Top Banner
CHAPTER 111 THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS A GENERAL SURVEY There was a remarkable improvement in a number of central balance of payments areas in 1976. Most notable are a considerable reduction of the deficit in the current account, a rapid increase in exports, especially in industrial exports, and an improvement in deifcit ifnancing. The latter was expressed by a remarkable increase in the weight of unilateral transactions and a decrease in .that of loans, but mainly by a halting of the growing dependence on shortterm sources for current deifcit financing. These developments brought relief to the shortterm problems of the balance of pay ments, and removed the danger of a financing crisis. They also reflect the creation of conditions which promise continuation of the improvement by means of economic restraint. These conditions are a vital component in any strategy for solving the balance of payments problem. Unfortunately these developments were achieved at a great price a third year of standstill in economic growth. Despite the positive aspects of these developments, in as far as the balance of payments is concerned, they are mostly related to the immediate inlfuence of restraint and the formation of a basis for further improvement. They have less effect on the core of the problem: the need to bring about a structural change that will get the economy out of its present standstill and return it to a course of growth, while at the same time continuing to reduce the deficit. Where relative prices and export proiftability are concerned, there is still a wide gap between objectives and achievements. Some indicators show that recent changes are in the irght direction. However, they may represent only a partial correction of the decrease in export profitability since 1972. FinaUy, considering the change in allocation of resources in the economy, the progress towards desired objectives which waS achieved in 1976 is not unequivocal. Recently, the share of consumption in the increment of resources has actually increased in comparison to 1972. There was in fact a change in this trend duirng 1976, expressed by the increase in the share of export, but this increase relfects not only rapid growth in exports, but also a considerable drop in the weight of domestic investment. 1. The Balance of Payments Problem Developments in the balance of payments situation, and in particular the remarkable decrease of the cunent account deifcit, are only one part of a complex picture. In order to evaluate their real signiifcance, it is necessary to comprehend the relative weight of inlfuences related to various levels of the problem: external factors, both incidental and CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS GENERAL SURVEY 41
19

OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

Jul 09, 2021

Download

Documents

dariahiddleston
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

CHAPTER 111

THE BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ A GENERAL SURVEY

There was a remarkable improvement in a number of central balance of payments areas in1976. Most notable are a considerable reduction of the deficit in the current account, arapid increase in exports, especially in industrial exports, and an improvement in deifcitifnancing. The latter was expressed by a remarkable increase in the weight of unilateraltransactions and a decrease in .that of loans, but mainly by a halting of the growingdependence on short­term sources for current deifcit financing.

These developments brought relief to the short­term problems of the balance of pay­ments, and removed the danger of a financing crisis. They also reflect the creation ofconditions which promise continuation of the improvement by means of economicrestraint. These conditions are a vital component in any strategy for solving the balanceof payments problem.

Unfortunately these developments were achieved at a great price ­ a third year ofstandstill in economic growth. Despite the positive aspects of these developments, in as

far as the balance of payments is concerned, they are mostly related to the immediateinlfuence of restraint and the formation of a basis for further improvement. They haveless effect on the core of the problem: the need to bring about a structural change thatwill get the economy out of its present standstill and return it to a course of growth,while at the same time continuing to reduce the deficit. Where relative prices and exportproiftability are concerned, there is still a wide gap between objectives and achievements.Some indicators show that recent changes are in the irght direction. However, they mayrepresent only a partial correction of the decrease in export profitability since 1972.

FinaUy, considering the change in allocation of resources in the economy, the progresstowards desired objectives which waS achieved in 1976 is not unequivocal. Recently, theshare of consumption in the increment of resources has actually increased in comparisonto 1972. There was in fact a change in this trend duirng 1976, expressed by the increasein the share of export, but this increase relfects not only rapid growth in exports, but alsoa considerable drop in the weight of domestic investment.

1. The Balance of Payments Problem

Developments in the balance of payments situation, and in particular the remarkabledecrease of the cunent account deifcit, are only one part of a complex picture. In orderto evaluate their real signiifcance, it is necessary to comprehend the relative weight ofinlfuences related to various levels of the problem: external factors, both incidental and

CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ GENERAL SURVEY 41

Page 2: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

TABLECURRENT

)$

ImportsTotal incl.defenseDefenseGoods £

GoodsimportsimportsservicesServicesGoods

At current pricesA.9003,0805552,5257671,7581971

1,0823,2614902,7718711,90019721,3665,3251,2534,0721,1762,89619731,4224,5544714,0831,1532,9301973a1,7066,9021,2245,6781,6054,07319741,8117,6781,8465,8321,8284,00419752,2817,5401,6035,9371,9633,9­741976

pricesAt 1972B.

9663,2535842,6697981,87119711,0823,2614902,7718711,90019721,1144,4161,1293,2871,0232,26419731,1743,8844373,4471,0422,4051973a1,1754,4749783,4961,1712,32419741,1913,7811,3463,7351,2472,18819751,4724,6581,1293,5291,2552,2251976

Index of quanti­C.tative growth)1972=100(

89100119969298197110010010010010010019721031762301191181191973109119891241201271973a109138200126135122197411014427512314311519751361402301251441171976

Pirces indexesD.)1972=100 (

939595959690197110010010010010010019721231211111241151281973145154125163137175197415216413717114718319751551651421721561791976

a First three quarters at annual rates.

42 BANK OF ISRAEL ANNUAL REPORT 1 976

Page 3: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

111­1

1971­1976ACCOUNT,million)

DeficitExportsTotalC/a withTotal incl.currentadmin.defenseTradeGoods 8ldeifcitareasimportsTotalServicesbalanceservicesServices

­1,22640­1,266­711147­8581,814914­1,10131­1,132­642176­8182,1291,047­2,64229­2,671­1,418112­1,5302,654U88­1,79428­1,822­1,351157­1,5082,7321,310­3,38761­3,448­2,224143­2,3673,4541,7484,0501154,183­2,317­124­2,1933,5251,704­3,268145­3,415­1,812­119­1,6934,1251,844

­1,352­760137­9051,901395­1,132­642176­8182,1291,047­2,160­1,0321181,1522,2551,141­1,499­1,062169­1,2312,3851,211­2,066­1,08861­1,1492,4081,233­2,415­1,069­72­9972,3661,175­1,947818­657532,6671,190

11912078111898910010010010010010019116167141106109135169811501121161831693514011311821316712211111217112792125114

9598100100118113143142149145154155

CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ GENERAL SURVEY 43

Page 4: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

short­range; the standstill in economic growth as a result of restraint policy (a necessarycondition for carrying out structural changes but by no means a substitute for suchchanges); and structural changes concerning relative prices and the allocation of resourcesin the economy.

The aim of such an analysis is to show these developments in a wide perspective, inorder to demonstrate the progress made in achieving the structural changes necessary foran effective solution of the problem.

In 1976 the deficit in the current account was reduced by nearly $800 milUon. Partof this reduction resulted from 3 decrease of $250 million in defense imports. In the cur­rent account excluding defense imports and trade with the administered areas, the deifcitdropped by more than 20 percent, or $500 million, totaling $1.8 billion. The immediatesignificance of this drop is that the dangerous dependence on short­term sources hasceased growing. This dependence had characterized the previous two years, when needfor short­term sources totaled $ 2 billion. In 1976 long­term capital imports were able tofinance the whole current deifcit, and the growth of the above­mentioned dependencestopped, but the fact of dependence itself remained at the same high level it had reachedat the end of 1975 (see Table HI­3).

To a great extent the reduction of the deficit is the result of both short­term andincidental factors, and the effects of the restraint of economic activity. Nevertheless, inthe last two years there are also indications of an improvement in the relative price ofexports in certain ifelds.

There were significant changes in stocks of imported inputs. These changes explainnearly $300 million of the decrease in the deifcit. The transition from stockpiling tostock­liquidation was due partly to the adaptation to a low level of economic activity,and partly to considerations of relative proiftability, relfecting the increase of domesticinterest rates as well as changing expectations concerning prices and exchange rates.

The 10 percent cumulative decrease over the past two years in imported investmentgoods mainly relfects the inlfuence of the restraint policy. It accounts for a decrease of$ 50 million in imports but is not an expression of long­range trends. On the other hand,in 1976 stockpiling of raw diamonds accounted for an increase of $ 100 million in im­ports.

One external factor also had a constraining effect: a decrease of world interest rates. 1This is relfected by the fact that total foreign liabilities of the economy increased in thelast two years by more than $4 billion while payments of interest rose by only $ 100 mil­lion .2 A recovery of world interest rates to their long­term average level would mean a

considerable inaease of interest payments.

1 One indicator of this is the interest rates for one­year Eurodollar loans, which fellfrom 10.7 percent in 1974 to 6.7 percent in 1976.

2 The comparison is not completely accurate, since the interest applies to the averagedebt, but this does not substantially change the picture presented here.

44 BANK OF ISRAEL ANNUAL REPORT 1976

Page 5: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

Another external factor explaining a decrease of about $100 million in the currentdeficit between 1975 and 1976 is a slight improving in the terms of trade.

A deficit drop of $300 million to $350 million can be explained by a combinationof all of these developments, in which incidental factors or the short­range effects ofadaptation to economic policy had a determinant weight.

