Top Banner
THREE ESSAYS ON INNOVATION AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP: DIVERSIFICATION, BOUNDARY EXPANSION, AND DIFFERENTIATION By SANG KYUN KIM A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY WASHINGTON STATE UNIVERSITY College of Business AUGUST 2010 © Copyright by SANG KYUN KIM, 2010 All Rights Reserve
130

NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

May 14, 2017

Download

Documents

Praman Chelsea
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

THREE ESSAYS ON INNOVATION AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP:

DIVERSIFICATION, BOUNDARY EXPANSION, AND DIFFERENTIATION

By

SANG KYUN KIM

A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of

DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

WASHINGTON STATE UNIVERSITY

College of Business

AUGUST 2010

© Copyright by SANG KYUN KIM, 2010 All Rights Reserve

Page 2: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

UMI Number: 3452349

All rights reserved

INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted.

In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript

and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion.

UMI 3452349

Copyright 2011 by ProQuest LLC. All rights reserved. This edition of the work is protected against

unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code.

ProQuest LLC 789 East Eisenhower Parkway

P.O. Box 1346 Ann Arbor, MI 48106-1346

Page 3: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

© Copyright by SANG KYUN KIM, 2010

All Rights Reserved

Page 4: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

ii

To the Faculty of Washington State University:

The members of the Committee appointed to examine the dissertation of

SANG KYUN KIM find it satisfactory and recommend that it be accepted.

___________________________________ John B. Cullen, Ph.D., Chair

___________________________________

Jonathan D. Arthurs, Ph.D. ___________________________________

Arvin Sahaym, Ph.D.

Page 5: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

iii

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

It has been long journey, and now I am standing in front of a new door. I appreciate the

number of individuals who have supported me during the doctoral program. First, I am

especially grateful to my dissertation chair, Dr. John Cullen, for his generous support, patience,

and encouragement throughout my studies. His guidance with kind and warm encouragement

motivated me to continue to focus on my studies. I am honored to be one of his students, and I

will always remember his kind instruction.

I also would like to thank my other committee members, Dr. Jonathan Arthurs and Dr.

Arvin Sahaym, who have taught me innumerable lessons and insights on the workings of

academic research. Dr. Arthurs has allowed me to work with him and to take advantage of his

broad knowledge. I appreciate the enthusiasm, kindness, and patience he displayed in working

with me. Dr. Sahaym was both a mentor and my friend who listened carefully when I needed

support, offered me excellent advice, and opened several doors to show me options I had not yet

considered. I am grateful to his endless support, patience, and guidance.

It is not often that one finds committee members who always find the time to listen to the

little problems and roadblocks that unavoidably crop up in the course of performing research. I

will remain indebted to all my committee members for each moment of kindness and the

dedication they provided to help me reach this goal. The friendship of Daeil, Fariss, Adi, Kevin,

Tera, Dustin, and Doug is appreciated for many good-spirited discussions. Also, I am indebted to

all the faculty and staff members in the Department of Management and Operations who have

helped me over the years. Especially, I would like to extend my appreciation for Dr. Ahn, who

as a mentor, always offered unlimited advice, support and dedication.

Page 6: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

iv

My parents receive my deepest gratitude and love for their dedication and the many years

of support during my studies. I also would like to express my gratitude to parents-in-law for their

emotional support. My lovely daughter, Suah, deserves recognition because she provides me

great strength and a smile which gives the drive to keep up my work. Last but not least, I would

like to thank my wife, Jihyun, for her understanding and endless love. Her support and

encouragement was in the end what made this dissertation possible. Without her, I could not

have completed the doctoral program and my dissertation.

These all wonderful individuals have helped me complete my Ph.D. degree, and have

made my time at Washington State University a rewarding experience.

Page 7: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

v

THREE ESSAYS ON INNOVATION AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP:

DIVERSIFICATION, BOUNDARY EXPANSION, AND DIFFERENTIATION

Abstract

by Sang Kyun Kim, Ph.D. Washington State University

AUGUST 2010

Chair: John B. Cullen

This dissertation investigated the topics of innovation and entrepreneurship. The first

essay discusses the relationship between diversification and innovation by integrating the

insights of organizational search and contingencies literatures. The main argument is that a

strategic fit between diversification and organizational contingencies leads to higher

technological innovation. We find that a related diversification strategy leads to higher

innovation when a local search is used by the company. In contrast, an unrelated diversification

strategy leads to higher innovation when a broader search is used. Further, this study shows that

technological capital is importance factor for a diversified firm to take an advantage of benefits

from broader corporate scope.

The second essay explores young firms’ boundary expansion activities to develop its

capabilities. Firms may differ in their search and renewal strategies based on their stage in the

life cycle. Unlike the incumbents, young firms that just went through Initial Public Offering (IPO)

may use different strategies contingent on their unique resources and the liabilities. Built on

Resource Based View (RBV), we find that young firms with R&D resources develop an internal

factor market to develop its competencies, while young firms with financial resource prefer to

engage in boundary expansion activities. We also find that young firms’ boundary expansion

Page 8: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

vi

activities are further constrained in the presence of environmental uncertainty, and strong

competition in the industry.

Finally, the third essay investigates the performance consequences of new venture’s

strategic differentiation. We address how the patterns of differentiation affect the new venture’s

short-term and long-term performance after going public. The main argument is that firms using

a differentiation strategy will have higher performance than those with similarity strategy.

Empirical support for the argument is found in the high technology industry. Additionally, the

results show that in the IPO context, strategic differentiation is more beneficial under high

uncertain environment.

Overall, the three essays in this dissertation 1) provide a more refined view of the

relationship between diversification strategy and innovation, 2) explain young firms’ strategic

choice to develop a capability, and 3) discuss the strategic behavior of new ventures and its

implication for performance after IPO.

Page 9: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

vii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ........................................................................................................... iii

ABSTRACT ....................................................................................................................................v

LIST OF TABLES ...................................................................................................................... viii

LIST OF FIGURES ...................................................................................................................... ix

CHAPTER

1. INTRODUCTION .............................................................................................................1

2. PAPER ONE ..................................................................................................................... 3

“Search Behavior and Technological Capital of the Diversified Firm:

The Impact of Fit on Innovation”

3. PAPER TWO ................................................................................................................... 42

“Resources and Organizational Boundary Expansion in the Early Stage”

4. PAPER THREE ...............................................................................................................81

“Initial Public Offering and the Strategic Behavior of Firm:

Differentiation and Performance”

5. DISSERTATION SUMMARY AND GENERAL CONCLUSION .............................117

Page 10: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

viii

LIST OF TABLES

2.1 Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix (Paper 1) .........................................................24

2.2 Results of Regression Analysis with Fixed Effects Predicting Innovation Productivity ........25

3.1 Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix (Paper 2) .........................................................63

3.2 Results of Tobit Regression Analysis for Boundary Expansion .............................................64

4.1 Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix (Paper 3) .......................................................101

4.2 Results of Multivariate Regression Analysis Estimating Short-Term and Long Term

Performance of New Ventures ................................................................................................102

Page 11: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

ix

LIST OF FIGURES

2.1 Model of Strategic Fit for Innovation Productivity: Diversification, Search, and

Technological Capital (Paper 1)............................................................................................... 17

2.2 Effect of Organizational Contingencies on Innovation Productivity ......................................29

3.1 Interaction Effects among R&D resource, Environmental Dynamism, and Industry

Competition (Paper 2) ...............................................................................................................67

4.1 Interaction Effects between Differentiation and Environmental Dynamism on the Short-

Term Performance (Paper 3) ...................................................................................................104

Page 12: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

x

Dedication

This dissertation is dedicated to Jihyun Kang, Suah Kim, and my family

who provided both emotional and financial support.

Page 13: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

1

CHAPTER ONE

INTRODUCTION

The topics of innovation and entrepreneurship have been among the main subjects

discussed in the strategic management field. The purpose of this dissertation is to provide a deep

understanding about the behavior of the firm with respect to innovation, organizational boundary

expansion, and IPOs. The first essay provides a new approach to account for the relationship

between diversification and innovation by integrating the insights of organizational search and

contingencies literature. Previous research on this relationship has provided inconclusive results.

To reconcile the debate, we identify organizational contingencies to explain the conditions under

which a diversified corporation has higher innovation output. The empirical results provide

support for the idea that a strategic fit among the diversification strategy, the search behavior,

and the technological capital all serve to increase innovation productivity, while misfit in these

areas decrease innovation output. More specifically, firms using a related diversification strategy

with local search are more likely to select the R&D projects that are related to their existing core

technologies and improve their overall innovation productivity. Also, the results show that

technological capital is a valuable resource that enables the firm to improve innovative

performance as it diversifies into either a related or unrelated industry.

The second essay explores firm’s preference in their search and renewal strategies in the

organizational life cycle. We particularly look into resource portfolio of young firms, and their

strategic choice between internal development and boundary expansion activities. From

capability perspective built on resource based view, we suggest that young firm’s unique

resource portfolio accounts for the patterns of their organizational boundary expansion activities.

Page 14: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

2

With 158 U.S. companies in high technology industry, we find support for the idea that boundary

choice between internal and external market is consistent with the available, unique resource

they posses. The results shows that internal market is preferred by young firms with high R&D

resources, while young firms with high financial resources are more likely to take advantage of

environmental opportunities through market transaction mechanisms, such as acquisitions,

alliances, and joint ventures. We also find that young firms’ boundary expansion activities are

further constrained in the presence of environmental uncertainty, and strong competition in the

industry.

Finally, the third essay addresses an impact of particular strategy of new venture on

short- and long-term performance. New ventures may pursue similarity or differentiation to

increase their performance. We mainly focus on the technological differentiation of new venture

before going public, and how the strategic choice taken before a firm’s IPO influences the firm’s

performance after IPO. The main argument is that new ventures that use a differentiation strategy

will have higher performance than those firms using a similarity strategy. Empirical support for

the argument is found in the high technology industry. We also find that that in the presence of

uncertainty, higher level of differentiation strategy is more positively related with new venture

performance at the time of IPO.

Page 15: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

3

CHAPTER TWO

PAPER ONE

SEARCH BEHAVIOR AND TECHNOLOGICAL CAPITAL OF THE DIVERSIFIED

FIRM: THE IMPACT OF FIT ON INNOVATION

ABSTRACT

This paper provides a new approach to account for the relationship between diversification and

innovation by integrating the insights of organizational search and contingencies literatures.

Unlike the extant literature that suggests a direct effect, we argue that a strategic fit between

diversification and organizational contingencies leads to higher technological innovation. With a

longitudinal study of 248 manufacturing firms’ patenting activity, we find support for the idea

that strategic fit is important for innovation output. More specifically, a related diversification

strategy leads to higher innovation when a narrow technological search strategy is used by the

company. In contrast, an unrelated diversification strategy leads to higher innovation when a

broader technological search strategy is used. We also find that technological capital is

importance for a diversified firm to take an advantage of benefits from broader corporate scope.

Our analyses provide a more refined view of the relationship between diversification strategy

and innovation.

Keywords:

Innovation, diversification, search, organizational contingency

Page 16: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

4

INTRODUCTION

Corporate level strategy is concerned with answering what businesses a company should

be in and how those businesses should be managed to create greater value (Montgomery, 1994;

Porter, 1987). Accordingly, corporate level strategy is concerned foremost with examining how

diversification affects performance. On this point, much research has been conducted over the

last 30 years. From this research we know that a modicum of diversification is associated with

superior performance, but too much diversification is actually detrimental. More specifically,

the relationship between diversification and performance exhibits an inverted-U shape (Palich,

Cardinal, & Miller, 2000).

While understanding the impact of diversification on performance is the primary focus of

corporate strategy research, a related focus in this area of research is understanding how

diversification affects innovation (Hoskisson, Hitt, & Hill, 1991). Given the importance of

innovation on performance (Zollo, Reuer, & Singh, 2002), these two issues are likely not

independent. On the one hand, scholars have suggested a negative relationship between

diversification levels and innovation (Baysinger & Hoskisson, 1989; Hitt, Hoskisson, & Ireland,

1994; Hoskisson, Hitt, Johnson, & Grossman, 2002). As a firm diversifies, it may move away

from its core business and gradually lose its ability to leverage its core competencies (Markides,

1992) particularly if those core competencies are not scalable (e.g. able to grow in relation to the

size of the organization). Additionally, diversification also increases the marginal costs in an

organization owing to the increased information processing demands (Bergh & Lawless, 1998;

Hill & Hoskisson, 1987). Oftentimes, organizations adopt simpler structures and resort to the use

of financial controls once the organization has grown significantly through acquisitions

(Hoskisson, Hitt, Johnson, & Moesel, 1993). Although these activities allow the organization to

Page 17: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

5

expand its span of control, these efforts reduce the amount of rich information used in decision

making (Galbraith, 1974) and can have a vitiating effect on internal innovation. Furthermore,

when business unit managers are evaluated strictly based on their unit’s financial performance,

they become risk averse and unwilling to invest in uncertain technology needed for internal

innovation. As a result, research has found that organizations which are more diversified tend to

acquire innovation rather than develop it internally (Hoskisson et al., 2002). In sum, this

research tends to evidence a negative relationship between diversification levels and innovation.

On the other hand, some scholars have suggested an alternative perspective and argue

that diversification actually abets innovation. A firm which actively engages in diversification

tends to have both a mindset of exploration and exploitation along with high R&D investment

(Chen, 1996). Since diversified firms possess more opportunities for the internal use of

knowledge, innovativeness may actually increase owing to the economies of scope arising

through diversification (Katila & Ahuja, 2002). Such firms may also develop higher and diverse

levels of absorptive capacity which, in turn increases innovativeness (Lane, Koka and Pathak,

2006). Additionally, transferring technology and skills may be easier within organizational

boundaries than beyond organizational boundaries (Miller, Fern, & Cardinal, 2007a). In an

international context, for example, Barkema and Vermeulen (1998) argued that higher levels of

international diversification were associated with Greenfield ventures and the use of internally

developed innovation whereas lower levels of international diversification were associated with

acquisitions. They argued that the less-diversified firm will generally use acquisitions to acquire

needed technology whereas the more-diversified firm will develop the technology internally as a

result of superior capabilities for internal innovation.

Page 18: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

6

Given these two apparently conflicting perspectives, it would seem that our

understanding of the relationship between diversification and innovation has reached an impasse.

With these issues in mind, we cannot simply conjecture about the relationship between

diversification and innovation without understanding the innovation process and the search

behavior of firms. Thus, we seek to identify when a diversified firm will have higher innovation

outputs and how organizational contingencies (i.e. search scope and technological capital)

influence the innovation. Overall, the purpose is to attempt to reconcile the above

inconsistencies by suggesting a contingency approach (Govindarajan, 1988; Venkatraman, 1989)

which combines organizational search theory, technological capital, and diversification strategy.

This paper contributes to the diversification and innovation literature by providing a more

elaborate explanation concerning the effect of diversification strategy on innovation. Instead of

assuming a simple positive or negative relationship between diversification and innovation, we

show how existing capabilities as well as the existing diversification strategy affects innovation.

Additionally, by taking into account firms’ search behavior, we are able to show that the type of

search (e.g. local or distant) moderates the relationship between diversification type and

innovation output. The paper is organized as follows. We first provide a brief review of the

literature on innovation, and organizational search. Afterwards, we develop a model that

accounts for the differences in innovation productivity in diversified firms. Hypotheses

concerning innovation are then developed based on the concept of strategic fit (between

diversification strategy and organizational contingencies). Next the hypotheses are tested on a

sample of 248 U.S. manufacturing firms during the period 1991-1998. Finally, implications and

topics for future research are discussed.

Page 19: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

7

THEORETICAL BACKGROUND

It is difficult to conclude whether diversification improves a firm’s innovation and extant

research addressing the relationship between diversification and innovation seems rather

inconsistent. We believe that there are four underlying reasons for the apparently inconsistent

findings. First, the labels given to corporate diversification strategies and the theories used to

explain the reasons for diversification have necessarily given the notion that higher levels of

diversification are driven primarily by agency motives (Montgomery, 1994). More specifically,

as noted above, higher diversification levels are associated with managerial self-interest seeking

as well as lower investment in uncertain technology because both actions reduce managerial

employment risk. Indeed, in one of the most impactful papers on corporate strategy, Porter

(1987) argued that an unrelated diversification strategy is only value creating in an inefficient

capital market (which is not applicable in developed economies) or when a company uses it for

restructuring purposes (wherein an acquiring company restructures a poorly performing company

and then spins or sells it off afterwards). Based on Rumelt’s (1974) classification of

diversification types, it is assumed that firms which are highly diversified such as Tyco Intl

(Collis & Montgomery, 1998) utilize an unrelated diversification strategy and therefore seek to

be run as lean as possible. From this research stream, the impression is that firms which are

more highly diversified must necessarily be ‘low tech’ and focused on reducing costs as low as

possible. However, this may not be true because there are companies like G.E. and Disney

which maintain high levels of diversification and still exhibit high levels of innovation.

Second, most prior papers focus on one of the two sides of innovation (Ahuja, Lampert,

& Tandon, 2008). Innovation, broadly defined as ‘the adoption of an idea or behavior related to

a device, a process, or a product, that is new to the organization’ (Aiken & Hage, 1971;

Page 20: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

8

Damanpour, Szabat, & Evan, 1989; Hage, 1999), can be separated into innovation inputs or

efforts (also synonymous with innovation intensity), and innovation outputs (Ahuja et al., 2008).

Although diversification scholars have primarily focused on innovation efforts (such as R&D

intensity), innovative efforts differ from innovative outputs in that the former is associated with

incentives, while the latter is related to productivity. Previous studies have assumed that there is

a strong correlation between R&D intensity and valuable internal innovation, but this assumption

may not be true (Trajtenberg, 1990). Again, innovation intensity should be a necessary condition,

but not necessarily a sufficient condition for valuable innovation. In addition, innovation input

and output may not be perfectly endogenous to corporate strategy. Some firms continue or even

increase their investment in R&D activities, and engage in R&D projects more intensively after

diversifying. Therefore, it is still unclear how diversification strategy influences the quality and

productivity of technological innovation.

Third, there is a need to integrate organizational search activity in a more nuanced way

into the diversification literature beyond the idea that some firms acquire innovation and some

develop it internally. Research activity in firms can be modeled as a search for solutions in the

knowledge domain (Ahuja & Katila, 2004; Fleming, 2001; Rosenkopf & Nerkar, 2001). And

scholars have viewed innovation as the result of organizational search (Cyert & March, 1963;

Greve & Taylor, 2000) or learning behavior (Levinthal & March, 1993; March, 1991). They

have endeavored to understand how organizations explore new knowledge that can be applied to

the existing knowledge and how those activities influence the magnitude of innovation.

Similarly, diversifying firms tend to engage in broader search for technological innovation

(Miller, 2006), and can take advantage of new knowledge across business units thereby leading

to better prospects for realizing economies of scope in R&D activities by sharing knowledge

Page 21: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

9

(Markides & Williamson, 1994; Miller et al., 2007a). Although organizational search behavior

has often been treated as exogenous to diversification strategy, it does not provide a clear

explanation about the effect of diversification on innovation productivity. Therefore, it would be

valuable to account for how organizational search behavior in combination with the

diversification strategy affects innovation.

Fourth, previous research examining the link between diversification and innovation has

not taken into account the firm’s existing resources and capabilities. A firm with its own set of

innovation capabilities in a technologically oriented industry may acquire another company

which has complementary technology that can be used to further improve the existing core

technology (Zahra, Ireland, & Hitt, 2000). Through this acquisition, the firm obtains and

accumulates new technological capital (Ahuja & Katila, 2001). Although diversified firms have

opportunities to explore new technology by integrating their existing technology with that which

is acquired, these opportunities may not result in high innovation output unless the firms have

sufficient R&D resources and capabilities to begin with. Thus, firm characteristics may

significantly influence the ability to explore potential opportunities of increased corporate scope.

In this paper we specifically focus on how newly-obtained technology can be integrated

with existing technology, and how a diversified firm improves its innovation productivity in the

process. Technological innovation, which is defined as ‘a technology new to a given

organization’ (Schoonhoven, Eisenhardt, & Lyman, 1990; Tornatzky et al., 1983), is an

intangible asset which often plays a critical role in achieving competitive advantage (Barney,

2001; Grant, 1996).

Page 22: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

10

INNOVATION, SEARCH, AND STRATEGIC FIT

Accessing external knowledge is important because it fosters innovation and enhances

firm performance (Zollo et al., 2002). Knowledge search and its incorporation into the

organization are very much a part of the innovation process. Since knowledge search is a central

part of the innovation process, a key question from a corporate level strategy perspective is

understanding how a diversified company goes about obtaining external knowledge.

From a corporate strategy perspective, technological innovation could be complementary

to the firms’ diversification strategy. As noted above, diversification has both positive and

negative effects on innovation. Simply investigating the direct relationship and drawing

conclusions hinders the possibility of identifying what factors may affect the relationship

between diversification levels and innovation. We argue that firms pursuing innovation must

find the right ‘fit’ between their diversification strategy and the organizational contingencies

needed for innovation. According to the strategic formulation literature, a strategic fit refers to

the situation in which a firm’s strategy is congruent with environmental or organizational

contingencies (Andrews, 1971; Siggelkow, 2001; Zajac, Kraatz, & Bresser, 2000). Organizations

pursue strategic fit in order to achieve desirable performance and output (Miles & Snow, 1994).

In this paper, search scope and technological capital are mainly focused among the

organizational contingencies which are directly related to the implementation of innovation

strategy.

Search Scope as Organizational Contingency

Cyert and March (1963) provided a basic frame for studying organizational search

behavior in their classic book. Organizations engage in search behavior to find solutions and

facilitate changes in organizational routines (Greve & Taylor, 2000). Thus, search behavior is

Page 23: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

11

part of the organizational learning process (Huber, 1991) and an essential step in innovation

dynamics (Nelson & Winter, 1982).

Organizational search can be classified into two types in terms of scope: 1) distant search

which refers to exploration of new opportunities that emphasize more experimental and distant

innovation beyond current organizational boundaries (Rosenkopf & Nerkar, 2001), and 2) local

search which refers to exploitation that emphasizes immediate refinement and proximate

alternatives in a firm’s R&D activity (Nelson & Winter, 1982). On the one hand, a firm may

concentrate on a bounded set of technologies to cultivate valuable and commercially viable

products, which is local search. On the other hand, a firm may expand its technological path into

new areas that will serve as the seed for future technological developments, which is distant

search (Levitt & March, 1988; March, 1991). For example, Stuart and Podolny (1996) found

that organizations tend to engage in local search in order to develop a related technological

domain from their existing knowledge store.

In terms of scope, local search is characterized as narrow or focused, while distant search

is broad. Based on the nature of these search types, it would make sense that firms using a

narrow diversification strategy would be more likely to utilize a narrow search since their

strategy is associated with sharing activities among subunits. On the other hand, as a firm’s level

of diversification increases the ability to share local knowledge would likely decline due to the

diseconomies of sharing (e.g. increasing differences among business units would make it less

useful to share the same knowledge across all units). As a result, we should expect to see

broader search as the level of diversification increases and empirical results support this direct

relationship (Miller, 2004). Since we are interested in testing the concept of fit in this paper,

however, we are seeking to examine how diversification levels and search types affect

Page 24: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

12

innovation outputs. If strategic fit is important (as we have argued thus far), then a lack of fit

should lead to lower innovation output.

As noted above, search scope and organizational scope follow similar themes. That is,

narrower search is consistent with related diversification in that both are associated with the

pursuit of resources or technologies in a related area. Broader search is consistent with unrelated

diversification in that both are associated with the pursuit of resources in a distant or unrelated

area. For example, when a firm in the automobile industry focuses on improving its core

technology and seeks to exploit possible complementary technologies in a similar industry,

related diversification would support the firm’s R&D activity. This strategic action could lead to

higher innovation productivity because the firm obtains a strategic fit between its corporate

strategy and search behavior. In this case, higher relatedness could lead to what Markides and

Williamson (1994) call ‘asset fission.’ After diversifying, the firm would have a greater number

of potential combinations of knowledge to extend to the existing knowledge bases of each unit

and thereby may develop new knowledge.

As a firm pursues greater diversification, it becomes more difficult to know which

combinations of knowledge will provide the highest rewards. Likewise, when a firm with lower

levels of diversification pursues more distant search, the same difficulty arises. It becomes

increasingly difficult to understand how technologies beyond the core can easily be applied to

current knowledge and it also becomes more difficult to extend this more distant knowledge to

all of the firm’s business units. Further, when a firm attempts to utilize knowledge combinations

outside of the core technologies, the ability to profitably utilize this knowledge will decline and

impede innovation productivity. As such, familiarity and similarity with a technology obtained

through local search should lead to a stronger ability to exploit this knowledge. Therefore, we

Page 25: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

13

suggest that extending the existing technology through local search will be positively associated

with the relationship between related diversification and innovation productivity.

Hypothesis 1. Search scope moderates the relationship between related

diversification and innovation productivity such that a diversified corporation in

related industries is positively (negatively) related to innovation productivity

when the firm pursues local (distant) search.

Diversification which is carefully managed and implemented supports exploiting new

opportunities by sharing and transferring resources across business units. While firms may stay

within their technological trajectories (Dosi, 1982), they may also go beyond their technological

trajectories in order to find novelty from the combination of inherent technologies and new ones

across domains (March, 1991; Miller, 2006). Studies in search scope have found support for the

argument that firms first diversify their technology in predictable ways, and then enter into new

markets on the basis of the technological trajectory (Miller, 2004; Silverman, 1999). However,

sharing complementary competencies in order to realize synergies between the existing units and

new units (Hoskisson & Hitt, 1990) also may lead to information overload, information

asymmetry, and complexity. Although there are more opportunities to develop innovation

through integrating core technologies and newly acquired technologies, a different direction

between diversification and search behavior results in decreased innovation productivity. In this

situation when firms engaging in unrelated diversification seek sources for innovation in a close

industry, a strategic misfit occurs. Additionally, simply having access to technologies in the

distant industry does not guarantee the development of new innovation unless the firm

Page 26: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

14

intentionally pursues innovation that integrates its existing technologies with the new

technologies unrelated to its core technology. Therefore, we believe that a strategic misfit

between organizational diversification levels and search behavior will decrease the firm’s

innovation productivity. In contrast, a strategic fit exists when firms with a tendency for distant

search diversify into unrelated industries, and this enables the firm to improve innovation

productivity.

Hypothesis 2. Search scope moderates the relationship between unrelated

diversification and innovation productivity such that a diversified corporation in

unrelated industries is positively (negatively) related to innovation productivity

when the firm pursues distant (local) search.

Technological Capital as Organizational Contingency

To explain technological capital as an organizational contingency, this paper builds on

the knowledge based view (KBV) of the firm, which views firms as heterogeneous, knowledge-

bearing entities (Grant, 1996). KBV considers knowledge the most strategically important

resource to achieve sustainable competitive advantage (Grant, 1996; Spender, 1996), and

emphasizes the importance of human and technological capital since the investment in firm-

specific human capital has a significant impact on learning and performance (Hatch & Dyer,

2004). According to this perspective, organizations should develop technological capital, which

is defined as a firm’s capability in creating new technology, products, and processes (Ahuja,

2000; Cohen & Levinthal, 1990). In technology-oriented industries, technological capital is a

necessary resource to gain a competitive advantage.

Page 27: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

15

As Arora and Gambardella (1990) note, a firm’s successful history in innovative

activities serves as signals of their accumulated technological capital. It also represents the firm’s

innovation intensity in that the efforts in innovation are reflected by the accumulated knowledge

stocks. Given this, diversified firms can be divided into two groups depending on their level of

technological capital. An organization with high technological capital is capable of utilizing the

technologies available from acquisitions, while another group with low technological capital

would experience lower innovation productivity because of a lack of this capability. Even in the

stage of selecting a target, other things being equal, firms prefer to acquire potential firms which

possess higher levels of technological capital themselves (Ahuja, 2000).

Although increases in the level of diversification through acquisition allow a firm to

access external sources for innovation and increase innovation productivity, this positive effect

may reduce the firm’s R&D intensity for internal R&D development (Hoskisson & Johnson,

1992). For the firm with low technological capital, high diversification makes the firm less

capable of developing new products and technology internally. This situation indicates a

strategic misfit which occurs when a firm with little technological capital (e.g. lack of an ability

to invent new technologies) highly diversifies in order to improve innovation productivity.

However, when a firm has high technological capital, the firm is more willing to explore

opportunities to combine available technologies. Thus, with high technological capital, the

diversified firm is more likely to pursue potential opportunities from the more available

resources, which positively influences the relationship between diversification and innovation

productivity. The firm’s capability to develop new technology internally complementarily

enhances innovation productivity. Therefore, a strategic fit exists when firms with high

technological capital diversify.

Page 28: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

16

Since the current position of a company in terms of technology is determined by the path

it has pursued (Teece, Pisano, & Shuen, 1997), this paper suggests hypotheses that test the effect

of a firm’s accumulated knowledge stock and R&D capability in the past, which represents the

amount of technological capital. Therefore, we suggest that diversification strategy is positively

associated with innovation productivity when a corporation has high levels of knowledge stock.

This effect will be consistent with both unrelated and unrelated diversification.

Hypothesis 3. Knowledge stock moderates the relationship between both related

and unrelated diversification, and innovation productivity such that a diversified

corporation is positively related to innovation productivity when the firm has

higher knowledge stock.

With little expertise in the technologies of an industry, firms are unable to innovate by

using technologies available from a diversification strategy. Thus, we suggest that diversification

strategy supports innovation activities when a firm has strong R&D capability.

Hypothesis 4. R&D capability moderates the relationship between both related

and unrelated diversification, and innovation productivity such that a diversified

corporation is positively related to innovation productivity when the firm has

higher R&D capability.

Page 29: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

17

FIGURE 2.1 Model of Strategic Fit for Innovation Productivity: Diversification, Search, and Technological

Capital

METHOD

Data and Sample

The research sample was drawn from U.S. companies in the manufacturing industries.

The data was mainly obtained from the COMPUSTAT Business Segment data and the National

Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Patent Citations data file. An updated NBER patent data

contains information about patent, technological class, application year, citation, and assignee in

the period 1975 -2002 (Hall, Jaffe, & Trajtenberg, 2001). Although many scholars have used

Innovation Productivity

Diversification

Related Diversification

Unrelated Diversification

Search Scope

Local Search

Dominant Search

Technological Capital

R&D Capability

Knowledge Stock

Page 30: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

18

patent data as a proxy measure for innovation (see Argyres & Silverman, 2004; Miller et al.,

2007a; Rosenkopf & Nerkar, 2001), Patent data is not without limitations in that not all

technological innovation is patented (Hall et al., 2001). Patent activities vary from industry to

industry, and patents are a way to protect intellectual property rights rather than measuring the

innovation output directly (Rodriguez-Duarte, Sandulli, Minguela-Rata, & Lopez-Sanchez,

2007). Additionally, patents represent invention rather than innovation (Becheikh, Landry, &

Amara, 2006). However, these concerns are mitigated by the benefits of using patent data. First,

NBER patent data allows scholars to measure a firm’s technological capital, flow of knowledge,

and interfirm relationships for knowledge building. Second, the availability of panel data is

helpful in determining the causality among variables. Additionally, Patel and Pavitt (1994) point

out the complements between codified knowledge and uncodified knowledge (so unpatented data

should not be a problem). Lastly, since this paper focuses on technological innovation, patent

data would be an appropriate source to measure firms’ behaviors concerning technological

innovation, and technological capital.

Using COMPUSTAT data, we collected all U.S. companies in the manufacturing

industries in the period between 1991 and 19981

1 NBER patent data was available for the period 1963-2002, but data in 2002 were not considered because of the few citations and patent applications. Innovation productivity and knowledge stock were measured by the 4-year accumulative number of patents before and after the focal year, respectively. Thus, the overall time windows were 1987-2001 for patent data, and 1991-1998 for financial data.

. The manufacturing firms were determined

based on 4-digit SIC codes 2011-3999. After matching the sample with patent data by using

CUSIP numbers, 947 firms remained. Of these, only 248 firms met the criteria that patent data

and financial data were available during 1987-2001, and that a firm existed at least 10 years

which allowed us to obtain a minimum of five years of longitudinal data. The final sample was

Page 31: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

19

248 companies in manufacturing industries in the period 1991-1998. The total number of

longitudinal observations in the period was 19052

Measures

.

Dependent variable. The dependent variable, innovation productivity, represents the

degree to which a firm benefits from R&D activities. It was measured by the natural log of the

accumulated number of patents applied for during the four years3

Independent Variable. The independent variable, diversification, was measured by the

entropy measure developed by Palepu (1985). There are multiple ways to measure the level of

diversification, but Hoskisson et al. (1993) found evidence of construct validity for the entropy

measure (Amit & Schoemaker, 1993; Jacquemin & Berry, 1979). It consists of two components

(Total diversification (DT) = Related Diversification (DR) + Unrelated Diversification (DU)). To

test the suggested hypotheses, we used related diversification (DR) and unrelated diversification

after the focal year. As noted

earlier, the technological innovation process can be separated into two different points of view:

innovation intensity (input side) and innovation productivity (output side) (Ahuja et al., 2008).

Innovation intensity investigates the sources and determinants of innovation, while innovation

productivity studies the output of R&D activities. To be consistent with the purpose of this paper

and the notion that innovation intensity does not fully account for the direct results of innovation,

we focused on the output side which is innovation productivity. The innovation intensity was

controlled for, however, to avoid an alternative explanation.

2 The minimum observation per firm was 5, and the maximum was 8. The average of the number of observation per firm was 7.7.

3 Increase or decrease in corporate scope requires substantial effort, time, and resources in the process of restructuring organizations. A four year span was chosen to reflect the change in innovation productivity both during and after the restructuring process.

Page 32: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

20

(DU). The entropy measure was calculated from COMPUSTAT business segment data each

target year.

Organizational contingencies. For three organizational contingency variables, we

measured search scope for search behavior, and knowledge stock and R&D capability for

technological capital. First, technological search scope refers to the degree to which a focal

patent cites prior art from a variety of technological domains. Our measure is the same as the

‘originality’ measure in the paper by Trajenberg, Henderson, and Jaffe (1997). The greater the

search scope, the broader the technological roots of the underlying research (Trajtenberg et al.,

1997). In other words, the more diverse the technologies cited by a focal patent, the broader was

the search effort underlying the patent (Argyres & Silverman, 2004). We calculated the search

scope of firm i in year t from the following equation:

Search Scopeit = NCit

(NCit − 1){1 − ��

NcitediktNcitedit

�2Ni

k=1

}

,where Ncitedit is the total number of citations that firm i made at year t, Ncitedikt is the total

number of citations that firm i made in the three-digit technological category k in year t, and NCit

is the number of total citation that a focal company i has made in year t. Technological search

scope as the Herfindahl-type measure suffers from bias due to the count nature of the underlying

data. The bias occurs when a patent with a small number of citations has a non-zero probability

that no citations will actually be observed. To remedy this bias, we applied the procedure

developed by Hall et al. (2001), which involves the search scope measure multiplied by N/(N-1).

Overall, the average value in the four prior years was used to represent firm-level search scope.

Second, knowledge stock was measured by the total number of patents obtained by a firm

in the four prior years as an indicator of a firm’s cumulated technical capital (Ahuja, 2000). The

Page 33: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

21

past innovative activities and capabilities serve as signals of a firm’s technical competences

(Arora & Gambardella, 1990). It is expected that the more patents the firm possesses, the greater

the firm’s knowledge store is.

Third, innovation impact was used to measure R&D capability. Innovation impact

indicates the degree to which a firm’s patents are subsequently cited by patents of other firms

(Miller et al., 2007a). Since higher impact leads to more economic benefits (Harhoff, Narin,

Scherer, & Vopel, 1999), impact itself is a good measure of R&D activity. When a firm has had

higher impact in the past, it indicates that the firm has strong capabilities for developing new

innovation. Innovation impact was calculated by measuring the average number of citations

received from others during four years before the focal year; thus a higher score, indicates

stronger impact. The equation to calculate innovation impact of firm i in year t is:

Innovation Impactit =1

NPit(0.05 + �

NcitingijtAvgcitingt

)Nj

j=1

,where Avgcitingt is the average of citations received from other firms in the application year t,

Ncitingijt is the number of citations that firm i’s patent j received from other firms in year t, and

NPit is the total number of patent that firm i applied in year t. To handle the truncation problem,

the fixed effects approach (Hall et al., 2001) was used. By dividing the number of citations

received by the yearly mean (i.e. Avgcitingt), the approach controls for the year effect in each

patent. Since many firms had 0 citations, a constant of 0.05 was added to the equation. The

value was divided by the number of patents applied for by firm i so that the overall value

represents the firm-level impact.

Control variables. We included control variables to avoid an alternative explanation. All

control variables were measured at the target year. First, R&D intensity (Chen, 2003; Cohen &

Levinthal, 1990) has been considered innovation input that may influence innovation output.

Page 34: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

22

R&D intensity was measured by the ratio of R&D expenses to total assets. It represents the

firm’s inputs and efforts into the innovation process. Second, a firm’s financial performance may

influence innovation productivity (Chen & Miller, 2007). Performance was measured by return

on assets (ROA) which is the ratio of income to total assets.

Third, three types of slack resources were controlled for since slack can abet innovation

(Nohria & Gulati, 1996). The three measures for slack include recoverable slack, potential slack,

and available slack (Bromiley, 1991; Singh, 1986). Recoverable slack was measured as the

selling, general and administrative expenses to sales ratio; potential slack was measured as the

debt to equity ratio; and available slack was measured as the current ratio (Bergh & Lawless,

1998; Bromiley, 1991; Singh, 1986). Data to measure slack resources were collected from

COMPUSTAT.

Fourth, the model also included firm size measured as the logarithm of the number of

employees. Previous studies have reported a positive effect of size on innovation (e.g. Chaney &

Devinney, 1992). Furthermore, larger firms may naturally hold more patents.

Fifth, there are external factors that make it more or less attractive to introduce new

technology, such as market conditions and the general economic environment. These factors are

changing over time and may significantly influence the patenting activities. Thus, the year effect

was controlled for by including year dummies (1991-1997).

Analysis

The unit of analysis was the firm’s level of innovation. Since the dependent variable,

innovation productivity, consisted of at least five observations (i.e. a natural log of all patents

applied for) for each firm during the 1991-1998 time period, we used a longitudinal regression

model with fixed effects for a cross-sectional time series panel data. We tested for serial

Page 35: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

23

autocorrelation using the Hausman test. The null hypothesis stating that the difference in

coefficients in the fixed effects model and the random effects model is not systematic, was

rejected (p <0.001). This suggests that a fixed effects model is more appropriate for the analysis

(Benner & Tushman, 2003; Hsiao, 2003; Miller & Eden, 2006), in which we used Xtreg, fe

command in STATA. To correct for potential variable bias, time-varying firm specific factors,

including R&D intensity, size, performance, and slack resources were included as control

variables. Year dummies were also used to control for the time-invariant omitted-variable effect.

Overall, this model allows us to test the effect of organizational contingencies on the relationship

between types of diversification and innovation productivity after controlling for all potential

biases. All continuous variables were centered in the analysis before testing the effect of

interaction terms.

Page 36: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

TABLE 2.1 Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix

Mean S.D. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 1. Innovation 4.22 1.56 1 2. ROA 0.06 0.08 0.08 *** 1 3. Available Slack 2.29 1.58 -0.25 *** 0.21 *** 1 4. Potential Slack 0.6 1.22 -0.02 -0.27 *** -0.20 *** 1 5. Recoverable Slack 0.27 0.13 0.06 ** 0.06 ** 0.16 *** -0.08 *** 1 6. Size 2.16 1.25 0.62 *** -0.02 -0.47 *** 0.12 *** -0.21 *** 1 7. R&D Intensity 0.06 0.05 0.23 *** -0.05 * 0.17 *** -0.16 *** 0.47 *** -0.23 *** 1 8. DR (related div.) 0.26 0.45 0.14 *** 0.00 -0.18 *** 0.11 *** -0.06 * 0.29 *** -0.11 *** 1 9. DU (unrelated div.) 0.23 0.36 0.04 † -0.06 * -0.19 *** 0.09 *** -0.26 *** 0.33 *** -0.29 *** 0.13 *** 1 10. Search Scope 0.78 0.16 0.56 *** -0.06 ** -0.23 *** 0.01 -0.06 * 0.48 *** 0.02 0.16 *** 0.15 *** 1 11. Knowledge Stock 220.83 608.83 0.59 *** -0.01 -0.15 *** 0.01 -0.02 0.48 *** 0.07 ** 0.23 *** 0.06 * 0.30 *** 1 12. R&D Capability 1.01 0.66 0.26 *** 0.05 * 0.17 *** -0.09 *** 0.20 *** -0.15 *** 0.40 *** -0.16 *** -0.24 *** -0.04 † 0.06 ** 1

N=1905 (248 firms during at least 5 years from 1991 to 1998) † p < .10 * p < .05 ** p < .01 *** p < .001

24

Page 37: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

25

TABLE 2.2

Results of Regression Analysis with Fixed Effects Predicting Innovation Productivity

Model1 Model2 Model3 Constant 3.95 *** 3.96 *** 3.98 *** ROA 0.23 0.26 0.29 † Available Slack -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 Potential Slack 0.00 0.00 0.00 Recoverable Slack -0.36 -0.27 -0.30 Size 0.28 *** 0.25 *** 0.23 *** R&D Intensity -0.72 -0.76 -0.47 Year Dummies 7 *** 7 *** 7 *** DR -0.03 0.04 DU 0.15 * 0.21 * Search Scope 0.35 ** 0.39 *** Knowledge Stock 0.14 **a 0.20 ***a R&D Capability 0.07 * 0.18 *** DR x Search Scope -0.68 *** DU x Search Scope 1.13 *** DR x Knowledge Stock 0.03 a

DU x Knowledge Stock 0.11 a

DR x R&D Capability 0.15 ** DU x R&D Capability 0.45 *** R2 Within 0.11 0.13 0.16 R2 Between 0.33 0.47 0.51 R2 Overall 0.31 0.43 0.48 F-value 16.35 *** 13.47 *** 13.09 *** F test that all u_i=0 46.36 *** 27.70 *** 27.78 ***

N=1905; number of firms =248 a The regression coefficients were multiplied by 1000 in the purpose of report. † p < .10 * p < .05 ** p < .01 *** p < .001

Page 38: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

26

RESULTS

Table 1 displays the descriptive statistics and correlations for each of the variables in the

regression model. Since there were no high correlations between any pair of independent

variables, multicollinearity was not the main concern (see Table 1).

Table 2 shows the results of the longitudinal regression model with fixed effect. Model 1

included all control variables; model 2 added related/unrelated diversification (i.e. DR and DU)

and all organizational contingencies; and model 3 tested hypotheses 1 to 4 by including all

interaction terms. The results indicate the importance of controlling for firm-level fixed effects.

The null hypothesis that all unobserved firm-level characteristics are equal was rejected

(F=46.36, p<0.001 in model 1; F=27.70, p<0.001 in model 2, and F=27.78, p<0.001 in model 3)

thereby providing support for the use of the fixed effects model. The strong year effects (p<0.001)

also indicates the importance of testing longitudinal data. Compared with model 1 with only

control variables, model 3 with organizational contingencies explained much more of the

variance in innovation productivity (R2=0.16, and F=13.09, p<0.001).

Hypothesis 1 and 2 proposed the contingency effect of searching behavior on the

relationship between each type of diversification strategy and innovation productivity. The

results in model 3 supported these hypotheses. The coefficient for the interaction term between

related diversification and search scope (DR x Search Scope) was negative and strongly

significant (β = -0.68, p<0.001). Also, the coefficient for the interaction term between unrelated

diversification and search scope (DU x Search Scope) was positive and also strongly significant

(β = 1.13, p<0.001). The interpretation is that a strategic fit between search behavior and the

types of diversification strategy is positively related to innovation productivity.

Page 39: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

27

Hypothesis 3 and 4 predicted that technological capital plays a role in organizational

contingency such that both types of diversification lead to higher innovation productivity when

the firm has a large knowledge store and high R&D capability. The results in model 3 provided

support for hypothesis 4 but not for hypothesis 3. The results in Model 3 show that although

knowledge store increases innovation productivity (β = 0.20, p<0.001), the coefficients for the

interaction terms (DR x Knowledge Store and DU x Knowledge Store) were not significant. It

means that simply having more knowledge and technology does not help a firm develop more

technology as it increases its level of diversification. Consistent with hypotheses 4, Model 3

shows that R&D capability positively moderates the effect of diversification on the development

of new technology (β = 0.15, p<0.05 for related diversification, and β = 0.45, p<0.001 for

unrelated diversification).

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

Research on the relationship between diversification and innovation has provided

inconclusive results (Ahuja et al., 2008). In this paper, we identified organizational contingences

to explain the conditions under which a diversified corporation has higher innovation

productivity. The empirical results provide support for the argument that a strategic fit among

search, diversification, and technological capital increases a firm’s innovation productivity,

while a misfit decreases innovation output. Thus, a related diversified firm improves its

innovation when it pursues local search. This focused search should help the firm build on its

core competencies and develop new knowledge. Local search prevents a firm from not only

losing sight of its core competencies but it also helps a firm from being overwhelmed by the

numerous opportunities arising in a diversification strategy. As a result, firms using a related

Page 40: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

28

diversification strategy with local search are more likely to select the R&D projects that are

related to their existing core technologies and improve their overall innovation productivity.

In the case of distant search, firms that pursue knowledge and resources from a distant

industry may enjoy the opportunities available from the acquisition of businesses in a different

industry. We find that unrelated diversified firms enjoy higher innovation when they engage in

distant search. It appears that those firms are interested in the integration of technologies across

industries, and unrelated diversification allows the firms to obtain these opportunities (See chart

a) and b) in Figure 2). Firms using higher levels of unrelated diversification may be willing to

expend greater resources after an acquisition to promote new innovation.

Page 41: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

29

FIGURE 2.2

Effect of Organizational Contingencies on Innovation Productivity

a) The strategic fit between search scope and related diversification

b) The strategic fit between search scope and unrelated diversification

Innovation productivity

Unrelated Diversification

Local search

Distant search

Low High

Innovation productivity

Related Diversification

Local search

Distant search

Low High

Page 42: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

30

FIGURE 2.2 (continued)

c) The strategic fit between technological capital (R&D capability) and related

diversification

d) The strategic fit between technological capital (R&D capability) and unrelated diversification

Innovation productivity

Unrelated Diversification

High R&D capability

Low R&D capability

Low High

Innovation productivity

Related Diversification

High R&D capability

Low R&D capability

Low High

Page 43: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

Also, technological capital is a valuable resource that enables the firm to improve

innovative performance as it diversifies into either a related or unrelated industry. The results

demonstrate that the opportunities for innovation generated from both types of diversification

strategies can be exploited only when a firm has high technological capital to begin with.

However, firms that are already well equipped with technological capital also may have lower

incentives to recombine technologies (Ahuja, 2000). Therefore, technological capital does not

simply reflect the positive effect on the relationship between diversification and innovation

productivity. Even though more opportunities for knowledge recombination are available with

increased diversification, only a firm that has high existing technological capital and is willing to

expend the effort to recombine technologies (through higher R&D intensity) can take advantage

of the opportunities (see chart c) and d) in Figure 2). Overall, this paper suggests that diversified

firms can improve their innovation productivity when they achieve a strategic fit between

diversification and organizational contingencies.

This paper builds on extant theory in four ways. First, this paper is one of a few that

applies a contingency approach to research the effect of corporate strategy on innovation. The

notion that changes in R&D investment caused by the change in corporate scope directly and

indirectly affects innovation output, may overstate the effect of corporate scope. Firms explore

and exploit opportunities so differently that the patterns of past behavior and accumulated

resources have a significant impact on innovation efforts and output. The findings in the analysis

confirm that firm-specific factors (i.e. past behavior and resources) should be taken into account

to understand how corporate strategy influences innovation output.

Second, the findings imply that a firm’s innovation efforts differ from innovation

productivity. Although corporate scope influences innovation efforts (i.e. R&D intensity), it is

Page 44: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

32

still unclear if this effect is derived from economies of scope in R&D activities, or if a necessary

investment in organizational coordination and integration reduces resources that can be used for

R&D projects. The assumption that innovation intensity is exogenous to the corporate strategy

contrasts previous literature which mainly discusses how diversification strategy influences

innovation intensity. Future studies may derive more useful research ideas from this perspective.

Third, the current study implicitly emphasizes the importance of absorptive capacity

(Cohen & Levinthal, 1990) for a diversified firm, which refers to a firm’s ability to value,

assimilate, and apply knowledge obtained from external sources. In this sense, R&D capability

of a diversified firm can be interpreted as absorptive capacity. Access to external resources

through acquisition does not support R&D activities unless the firm possesses technological

know-how (i.e. absorptive capacity) for exploiting the opportunities.

Lastly, both related and unrelated diversification strategies were examined as well as

their relationship with innovation. The literature on innovation and diversification has mainly

investigated related diversification, and has paid less attention to unrelated diversification. By

including both of the components of the entropy measure, this paper contributes to the study of

unrelated diversification strategy and suggests that strategic fit accounts for the variation in

innovation for unrelated-diversified firms, as well as that in related diversified firms.

The findings also provide implications to managers in a diversified firm. When a firm

explores a new technology through diversification, managers may be concerned about a potential

negative effect on the company’s ability to develop new innovations afterwards given the

increased complexity, potential inflexibility, and information overload. However, the firm will

be able to improve its innovation if it possesses strong R&D capability and if its search patterns

are consistent with the nature of its corporate strategy. Thus, it is important to evaluate if a

Page 45: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

33

diversified firm has strong internal R&D capability and if there is consistency between a firm’s

strategy and R&D activity. In addition to these conditions, investment in organizational

coordination and integration should be accompanied with investment in innovation in order to

achieve economies of scope and effectiveness. After finishing coordination and integration

activities, the firm should refocus on R&D activities to exploit the opportunities from richer

knowledge stores and resources.

There are a few limitations in this paper. First, using patent data as a measure of

innovation inherently involves some limitations as discussed in the methods session. Second, the

causal relationship among diversification strategy, search behavior, and innovation was not

specified. On the one hand, scholars have examined the causal direction from search behavior or

innovation to diversification. For example, Chang (1996) argued that the search for new

combinations of knowledge may account for patterns of a firm’s strategic actions, such as

acquisition, restructuring, and divestitures. Silverman (1999) suggested that the technology

classes in a firm’s patents predict the future industry-related direction of diversification. On the

other hand, there has been research examining the causality of diversification on innovation. For

example, Hoskisson and Johnson (1992), and Hoskisson and Hitt (1988) suggested that firms

which increased organizational scope reduced R&D intensity by shifting from strategic control to

financial control. However, Rodriguez-Duarte et al. (2007) suggested a bidirectional relationship

between innovation and diversification. Thus, future search should seek to probe this issue

further.

Lastly, environmental contingencies were not considered. Organizational contingency

variables are part of all possible conditions that influence the relationship between innovation

and diversification. Environmental uncertainty, industry competitiveness, and the economic

Page 46: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

34

situation are external conditions that may affect the relationship. In addition to the identified

organizational contingency variables, future research could contribute to the literature in

diversification and innovation areas by identifying important environmental elements which have

not been already identified.

In summary, this paper provides new insight to understand the relationship between

diversification strategy and innovation. Building on a contingency approach, we have

emphasized the importance of strategic fit among the types of diversification, search behavior,

and technological capital to improve innovation productivity.

Page 47: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

35

REFERENCES

Ahuja, G. 2000. The Duality of Collaboration: Inducements and Opportunities in the Formation of Interfirm Linkages. Strategic Management Journal, 21(3): 317-343.

Ahuja, G., & Katila, R. 2001. Technological acquisitions and the innovation performance of acquiring firms: A longitudinal study. Strategic Management Journal, 22(3): 197-220.

Ahuja, G., & Katila, R. 2004. Where do resources come from? The role of idiosyncratic situations. Strategic Management Journal, 25(8-9): 887-907.

Ahuja, G., Lampert, C. M., & Tandon, V. 2008. Chapter 1: Moving beyond Schumpeter: Management research on the determinants of technological innovation. The Academy of Management Annals, 2(1): 1-98.

Aiken, M., & Hage, J. 1971. The organic organization and innovation. Sociology, 5(1): 63-82.

Amit, R., & Schoemaker, P. J. H. 1993. Strategic assets and organizational rent. Strategic Management Journal, 14(1): 33-46.

Andrews, K. R. 1971. The concept of corporate strategy. Homewood, IL: Dow Jones Irwin.

Argyres, N. S., & Silverman, B. S. 2004. R&D, organization structure, and the development of corporate technological knowledge. Strategic Management Journal, 25(8/9): 929-958.

Arora, A., & Gambardella, A. 1990. Complementarity and external linkages: the strategies of the large firms in biotechnology. Journal of Industrial Economics, 38(4): 361-379.

Barkema, H. G., & Vermeulen, F. 1998. International expansion through start up or acquisition: A learning perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 41(1): 7-26.

Barney, J. B. 2001. Is the resource-based" view" a useful perspective for strategic management research? Yes. Academy of Management Review, 26(1): 41-56.

Baysinger, B., & Hoskisson, R. E. 1989. Diversification strategy and R&D intensity in multiproduct firms. Academy of Management Journal, 32(2): 310-332.

Becheikh, N., Landry, R., & Amara, N. 2006. Lessons from innovation empirical studies in the manufacturing sector: A systematic review of the literature from 1993?003. Technovation, 26(5-6): 644-664.

Page 48: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

36

Benner, M. J., & Tushman, M. L. 2003. Exploitation, exploration, and process management: The productivity dilemma revisited. Academy of Management Review, 28(2): 238-256.

Bergh, D. D., & Lawless, M. W. 1998. Portfolio restructuring and limits to hierarchical governance: the effects of environmental uncertainty and diversification strategy. Organization Science, 9(1): 87-102.

Bromiley, P. 1991. Testing a causal model of corporate risk taking and performance. Academy of Management Journal, 34(1): 37-59.

Chaney, P. K., & Devinney, T. M. 1992. New product innovations and stock price performance. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 19(5): 677-685.

Chang, S. J. 1996. An evolutionary perspective on diversification and corporate restructuring: Entry, exit, and economic performance during 1981-1989. Strategic Management Journal, 17(8): 587-612.

Chen, R. 1996. Technological expansion: The interaction between diversification strategy and organizational capability. Journal of Management Studies, 33(5): 649-666.

Chen, W. R. 2003. Firms' technological search behaviors. Purdue University.

Chen, W. R., & Miller, K. D. 2007. Situational and institutional determinants of firms R&D search intensity. Strategic Management Journal, 28(4): 369-381.

Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. 1990. Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1): 128-152.

Collis, D. J., & Montgomery, C. A. 1998. Creating corporate advantage. Harvard Business Review, 76(3): 70-83.

Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. 1963. A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Damanpour, F., Szabat, K. A., & Evan, W. M. 1989. The relationship between types of innovation and organizational performance. Journal of Management Studies, 26(6): 587-601.

Dosi, G. 1982. Technological paradigms and technological trajectories:: A suggested interpretation of the determinants and directions of technical change. Research policy, 11(3): 147-162.

Page 49: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

37

Fleming, L. 2001. Recombinant uncertainty in technological search. Management Science, 47(1): 117-132.

Galbraith, J. R. 1974. Organization design: An information processing view. Interfaces, 4(3): 28-36.

Govindarajan, V. 1988. A contingency approach to strategy implementation at the business-unit level: integrating administrative mechanisms with strategy. Academy of Management Journal: 828-853.

Grant, R. M. 1996. Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 17(Special Issue): 109-122.

Greve, H. R., & Taylor, A. 2000. Innovations as catalysts for organizational change: Shifts in organizational cognition and search. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45(1): 54-80.

Hage, J. T. 1999. Organizational innovation and organizational change. Annual Review of Sociology, 25(1): 597-622.

Hall, B. H., Jaffe, A. B., & Trajtenberg, M. 2001. The NBER patent citations data file: lessons, insights and methodological tools. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau Economic Research.

Harhoff, D., Narin, F., Scherer, F. M., & Vopel, K. 1999. Citation frequency and the value of patented inventions. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(3): 511-515.

Hatch, N. W., & Dyer, J. H. 2004. Human capital and learning as a source of sustainable competitive advantage. Strategic Management Journal, 25(12): 1155-1178.

Hill, C. W. L., & Hoskisson, R. E. 1987. Strategy and Structure in the Multiproduct Firm. Academy of Management Review, 12(2): 331-341.

Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E., & Ireland, R. D. 1994. A mid-range theory of the interactive effects of international and product diversification on innovation and performance. Journal of Management, 20(2): 297-326.

Hoskisson, R. E., & Hitt, M. A. 1988. Strategic control systems and relative R&D investment in large multiproduct firms. Strategic Management Journal, 9(6): 605-621.

Hoskisson, R. E., & Hitt, M. A. 1990. Antecedents and performance outcomes of diversification: A review and critique of theoretical perspectives. Journal of Management, 16(2): 461.

Page 50: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

38

Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., & Hill, C. W. L. 1991. Managerial risk taking in diversified firms: An evolutionary perspective. Organization Science, 2(3): 296-314.

Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Johnson, R. A., & Grossman, W. 2002. Conflicting voices: The effects of institutional ownership heterogeneity and internal governance on corporate innovation strategies. Academy of Management Journal, 45(4): 697-716.

Hoskisson, R. E., Hitt, M. A., Johnson, R. A., & Moesel, D. D. 1993. Construct validity of an objective (entropy) categorical measure of diversification strategy. Strategic Management Journal: 215-235.

Hoskisson, R. O., & Johnson, R. A. 1992. Corporate restructuring and strategic change: The effect on diversification strategy and R&D intensity. Strategic Management Journal, 13(8): 625-634.

Hsiao, C. 2003. Analysis of panel data. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Huber, G. P. 1991. Organizational learning: The contributing processes and the literatures. Organization Science, 2(1): 88-115.

Jacquemin, A. P., & Berry, C. H. 1979. Entropy measure of diversification and corporate growth. Journal of Industrial Economics, 27(4): 359-369.

Katila, R., & Ahuja, G. 2002. Something old, something new: A longitudinal study of search behavior and new product introduction. Academy of Management Journal, 45(6): 1183-1194.

Levinthal, D. A., & March, J. G. 1993. The myopia of learning. Strategic Management Journal, 14: 95-112.

Levitt, B., & March, J. G. 1988. Organizational learning. Annual Review of Sociology, 14(1): 319-338.

March, J. G. 1991. Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science, 2(1): 71-87.

Markides, C. C. 1992. Consequences of corporate refocusing: Ex ante evidence. Academy of Management Journal, 35(2): 398-412.

Markides, C. C., & Williamson, P. J. 1994. Related diversification, core competencies and corporate performance. Strategic Management Journal, 15: 149-165.

Page 51: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

39

Miles, R. E., & Snow, C. C. 1994. Fit, failure, and the hall of fame. Macmillan, NY.

Miller, D. J. 2004. Firms' technological resources and the performance effects of diversification: a longitudinal study. Strategic Management Journal, 25(11): 1097-1119.

Miller, D. J. 2006. Technological diversity, related diversification, and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 27(7): 601.

Miller, D. J., Fern, M. J., & Cardinal, L. B. 2007. The use of knowledge for technological innovation within diversified firms. Academy of Management Journal, 50(2): 308-326.

Miller, S. R., & Eden, L. 2006. Local density and foreign subsidiary performance. Academy of Management Journal, 49(2): 341-355.

Montgomery, C. A. 1994. Corporate diversification. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(3): 163-178.

Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.

Nohria, N., & Gulati, R. 1996. Is slack good or bad for innovation? Academy of Management Journal, 39(5): 1245-1264.

Palepu, K. 1985. Diversification strategy, profit performance and the entropy measure. Strategic Management Journal, 6(3): 239-255.

Palich, L. E., Cardinal, L. B., & Miller, C. C. 2000. Curvilinearity in the diversification-performance linkage: An examination of over three decades of research. Strategic Management Journal, 21(2): 155-174.

Patel, P., & Pavitt, K. 1994. Technological competencies in the world's largest firms: Characteristics, constraints and scope for managerial choice. Brighton, U.K.: Unpublished manuscript, Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex.

Porter, M. E. 1987. From competitive advantage to competitive strategy. Harvard Business Review, 65(3): 43-59.

Rodriguez-Duarte, A., Sandulli, F. D., Minguela-Rata, B., & Lopez-Sanchez, J. I. 2007. The endogenous relationship between innovation and diversification, and the impact of technological resources on the form of diversification. Research policy, 36(5): 652-664.

Page 52: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

40

Rosenkopf, L., & Nerkar, A. 2001. Beyond local search: Boundary-spanning, exploration, and impact in the optical disk industry. Strategic Management Journal, 22(4): 287-306.

Rumelt, R. P. 1974. Strategy, structure, and economic performance. Boston, MA: Harvard business school press.

Schoonhoven, C. B., Eisenhardt, K. M., & Lyman, K. 1990. Speeding products to market: Waiting time to first product introduction in new firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1): 177-207.

Siggelkow, N. 2001. Change in the presence of fit: The rise, the fall, and the renaissance of Liz Claiborne. Academy of Management Journal, 44(4): 838-857.

Silverman, B. S. 1999. Technological resources and the direction of corporate diversification: Toward an integration of the resource-based view and transaction cost economics. Management Science, 45(8): 1109-1124.

Singh, J. V. 1986. Performance, slack, and risk taking in organizational decision making. Academy of Management Journal, 29(3): 562-585.

Spender, J. C. 1996. Making knowledge the basis of a dynamic theory of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 17: 45-62.

Stuart, T. E., & Podolny, J. M. 1996. Local search and the evolution of technological capabilities. Strategic Management Journal, 17: 21-38.

Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. 1997. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 18(7): 509-533.

Tornatzky, L. G., Eveland, J. D., Boylan, M. G., Hetzner, W. A., Johnson, E. C., Roitman, D., & Schneider, J. 1983. The process of technological innovation: Reviewing the literature. Washington, DC: National Science Foundation.

Trajtenberg, M. 1990. A penny for your quotes: patent citations and the value of innovations. The Rand Journal of Economics, 21(1): 172-187.

Trajtenberg, M., Henderson, R., & Jaffe, A. 1997. University vs. corporate patents: a window on the basicness of innovations. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 5(1): 19-50.

Venkatraman, N. 1989. The concept of fit in strategy research: Toward verbal and statistical correspondence. Academy of Management Review, 14(3): 423-444.

Page 53: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

41

Zahra, S. A., Ireland, R. D., & Hitt, M. A. 2000. International expansion by new venture firms: International diversity, mode of market entry, technological learning, and performance. Academy of Management Journal, 43(5): 925-950.

Zajac, E. J., Kraatz, M. S., & Bresser, R. K. F. 2000. Modeling the dynamics of strategic fit: A normative approach to strategic change. Strategic Management Journal, 21(4): 429-453.

Zollo, M., Reuer, J. J., & Singh, H. 2002. Interorganizational routines and performance in strategic alliances. Organization Science, 13(6): 701-713.

Page 54: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

42

CHAPTER THREE

PAPER TWO

RESOURCES AND ORGANIZATIONAL BOUNDARY EXPANSION IN THE EARLY

STAGE

ABSTRACT

Search and renewal strategies differ based on the life-cycle stage of the firm. An incumbent

generally expands via acquisition. However, a firm that has recently held an Initial Public

Offering may use different strategies contingent on their unique resources and liabilities. For

example, the firm may rather focus on the development of internal factor markets for meeting

legitimacy demands. The priorities of a young firm may be further refined in the face of

environmental contingencies resulting from the multiple liabilities and constraints of the market.

We found that young firms with R&D resources create competencies by developing internal

factor markets, while those with financial resources preferred to engage in boundary expansion

activities. Further, we found that the boundary expansion activities of young firms are

constrained in the presence of environmental uncertainty and strong competition.

Keywords:

Capability, resources, boundary expansion, environmental contingency

Page 55: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

43

INTRODUCTION

Firms expand their boundaries in response to environmental contingencies and to the

availability of resources (Iyer & Miller, 2008; Schilling & Steensma, 2001). The need to search

for and renew competencies prompts firms to expand their boundaries through a variety of

modes including acquisitions, alliances, and joint ventures. Acquisition is one of the more

extreme modes of boundary expansion whereas alliances and joint ventures are more moderate

(Poppo & Zenger, 1995; Steensma & Corley, 2001). Boundary expansion via such modes

provides opportunities to gain resources as well as numerous competitive and comparative

advantages (Santos & Eisenhardt, 2005). However, young firms that have recently undergone

Initial Public Offerings (IPO)4

Young firms’ unique resources and constraints may have a bearing on their search and

renewal and organizational boundary decisions. They may focus on the development of internal

factor markets in order to build capability and meet legitimacy demands. Alternatively, they

may respond to the substantial pressures they face by seeking competencies (via modes such as

acquisition or alliances) from the market consistent with the strategies of ‘upstream’ incumbents

(Robinson & McDougall, 2001).

may have different priorities based on their unique position in the

market. On the one hand, such firms possess unique resources and need additional investment for

internal growth; on the other hand, they face close and constant scrutiny from the market and

must continue to validate their claims of resource , role, and endorsement legitimacy (Higgins &

Gulati, 2003; Robinson & McDougall, 2001).

4 IPO firms are organizations that offer their stock to the public market for the first time, when they are moving from private to public ownership. This move requires a substantial effort, particularly on the part of a company’s top management team.

Page 56: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

44

We begin with the premise that a young firm may have different priorities in making

boundary expansion decisions than incumbents. Early in the life cycle a firm may not want the

burden of organizational and structural complexities inherent in some modes of boundary

expansion. The organizational boundary literature considers capability and competence

development an important motive for boundary expansion. However, it is unclear how various

resources influence boundary expansion and how young firms’ preferences differ from those of

incumbents. We begin by taking a resource based view (RBV) and focusing on the resource

portfolio to explore the boundary expansion activities of the young firm.

The young firm generally faces multiple liabilities and constraints in the market, and the

firm’s priorities may be further refined in the face of these environmental contingencies.

Although not mechanistically determined (Aldrich, 1999; Aragon-Correa & Sharma, 2003),

environmental contingencies substantially influence major strategic decisions. For example,

environmental uncertainty can dampen acquisition activity by placing in doubt the value of new

resource combinations (Hoskisson & Hitt, 1990). Further, when pursuing search and renewal

activities (Aldrich, 1999; Scherer, 1980), firms are constrained by competitive dynamics. At the

same time, strategic factors such as slack also influence boundary expansion decisions and the

choice of expansion modes (Iyer & Miller, 2008; Patzelt, Shepherd, Deeds, & Bradley, 2008).

A more complete picture of the young firm’s competency search strategies and boundary

expansion choices would emerge if, in addition to contingencies, we considered the firm’s

unique resources. The purpose of this paper is to examine the impact of two key resources and

two environmental contingencies on the young firm’s boundary choice. Specifically, we explore

whether young firms should cultivate internal factor markets or expand organizational

boundaries to renew competencies in the face of contingencies. The two strategic resources

Page 57: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

45

considered are R&D and financial. We regard environment and industry as the environmental

contingencies that influence the boundary decisions of young firms.

The paper is organized as follows. First, we discuss the literature on young firms’

boundary expansion decisions, particularly regarding investment in and development of existing

competencies versus searching for new competencies beyond the firm’s boundaries. Next, we

discuss the influence of unique resources and capabilities on young firms’ preferences regarding

boundary expansion; we develop testable hypotheses regarding these strategic choices in the

presence of environmental contingencies. Third, we detail the hypothesis testing methodology

based on a sample of 158 young, high technology firms. We conclude with a discussion of the

results, implications, and future research directions.

THEORETICAL BACKGROUND

Organizational boundary refers to “the demarcation between the organization and its

environment” (Santos & Eisenhardt, 2005). The resource-based view (RBV) (Barney, 1991;

Penrose, 1959) posits that possession of valuable, rare, inimitable, and non-substitutable (VRIN)

resources is a source of competitive advantage (Barney, 1991). The young firms’ organizational

boundaries can be dynamically determined prior to an IPO by identifying environmental

opportunities that will allow the firm to gain a competitive advantage from their unique resources.

A fit between a firms’ resources and the environment delivers market share and enhances

legitimacy (Powell & DiMaggio, 1991). In the context of young firms, such a fit maximizes the

value of the resource portfolio and provides competitive advantage.

According to Poppo (1995), firms generally make a boundary choice between internal

(make) and external (buy /cooperate) markets. Cultivating the internal market allows firms to

Page 58: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

46

develop competencies by investing in internal R&D projects and has the advantages of reduced

information complexity and increased flexibility (Williamson, 1985). Expansion by venturing in

external markets provides opportunities to gain needed resources and capabilities in the market

through acquisition and inter-organizational relationships; this has the potential advantage of

new search, improved efficiency, and greater adaptability. Building on the RBV5

Firms set their boundaries at the point that maximizes the value of their resource portfolio

with a focus on firm-specific, resource-based advantages for organizational growth (Chandler,

1977; Helfat, 1997; Santos & Eisenhardt, 2005). Prior literature suggests that new and young

ventures often ensure viability by exploiting the knowledge capital of the parent firm which they

subsequently increment through internal R&D (Gompers, Lerner, & Scharfstein, 2005; Levinthal

& March, 1993). Klepper and Sleeper (2005) found that nearly every venture in the laser

industry used internal R&D to improve lasers produced by the parent firms. Chatterji (2009)

found that such ventures generally outperform other entrants in an industry and, arguably, had no

, the capability

perspective argues that a firm’s boundary expansion choice is associated with its resource

portfolio and emphasizes value maximization resulting from engagement in activities within or

beyond the organizational boundary (Barney, 1999; Leiblein & Miller, 2003).

5 A consensus is building in the management literature that the term ‘resources and capabilities’ could be used in parallel (Barney & Clark, 2007) because distinctions between these terms are likely to “become badly blurred” in practice (Barney, 2007). According to Barney and Clark (Barney & Clark, 2007, pp. 23-24) “in principle, distinctions among terms like resources, competencies, capabilities, dynamic capabilities…can be drawn. …(however) they share the same underlying theoretical structure…(thus) the terms resources and capabilities will be used interchangeably and often in parallel (pp. 23-24)….what makes resources a potential source of sustained competitive advantage are the same as what makes capabilities…potential sources of competitive advantage (p. 249).” In essence, though we acknowledge the academic distinctions between resources and capabilities made by a number of scholars (e.g., Amit & Schoemaker, 1993, among others; Makadok, 2001; Teece, Pisano, & Shuen, 1997), we use the terms resources and capabilities together.

Page 59: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

47

need to seek competencies beyond their boundaries early in the life cycle. Thus, if the resources

and capabilities in the internal market are valuable, rare, inimitable, and non-substitutable, firms

can gain competitive advantage by exploiting just these resources and may not need to seek

outside competencies (Barney, 1991, 2001).

Concomitantly, young firms face a number of liabilities and resource constraints

requiring them to balance competency development with efficiency in their operations and

transactions. Environmental contingencies play a critical role in boundary expansion (Santos &

Eisenhardt, 2005, 2009). In the face of contingencies, the manipulation of pre-IPO resources and

development of new resource combinations in the form of capabilities becomes crucial6

6 Capabilities development reflects specific organizational processes that manipulate resources for creating value by building new resources inside the firm, accessing resources from outside the firm, recombining existing resources in new ways, and eliminating no longer valuable resources (Eisenhardt & Martin, 2000; Teece et al., 1997).

. In

uncertain environments, firms shape horizontal and vertical boundaries by blending existing and

new resources into fresh combinations. Uncertainty can provide opportunities for combining

path-breaking and path-dependent resources (Santos & Eisenhardt, 2005). Firms often expand

their boundaries for the co-evolution of resources with environmental opportunities. Karim and

Mitchell (2000) found that managers of U.S. medical firms use acquisitions to alter horizontal

boundaries. Young firms may engage in path-breaking expansion into more distant domains

using resouce combinations from both the focal and acquired firms. Even established firms

explore internal markets before looking beyond their boundaries. The CEO of Philips notes: “we

used to start by identifying our core competencies and then looking for market opportunities.

Now we ask what is required to capture an opportunity and then either try to get those skills via

alliances or develop them internally to fit” (The Economist, Feburary 7, 2002).

Page 60: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

48

Young firms must make a strategic choice to either continue exploiting their own

resources and competencies or to explore new competencies from the market. Building on the

resources- and -capabilities perspective, the following section looks at how a firm’s resource

portfolio influences boundary expansion choices between internal and external markets.

HYPOTHESES DEVELOPMENT

Boundary decisions to gain access or develop resources and capabilities are contingent on

the firm’s current resources and the resource requirements of the industry (Argyres, 1996). The

literature suggests that various types of resources influence boundary expansion activities, such

as strategic alliances and inter firm linkages (Ahuja, 2000; Das & Teng, 1998). For example,

Mishina, Pollock, and Porac (2004) found that financial and human resources are directly and

indirectly associated with product and market expansion. Firm-specific resources and capabilities

(e.g., knowledge, proprietary research and innovations) are more likely to be coordinated within

firm boundaries (e.g., Miller, Fern, & Cardinal, 2007; Zander & Kogut, 1995). Therefore, the

firms’ resource- and capability-portfolio assumes importance in boundary decisions, particularly

for young firms, because their resources and capabilities influence the decision between

exploitation of existing capability and exploration of new capability from the market. Next, we

discuss the role of R&D and financial resources in boundary expansion decision.

R&D Resources and Boundary Choice

R&D resources7

7 The concept of R&D resources has similarities to that of technological capital. However, they are conceptually distinct. Technological resource narrowly refers to technologies (e.g. patents, and uncodified technologies) pertinent to its business and R&D, while an R&D resource includes

include expensive equipments, skilled researchers, continuous support,

technological capital (e.g. patent), and substantial investments. Montgomery and Hariharan

Page 61: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

49

(1991) found that higher R&D investment is related to greater diversification and is an outcome

of boundary expansion activities. This may not be true, however, for firms that have recently

gone public. The young firm’s boundary expansion strategy is influenced by their R&D

resources and differs from incumbents’ boundary preferences for a couple of reasons. The newly

public firm is obligated to meet the investor expectations for R&D investment. New ventures,

go public to raise investment capital, and the potential value of intangible assets plays a major

role in the firm’s valuation (Arkebauer, 1991; Certo, 2003; Nelson, 2003). Prior to an IPO, the

new ventures signals investors and the market to highlight the promise of their promising

technologies, patents, R&D, and human capital (Certo, 2003; Grabowski & Vernon, 1990;

Graves & Langowitz, 1993; Nelson, 2003). The new ventures must continue to build on these

signals after going public. The post –IPO stage is one of transition in terms of structure and

governance. In this phase, they have an opportunity to focus on the exploitation of accumulated

intellectual capital, patents, and R&D capabilities and to try to lead their product-market (Deeds,

Decarolis, & Coombs, 1997; Jain & Kini, 2000). Hence, TMTs—who have already invested

large sums in the propriety technologies favored by external stakeholders—would rather exploit

this pre-existing intellectual capital through continued investment rather than expand their

boundaries (e.g., acquire a new firm) and deal with the associated structural and governance

complexities.

A second reason for the different boundary preferences of young firms is that the internal

market may be more beneficial to young firms with considerable R&D resources. Further,

any resources related to R&D activities. Broadly, R&D resources include technological, human, and financial resources as well as any physical resources that support R&D. From the capability perspective, possession of technological resource may not be sufficient to represent a firm’s potential R&D capability.

Page 62: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

50

developing technologies within firm boundaries offers better control over property rights and

issues of appropriability than does negotiating for technologies through acquisitions. Although

choosing to develop technologies within the firm’s boundaries decreases exposure to

opportunistic behavior, the growth of the strategic factor market via R&D investments promotes

synergy, complementarity, and learning within business units in the hierarchy (Karim & Mitchell,

2000). The TMT of a young firm may prefer internal R&D over acquisitions (for both

appropriation and coordination issues) given the constraints on managerial time, attention, and

resources (Karim & Mitchell, 2000). Further, research and development divisions that grow from

within have better communication and coordination both within and across organizational

functions and hierarchies.

In addition, internal R&D investments develop strategic factor markets for the creation of

innovative product-markets for long term success (Thompson & Strickland, 1980). Because

firms’ innovation strategies often build on the absorptive capacity developed over time by

internal R&D (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990), the existence of strategic factor markets has important

implications for the development of technological strategy and choice of product-markets

(Burgelman, 1986; Hoskisson & Hitt, 1990). Young firms need to develop such absorptive

capacity sooner rather than later because they are in the early stage of life cycle. Internal R&D

investment is higher priority than acquisitions from the external market. Even after developing

large absorptive capacity, young firms still have less incentive than incumbents to expand

capabilities through acquisitions or inter-firm relationships. The process of capability

development tends to be path dependent (Leonard-Barton, 1992). Past R&D successes are likely

to lead to stick on its preference on in-house development. Proponents of the resource allocation

view suggest that resource allocation is a primarily internal process (Bower, 1970; Burgelman,

Page 63: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

51

1983a, 1983b). Founder preference for legacy projects may lead young firms to continue to focus

resource allocation on the internal factor market.

The need for resource and competency development is another reason for the different

boundary preferences of young firms. Young firms may first exploit resources from within

organizational boundaries or internal markets (Chandler, 1962); focus on internal aggregation of

resources; and efficiently use business units for resource and competency development (Galunic

& Eisenhardt, 1996, 2001; Siggelkow, 2001). Because internal markets provide synergy between

the development of resources and competencies and superior control and efficiency in the

process of innovation (Jacobides & Hitt, 2005; Santos & Eisenhardt, 2005), young firms may

create and maintain an optimal resource portfolio developed by R&D investments while reducing

complexity and increasing control and efficiency (Williamson, 1985). In a study of new ventures,

Santos (2003) found that entrepreneurs first develop resources around internal processes

reflecting resources and competencies and only later pursue boundary expansion. Within the IPO

context, given the advantages of expanding through the internal market, and considering the

order of capability development, we propose that young firms with heavy R&D investment

continue developing resources and capabilities internally rather than through boundary expansion.

Hypothesis 1. For young firms that have undertaken an IPO, R&D resources are

negatively related to boundary expansion activities in the initial post-IPO stage.

Financial Resources and Boundary Expansion

Although internal markets are a useful way for young firms to develop resources

and capabilities, they are costly and difficult to develop single-handedly (Barney, 1999).

Page 64: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

52

Developing capabilities involves a difficult to identify, unique historical condition.

Capability development is path dependent (Leonard-Barton, 1992) and requires

engagement with complex social networks. Finally, actions to develop capabilities may

be causally ambiguous (Reed & DeFillippi, 1990). Thus, firms are constrained from

developing capabilities on their own, and are lead to rely on external markets. The use of

external markets for this purpose via modes such as acquisitions or alliances has several

advantages over such efforts in the internal market. They include resource sharing, low

governance costs, resource reallocation, and increased market power (Hitt, Hoskisson,

Johnson, & Moesel, 1996; Walter & Barney, 1990). Use of the external market to gain

desired capabilities, however, is not risk free and requires substantial efforts. Among the

various types of resources, the most important to boundary expansion is financial (Iyer

& Miller, 2008; Santos & Eisenhardt, 2005).

Early-stage firms obtain financial resources in a number of ways, including

venture capital, banks, family, and IPO. Financial resources refer to liquid funding

(which is available for investment in new projects) and monetary-equivalent resources.

The resources are easily accessible and therefore usually support the firm’s growth

strategy (Penrose, 1959). Thus, financial resources provide a competitive advantage to

firms (Barney, 1991; Latham & Braun, 2008). The existence of liquid financial resources

demonstrate the firm’s ability to meet current capital needs and support operations

(Mishina et al., 2004). Young firms with sufficient financial resources have more options

and a different perspective on boundary expansion through acquisition, strategic alliances,

and joint venture. In the presence of adequate financial resources, young firms may be

motivated to engage in boundary expansion activities for the following reasons. After an

Page 65: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

53

IPO, firms generally have sufficient capital (e.g., net proceeds) to support boundary

expansion. The substantial cash infusion provided by an IPO can increase firm

performance and survivability. The TMT should decide how to deploy IPO resources.

Young firms may create value through vertical or horizontal boundary expansion by

exploiting excess valuable resources (Teece, 1982), or by intensifying exiting strategies.

Unlike R&D, financial resources enable young firms to engage in boundary expansion

gain access to additional resources and capabilities that are consistent with the firm’s

current capabilities, potentially fueling future growth.

A second motivation for boundary expansion in the presence of adequate financial

resources is that these if financial resources reduce the managerial risk that when the

scope of the firm broadens derived by broadening scope of firms. Managers deploy their

financial resources with the expectation of creating value, enabling them to consider a

broader range of strategic options. Financial resources can be used to purchase equipment,

employ expertise, build and expand plants, invest in R&D, and enhance operations (Amit

& Schoemaker, 1993). Because firm size and executive compensation are highly

correlated (Tosi Jr & Gomez-Mejia, 1989) and because diversification smoothes cash

flow and reduces employment risk (Amihud & Lev, 1981), mangers have incentive to

increase the size of the firm through boundary expansion.

Adequate financial resources also support the growth strategy of the firm through

boundary expansion (Kumar, 2009). With these resources, the top management team

(TMT) can take advantage of emerging opportunities in the market by acquiring

capabilities from others or by working with others to develop new competencies. There is

evidence that firms are more likely to expand their product lines through strategic

Page 66: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

54

alliances when they have greater financial resources (Garrette, Dussauge, & Castaner,

2008). Iyer and Miller (2008) also found that financial resources increase the probability

of acquisition. Because IPO firms are under strong demands for growth, they are less

likely to conserve and more likely to deploy available capital to support their growth

strategy. On the other hand, lack of financial resources constrains firm’s strategic options

because strategic decisions regarding organizational boundary expansion are risky and

uncertain. Therefore, we propose that financial resources facilitate boundary expansion in

young firms.

Hypothesis 2. For young firms that have undertaken an IPO, financial resources

are positively related to boundary expansion activities during the initial post-IPO

stage.

Role of Environmental Contingencies

In addition to availability of the above mentioned resources, environmental contingencies

(e.g., environmental dynamism and industry competition) also influence boundary expansion

decisions (Poppo & Zenger, 1998; Santos & Eisenhardt, 2005; Schilling & Steensma, 2001). We

now examine the roles of environmental uncertainty and competitive intensity in boundary

expansion decisions.

Environmental uncertainty. Firms adapt their strategies to match environmental changes.

A firm’s preference for internal or external markets in searching out new competencies changes

in the face of environmental uncertainty (Galunic & Eisenhardt, 2001; Gilbert, 2005). For a

young firm that has recently undertaken an IPO, market uncertainty is a primary contingency that

Page 67: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

55

must be considered before exploring opportunities for boundary expansion. In general,

uncertainty is the inability to predict or foresee events (Anderson & Tushman, 2001).

Uncertainty arises when a decision maker cannot reliably forecast future events based on the

available information. Uncertainty influences boundary decisions for several reasons. First,

young firms find it difficult to define the parameters of a changing environment and to find a fit

with the changing environment. Secondly, in an unpredictable environment, resources such as

knowledge and learning become obsolete more quickly and success is more difficult to

reproduce (Leonard-Barton, 1992; Tushman & O'Reilly, 2002). Third, TMT becomes risk averse

in an unpredictable environment. Risk-averse principals fear losing a dollar more than they value

gaining a dollar (Benartzi & Thaler, 1995; Kahneman & Tversky, 1979). Consequently, the less

predictable the outcomes, the more likely principals will avoid boundary expansion. Indeed,

Christensen and Bower (1996) found that risk-averse managers do not experiment with new

strategies or technologies unless benefits are guaranteed. In essence, faced with market

uncertainty, TMTs of young firms are averse to investing time, attention, or resources in

boundary expansion activities that are difficult to undo (Ghemawat, 1991).

Through the lens of transaction cost economics, uncertainty about the future is a source

of inefficiency in establishing business relationships with outside parties (Pisano, 1990). An

environment fraught with uncertainty makes it difficult to write, execute, or monitor contractual

arrangements (Leiblein & Miller, 2003; Walker & Weber, 1987; Williamson, 1985). It is

particularly difficult to specify boundary expansion contracts when uncertainty is high. An

increase in uncertainty makes it difficult to complete the due diligence required for boundary

expansion; the basic task of correctly evaluating potential boundary expansion modes becomes

challenging due to market fluctuations and the resulting risk of paying abnormally high

Page 68: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

56

premiums. Further, uncertainty exacerbates legal, structural, and governance related complexity.

Any boundary expansion contract remains incomplete under such circumstances, potentially

leading to a series of renegotiations. Each renegotiation opens the firm to the self-serving

behavior of the other party. The potential for self-serving behavior leads to intensive monitoring

and possible legal recourse, which, in turn, generates transaction costs and inefficiency. Thus,

according to transaction cost economics, high levels of uncertainty make boundary expansion

(through modes such as acquisition) problematic, pressuring firms to avoid such activities.

Young firms that have already invested in R&D and developed promising technologies

would be further discouraged from taking boundary expansion initiatives in the face of

uncertainty. Such firms would prefer to exploit intellectual capital, launch new products, and

counter uncertainty by creating market demand. They would focus on developing absorptive

capacity rather than acquire new firms and deal with the additional structural and governance

complexities. Uncertain times motivate young firms to enhance their internal R&D efforts over

boundary expansion modes for greater appropriation, control, and coordination from within the

hierarchy. In addition, environmental uncertainty decreases the external market preference of

young firms with excess of financial resources. When the future is unpredictable and unstable,

managers do not take the considerable risk of boundary expansion; they are unwilling to make

bold decisions, preferring to manage their careers in less risky ways. Instead, they back internal

R&D projects where trajectory and demand are assured. In sum, uncertainty makes difficult for

young firms to expand their boundaries.

Hypothesis 3. For young firms that have undertaken an IPO, environmental

dynamism in the industry moderates the relationship between R&D resources and

Page 69: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

57

boundary expansion such that when the level of environmental dynamism is high,

R&D resource is more negatively related to boundary expansion.

Hypothesis 4. For young firms that have undertaken IPO, environmental

dynamism in the industry moderates the relationship between financial resources

and boundary expansion such that when the level of environmental dynamism is

high, financial resources are less positively related to boundary expansion.

Industry competition. Competition provides pressures of inherent instability and change

(D'Aveni, 1994). Young firms with unique resources will be motivated to focus on their

competencies to exploit their intellectual capital and launch competitive products that create a

niche for them in the market. Further, in highly competitive environments, young firms must

respond to the environment and achieve a close fit with market demand; they must do so quickly

in order to survive. Because competitors create frequent discontinuities in the stable industry

structures, corporate forms, and business-specific resources (D'Aveni, 1994; Hamel, 2000;

McNamara, Vaaler, & Devers, 2003); competitive pressures offer little room for delay in

exploiting intellectual capital, resources, and capabilities. Competition pressures firms to rapidly

exploit resources, capabilities, and core competencies, giving managers little time or opportunity

for boundary expansion.

To be competitive, young firms with R&D resources would focus on developing new

competencies and absorptive capacity in-house, rather than become involved in the complexities

of building inter organizational relationships or acquiring another firm. Under competitive

Page 70: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

58

pressures, the risks of technology spillover and espionage motivate young firms to take greater

control and appropriation which are the characteristics of hierarchy.

In contrast, sufficient financial resources play the role of slack, giving the firm added

flexibility. Under strong competitive pressures, the young firm’s preference for external markets

is more pronounced. Choosing an external market gives the young firm access to the resources

and capabilities of other firms. Through external markets, young firms are able to enter niche

markets or deal with competitive pressure by increasing their market power. Competitive

industries offer fewer opportunities for growth. Working with others and acquiring another firm

would be of the best choice, even for post IPO firms with sufficient financial resources.

In sum, in the face of competitive pressures, young firms that have developed superior

R&D resources should focus on enhancing their existing capabilities in house. In contrast,

adequate financial resources provide young firms with some leeway for boundary expansion

initiatives in face of competition.

Hypothesis 5. For young firms that have undertaken an IPO, industry competition

moderates the relationship between R&D resources and boundary expansion such

that when the level of competition is high, R&D resources are more negatively

related to boundary expansion.

Hypothesis 6. For young firms that have undertaken an IPO, industry competition

moderates the relationship between financial resources and boundary expansion

such that when the level of competition is high, financial resources are more

positively related to boundary expansion.

Page 71: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

59

METHODS

Data and Sample

The initial sample consisted of 175 IPO firms between 2001 and 2005. The firms were in

the U.S. high technology industry, which includes the two digit SICs 28 (chemicals and allied

products), 35 (industrial machinery and computer equipment), 36(electronics and other electric

equipment), 38 (instruments and related products), 48 (communications), and 73 (Business

services-software) (Bradley, Jordan, Yi, & Roten, 2001; Carpenter & Petersen, 2002; Loughran

& Ritter, 2004). The time frame of 2001to 2005 was selected to avoid selection bias. The number

of IPO firms in the late 1990s, when Internet bubble occurred, could cause unbalanced sample

sizes and possible over- or under-estimation of results.

We collected data from a variety of sources. The IPO data was collected from

prospectuses (i.e., 424b form) provided to the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC)

electronic data gathering and retrieval system. Boundary expansion data were gathered from the

Securities Data Company (SDC) platinum, and other financial data were retrieved from

COMPUSTAT. After matching IPO, boundary expansion, and financial data, the final sample

included 1588

Measures

IPO firms from 2001 to 2005 in 41 4-digit SIC industries, consisting of 19, 18, 24,

63, and 34 firms in each year.

Dependent variable. This paper examines the organizational boundary activities of a

focal firm resulting from unique resources in the early stage. Therefore, organizational boundary

expansion activity was measured by the aggregated number of acquisitions, strategic alliances,

8 14 firms in the final sample could not be used in the analysis because of the lack of financial data or the unusual value (e.g. -838.2 of ROA). Three firms were excluded because the prospectuses could not be found for them.

Page 72: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

60

and joint ventures (Keil, Maula, Schildt, & Zahra, 2008) initiated by a focal firm four years after

an IPO. This measure captures the organizational boundary expansion intensity, in that the

higher the firm’s boundary expansion intensity, the more the firm acquires, engages in strategic

alliances, and forms joint ventures. The sample of IPO companies is belonged to relatively early

stage in the organizational life cycle. Forty-eight percent of the sample firms reported no

boundary expansion activities (zero). About 52 percent engaged in 1-11 (1 being the least and

11 the most) boundary expansion activities.

Independent variables. We had two independent variables: R&D resources and financial

resources. First, R&D intensity has been used as a proxy for technological resources by many

scholars (e.g., Hill & Snell, 1988; Montgomery & Hariharan, 1991). Although others use patent

portfolio for technological resources, the concept of resources in this paper is broader and

includes tangible and intangible resources that support R&D activities. Thus, we measured R&D

resources using R&D intensity, which is the value of R&D expenses divided by total assets.

Because more than 20 percent of young IPO firms in the sample did not have the amount of sales

in the early years of product development, we used total assets as the denominator rather than

total sales. We collected this data from the prospectuses of IPO firms.

Second, young firms may have sufficient financial resources to initiate new projects or

expand their organizational boundaries. We measured financial resources using the number of

months if the existing cash flows from operations, together with borrowings and net proceeds

from IPO, are sufficient to fund its working capital requirements in the future without raising

additional security. The data was collected from IPO prospectuses. The number of months varies

from 6 to 42. It is expected that the higher the number, the more financial resources the firm has.

Page 73: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

61

Organizational contingencies. Environmental uncertainty can be broken into three

dimensions (e.g. complexity, munificent, and dynamism) (Dess & Beard, 1984). To capture the

uncertain and volatile characteristics of environment, we used the environmental dynamism

dimension and measured it as the natural logarithm of sales figures were entered into quasi-time

series regressions with time serving as the independent variable. The antilog of the standard

errors of the resulting regression slope coefficients were then used to capture environmental

volatility (Dess & Beard, 1984; Keats & Hitt, 1988). For competition in the industry, literature

measured a firm level competitive intensity as the firm’s market share (e.g., Mezias & Boyle,

2005; Swaminathan, 1995).

To measure the level of competition in the industry, we used the inverse of the four-firm

concentration ratio obtained from the U.S. Census of manufacturers for the year of IPO. We

collected this data from COMPUSTAT. Each value represents environmental uncertainty based

on the four-digit SIC.

Control variables. We included several control variables to avoid alternative

explanations. First, we controlled for the use of proceeds if an IPO firm disclosure expansion-

related use of proceeds. IPO firms disclose how they intend to use the proceeds of the IPO.

Uses can be categorized as debt repayment; distribution to pre-IPO shareholders; expansion or

acquisitions; advertising, marketing, promotion, or sales; working capital; R&D; and general

corporate purposes (Leone, Rock, & Willenborg, 2007). This variable was dummy coded 1 if the

firm intended to use the proceeds for expansion (i.e. acquisition, joint venture, alliance, or

expansion); otherwise it was coded as 0. This data was collected from SDC Platinum and

prospectuses. Organizational boundary expansion may differ across industries. To control for

the unobserved industry effect, dummy variables based on two-digit SIC codes were included.

Page 74: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

62

The total number of patents was included in the model as a control variable. Patent data has

been used as a proxy for technological resources or competencies (Silverman, 1999).

Additionally, patent numbers may influence the young firm’s boundary expansion activities by

providing more opportunities to build interorgnaizational relationships.

We included year dummies to control for the possible influence of yearly trends in IPO

and acquisition. Founder and insider ratios in BOD were used to control for the influence of

governance on expansion decisions. CEO as a founder and board of directors (BOD) consisting

of large number of insider are more likely to prefer to internal market (Certo, Covin, Daily, &

Dalton, 2001). Founder effect was dummy-coded based on whether the CEO was a founder. The

insider ratio was determined from the number of insiders on the board of directors divided by the

total number of directors. Finally, we controlled for two firm specific factors: firm size

measured as the natural log of total assets at the time of IPO, and firm age as the difference

between foundation year and IPO year.

Analysis

Because the number of boundary expansion activities is constrained, and a number of

observations had a value of zero, we used the Tobit regression model to test the hypotheses.

Tobit regression works better with censored data, which may be left or right censored (Greene,

2003). In the Tobit model, the independent variables are tested if they influence the probability

that the dependent variable exceeds zero (or a given threshold value); the value of the dependent

variable is tested if it exceeds zero (Bowen & Wiersema, 2004; Helfat, 1994). All continuous

variables in the model were centered with mean to avoid multicollinearity problems between

variables (Aiken & West, 1991). This procedure also makes it easier to interpret the results.

Page 75: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

TABLE 3.1 Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix a

Mean S.D. Min Max 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1. Boundary expansion 1.41 1.96 0 11 1 ***

***

***

***

***

***

***

***

***

2. Firm size 5.48 1.48 2.08 10.71 0.14 † 1 3. Firm age 2.10 0.72 0 4.45 0.02

0.30 *** 1

4. ROA -0.29 0.50 -2.18 0.73 0.01

0.49 *** 0.26 *** 1 5. Number of patent 1.38 1.61 0 7.65 -0.03

0.00

0.09

-0.07

1 6. Insider ratio 0.57 0.11 0.25 0.86 0.00

0.29 *** -0.04

0.15 † 0.02

1

7. Environmental dynamism 1.12 0.19 1.01 2.84 0.03

0.17 * 0.06

-0.03

0.10

0.12

1 8. Industry competition 1.70 0.58 1 2.70 0.19 * -0.12

-0.18 * -0.12

-0.09

0.02

-0.29 *** 1

9. R&D resource 0.25 0.27 0 1.34 -0.10

-0.49 *** -0.18 * -0.68 *** 0.30 *** -0.16 * -0.05

0.26 *** 1 10. Financial resource 14.92 5.83 6 42 -0.03 -0.34 *** -0.05 -0.17 * 0.12 -0.24 ** 0.05 0.11 0.28 ***

a N=158 † p < .10 * p < .05 ** p < .01 *** p < .001

63

Page 76: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

64

TABLE 3.2

Results of Tobit Regression Analysis for Boundary Expansion a

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Constant 3.07 *** 2.96 *** 3.39 ***

Control variables Firm size 0.19

0.22

0.16

Firm age 0.06

0.02

0.20 ROA -1.19 + -2.29 *** -2.29 ***

Number of Patent 0.20

0.26 + 0.34 * Use of Proceed -0.15

-0.03

-0.29

Founder -1.14 * -1.13 * -1.00 * Insider ratio 0.29

1.18

0.89

Sic28 -2.20 ** -3.04 *** -2.96 *** Sic35 -3.36 ** -2.97 * -3.74 ** Sic36 -1.54 * -1.02

-1.54 *

Sic38 -3.03 *** -2.80 ** -4.09 *** Sic48 -4.78 ** -5.10 *** -4.99 *** Year01 -0.33

-0.78

0.26

Year02 -1.01

-1.08

-0.75 Year03 0.09

0.59

0.90

Year04 -0.47

-0.08

0.08

Direct effect Environment dynamism

1.05

-2.10 Industry competition

0.91 * -0.10

R&D resource

-3.44 ** -2.22 + Financial resource

0.13 ** 0.11 *

Two way interaction effect R&D resource X Environmental dynamism

-18.86 ** R&D resource X Industry competition

-8.20 ***

Financial resource X Environmental dynamism

-0.20 Financial resource X Industry competition

0.04

Log likelihood -254.77

-248.36

-242.82

Chi-square 31.28 * 44.10 ** 55.18 *** Chang in Chi-square 12.82 *** 11.08 ***

a N=158, † p < .10, * p < .05, ** p < .01, *** p < .001

Page 77: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

65

RESULTS

The descriptive statistics of all variables and correlations among dependent variables,

independent variables, and control variables are reported in Table 1. The correlation matrix

shows that there is no high correlation between any two variables, proving that multicollinearity

is not a problem in this model. We also did a more conservative check of multicollinearity using

robust regression analysis. The tolerance and variance inflation factor (VIF) demonstrate that

multicollinearity among the independent and control variables was not severe.

The results of the Tobit regression model are in Table 2. Model 1 includes all control

variables. In Model 2, direct effects were tested, and two-way interaction terms were included in

Model 3. All models were statistically significant (p<0.05). Model 3, with interaction terms,

significantly improved the model fit on Model 1 and Model 2 as indicated by the change in chi-

square (p<0.001). Hypothesis 1 proposes that R&D resources are negatively associated with

boundary expansion. The regression coefficient for R&D resource in model 2 was negative and

significant (β = -3.44, p<0.01). Thus, the results from Model 2 provide support of hypotheses 1.

As suggested, young firms with high R&D investment are less likely to build capability through

boundary expansion activities in the industry.

In hypothesis 2, we argue that higher levels of financial resources increase the levels of

boundary expansion activity. The coefficient associated with financial resource in Model 2 is

significant and positive (β = 0.13, p<0.01). Thus, hypothesis 2 is supported.

In hypotheses 3 to 6, we suggest that the relationship between unique resources and

boundary expansion activities depends on environmental contingencies in the industry. It is

expected that both environmental uncertainty and industry competition affect the young firms’

strategic choices in terms of boundary expansion. Model 3 in table 2 supports hypotheses 3 and 4

Page 78: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

66

(p<0.01 for hypothesis 3, and p<0.001 for hypothesis 4), but not hypotheses 5 and 6. Only, the

interactions between R&D resources and environmental contingencies have significant and

consistently negative coefficients.

To further explore the nature of these relationships, we plotted the two-way interactions

using ±1 standard deviation from the mean of environmental uncertainty and industry

competition (Aiken & West, 1991). The one standard above from the mean represents high level

of environmental contingency, and vice versa. The graph a) in Figure 1 shows that R&D

resources are more negatively associated with acquisition for young firms in highly dynamic

environments, than for those in stable environments. Graph b) can be interpreted to show that as

industry competition increases, boundary expansion activities implemented by young firms with

high R&D resources decrease. In stable environments with low industry competition, however,

R&D resources are less negatively related to acquisition, and the number of acquisitions,

alliances, and joint ventures increase. However, the relationship between financial resources and

boundary expansion is unaffected by environmental factors. Overall, the results are consistent

with the argument regarding two contingencies and R&D resources and show that with which

resources firms are more or less exploring outside of firm boundaries.

Page 79: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

67

FIGURE 3.1

Interaction Effects among R&D Resource, Environmental Dynamism, and Industry Competition

a) The Interaction Effect of Environmental Dynamism

b) The Interaction Effect of Industry Competition

High

Low

Boundary expansion

R&D resource

Low environmental dynamism High environmental dynamism

Low High

High

Low

Boundary expansion

R&D resource

Low industry competition High industry competition

Low High

Page 80: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

68

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

Firms prefer different search and renewal strategies depending on their life-cycle stage.

Incumbents expand boundaries through acquisitions, alliances, joint ventures, and other means to

seek new competencies and renew existing competencies. However, there is a gap in the

literature regarding the preferences of young firms’ for various boundary expansion options

under contingencies—how young firms differ from incumbents in this regard and how their

unique resources and inherent liabilities affect their preferences. This study examines the

boundary choices made by young firms’. From the capability perspective, we suggest that the

unique resources of a young firm can explain patterns of organizational boundary expansion.

The results of this study, based on a sample of high technology firms, suggest that young firms’

boundary expansion decisions are consistent with the available, unique, resources they possess.

Young firms with substantial R&D resources are more likely to continue developing internal

capability due to the obligations and legitimacy needs of the IPO firm, the advantages of the

internal market, and the order of capability development. In industries such as biotechnology,

product development cycles are extremely long (seven to ten years) and the need for cash

investments is immense (Burrill & Lee, 1993). Continuous exploiting capability within

organization boundary is necessary and more preferred than exploring new capability in the

market.

In contrast, young firms with high financial resources prefer to take advantage of

environmental opportunities beyond their current organizational boundary through market

transaction mechanisms such as acquisitions, alliances, and joint ventures. Young firms need

continued funding to grow and prosper (Jain & Kini, 1999). Going public provides sufficient

capital to support the growth of a young. When managers identify opportunities in the market,

Page 81: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

69

they have strong incentive to exploit them using IPO capital. This strategic choice allows young

firms to gain access to a greater variety of opportunities and to increase the firm’s potential value

(Sirmon, Hitt, & Ireland, 2007).

Considering the characteristics of environment, R&D resources are more deterministic

than financial resource regarding organizational boundary decision. That is, young firms with

substantial R&D resources rely more on the internal factor market to develop competence and

capability in competitive and dynamic environments. This could be due to the increased

management costs associated with uncertainty (Dundas & Richardson, 1980). In situations of

uncertainty and rapid technological change, where divisions are connected by investment in

specific technological assets, the advantages of being closely linked evaporate (Hill & Hoskisson,

1987). Strong competition also pressures young firms with R&D resources to focus on

developing new competencies and absorptive capacity in-house rather than shouldering the

complexities associated with acquisition.

However, the boundary expansion decisions of young firms with sufficient financial

resources are not affected by environmental contingencies. This can be interpreted to mean that

financial resources as slack have stronger effect on boundary decisions regardless of the market

context. Financial resources provide a cushion that gives firms discretion (Bourgeois, 1981),

allowing them to adapt to internal and external pressures, and to change strategies. Given that

slack resources could be diverted or redeployed to achieve organizational goals (George, 2005),

it seems logical then that the existence of these liquid financial resources—which indicate that

the firm has resources in excess of what is required to meet current obligations and support sales

levels (Mishina et al. 2004)—would permit IPO firms to engage in boundary expansion activities

without worrying much about the specific context. Although external markets have greater risks

Page 82: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

70

in uncertain markets, managers consider acquisitions and joint ventures to be superior means of

accessing to capabilities and exploiting market opportunities.

Theoretical and Practical Implications

This study has several important implications for boundary expansion research, IPO firms,

and practitioners. Firm boundary research has typically examined decisions such as performing

internal R&D, or using a technological alliance (Pisano, 1990; Robertson & Gatignon, 1998),

making or buying car parts (Monteverde & Teece, 1982), pursuing a joint venture or a wholly

owned subsidiary (Hennart, 1991). Similarly, this paper focuses on the decision of whether to

continue investing in R&D or gain access to capabilities through the market. More specifically,

we focus on high technology IPO firms. This article contributes to the literature by moving

away from the traditional focus on well-established firms. The motivations and behaviors of

managers are different in pre and post-IPO firms where market scrutiny and the need to deliver

results every fiscal quarter are increased (George, 2005). This paper provides support for the

capability perspective in the boundary literature. IPO context differs from the general context

where incumbents are experiencing. Net proceeds from going public give IPO firms a

substantial advantage in capability development. Our findings suggest that, in the IPO context,

the most important factors influencing boundary choice are the firms resources specifically R&D

and financial. It implies that the nature and potential value of different types of resources

(Walter & Barney, 1990) should be understood differently over the life cycle.

From a managerial perspective, resources should be taken into account when making

boundary expansion decisions. Evaluating strategic options based on transaction costs may not

be sufficient to create value for the firm. Although transaction costs in the external market are

low and attractive, seeking capabilities beyond the organizational boundary, will likely fail

Page 83: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

71

without a solid analysis of the available internal resources and firm’s capability needs. Thus,

managers should first understand their resource portfolio and then decide whether exploitation is

beneficial and increases their long-term competitive advantage.

Limitations and Future Research

Despite the care taken in data gathering and statistical analysis, this study has some

limitations. First, although this study included a fairly broad range of firms from different

industries, the unique characteristics of high-tech firms may have influenced the results. A focus

on less technology-intensive IPO firms, or firms in more stable industries might reveal additional

insights into the search and renewal strategies of IPO firms. Second, the exclusive focus on R&D

and financial resources limits the study. Other resource dimensions, such as physical or

commercial, might significantly influence a firm’s boundary choice. Third, boundary expansion

can be narrowed down in terms of industry and national boundary, and future research may

examine how different types of resources influence these dimensions of boundary expansion.

Fourth, organizational boundary can be explained through a number of different perspectives—

power, competency, efficiency, and identity (Santos & Eisenhardt, 2005). In this paper, we

discuss boundary primarily from the competency perspective using resource-and capability-

views because they arguably explain boundary expansion more completely than others (such as

efficiency or power) (Jacobides & Hitt, 2005). Future research may compare and contrast all four

perspectives with comprehensible sample. Finally, this paper does not consider the implications

of boundary choice on performance. Although, not part of the study, we found that high R&D

intensity in early stage firms is positively related to market-based performance (measured by

Tobin’s q). Future research may investigate the best time for IPO firms to engage in boundary

Page 84: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

72

expansion. Additionally, researchers may examine conditions affecting how timing and the

choice of mode influences the market performance of a young firm.

In conclusion, this study investigates the various search and renewal strategies of young

firms. Based on the resources- and -capability perspectives, this study found that R&D resources

increase the boundary expansion activities in early stage firms, contingent on environmental

uncertainty and competitive intensity. Financial resources also influence the extent to which

firms engage in boundary expansion activities. These findings help to explain the implications

of resources on exploitation and exploration decisions, and contribute to the boundary expansion

and capability development literature, particularly in the IPO context.

Page 85: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

73

REFERENCES

Ahuja, G. 2000. The Duality of Collaboration: Inducements and Opportunities in the Formation of Interfirm Linkages. Strategic Management Journal, 21(3): 317-343.

Aiken, L. S., & West, S. G. 1991. Multiple regression: Testing and interpreting interactions. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.

Aldrich, H. 1999. Organizations evolving. London: Sage Publications.

Amihud, Y., & Lev, B. 1981. Risk reduction as a managerial motive for conglomerate mergers. The Bell Journal of Economics, 12(2): 605-617.

Amit, R., & Schoemaker, P. J. H. 1993. Strategic assets and organizational rent. Strategic Management Journal, 14(1): 33-46.

Anderson, P., & Tushman, M. L. 2001. Organizational environments and industry exit: The effects of uncertainty, munificence and complexity. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(3): 675-711.

Aragon-Correa, J. A., & Sharma, S. 2003. A contingent resource-based view of proactive corporate environmental strategy. Academy of Management Review, 28(1): 71-88.

Argyres, N. 1996. Evidence on the role of firm capabilities in vertical integration decisions. Strategic Management Journal, 17(2): 129-150.

Arkebauer, K. R. 1991. Cashing out. New York: Harper Business.

Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm resources and sustainable competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1): 99-120.

Barney, J. B. 1999. How a firm's capabilities affect boundary decisions. Sloan Management Review, 40(3): 137-145.

Barney, J. B. 2001. Is the resource-based" view" a useful perspective for strategic management research? Yes. Academy of Management Review, 26(1): 41-56.

Barney, J. B. 2007. Gaining and sustaining competitive advantage (3rd ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education.

Barney, J. B., & Clark, D. N. 2007. Resource-based theory: creating and sustaining competitive advantage. New York, NY: Oxford University Press Inc.

Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. H. 1995. Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(1): 73-92.

Page 86: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

74

Bourgeois, L. J. 1981. On the measurement of organizational slack. Academy of Management Review, 6(1): 29-39.

Bowen, H. P., & Wiersema, M. F. 2004. Modeling limited dependent variables: Methods and guidelines for researchers in strategic management. Research Methodology in Strategy and Management, 1: 87-134.

Bower, J. L. 1970. Managing the resource allocation process. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

Bradley, D. J., Jordan, B. D., Yi, H. C., & Roten, I. C. 2001. Venture capital and IPO lockup expiration: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Research, 24(4): 465-494.

Burgelman, R. A. 1983a. A model of the interaction of strategic behavior, corporate context, and the concept of strategy. Academy of Management Review, 8(1): 61-70.

Burgelman, R. A. 1983b. A process model of internal corporate venturing in the diversified major firm. Administrative Science Quarterly, 28(2): 223-244.

Burgelman, R. A. 1986. Strategy-making and evolutionary theory: Towards a capabilities-based perspective. In M. Tsuchiya (Ed.), Technological Innovation and Business Strategy. Tokyo, Japan: Nihon Keizai Shinbunsha.

Burrill, G. S., & Lee, K. B. 1993. Biotech 94: long term value, short term hurdles: the industry annual report. San Francisco, CA: Ernst & Young.

Carpenter, R. E., & Petersen, B. C. 2002. Capital market imperfections, high-tech investment, and new equity financing. The Economic Journal, 112(477): 54-72.

Certo, S. T. 2003. Influencing initial public offering investors with prestige: Signaling with board structures. Academy of Management Review, 28(3): 432-446.

Certo, S. T., Covin, J. G., Daily, C. M., & Dalton, D. R. 2001. Wealth and the effects of founder management among IPO-stage new ventures. Strategic Management Journal, 22(6-7): 641-658.

Chandler, A. D. 1962. Strategy and structure. Cambridge: MIT Press.

Chandler, A. D. 1977. The visible hand: The managerial revolution in American business. Cambridge: Belknap Press.

Chatterji, A. K. 2009. Spawned with a silver spoon? Entrepreneurial performance and innovation in the medical device industry. Strategic Management Journal, 30(2): 185-206.

Christensen, C. M., & Bower, J. L. 1996. Customer power, strategic investment, and the failure of leading firms. Strategic Management Journal, 17(3): 197-218.

Page 87: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

75

Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. 1990. Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1): 128-152.

D'Aveni, R. A. 1994. Hypercompetition. New York: Free Press

Das, T. K., & Teng, B. S. 1998. Resource and risk management in the strategic alliance making process. Journal of Management, 24(1): 21-42.

Deeds, D. L., Decarolis, D., & Coombs, J. E. 1997. The impact of firmspecific capabilities on the amount of capital raised in an initial public offering: Evidence from the biotechnology industry. Journal of Business Venturing, 12(1): 31-46.

Dess, G. G., & Beard, D. W. 1984. Dimensions of organizational task environments. Administrative Science Quarterly, 29(1): 52-73.

Dundas, K. N. M., & Richardson, P. R. 1980. Corporate strategy and the concept of market failure. Strategic Management Journal, 1(2): 177-188.

Economist, T. 2002. Struggling with a supertanker.

Eisenhardt, K. M., & Martin, J. A. 2000. Dynamic capabilities: What are they? Strategic Management Journal, 21(10/11): 1105-1121.

Galunic, D. C., & Eisenhardt, K. M. 1996. The evolution of intracorporate domains: Divisional charter losses in high-technology, multidivisional corporations. Organization Science, 7(3): 255-282.

Galunic, D. C., & Eisenhardt, K. M. 2001. Architectural innovation and modular corporate forms. Academy of Management Journal, 44(6): 1229-1249.

Garrette, B., Dussauge, P., & Castaner, X. 2008. A resource need and availability view of the make or ally choice: evidence from the worldwide aircraft industry 1945-2000. Les Cahiers de Recherche.

George, G. 2005. Slack resources and the performance of privately held firms. Academy of Management Journal, 48(4): 661.

Ghemawat, P. 1991. Commitment: The dynamic of strategy. New York: Free Press.

Gilbert, C. 2005. Unbundling the structure of inertia: Resource versus routine rigidity. Academy of Management Journal, 48(5): 741-763.

Gompers, P., Lerner, J., & Scharfstein, D. 2005. Entrepreneurial spawning: Public corporations and the genesis of new ventures, 1986 to 1999. Journal of Finance, 60(2): 577-614.

Page 88: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

76

Grabowski, H., & Vernon, J. 1990. A new look at the returns and risks to pharmaceutical R&D. Management Science, 36(7): 804-821.

Graves, S. B., & Langowitz, N. S. 1993. Innovative productivity and returns to scale in the pharmaceutical industry. Strategic Management Journal, 14(8): 593-605.

Greene, W. H. 2003. Econometric analysis. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall

Hamel, G. 2000. Leading the revolution. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

Helfat, C. E. 1994. Evolutionary trajectories in petroleum firm R&D. Management Science, 40(12): 1720-1747.

Helfat, C. E. 1997. Know-how and asset complementarity and dynamic capability accumulation: The case of R&D. Strategic Management Journal, 18(5): 339-360.

Hennart, J. F. 1991. The transaction costs theory of joint ventures: An empirical study of Japanese subsidiaries in the United States. Management Science, 37(4): 483-497.

Higgins, M. C., & Gulati, R. 2003. Getting off to a good start: The effects of upper echelon affiliations on underwriter prestige. Organization Science, 14(3): 244-263.

Hill, C. W. L., & Hoskisson, R. E. 1987. Strategy and Structure in the Multiproduct Firm. Academy of Management Review, 12(2): 331-341.

Hill, C. W. L., & Snell, S. A. 1988. External control, corporate strategy, and firm performance in research-intensive industries. Strategic Management Journal, 9(6): 577-590.

Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E., Johnson, R. A., & Moesel, D. D. 1996. The market for corporate control and firm innovation. Academy of Management Journal, 39(5): 1084-1119.

Hoskisson, R. E., & Hitt, M. A. 1990. Antecedents and performance outcomes of diversification: A review and critique of theoretical perspectives. Journal of Management, 16(2): 461-509.

Iyer, D. N., & Miller, K. D. 2008. Performance feedback, slack, and the timing of acquisitions. Academy of Management Journal, 51(4): 808-822.

Jacobides, M. G., & Hitt, L. M. 2005. Losing sight of the forest for the trees? Productive capabilities and gains from trade as drivers of vertical scope. Strategic Management Journal, 26(13): 1209.

Jain, B. A., & Kini, O. 1999. The life cycle of initial public offering firms. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 26(9/10): 1281-1307.

Page 89: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

77

Jain, B. A., & Kini, O. 2000. Does the presence of venture capitalists improve the survival profile of IPO firms? Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 27(9/10): 1139-1183.

Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. 1979. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2): 263-291.

Karim, S., & Mitchell, W. 2000. Path-dependent and path-breaking change: Reconfiguring business resources following acquisitions in the US medical sector, 1978-1995. Strategic Management Journal, 21(10/11): 1061-1081.

Keats, B. W., & Hitt, M. A. 1988. A causal model of linkages among environmental dimensions, macro organizational characteristics, and performance. Academy of Management Journal, 31(3): 570-598.

Keil, T., Maula, M., Schildt, H., & Zahra, S. A. 2008. The effect of governance modes and relatedness of external business development activities on innovative performance. Strategic Management Journal, 29(8): 895-907.

Klepper, S., & Sleeper, S. 2005. Entry by spinoffs. Management Science, 51(8): 1291-1306.

Kumar, M. V. S. 2009. The relationship between product and international diversification: the effects of short-run constraints and endogeneity. Strategic Management Journal, 30(1): 99-116.

Latham, S. F., & Braun, M. R. 2008. The performance implications of financial slack during economic recession and recovery: observations from the software industry (2001-2003). Journal of Managerial Issues, 20(1): 30-50.

Leiblein, M. J., & Miller, D. J. 2003. An empirical examination of transaction-and firm-level influences on the vertical boundaries of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 24(9): 839-859.

Leonard-Barton, D. 1992. Core capabilities and core rigidities: A paradox in managing new product development. Strategic Management Journal, 13(1): 111-125.

Leone, A. J., Rock, S., & Willenborg, M. 2007. Disclosure of intended use of proceeds and underpricing in initial public offerings. Journal of Accounting Research, 45(1): 111-153.

Levinthal, D. A., & March, J. G. 1993. The myopia of learning. Strategic Management Journal, 14(2): 95-112.

Loughran, T., & Ritter, J. 2004. Why has IPO underpricing changed over time? Financial management, 33(3): 5-37.

Makadok, R. 2001. Toward a synthesis of the resource-based and dynamic-capability views of rent creation. Strategic Management Journal, 22(5): 387-401.

Page 90: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

78

McNamara, G., Vaaler, P. M., & Devers, C. 2003. Same as it ever was: The search for evidence of increasing hypercompetition. Strategic Management Journal, 24(3): 261-278.

Mezias, S. J., & Boyle, E. 2005. Blind trust: Market control, legal environments, and the dynamics of competitive intensity in the early American film industry, 1893-1920. Administrative Science Quarterly, 50(1): 1-34.

Miller, D. J., Fern, M. J., & Cardinal, L. B. 2007. The use of knowledge for technological innovation within diversified firms. Academy of Management Journal, 50(2): 308-326.

Mishina, Y., Pollock, T. G., & Porac, J. F. 2004. Are more resources always better for growth? Resource stickiness in market and product expansion. Strategic Management Journal, 25(12): 1179-1197.

Monteverde, K., & Teece, D. J. 1982. Supplier switching costs and vertical integration in the automobile industry. The Bell Journal of Economics, 13(1): 206-213.

Montgomery, C. A., & Hariharan, S. 1991. Diversified expansion by large established firms. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 15(1): 71-89.

Nelson, T. 2003. The persistence of founder influence: Management, ownership, and performance effects at initial public offering. Strategic Management Journal, 24(8): 707-724.

Patzelt, H., Shepherd, D. A., Deeds, D., & Bradley, S. W. 2008. Financial slack and venture managers' decisions to seek a new alliance. Journal of Business Venturing, 23(4): 465-481.

Penrose, E. T. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New York, NY: Wiley.

Pisano, G. P. 1990. The R&D boundaries of the firm: an empirical analysis. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1): 153-176.

Poppo, L. 1995. Influence activities and strategic coordination: Two distinctions of internal and external markets. Management Science, 41(12): 1845-1859.

Poppo, L., & Zenger, T. 1995. Opportunism, routines, and boundary choices: A comparative test of transaction cost and resource-based explanations for make-or-buy decisions. Academy of Management Journal, 38(1): 42-46.

Poppo, L., & Zenger, T. 1998. Testing alternative theories of the firm: transaction cost, knowledge-based, and measurement explanations for make-or-buy decisions in information services. Strategic Management Journal, 19(9): 853-877.

Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, P. J. 1991. The new institutionalism in organizational analysis. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press

Page 91: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

79

Reed, R., & DeFillippi, R. J. 1990. Causal ambiguity, barriers to imitation, and sustainable competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review, 15(1): 88-102.

Robertson, T. S., & Gatignon, H. 1998. Technology development mode: A transaction cost conceptualization. Strategic Management Journal, 19(6): 515-531.

Robinson, K. C., & McDougall, P. P. 2001. Entry barriers and new venture performance: a comparison of universal and contingency approaches. Strategic Management Journal, 22(6): 659-685.

Santos, F. M. 2003. Constructing Niches and Shaping Boundaries: Entrepreneurial Action in Nascent Markets? Unpublished Dissertation, Stanford University, Stanford, CA.

Santos, F. M., & Eisenhardt, K. M. 2005. Organizational boundaries and theories of organization. Organization Science, 16(5): 491.

Santos, F. M., & Eisenhardt, K. M. 2009. Constructing markets and shaping boundaries: Entrepreneurial power in nascent fields. Academy of Management Journal, 52(4): 643-671.

Scherer, F. M. 1980. Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. Chicago: Rand McNally & Co.

Schilling, M. A., & Steensma, H. K. 2001. The use of modular organizational forms: an industry-level analysis. Academy of Management Journal, 44(6): 1149-1168.

Siggelkow, N. 2001. Change in the presence of fit: The rise, the fall, and the renaissance of Liz Claiborne. Academy of Management Journal, 44(4): 838-857.

Silverman, B. S. 1999. Technological resources and the direction of corporate diversification: Toward an integration of the resource-based view and transaction cost economics. Management Science, 45(8): 1109-1124.

Sirmon, D. G., Hitt, M. A., & Ireland, R. D. 2007. Managing firm resources in dynamic environments to create value: Looking inside the black box. Academy of Management Review, 32(1): 273-292.

Steensma, H. K., & Corley, K. G. 2001. Organizational context as a moderator of theories on firm boundaries for technology sourcing. Academy of Management Journal, 44(2): 271-291.

Swaminathan, A. 1995. The proliferation of specialist organizations in the American wine industry, 1941-1990. Administrative Science Quarterly, 40(4):653-680.

Teece, D. J. 1982. Towards an economic theory of the multiproduct firm. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 3(1): 39-63.

Page 92: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

80

Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. 1997. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 18(7): 509-533.

Thompson, A. A., & Strickland, A. J. 1980. Strategy formulation and implementation: Tasks of the general manager. Dallas: Business Publications.

Tosi Jr, H. L., & Gomez-Mejia, L. R. 1989. The decoupling of CEO pay and performance: An agency theory perspective. Administrative Science Quarterly, 34(2): 169-189.

Tushman, M., & O'Reilly, C. A. 2002. Winning through innovation: A practical guide to leading organizational change and renewal. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

Walker, G., & Weber, D. 1987. Supplier competition, uncertainty, and make-or-buy decisions. Academy of Management Journal, 30(3): 589-596.

Walter, G. A., & Barney, J. B. 1990. Research notes and communications management objectives in mergers and acquisitions. Strategic Management Journal, 11(1): 79-86.

Williamson, O. E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.

Zander, U., & Kogut, B. 1995. Knowledge and the speed of the transfer and imitation of organizational capabilities: An empirical test. Organization Science, 6(1): 76-92.

Page 93: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

81

CHAPTER FOUR

PAPER THREE

INITIAL PUBLIC OFFERING AND THE STRATEGIC BEHAVIOR OF FIRM:

DIFFERENTIATION AND PERFORMANCE

ABSTRACT

This study examines the role of new ventures’ differentiation strategy on their short- and long-

term performance after the IPO—particularly, at the time of IPO (initial public offering) and

during post-IPO stages. New ventures in the high technology industry strategically differentiate

themselves by exploring novel technologies rather than continuing to exploit existing

technologies or mimicking other firms’ technologies. We argue that the new ventures’ use of

novel technologies developed upon their unique resources and capabilities provide an initial

setting for competitive advantage both in the short- and long run. We find that new ventures that

use differentiation as their innovation strategy would yield superior performance as compared to

the ventures that mimic existing technologies. Further, we find that the presence of

environmental uncertainty enhances the performance of those new ventures that have developed

novel technologies drawing upon their unique resources and capabilities.

Keywords:

New venture, differentiation, performance, IPO

Page 94: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

82

INTRODUCTION

Scholars in strategic management and organization theory have argued that firms

particularly a new venture, is in direct competition with its competitors in the industry and also

faces indirect competition with other actors in the external environment (Baum & Haveman,

1997; Deephouse, 1999; Lieberman & Asaba, 2006). New ventures’ technology strategy

regarding differentiation or mimicry plays an important role in their future performance

(Chatterji, 2009; Phillips, 2002; Ruef, Aldrich, & Carter, 2003; Vesper, 1990). On one hand, a

new venture’s performance is related to its ability to differentiate itself from its competitors. By

differentiating their resources and market position from those of incumbents, new ventures are

able to reduce the likelihood of imitation and place themselves in a more competition position

(Lieberman & Asaba, 2006). Additionally, differentiation of resources from competitors reduces

competition for them in the market (Barney, 1991; Porter, 1991), leading to higher performance.

On the other hand, new ventures may rely on conformity to the industry norm. Entrepreneurial

ventures may mimic incumbents’ behavior in the industry because they face of high levels of

uncertainty regarding technology strategy (Meyer & Rowan, 1977; Pfeffer & Salancik, 2003).

Strategic similarity allows the new venture to be recognized as following legitimacy, reducing

risks inherent in exploration (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983). However, it is still less understood

which approach is more beneficial in an initial public offering (IPO) context.

IPO is a process through which a new venture goes public. IPO provides new ventures an

opportunity to obtain financial capital from investors, increase recognition and visibility of the

new ventures by exposing to investors, and often obtain higher values as the acquisition targets

(Brau & Fawcett, 2006; Certo, Holcomb, & Holmes Jr, 2009; Nelson, 2003; Pagano, Panetta, &

Zingales, 1998). In addition, going public allows new ventures not only to increase their

Page 95: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

83

legitimacy in the business community but also to gain improved access to debt financing (Cohen

& Dean, 2005; Deeds, Mang, & Frandsen, 2004; Higgins & Gulati, 2005; Pollock & Rindova,

2003; Sutton & Benedetto, 1988). IPO also involves disadvantages, such as a loss of ownership,

increased financial and operational scrutiny of the business, vulnerability to the external

environment, and high cost of going public (Certo et al., 2009). For a new venture, delivering

correct signal to the market is important (Daily, Certo, Dalton, & Roengpitya, 2003) and as such

mangers of recently IPO firms should find a mechanism to manage the quality of their new

venture for reducing uncertainty and attracting more investors. Signals, such as the

characteristics of top management team, help in gaining legitimacy in the market (e.g., Deeds et

al., 2004; Gulati & Higgins, 2002; Higgins & Gulati, 2003; Pollock & Rindova, 2003). However,

literature is yet to focus its attention on how a new venture’s technology strategy influences its

performance both in the short and long term.

This study builds on signaling theory (Spence, 1973, 1974b) and explores which strategic

action, technological mimicry or differentiation, delivers superior performance in the IPO and

post-IPO context. We consider mimicry and differentiation as a continuum of strategic actions

and choices. We consider differentiation as one end of the continuum whereas mimicry is other

end. In the context of technology strategy, we define differentiation as those technology choices

that help distinguish a new venture from others whereas strategic similarity refers to strategic

actions that lead to technological mimicry and help resemble other firms in the industry. A new

venture’s choice on this continuum delivers appropriate signal to the potential investors in the

market. We propose that a new venture’s strategic choice before IPO plays a critical role in its

short- and long-term performance after the IPO because investment decisions of shareholders at

Page 96: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

84

the time of IPO and subsequent investments depend on the new venture’s potential to create high

return on investment.

This paper is structured as follows: First, we discuss the role of information asymmetry

and signaling theory on IPO- and subsequent performance. Second, we explain strategic actions

and technological choice from signaling perspective. Third, we develop hypotheses explicating

the role of such actions and choices on new venture’s short- and long-term performance. Fourth,

we test the proposed hypotheses and finally, we discuss the findings and implications.

THEORY AND HYPOTHESES

Information Asymmetry and Signaling Theory

IPO is characterized by information asymmetry because the current owners (i.e., internal

managers) have access to more information about the internal operations while potential

investors in the market have access to relatively less information (Downes & Heinkel, 1982).

Information asymmetry is created because IPO takes place when potential investors have

relatively less knowledge than the security owners and such asymmetry open up the potential for

opportunistic behavior by owners(Carter & Manaster, 1990; Stuart, Hoang, & Hybels, 1999).

The available information in the market plays the role of a signal from owners to the

potential investors. Signaling theory (Spence, 1973, 1974b) suggests that certain indicators about

quality of IPO new venture provide signals to potential investors, increasing the future value of

the new venture (Deeds, DeCarolis, & Coombs, 2000). Signaling activities are useful, especially

when high information asymmetry exists (Spence, 1973). When there is significant difference in

the amount of information between owners and investors, the signal reduces the information

asymmetry because signal is both observable and costly to imitate (Certo, Daily, & