 1)

b(N 1 1)]]]* * *2 a 2 ec 1 ((m 1 1)x 2 m q ) 5 0 (13)F G(N 2 m)

The first expression in square brackets represents the marginal effect on firm i’sprofits derived from the sales of the final good as a result of raising rivals’ costs.The symmetric best response x must be such that this marginal gain is just offsetby the additional resources lost in buying the intermediate good at a higher price

* *p (compared to its own constant marginal cost c ). The Nash equilibrium valuesof x and q are readily obtained from (12) and (13):

* *q 5 a(m)(a 2 ec ) (14)

*x 5 b(m)(a 2 ec ) (15)

*and total output Q available for noninvesting firms is given by:

* * * *Q 5 m q 2 mx 5 (N 2 m)r 5 g(m)(a 2 ec ) (16)

where the terms a(m), b(m) and g(m) are given by:

Page 11: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 263

a(m)

(N 2 m)(N 1 2m 1 1)(m 1 1)]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]5 3 2 2 *b(N 1 1)[(m 1 1) 1 (N 2 m)(m 1 1) 1 ((m 1 1) 1 (N 2 m)(m 1 1))m ]

2*a(m)bm [(m 1 1) 1 (N 2 m)(m 2 1)] 2 (N 2 m)(m 2 1)]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]]b(m) 5 3 2b[(m 1 1) 1 (N 2 m)(m 1 1)]

*g(m) 5 m a(m) 2 mb(m)

for m50, 1,...,N21. Note that a(m), b(m) and g(m) are independent of e. It canbe checked that a(m) and g(m) are strictly positive for all values of m,N, whileb(m) can be positive or negative which suggests that x may take positive ornegative values in equilibrium. If all firms invest that is, m5N, the intermediategood market disappears. We then set a(N)5b(N)5g(N)50 and the game reducesto a N-firm symmetric Cournot game where the marginal cost of each firm is given

˜ *by ec . From (10) and (16):

1 (N 1 1)bg(m)]]] ]]]]* * *ep 5 ec 1 1 2 a 2 ec $ 0 (17)s dF G(m 1 1) (N 2 m)

Using (6), (9) and (17), the profit of firm j from the reduced form game in thesecond stage (with m investing firms and given e) is:

2(g(m))2]]] *P (mue) 5 a 2 ec . 0 (18)s dj 2(N 2 m)

Using (5), (8), (15) and (17), the reduced form profit of firm i is:

2*P (mue) 5 V(m) a 2 ec . 0 (19)s di

where V(m) is given by:

21 (1 2 bg(m)) bg(m)(N 1 1)]]] ]]]] ]]]]V(m) 5 2 bb(m) 1 2F GF G S Db(m 1 1) (m 1 1) (N 2 m)

for m51,...,N. Note that V(m) is independent of e and it can be checked that V(m)is strictly positive. If m50 that is, no firm invests, then the profit of an investingfirm is not defined. This completes our derivation of the equilibrium in stage 2.

Before concluding this section, we wish to make certain points about the extentof exchange rate pass-through in our model, in particular, about the effect ofexchange rate movement on the domestic currency price of intermediate goods

*ep , as well as the final good price p. Taking the partial derivative of (17) with* *respect to e and multiplying by (e /ep ) gives the elasticity of ep with respect to

e:

Page 12: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

264 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

*c 1 b(N 1 1)g(m)] ]]] ]]]]]h 5 1 2 1F G1 *p (m 1 1) (m 1 1)(N 2 m)

Similarly, substituting (17) into (7) we can derive the elasticity of p with respectto e:

*ec m 1 bg(m)] ]]]h 5 F G2 p (m 1 1)

The above expressions indicate that there are three main determinants of thepass-through coefficients: the relative number of investing firms, the number offoreign producers of the intermediate good and the ratio of actual marginal cost to

*price. Of course, both p and p are endogenously determined in the model and sothe elasticity captures local response of the equilibrium values to exchange ratechanges. As the expressions turn out to be large, we solve numerically for the two

*elasticities for different values of m and m , while fixing the other parameters.Figs. 1 and 2 plot the relationship between m and the pass-through elasticities, for

˜* *alternative values of m when N510, a5100, b51, c 51 and e is taken to be*deterministic with value equal to 1. We observe that given m , as m increases (for

Fig. 1. Exchange rate pass-through: Elasticity of the domestic currency price of intermediate good (h )1

plotted against the number of vertically investing firms m, for alternative number of foreign* * *intermediate firms m . (The lowest curve corresponds to m 55, the next higher to m 523 and the

*highest to m 530.)

Page 13: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 265

Fig. 2. Exchange rate pass-through: Elasticity of final good price (h ) plotted against the number of2

*vertically investing firms m, for alternative number of foreign intermediate firms m . (The lowest curve* * *corresponds to m 55, the next higher to m 523 and the highest to m 530.)

example, in response to a reduction in f as discussed below) the pass-throughelasticities increase as the input market becomes increasingly competitive.

*Similarly, increase in m also increases the pass-through elasticities. It is worthnoting that the absolute values of pass-through elasticities are quite small. To seewhy, let us go through the following sequential reasoning. An increase in e leadsto an increase in the realized cost structure of final good producers which in turn,depresses the derived demand for the intermediate good by noninvesting firms.The latter has a depressing effect on the intermediate good price so that the net

*effect on ep of a movement in e tends to be small. This also means that the neteffect on final good price p is small.

4. Equilibrium of reduced form investment game

In this section, we analyze the strategic foreign investment decisions of the Nfinal good firms, where the payoff from each profile of investment decisions is theexpected profit from stage 2 equilibrium, as derived in the previous section, net ofinvestment cost. At the point of time in which the N domestic final good firmsmake their investment decisions, exchange rate uncertainty is not yet resolved.

Page 14: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

266 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

¯ ¯Suppose that m (0,m ,N) firms invest. Then, using (19), the payoff to the¯ ¯investing firms i 51, 2,...,m denoted by R (m ) is given by:i

2] ] ]˜ ˜ *R (m) 5 EP (mue ) 2 f 5 V(m)E[(a 2 ec ) ] 2 f (20)i i

where E is the expectation operator with respect to the uncertainty caused by˜ ¯exchange rate e. Using (18), the payoff to a noninvesting firm j51, 2,...,N2m,¯denoted by R (m ), is given by:j

2](g(m)) 2] ] ˜ ˜]]] *R (m) 5 EP (mue ) 5 E[(a 2 ec ) ] (21)j j 2](N 2m)

¯If m5N, that is, all firms invest, then the payoff to each firm i is also obtained¯from (20). If m50, that is, no firm invests, the payoff to each firm j is given by

(21).¯ ¯A Nash equilibrium of this game where exactly m firms, m51, 2,...,N21,

undertake foreign investment exists if and only if, given the investment decisionsof other firms, two conditions hold:

(a) a firm which invests cannot gain by deviating, that is, not investing (in which¯case there would be only (m21) investing firms):

¯ ¯R (m ) $ R (m 2 1) (22)i j

(b) a firm which does not invest cannot gain by deviating, that is, by¯undertaking to invest (in which case there would be (m 11) investing firms):

¯ ¯R (m ) $ R (m 1 1) (23)j i

¯An equilibrium where all N firms invest exists if and only if (22) holds at m5N.¯An equilibrium where no firm invests exists if and only if (23) holds at m50.

For m50, 1,...,N21, let f(m) denote the ‘‘gain from investment’’ that is, theincrease in expected profit (gross of the fixed cost of investment) of a firm whichchanges its decision from ‘‘no investment’’ to ‘‘investment’’, in a situation wherethere are exactly m other investing firms. More formally:

˜ ˜f(m) 5 E(P (m 1 1ue )) 2 E(P (mue )) (24)i j

which, using (18) and (19), implies:

2(g(m)) 2˜]]] *f(m) 5 V(m 1 1) 2 E[(a 2 ec ) ] (25)F G2(N 2 m)

It can be verified that f(m) is strictly positive for m50, 1,...,N21. The necessaryand sufficient conditions (22) and (23) for Nash equilibrium can now be rewrittenin terms of a relation between the gain from investment f(m) and the fixed cost ofinvestment f :

Page 15: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 267

Proposition 1. In a Nash equilibrium of the reduced form investment game,¯ ¯exactly m firms, m51, 2,...,N21, undertake foreign investment if and only if :

¯ ¯f(m ) # f # f(m 2 1) (26)

¯There exists an equilibrium where all firms invest (m5N) if and only if :

f # f(N 2 1) (27)

¯There exists an equilibrium where no firm invests (m50) if and only if :

f $ f(0) (28)

In our model, the number of firms which invest in equilibrium reflects the flowof vertical foreign investment. The fixed cost of investment, in part, reflectsbarriers to foreign direct investment.

It is of interest to see how one can characterize the flow of foreign investment asa function of the level of fixed cost f, given the function f(m). Note that if

¯f(m21),f(m) for some m, then (26) cannot hold at m5m, for any level of f.This means that there is no equilibrium with exactly m firms investing. In suchsituation, what can we say about the amount of investment if we know that fexceeds or lies below f(m) for a certain m? The following result is useful in thiscontext:

Proposition 2. (i) For m51, 2,...,N, if f $f(m21), then there exists at least oneequilibrium where strictly less than m firms invest;

(ii) For, m50, 1, 2,...,N21, if f #f(m), then there exists at least oneequilibrium where strictly greater than m firms invest.

¯Proof: (i) If f $f(0)5f(121), then m50 is an equilibrium which proves theproposition. So consider the case where f ,f(0) and suppose that, contrary to the

¯proposition, there is no equilibrium with m50, 1, 2,...,m21. Using Proposition 1,¯as (26) does not hold for m51, 2,...,m21, one can show by induction (starting¯ ¯from f ,f(0)), that f ,f(m21), m51, 2,...,m which, in particular, implies that

f ,f(m21), a contradiction.¯(ii) If f #f(N21), then m5N is an equilibrium which proves the proposition.

So consider the case where f(N21),f #f(m) for some m,N21 and suppose¯that, contrary to the proposition, there is no equilibrium with m5m11, m12,...,N.

¯Using Proposition 1, as (26) does not hold for m5m11,...,N, it follows by¯ ¯induction (start from f .f(N21)), that f .f(m ), m5N21, N22,...,m, a

contradiction. i

The intuition behind Proposition 2 is simple. As we have said earlier, f(m21),m51, 2,...,N, reflects the additional gain from becoming an investor when (m21)firms are already investing. If f exceeds this additional gain, it appears reasonable

Page 16: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

268 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

that in equilibrium less than m firms should be investing. On the other hand, if ffalls below this level, more than (m21) firms should be investing. It thereforestands to reason that as the barriers to investment go down, the flow of investmentshould increase. One has to be a bit careful in stating this however, as equilibriumis not necessarily unique. For f .0, let M( f ) be the set defined by:

M( f )

¯ ¯5 hm :m firms undertaking foreign investment is an equilibrium, given f j

Proposition 3. If f ,f , then1 2

(i) if m [M( f ), then there exists m [M( f ) such that m #m ;1 1 2 2 2 1

(ii) if m [M( f ), then there exists m [M( f ) such that m $m ;2 2 1 1 1 2

Proof. (i) If m 5N, then the statement holds by definition. So consider the case1

where m ,N. From Proposition 1, (26) and (28) imply that f .f $f(m ). Using1 2 1 1

Proposition 2, we obtain that there exists at least one equilibrium at f5f , where2

less than m firms invest.1

(ii) If m 50, the statement holds by definition. So consider the case where2

m .0. From Proposition (1), (26) and (27), it follows that f ,f #f(m 21).2 1 2 2

Using Proposition 2, f ,f(m 21) implies that there exists at least one equilib-1 2

rium at f5f , where more than m firms invest. i1 2

One of the implications of Proposition 3 is that the maximum and the minimumnumber of firms which invest in equilibrium at any level of f, decreases as fincreases. Further, if equilibrium is unique at f and f , the number of firms1 2

investing at f is always at least as large as the number of firms investing at f ; for1 2

values of f close to certain critical values, an increase in f can lead to a strictdecline in the number of firms investing.

Consider the behaviour of the function f(m). Suppose that the function f isdecreasing over integer values of m going from 0 to (N21), that is

f(0) $ f(1) $ ... $ f(N 2 1) (29)

As more and more other firms invest, the additional gain from becoming aninvestor, decreases. In this case, the correspondence M( f ) is very well behaved.The range of possible values of f can be divided into a finite chain of intervals h[0,f(N21)], [f(N21), f(N22)],..., [f(1), f(0)], [f(0), `)j, nonintersecting exceptat end points. The equilibrium number of firms is unique in the interior of eachinterval. As the value of f moves from a higher to a consecutive lower interval, the

16number of firms investing in Nash equilibrium goes up by exactly one.

16 ¯Note that in this case, for any m50, 1, 2,...,N, there is always a nonempty interval such that if f¯lies in this interval, it is an equilibrium for exactly m firms to invest. This is not necessarily so if f is

not decreasing in m.

Page 17: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 269

However, f(m) is not necessarily decreasing; it can also be increasing in m overa subset of the possible values of m. The behaviour of f(m) depends on theexpected profit from the product market accruing to investors and noninvestorscorresponding to various configurations of investment. If f(m) is monotonicdecreasing as in (29), then the market profits are such that investment by firms arestrategic substitutes; more other firms invest, the less worthwhile it is for anoninvestor to invest. This is actually something one would normally expect. Onthe other hand, f(m) increasing over a range of values of m implies that there isstrategic complementarity between investment decisions of firms. As the numberof firms which invest goes up, there might actually be greater incentive for anoninvestor to become an investor. The reason behind this is that the strategicactions of the investing firms in the upstream market designed to raise theintermediate good price might become more damaging as the number of investing

17firms increases, so that the relative disadvantage of being a noninvestor increases.There are two interesting features of foreign investment flows that can occur as

a consequence of strategic complementarity of investment that is, of f increasingin m. The first feature is that there can be a relatively large increase in the amountof foreign investment when f falls just below a critical level. To see this, suppose f

exhibits the following nonmonotonic behaviour:

¯ ¯ ¯f(N 2 1) , f(N 2 2) , ... , f(m ) , f(m 2 1) . f(m 2 2)... . f(0) (30)

¯For f .f(m21), the only equilibrium is that no firm invests. However, if f is¯reduced to a level just below f(m21), there is an equilibrium where the number

¯of firms investing is m which implies a jump in the flow of foreign investment, the¯size of the jump depending on how large m is. The second interesting consequence

of strategic complementarity is the possibility of multiple equilibria. In thesituation described by (30), one can easily check (using Proposition 1) that for

¯f [[f(0), f(m21)], there are two equilibria, one in which no firm invests and the¯other in which at least m firms invest. The fact that there can be multiple

equilibria, some with large investment flows and others with little or none, bringsout the importance of coordination devices as an instrument of securing a boost inforeign direct investment. This also illustrates the so-called bandwagon effect orherding in investment behaviour; firms invest when many others decide to do so,but would rather refrain from investing otherwise. If investment decisions exhibitstrategic complementarity globally that is, the function f(m) is always increasingin m:

f(0) # f(1) # ... # f(N 2 1) (31)

then we have an extreme form of herding. There are just two possible equilibrium

17If our model is modified such that investing firms are not allowed to make strategic purchaseupstream in order to raise noninvesting rivals’ costs, that is, we put an exogenous constraint x #0, theni

it can be shown that f(m) is always decreasing in m.

Page 18: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

270 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

outcomes viz., either all firms invest or no firm invests. For f .f(0), the only¯ ¯outcome is that no firm invests whereas for f #f(0), m50 and m5N are the two

equilibrium outcomes. This implies that as f just falls below f(0), there can be areally big jump in investment. However, there is a coordination problem. Firmswill invest only if they think all their rivals will do so.

Figs. 3–5 illustrate the function f(m) for different parameter configurations. In˜*all three figures N510, a5100, b51, c 51 and e is taken to be deterministic

*with value equal to 1. Fig. 3 depicts the situation when m 55. Here f(m) isdecreasing in m everywhere as in (29) and investment decisions are strategic

*substitutes. Fig. 4 depicts the case where m 523. In this case, f(m) is increasingfor small values of m and decreasing thereafter, as in (30). Fig. 5 depicts the

*situation where m 530. In this case, f(m) is strictly increasing in m everywhereso that investment decisions are strategic complements globally.

For the case where N52, it is easy to verify that f(0)#f(1) i.e. the situation*depicted in (31) obtains for any configuration of parameter values if m .4, while

*at m 51, it is always the case that f(0)$f(1) i.e. the situation depicted in (29)obtains. The general conclusion obtained by plotting the function f(m) for variousalternative parameter configurations is that, other things being equal, for low

* *values of m investment decisions are strategic substitutes while for m largeenough, they are strategic complements.

Thus, the extent to which firms may engage in foreign investment hinges on a

Fig. 3. Investment decisions are strategic substitutes: f(m) is globally decreasing in m.

Page 19: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 271

Fig. 4. Investment decisions exhibit strategic complementarity when m is small: f(m) is initiallyincreasing in m.

crucial factor: the degree of concentration in the intermediate good market. Lowconcentration in this market leads to a conventional result viz., the larger thenumber of final good firms which invest abroad vertically, the less is the incentivefor an individual firm to undertake foreign investment. On the other hand, with ahigh level of concentration in the foreign intermediate good market, an increase inthe number of final good firms undertaking investment can increase the incentiveto invest abroad for an individual firm leading to herding in investment decisions,multiple equilibria and a positive role for coordination activities. The reason is thatwhen the number of foreign producers in the intermediate good market is small,the market price is relatively high. This implies that not many producers of thefinal good will purchase inputs from the market and those that do, will produce arelatively smaller output as they will have a relatively high marginal costcompared to investing firms. Then, a final good firm’s incentive to ‘‘raise rivalscost’’ by strategic purchase is likely to be very low and the incremental gain frominvesting comes mostly from the conventional cost reducing aspect i.e., purchasinginput at lower ‘‘marginal price’’. The more the number of rival firms which invest,the lower is the increase in profit from the final good market achieved through thelower cost resulting from investment. On the other hand, when there is a very largenumber of foreign producers in the intermediate good market, the equilibriummarket price of the intermediate good tends to be low which means a lot of final

Page 20: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

272 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

Fig. 5. Investment decisions are strategic complements everywhere: f(m) is globally increasing in m.

good firms will find it attractive to rely on the market to procure the intermediategood. This, in turn, means that strategic purchase by investing firms can have asignificantly large effect on their Cournot profit by raising the rivals’ costs and asthe market price of the intermediate good is low, it is not very costly to indulge insuch strategic purchase. This means that a significant part of the gain fromincremental investment comes from the ability to raise rivals cost which it conferson investing firms. The more the number of noninvesting final good firms, thegreater is the effect of strategic purchase designed to raise their cost in the finalgood market and hence, the greater the increase in profit resulting from investment

18by an individual final good firm.

5. Effect of change in exchange rate

The expected profits of final good firms resulting from any given investmentprofile (contained in (20) and (21)) depend on the random exchange rate. We haveassumed that firms are ex ante risk neutral, that is, maximize expected profits. Theexpression for expected profit (gross of the fixed cost of investment) of any finalgood firm, whether or not the firm invests, is multiplicatively separable into two

18We thank an anonymous referee for this explanation.

Page 21: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 273

˜terms—one of which is positive and independent of e and the other is E[(a22 2˜ ˜ ˜*ec ) ]. Observe that [(a2ec*) ] is a strictly convex function of e. Therefore,

2˜ *E[(a2ec ) ], and hence the expected profit, increases whenever, ceteris paribus,there is a second-order stochastic decrease (for example, an increase in themean-preserving spread) of the distribution of the exchange rate. A second orderstochastic decrease is equivalent to an increase in risk (see Rothschild and Stiglitz,1970). It follows that if the forward exchange rate market is unbiased (forward

˜rate is equal to the expected value of e ), final good firms will prefer not to hedgeagainst the exchange rate risk. To summarize:

Proposition 4. Given any profile of investment decisions, an increase in exchangerate risk (a second order decrease in the distribution of exchange rate) leads to anincrease in the expected profit for both investing as well as noninvesting domesticfirms. If a forward market exists and is unbiased, final good firms will not hedgeagainst the exchange rate risk.

The basic intuition behind Proposition 4 is that with an increase in the spread ofthe exchange rate, the profitability of production increases when there is afavourable realization of the exchange rate and this increase is stronger than thedecrease in profitability in case of relatively unfavourable realizations of theexchange rate.

Now, an increase in exchange rate variability increases the expected net profit ofboth investing as well as noninvesting firms. Therefore, it is not immediately clearwhat the net effect on the equilibrium investment profile is. Obviously, therelevant consideration here is the gain in expected profit when a noninvestorbecomes an investor, which means that we should be looking at the effect ofincrease in exchange rate risk on the function f(m). To look at f as a function of

˜both m and e, we can rewrite (25):

2(g(m))2˜ ˜]]] *f(m, e ) 5 V(m 1 1) 2 E a 2 ec (32)s dF G2(N 2 m)

Note that exchange rate uncertainty enters the gain from investment only through2˜ *the term E[(a2ec ) ]. As the expression enclosed in square brackets in (32) is

strictly positive, for any m,N the gain from undertaking foreign investment f(m)19increases with any increase in exchange rate variability. More specifically,

˜consider two possible exchange rate situations and let e denote the randomh

19In a model of hysteresis involving entry and exit costs by final goods producers, Dixit (1989) hasshown the existence of a zone of inaction by firms and that this zone is increasing with the degree ofexchange rate uncertainty. In our model, despite the absence of exit sunk costs, exchange rateuncertainty increases both the gain from investment (see (32)) and the interval of inaction defined by(26).

Page 22: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

274 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

exchange rate in these situations (h51, 2). Assume that the distribution of theexchange rate in situation 1 has a second-order stochastic dominance over that insituation 2. Situation 2 is one of greater exchange rate risk. Then,

˜ ˜f(m, e ) # f(m, e ), m 5 0, 1,...,N 2 1. (33)1 2

It follows intuitively that the equilibrium number of firms investing in situation 2should be at least as large as that in situation 1, for any given level of f. As ourmodel contains possibility of multiple equilibria, the exact sense in which theequilibrium number of firms goes up must be carefully specified. Recall that weused the notation M( f ) to denote the set of equilibrium outcomes (in terms of thenumber of firms that undertake investment) when fixed cost of investment equals f.

˜To bring in the effect of exchange rate variability, let us now denote it by M( f, e ).˜ ˜We want to see how, for any given f, the sets M( f, e ) and M( f, e ) compare.1 2

˜ ˜Proposition 5. Suppose e has a second order stochastic dominance over e .1 2

Then,˜ ˜(i) for any m [M( f, e ), there exists m [M( f, e ) such that m $m ;1 1 2 2 2 1

˜ ˜(ii) for any m [M( f, e ), there exists m [M( f, e ) such that m $m .2 2 1 1 2 1

˜Proof. (i) Suppose m [M( f, e ). If m 50, then it is clear that there must be some1 1 1

˜m [M( f, e ), such that m $m . If m .0, then it follows from (26) and (27) that:2 2 2 1 1

˜f # f(m 2 1,e ) (34)1 1

which, using (33), implies that

˜f # f(m 2 1,e ) (35)1 2

Proposition 2 implies then that there exists an equilibrium in situation 2 where at˜least m firms invest. (ii) Suppose m [M( f, e ). If m 5N, then it is clear that1 2 2 2

˜there must be some m [M( f, e ), such that m $m . If m ,N, then it follows from1 1 2 1 2

(26) and (27) that:

˜f $ f(m 2 1, e ) (36)2 2

which, using (33), implies that

˜f $ f(m 2 1, e ) (37)2 1

Proposition 2 implies that there is an equilibrium in situation 1 where less than m2

firms invest. i

One of the implications of Proposition 5 is that for any given f, both themaximum as well as the minimum number of firms which invest in equilibrium isnondecreasing in exchange rate risk.

Page 23: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 275

˜ ˜If e has a strict second order dominance over e , then (using the fact that1 22˜ ˜*(a2ec ) is strictly convex in e ) from (32):

˜ ˜f(m, e ) , f(m, e ), m 5 0, 1,...,N 2 1 (38)1 2

This implies that, compared to situation 1, there is a strictly greater incentive toinvest in situation 2 in terms of the additional gain from investment at any givenlevel of m. It is intuitive, therefore, that for certain intervals of values of f, therewill be strictly greater foreign investment under situation 2.

˜ ˜Proposition 6. Suppose e has a strict second order stochastic dominance over e .1 2]]˜ ˜Then, for m50, 1, 2,...,N21 and f [[f(m, e ), f(m, e ], there always exist m ,1 2 1

˜ ˜m where m #m,m , m [M( f, e ) and m [M( f, e ), that is, one can always2 1 2 1 1 2 2

select a pair of equilibria, one for each exchange rate situation, such that notmore than m firms invest in the equilibrium in situation 1 and strictly greater thanm firms invest in the equilibrium pertaining to situation 2.

˜ ˜Proof. Consider m,N and f [[f(m, e ), f(m, e )]. From Proposition 2, we can1 2

˜ ˜see that as f $f(m, e )5f((m11)21, e ), there exists an equilibrium at fixed1 1

cost level f in situation 1 where strictly less than m11 firms invest. Thus there˜ ˜exists m [M( f, e ) where m #m. Similarly, as f #f(m, e ), from Proposition 21 1 1 2

˜we have that there exists m [M( f, e ) where m .m. i2 2 2

Proposition 5 states that an increase in exchange rate volatility does not decreasethe total volume of vertical foreign investment. Proposition 6 indicates that forcertain intervals of values for the level of fixed cost, there is a strict increase in thelevel of foreign investment following a strict increase in exchange rate risk. Using(7), one can observe that an increase in exchange rate variability by affecting mpositively leads to a fall in expected domestic final good price p and as a resultantan increase in the total output sold in the final good market which, in our model, isexactly the total volume of trade. While domestic consumer surplus is positivelyaffected as a result, the effect on net social surplus is ambiguous as it is influenced(somewhat arbitrarily) by the level of fixed cost of investment.

The empirical literature has provided mixed answers concerning the linkbetween exchange rate uncertainty and direct investment. While a large class ofempirical studies have dealt with horizontal direct investment, their results are notfully comparable to those of Propositions 5 and 6 derived in the context of verticalinvestment. In a direct test of the model by Dixit (1989), Campa (1993) findsexchange rate volatility to be negatively correlated with entry events that occurredin 61 U.S. wholesale industries. In a different context, Goldberg and Kolstad(1995) show that the effect of short-term exchange rate volatility is to increase theshare of production activity that is located offshore. Empirical work concerningexchange rate uncertainty and vertical direct investment is rare. An exception is

Page 24: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

276 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

case III of Cushman (1985) that assumes, as in our paper, the use of anintermediate good which is imported from a foreign subsidiary. The results supportthe hypothesis that increases in exchange rate risk consistently raise directinvestment. In addition, Cushman found that foreign subsidiaries have alsoincreased exports of intermediates to the home country.

5.1. Change in the level of exchange rate

In order to study the effect of a change in the level of exchange rate, assume˜that there is no exchange rate uncertainty that is, e5e, where

*0 , e , (a /c )

is a deterministic number. Note that ceteris paribus, an increase in e increases the*domestic currency equivalent of the arm’s length price (ep ) as well as that of the

*unit cost of producing directly through a subsidiary (ec ). Further, the consequent*changes in demand for the intermediate good leads to changes in p . So, the net

effect on the relative profitability of direct production vis-a-vis purchase from themarket is not obvious. However, our earlier analysis of exchange rate pass-throughin Section 3 indicates that the elasticity of domestic currency price of intermediategood with respect to a change in e(h ) is quite low (see Fig. 1). Therefore, one1

would expect that an increase in e would make purchase from the market moreattractive than direct production. This is precisely what we show:

Proposition 7. A depreciation of the investor’s home currency (increase in e)always leads to a decrease in the strategic incentive to invest; the gain frominvestment for a firm ( given the investment decisions of rival firms) decreases.

This result follows directly from (32); for any m#(N21), f(m, e) is strictlydecreasing in e. Thus, when e increases, the incentive to undertake directinvestment (and replace inter-firm trade by intra-firm trade) decreases. Thus, ourmodel provides another explanation of the effect of change in exchange rate level

20on FDI as observed empirically (see, for example, Cushman, 1988; Caves, 1989).

6. Conclusion

We have shown that the strategic incentive to undertake vertical foreigninvestment by oligopolistic downstream firms may increase as more firms invest,

20The mechanism through which change in exchange rate level affects FDI in our model is differentfrom those found in the existing literature. For example, currency movements can affect the relativewealth of firms across countries and therefore the relative ability to undertake mergers or acquisitions(see, Froot and Stein, 1991; Klein and Rosengren, 1994).

Page 25: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 277

leading to possibility of herding in foreign investment decisions. A small declinein the fixed cost of investment can lead to a big jump in the flow of investment.There can be multiple equilibria some involving lot of firms investing and others,very few, thus opening up room for coordination efforts. We have also shown that,contrary to popular conjectures advocated by governments and various internation-al organizations, an increase in exchange rate volatility has a positive effect onvertical foreign investment and on trade in intermediate goods. An appreciation ofthe investor’s currency also has a similar effect.

Our results are derived for the specific case of linear demand and cost functions.Under more general demand and cost structures, the effect of exchange rateuncertainty could be ambiguous or even reversed. In addition, our model does notcapture barriers to vertical foreign investment due to entry deterring activities byincumbents in the intermediate good market abroad. Alternative models of verticalforeign investment could therefore be used to study questions similar to thoseraised in our model. It is our understanding that qualitatively similar results can bederived in a model where intermediate good firms invest upstream. If, instead ofdomestic firms setting up their own subsidiaries, we allowed for vertical mergers,then the input-price-raising effect of vertical investment would be even sharper asthe total number of firms willing to supply positive quantity in the input marketwould be smaller. Another interesting extension of our model would be one whichallows for two-way strategic vertical investments by international oligopolisticfirms, located upstream as well as downstream.

Acknowledgements

We thank Rafael Eldor, Henrick Horn, Stephen Martin, Itzhak Zilcha andseminar participants at the Tinbergen Institute, Tel Aviv University, IndianStatistical Institute, Delhi, the 1996 Instanbul Meeting of the European EconomicAssociation and the 1997 Toulouse Meeting of the Econometric Society for usefulsuggestions. The second author thanks the University of Konstanz for itshospitality and the SEW-Eurodrive Stiftung for financial assistance. Researchassistance from Daisy Kersemakers and U. Sachs is gratefully acknowledged. Thecurrent version has considerably benefitted from the comments made by twoanonymous referees and a coeditor of this journal.

Appendix A

Glossary of Symbols

N 5number of firms in the final good marketm 5number of investing firms (subscript i)

Page 26: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

278 S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279

N2m 5number of noninvesting firms (subscript j)*m 5number of foreign producers of the intermediate good (subscript k)

e 5exchange rate (domestic price of foreign currency)p 5domestic price of the final good

*p 5foreign currency price of the intermediate good*c 5foreign currency marginal cost of producing one unit of inter-

mediateq 5final good output of investing firm ii

r 5final good output of noninvesting firm jj

Q 5aggregate output of the final goodx 5firm i’s net purchase of the intermediate goodi

*q 5output of foreign intermediate good by firm kk

*Q 5aggregate output of the intermediate goodP 5gross profit of investing firm ii

R 5net payoff of investing firm ii

P 5profit of noninvesting firm jj

R 5profit of noninvesting firm jj

*P 5gross profit of intermediate producer kk

f 5fixed cost of vertical investment˜M( f, e ) 5set of equilibrium outcomes in terms of the number of firms

investing (also denoted by M( f ))f(m) 5expected gain from investment (reduced form), gross of the fixed

cost of investment, when m rival firms invest.

References

Belderbos, R., 1997. Japanese electronics multinationals and strategic trade policies. Oxford UniversityPress, Oxford.

Bolton, P., Whinston, M.D., 1991. The ‘‘foreclosure’’ effect of vertical mergers. Journal of Institutionaland Theoretical Economics 147, 207–226.

Broll, W., Zilcha, I., 1992. Exchange rate uncertainty, futures markets and the multinational firm.European Economic Review 36, 815–826.

Campa, J.M., 1993. Entry by foreign firms in the United States under exchange rate uncertainty.Review of Economics and Statistics 75, 614–622.

Caves, R., 1996. Multinational enterprise and economic analysis. Cambridge University Press,Cambridge.

Caves, R., 1989. Exchange rate movements and foreign investments in the United States. In: Audretsch,D.B., Claudon, M.P. (Eds.), The internationalization of U.S. markets. New York University Press,New York, pp. 199–228.

Cushman, D., 1985. Real exchange rate risk, expectations, and the level of direct investment. Review ofEconomics and Statistics 67, 297–308.

Cushman, D., 1988. Exchange rate uncertainty and foreign direct investment in the United States.Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 124, 322–336.

Dellas, M., Zilberfarb, B.-Z., 1993. Real exchange rate variability and international trade: A reexamination of the theory. Southern Economic Journal 4, 641–647.

Page 27: On strategic vertical foreign investment Santanu Roy ...faculty.smu.edu/sroy/JIE98.pdf · Santanu Roy , Jean-Marie Viaenea, a,b* aDepartment of Economics ,Erasmus University P .O

S. Roy, J. Viaene / Journal of International Economics 46 (1998) 253 –279 279

Dixit, A., 1989. Entry and exit decisions under uncertainty. Journal of Political Economy 97, 620–638.Dornbusch, R., 1987. Exchange rates and prices. American Economic Review 77, 93–106.Froot, K., Stein, J., 1991. Exchange rates and foreign direct investment: An imperfect capital markets

approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 1191–1217.Goldberg, L.S., Kolstad, C.D., 1995. Foreign direct investment, exchange rate variability and demand

uncertainty. International Economic Review 36, 855–873.Grossman, S.J., Hart, O.D., 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral

integration. Journal of Political Economy 94, 691–719.Hart, O.D., Tirole, J., 1990. Vertical integration and market foreclosure. Brookings Papers on Economic

Activity: Microeconomics, pp. 205–286.Horstmann, I., Markusen, J.R., 1987. Strategic investments and the development of multinationals.

International Economic Review 28, 109–121.Klein, M.W., Rosengren, E., 1994. The real exchange rate and foreign direct investment in the United

States: Relative wealth vs. relative wage effects. Journal of International Economics 36, 373–389.Knickerbocker, F., 1973. Oligopolistic reaction and multinational enterprise. Harvard Business School,

Division of Research, Boston.Markusen, J.R., 1995. The boundaries of multinational enterprises and the theory of international trade.

Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, 169–189.Matsuyama, K., 1995. Complementarities and cumulative processes in models of monopolistic

competition. Journal of Economic Literature XX–XIII, 701–729.Motta, M., 1992. Multinationals and the tariff-jumping argument: A game theoretic analysis with some

unconventional conclusions. European Economic Review 36, 1557–1572.Mullin, J., Mullin, W., 1996. United States Steel’s acquisition of the Great Northern Ore Properties:

Vertical foreclosure or efficient contractual governance. NBER Working Paper [5662.Murphy, K., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1989. Industrialization and the big push. Journal of Political

Economy 97, 1003–1026.Ordover, J., Saloner, G., Salop, S.C., 1990. Equilibrium vertical foreclosure. American Economic

Review 80, 127–142.Rosengren, E., Meehan, Jr. J., 1994. Empirical evidence on vertical foreclosure. Economic Inquiry 32,

303–317.Salinger, M.A., 1988. Vertical mergers and market foreclosure. Quarterly Journal of Economics 103,

345–356.Salop, S.C., Scheffman, D.T., 1983. Raising rivals’ costs. American Economic Review 73, 267–271.Salop, S.C., Scheffman, D.T., 1987. Cost-raising strategies. Journal of Industrial Economics 36, 19–34.Smith, A., 1987. Strategic investment, multinational corporations and trade policy. European Economic

Review 31, 89–96.Schrader, A., Martin, S., 1995. Vertical market participation. Mimeo, Department of Economics,

European University Institute, Florence.Rothschild, M., Stiglitz, J.E., 1970. Increasing risk I: A definition. Journal of Economic Theory 2,

225–243.UNCTAD, 1993. World investment report 1993: Transnational corporations and integrated international

production. United Nations, New York.UNCTAD, 1994. World investment report 1994: Transnational corporations, employment and work-

place. United Nations, New York.Vernon, R., 1993. Where are the multinationals headed? In: K. Froot (Ed.), Foreign Direct Investment.

The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 57–83.Wells, L., 1993. Mobile exporters: New foreign investors in east Asia. In: Froot, K. (Ed.), Foreign

Direct Investment. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 173–196.Yoffie, D., 1993. Foreign direct investment in semiconductors. In: Froot, K. (Ed.), Foreign Direct

Investment. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 197–228.Yu, C.J., Ito, K., 1988. Oligopolistic reaction and foreign direct investment. Journal of International

Business Studies 19, 449–460.