The restraint policy manifests itself mainly in the very fact that halting of growthcreates a drop in imports and the creation of conditions for carrying out structuralchanges.

The sharp turnabout in export trends in 1976 is partly the result of the restraintpolicy. But it seems that the main cause is the less significant part of the policy effectsin terms of long­range developments ­ those effects which reflect the inhibition ofdomestic activity, which is a short­range factor ­ and not the structural influence whichthe restraint was intended to make possible.

In 1976 exports increased by 13 percent in real terms, after an average increase of4 percent in each of the previous three years. Exports of products increased by 22 per­cent, while industrial exports (excluding diamonds, minerals, and fuel) increased by28 percent, after an average increase of 5 percent in the previous three years. Recoveryof world demand played an important part in this rise. The increase of export profi­tability was less unequivocal. A comparison of product price in exports (and in tradeablegoods in general) with (nontradeable) product pirce in the domestic market shows animprovement in the relative pirce of exports compared to 1975. But this improvementonly partially compensates for the worsening which took place in the years 1973­74.From this aspect the situation is still significantly worse than it was in 1972, the year be­fore the balance of payments crisis, while the developments that have occurred sincethen require a significant improvement relative to this starting point.

An analysis of industiral exports shows a lack of signiifcant change in profitabilitywhen the compairson is made between the change of export pirces and the cost level.'In compairson to the domestic market there was in fact an improvement, but it relfectsthe restraint of the domestic market, together with cost inflation, resulting in a strongpressure on profits. This situation does not reflect a permanent change in relative pirces,but is related to the continuity of restraint policy and lack of growth.

World demand recovery stands out against these tendencies, as a factor for increasingexports. It should be remembered that a high rate of growth was achieved after threeyears of very slow increase, averaging 5percent .3 The cumulative irse of exports is stillslow, compared both to the objectives in this area and the increase in production capa­

city of the economy. This is happening while unutilized production capacity is accu­mulating at a growing rate as a result of the restraint policy.

3 In industiral exports excluding diamonds, minerals and fuel.

CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ GENERAL SURVEY 45

Page 6: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

TABLE

DEFICIT AND THE

)$_ million,CURRENT

Long­term capital

Surplus (+) ordeficit (­) oflong­termcapital over IMFthe deifcit creditTotal

Foreigninvestment

Long­termloans

Uni­lateraltransfers

Currentdeficit

22­22464518168459­8691969

­­41,23022559649­1,2341970

10­2551,48375642766­1,2281971

­39+6741,7751435801,052­1,1011972

­+5323,1741858162,173­2,6421973

39­1,0172,370945391,737­3,3871974

215­7373,313671,4741,7714,0501975

89+263,294441,0112,239­3,2681976

94­17084728295524­1,01719751

16­1018249374441­92511

­­33778422337425­1,121111

105­1298489468381­987**

­­77188198512­72519761

­­2106918189494­89911

75+9586516130669­769111

14+ 1451,01912lRn

444563­875**

Bureau of Statistics.CentralSOURCE:

46 BANK OF ISRAEL ANNUAL REPORT 1976

Page 7: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

111­2

1969­1976CAPITAL ACCOUNT,

at current prices)

Short­term capital

Errors

Otheritems.esp.short­termShort­Foreign

Totalshort ­

Liquid foreignobligations

Credit to non­financial sectors

8lomissions

foreignassets

termcapital

currencyreserves

termcredit

of Israelibanks

Governmentsector

Privatesector

­6422+258321­63­38­25

491+23­19421923

47­125­187­24558499

47­23­663­534­129­93­36

28­266­315­526229212+23­6

­272­69+1,323+778546464+46+36

­18­77+620­68688528­70+230

­92­231+206­11632295+78+149

162­227+140­254394297+14+83

74+158­144­8­136­62­111+37

5+95+238+180582+11+45

­259­104+385+13372291+16+65

­20+86­60+59­119­120+25­24

154­71+125­6418934+16+139

­79­101+8­728042+53­15

­147­109+134­39173140­16+49

CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ GENERAL SURVEY 47

Page 8: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

to>

o.von

>Mr"<

z

70

§?0

TABLE III­3

CHANGES IN RESOURCE ALLOCATION IN THE ECONOMY, 1972­1976(percent(

Weight inWeightWeightincrease ofin increasein usesRate of real growthGNPaof uses

1973­7619721972 1976

Uses

Private consumption

Public consumption(excl. direct defense imports)

Total consumption

Investment (excl. ships and aircraft)

Exports

Total uses

Sources

GNP

Imports (excl. defense imports(

100 122.8 39.2

a Assuming a 40 percent import component in exports.b This calculation ignores the effect of price differentials of different uses.

45.7

73.225.415.4132.3100

71.154.6125.3100

­3.621.896.8100

26.832.423.6126.8100

100100100119.6100

116.0100

127.6100

Page 9: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

Most of the increase in exports was due to the growth of defense exports/* whichrepresent a narrow segment of industry. Since they are subject to special factors, we

must ask to what extent their vigorous growth is the result of these special factors and towhat extent the resultof the overall economic conditions.

An analysis of export tendencies and changes in relative prices shows the centralfunction of economic restraint as a means of influencing the balanceof payments. How­ever, restraint can only function as a limited instrument of balance of payments policy,and achievements gained through it involve a heavy economic price. Restraint is a neces­sary component in dealing with this problem. Its function is to allow the necessary struc­tural changes to take place, but it cannot be a substitute for them.

Two main structural changes are needed: raising the price of foreign currency in rela­

tion to domestic prices and wages ­ a change which will allow the expansion of exports(and import substitutes), and a change in the allocation of resources in the economy bydecreasing domestic uses in relation to production. This will release resources for exportneeds. We are still far from achieving that change in relative pirces required by balanceof payments objectives. Some indicators show that recent changes are in the right direc­tion, but apparently they can only correct in part the previous negative developments.Nevertheless, according to these indicators the correction in the last two years has beensignificant. The necessity still exists to bring the economy to above the level it attainedbefore the severe cirsis in the balance of payments occurred.

Some of the changes in the relative prices resulted from a combination of specialfactors. One of these was cost inflation in a restrained economy, expressed by pressureon profits. For this change to remain effective, the restraint must also continue. Logi­cally, such conditions are a necessary component of policy in a transitional peirod.But they are not part of the long­range solutionof the balance of payments problem,whose basic feature is the return to a course of rapid growth without balance of pay­ments dififculties.

Nor has there been unequivocal progress towards the desired objective in as faras the reallocation of economic resources is concerned. In recent years, which were main­ly years of restraint, a reverse change in resource allocation took place: instead of falling,the share of consumption in the resource increment rose appreciably (see Table 111­3).

A partial change of this trend did in fact take place in 1976, shown by a growth of ex­port's share in resource increase. However, this increase ­ in a restraint economy ­ wasactually made possible by a considerable drop in the weight of domesticinvestments.5

4 The average annual increase between 1973 and 1976, deducting defense exports,was 4­5 percent.

5 Hypothetical calculations based on the given data show that an increase of 10 per­cent in product with no increase of the deficit will allow, after allocation of the neededresources for an increase in exports and a recoveryof investments, an increaseof 3­4 per­cent in consumption (1­2 percent per capita). Every calculationof this kind emphasizesthe general outlines of the problem and the severity of its constraints.

CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ GENERAL SURVEY 49

Page 10: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

o TABLE 111­4

> INDICATORS OF EXPORT PROFITABILITY AND RELATIVE PROFITABILITY£ COMPARED TO DOMESTIC MARKET, 1973 TO 1976Z (1972=100(

r? Industrial export GNP delfator in> Industrial export return relative Domestic market exports relativez return relative to to domestic return relative to (non­tradeable)> cost level market return to inputs domestic market

§ 0) (2) (3) (4)50 H£ 1973 104.2 106.6 97.7 86.4

1974 102.8 107.3 95.8 69.3

1975 107.6 116.0 92.8 81.7

1976 106.3 117.6 90.4 93.8

NOTE: The source of columns (1) and (2) ­ TableIV­13 below; column (3) = column (1) divided by column (2); the source ofcolumn (4) ­ TableIV­1 1 . The picture drawn by column (4) is different from that of column (2), but that is because the frame ofreference of the two columns is different. Column (2) deals with industry only, and with the relation between product prices;column (4) deals with the whole economy and the relation between GNP deflators; because of this it requires a set of assumptions:the extent of the import component in exports as compared to domestic uses, as well as the extent that the rise in cost of imports ispassed on in the domestic purchase inputs of exports (since it is necessary to deal with the entire import component). If the re­straint of the economy does not allow this cost to be passed on, the calculation gives an exaggerated bias to the drop in relation,and to the following rise. In addition, one must remember the relatively low reliability of someof the national accounts included incolumn (4). The ifgures in column (2) are based on much more reliable data.

Page 11: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

The decrease in investments is a natural and desirable phenomenon in the conditionsof a restraint policy, especially when the restraint is intended to lead to structural changein the economy, and it does not harm long­term growth. But it is a component of short­term policy which must disappear after an interim, and not become part of the long­term solution.

The reallocation of resources that took place in the economy in the peirod under dis­cussion has an acute significance concerning the balance of payments objectives. Anychange from standstill conditions to a rapid course of growth will be accompanied by a

considerable rise in imports (for current production, increase in stocks and expansion ofinvestment). In order to achieve this transition without increasing the existing deifcit(which is still much too high), most of the increment in domestic product will have to beallocated to export. In addition, the expected increase of investments will take its share,so that public and private consumption will receive only a small portion of the productincrease.6 This means a "marginal tax" (the absorption of income rise by means oftaxation) of 80­90 percent ormore.7 In any situation this would be a dififcult objective,and the difficulty is emphasized by the nature of the achievements of economic policy inrecent years. It is reasonable to assume that a transition to a higher level of activity will

nake these dififculties more severe. Here the balance of payments constraint which keepsthe economy at a standstill is clearly expressed: the inability to perform needed alloca­tion changes (a significant decrease ofconsumption as a ifrst step for renewed growth, orthe absorption ofthe greater part of income irse after renewal of growth) means that thereturn of the economy to a course of growth will be accompanied by an increase of thedeifcit.

Another aspect of this constraint is the need for signiifcant change in relative pirces ­in favor of foreign currency pirces and against domestic pirces. Such a change is dififcultto achieve, and it is generally assumed to be possible only under conditions of economicrestraint.

The developments in these two ifelds in recent years indicate that despite improve­ments there are still no deifnite signs of signiifcant progress toward the primary goal:breaking through the balance of payments constraint, which prevents growth in the econ­omy and leads to an ever increasing underutilization ofproduction capacity. The develop­ments and changes achieved so far have left us with the same basic dilemma, stagnationor increase of deifcit.

6 In 1976 there was a small drop in real per capita income which did not cause aparallel drop in real consumption. It is possible that its effects will be felt in future,though the weightof this potential development is not great.

? Growth in savings is also possible, though the problem is too great for this to havemuch effect. Another means would be a drastic reduction of public consumption.

CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ GENERAL SURVEY 51

Page 12: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

TABLE III­5ISRAEL'S TERMS OF TRADE FOR PRODUCT TRADE, 1969 TO 1976

Termsof tradeexcludingdiamonds^

Exportpirce indexexcludingdiamonds

Importprice indexexcludingdiamonds

Termsoftradea

Exportpirce index

Importpirce index

Annualdata(1969= 100(

99.3103.7104.499.7104.7105.01969

97.0103.5106.798.9104.4105.61970

94.4105.6111.999.3108.4109.21971

93.1109.9118.0100.4116.2115.81972

86.9131.5151.396.5142.9148.11973

78.9167.5212.383.3169.1202.91974

80.8179.6222.383.5177.0211.91975

82.6178.0215.687.1180.2206.81976

Quarterly data (1973 = 100(106.488.583.2106.089.684.519731

106.098.993.3105.499.394.2II

102.5109.9107.2101.0108.3107.2III

93.3108.0115.893.0106.3114.3IV

77.8113.7146.278.1109.8140.61974179.3123.1155.380.1120.3150.2II

84.3125.9149.383.0119.4143.9III

85.5131.0153.383.5120.7144.6IV

81.7137.4168.179.0126.0159.519751

82.9138.2166.778.0124.0159.0II

84.5132.3156.580.9121.3150.0III85.9130.7152.183.0121.2146.0IV

85.8132.0153.985.5126.4147.81976183.1130.0156.480.8121.7150.6II

83.5131.9157.981.1123.2151.9ni83.3136.6163.983.0129.7156.3IV

a Export pirce index + import price index.b As the diamond pirce index is problematical from the statistical point of view, theterms of trade excluding diamonds have also been given.

52 BANK OF ISRAEL ANNUAL REPORT 1976

Page 13: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

2. The Current Account

The main development in the current account in 1976 was a sharp drop in the deifcitby $800 million, from more than $4 billion to $3.3 billion. This decrease was achievedthrough a rapid rise in exports (13 percent in real terms) and a slight fall in imports(3 percent). Part of the decrease in the deficit results from a drop in defense imports.Excluding defense imports, there was a $500 miUion decrease in the current deficit (morethan 20 percent).

Patr of the decrease in the deficit is a result of cetrain shotr­term factors, especiallychanges in inventory levels resulting from the adaptation to a new level of economicactivity and from changes in expectations and ifnancial profitability. The change in thesefactors may explain the decrease of about $300 million in the impotr of inputs, and anincrease of about $100 million in the impotrof raw diamonds.

The lack of import growth was a major contribution toward improving the balance ofpayments. This was mainly the result of the economic restraint and the absence of growthsince mid­1974. This influence can be clearly seen in the two main components of pro­duct impotrs: impotred inputs (except for fuel and diamonds) fell by 5 percent as com­pared to 1975, while there was a slight irse (2 percent) of the level of total uses in theeconomy accompanied by a substanial growth (9 percent) in import needs for currentinputs (on the average, the composition of uses became more impotr­intensive). Thiswas largely due to the increased share of exports in total uses and to the growth of theaverage import component in it. There was an increase of only 2 percent in impotredinput requirements for domestic uses, which was in line with the overall increase in do­

mestic uses. Impotred input requirements for expotr rose by 31 percent, compared to anincreaseof 13 percent in expotrs. The 5 percent decrease in total import of inputs reflectsthe fact that 1975 was a year of stockpilingof impotred inputs while in 1976 the reverseprocess ­ inventory liquidation ­ took place.

There was an 8 percent drop in the impotr of capital goods (excluding ships and air­craft) and a 10 percent decrease in imports of plant and equipment. This is a clearexpression of the economic restraint and of its effect on proiftability. It is impotrant tonote that the drop in imported plant and equipment is considerably smaller than thedrop in investment of domestic equipment. This is relfected in an increase in the weightof impotred equipment in total investments of equipment. This new development istypical of the peirod since 1973. It is not explained by the change of relative pirces;it may possibly reflect a change in investment composition related to long­term factors.It may also relfect shotr­term inlfuences: on the one hand^ growing expectations of a

relative appreciation of foreign currency and of impotr products (perhaps even of importlimitations) due to the balance of payments situation; and on the other hand a con­siderable increase of the subsidy element in unlinked credit for investments in a time ofsteep pirce irses. Industry and agriculture are the main beneifciaries of this subsidy, and

CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ GENERAL SURVEY 53

Page 14: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

the increased weight of these sectors in recent years is the main source for the increasein import intensity of investments.

Growth of exports results entirely from the export of goods. Here the increase in realterms reached 22 percent. This increase stands out even more in industrial exports (ex­eluding diamonds, minerals and fuel) ­ 28 percent, and in agricultural expotrs (excludingcitrus fruit) ­ 30 percent.

The turnabout in industrial expotrs, which occurred after four yearsof very slight in­creases (an averageof 6 percent in the years 1972­75), mainly reflects two factors: on theone hand a considerable increase in world demand due to the economic recovery thatbegan in the developed countries at the end of 1975 and accelerated in 1976; and on theother hand an economic restraint in Israel and the slackening of domestic demand in

general, and of defense expenditure in particular.It is difficult to make an unequivocal statement concerning the effectof profitability;

different indicators do not give a homogeneous picture. The comparison of product pircein export (and tradeable goods in general) to product price in nontradeable goods, showsa change in favor of tradeable goods in the last two years, but this increase only partiallycorrects for the considerable worsening of relative profitability in 1973­74, and the 1972level has not yet been reached. The balance of payments situation requires that thechange in favor of exports will considerably exceed the 1972 level. These comparisonsdeal with the economy as a whole and their accuracy and, in particular, the accuracy ofthe price data included in them, are limited, but this does not undermine the broad out­lines indicated by them.

The picture of industrial export profitability is not as clear. The ratio index (inputpirces) between level of export pirces and costs does not show a signiifcant change in thelast four years, although it is possible that a slight increase took place compared to theperiod before 1973. In any case this change was insignificant relative to the balance ofpayments objectives.

A comparison of the average price changes in industrial exports and in the domesticmarket shows a considerable improvement in expotrs. It seems that the main explanationfor this is the existence of conditions of restraint in the economy, together with cost in­lfation, a situation expressed by a strong pressure on proifts in the domestic market (seeTable 114). The relative proiftability of export grew,of course, under these conditionsbut the durability of this change is conditional upon the continuation of restraint in theeconomy.

Against this background both the slow accumulating change of export growth duringthe last four or ifve years, as well as the absence of growth in the past six months, acquiiiegreat significance for several reasons; these developments should be viewed against the

background of the economic restraint, the existence of a great surplus of underutilizedproduction capacity, and an economic policy that gives pirority to export stimulus.

54 BANK OF ISRAEL ANNUAL REPORT 1976

Page 15: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

The composition of export increase, which is connected with the problematical natureof export stimulus and the efifciency of this policy has already been noted. In this ifeldsharp differences in trends can be seen: a considerable part of export increase originatesfrom a relatively narrow segment of the industrial sector, namely defense exports. Theseexports have a very special character from many points ofview, concerning both marketsand the behavior of producers. Keeping in mind the great differences in the export per­formance of this sector and the industrial sector in general, the question arises, to whatextent does the continued increase in defense exports reflect special conditions and towhat extent is it the fruit of overall economic conditions, influenced by the economicpolicy. if the increase results mainly from the former, it shows the limited effectivenessof economic policy on export promotion.

The policy of the creeping devaluation is vital for the preservation of export pro­iftability. As part of this policy , the exchange rate of the Israeli pound was raised atifrst in relation to the dollar through mid­year by 14.4 percent, and later in relationto a basket of currencies by 9.6 percent by the end of the year.

During the year the devaluation of the Israeli pound in relation to the main cur­rencies reached an average of 24 percent. There was a 17 percent average drop in the ex­change rate of the Israeli pound compared to 1975, caused by a higher average deva­

luation against the dollar (25 percent) which has been offset in part due to the rise ofthe dollar rate relative to other important currencies. The transition from defining theIsraeli pound in terms of the dollar to a deifnition in terms of a basket of currenciesshould be seen in this context. This transition preserves a constant average exchange rateof the Israeli pound from one devaluation to another. This constancy was not possibleunder the previous arrangement where the exchange rate was ifxed in terms of the dollarbut floating in relation to all other currencies, and also in relation to their average. In

the present framework, the exchange rate is constant relative to a weighted average ofthe currencies (represented in the basket) and floating in relation to the dollar.

3. The Capital Account

The main development in the capital account in 1 976 is the reduction of the current de­ifcit to the level of long­term capital import totaling $3.3 billion, similar to 1975. In thisrespect, the great gap which existed in 1975 disappeared. This manifested itself in asigniifcant improvement in the capital account ­ the fast growth of dependence on short­term ifnancing ceased. This growth had characterized the previous two years, when theeconomy's use of short­term ifnancing reached $2 billion. Nevertheless, dependence uponthese sources remained at the same level that it had reached at the end of 1975. Thischange allows some breathing space for economic policy, but reductionof the dangerousdependence upon short­term sources is still one of the primary objectives of the econ­omy.

CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ GENERAL SURVEY 55

Page 16: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

TABLE

FOREIGN EXCHANGE RESERVES ANDNET

)$

Foreign exchange reserves

Total officialDeposits of otherreserve assetscentral monetary)l)+(2( =institutionsAt Bank of IsraelEnd of period

)3()2(0(483244591970758367321971

1,287571,23019721,9791691,81019731,258581,20019741,2891651,18419751,458901,36819761,061401,021197211,126411,085n1,144361,108HI1,287571,230rv1,522771,4451973 I1,6641451,519n1,7511441,607hi1,9791691,810IV1,7791311,6481974 I1,5401241,416n1,222771,145HI1,258581,200IV1,537481,4891975 I1,541601,481n1,286491,237in1.2891051,184rv1,244941,1501976 I1,308941,214n1,402861,316in1,458901,368rv

a The changes in the balances in this table are not the same as the changes inliabilities and assets of the banks shown in Table 111­2. In the latter only changesfrom current transactions are shown, while in this table the reserves are inlfuenced

56 BANK OF ISRAEL ANNUAL REPORT 1976

Page 17: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

111­6

FOREIGN LIABILITIES OF ISRAELI BANKS, 1970­19758million)

Liquid foreign oblicationsof banksNet liquidLiquidforeignobligationsDeposits in

obligations)5) ­(4)=

to foreignersforeign banks

(6)(5)(4)2626313693099866772091,3431,1344141,7421,3289202,1661,246

1,4652,6901,2251,5692,9371,3683201,0397192759126372271,0458182091,3431,1341971,3591,1623131,5361,2235081,8551,3474141,7421,3282881,6961,4084101,7081,2984531,6081,1559202,1661,246

1,2522,0775281,1922,0318391,1522,0899371,4652,6901,2251,3232,4121,0891,3622,4911,1291,4212,5881,1671,5692,9371,386

by changes in foreign exchange rates as well as other changes whichdo not resultfrom current transactions (as the closing of the Israeli­British Bank).

CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ GENERAL SURVEY 57

Page 18: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

In long­term capital import the same trends that characterized 1975 remained. Theprincipal fact was the great dependence upon financial aid from American sources, whoseweight reached 52.3 percent of all transfers and long­term loans (52.9 percent in 1975).This followed a steep rise from an average level of 19 percent during 1971­1972, and alevel of 8 percent in 1969. This increase paralleled the steep rise in defense imports, froma level of $250 million in 1968 to about $500 million in the years 1971­1972, reaching$1 .6­1 .8 billion in the last two years.

There was a positive change from 1975 in the composition of capital import: a con­siderable increase in the weight of unilateral transfers (from $1.9 to $2.2 billion) and adecrease in the weight of loans (from $1.5 to $1.0 billion).This reflects mainly a changein the composition of American aid; here there was a considerable increase in the weightof unilateral transfers ­ from 35 percent to 69 percent ­ while in the total of all othertransfers there was a general drop : an increase in Jewish Agency and nonprofit institu­tion transfers (from $510 to $540 miUion), which was outweighed by a decrease in pir­vate transfers (from $640 to $590 million). This continues the trend of previous year.The increase in transfers to institutions is small in real terms, but probably reflects the im­provement of economic conditionsof the contributors abroad.^

The decrease in private transfers continues a trend of recent years. The drop in trans­fers of German restitutions, after years of continuous increase, is due to the completionof many cases involving one­time payments. Pension payments continued to irse, whileother private transfers continued to fall at considerable cumulative rates: the real decreasein compairson with 1972 reaches 60 percent in the general total, and 85 percent forimmigrant transfers. This decrease reflects the effect of the restraint of economic activity,and a decrease in profit expectations in the economy, and expectations for devaluationsdue to the balance of payments problem. The combinations of these factors also explains'the steep cumulative drop in investments from abroad.

Despite the outstanding improvement in the. deficit situation (the closing of the gap

between long­term capital import and the current deficit), resort to short­term capitalfrom abroad continued, though to a lesser extent than in 1975 (see Table 11­2). Thisirse in short­term financing was mainly expressed by an increase of the foreign currencyreserves of the Bank of Israel and did not create a net increase inshort­term liabilitiesfrom foreign sources.

The picture of events in this area is incomplete and unclear. There is no informationon the use of one central instrument ­ exchange rate guarantees from the Treasury for

8 The data are based upon classifications in the balance of payments, and may bemisleading, because money raised by the Jewish Agency abroad as loans is entered asunilateral transfers. In 1975, which was a year of world recession, there was a con­siderable increase in transfers of the Jewish Agency, which was partly the result of amobilization of capital loans due to Israel's balance of payments difficulties. Part of thereal increase in income of the UJA in 1976 was used for repayment of loans taken inprevious years.

58 BANK OF ISRAEL ANNUAL REPORT 1976

Page 19: OF · 2013. 4. 17. · 1976 3,268 2,239 1,011 44 3,294 +26 89 19751 1,017 524 295 28 847 170 94 11 925 441 374 9 824 101 16 111 1,121 425 337 22 784 337 ** 987 381 468 9 848 129 105

foreign loans ­ a factor whose inlfuence drastically changes all calculations of the relativeadvantagesofvarious financial and realassets .9

Nevertheless, the general outlines of various activities can be pointed out. Concurrentto the drop in additional short­term credit from abroad, a considerable change took placein 1976 in its sectorial composition: there was a sharp drop in credit granted to the go­

vernment, and the balance shrank, while there was a slight rise in credit to the privatesector compared with the increase in 1975. Part of the increase in 1976 resulted from a

change in the institutional framework: the regulations regarding short­term credit werechanged, and the banks were allowed to use financial resources from abroad to grantcredit to exporters within the framework of the Export Shipments Fund. This meansthat the short­term accumulation of assets abroad is balanced by a parallel accumulationof short­term liabilities abroad, instead of a decrease in other assets (the reserves of theBank of Israel). Discounting the inlfuence of this factor, the increase of credit for theprivate sector was a little lower than in 1975.

The increase in the balance of short­term credit coincided with a slight drop in im­ports and with a drop ­ apparently quite signilfcant ­ in the stockof import products.Thus, a certain change in the composition of the private sector's assets towards an in­crease of net ofreignliabilities10 can be seen. This evaluation is based on a partial pictureand mainly deals with shotr­term rather than the long­term components of assets, inwhich a reverse trend is possible. This development must be seen against a backdrop ofchanges in interest differentials and exchange rate expectations: an increase in rates ofinterest in the Israeli economy in contrast with the continuing decrease in the worldmoney markets, an apparent weakening of expectations of devaluation due to the im­provement in the balance of payments, adaptation to the creeping devaluation as.a factof life, and the nearing of elections.

A parallel change took place in the allocation of financial resources of the banks: thenet foreign liquid liabilities only increased at a low rate (perhaps relfecting the abilityto mobilize further financial resources by Israelis abroad, but the banks decreased assetsabroad (loans to companies abroad, especially those connected with the Israe­h economy).This gave them sources for credit expansion in foreign currency to the domestic privatesector.

The picture drawn above in broad outlines shows the sensitivity of the movements ofshotr­term capital to changes in the evaluationof relative proiftability while the expecta­tion of a large devaluation overshadows all other factors.

9 This factor also inlfuences long­term loans from abroad and their possible substi­tution for shotr­term credits.

10 Stock import, for our purposes, can be seen as a substitute for assets abroad.

CHAPTER III, BALANCE OF PAYMENTS ­ GENERAL SURVEY 59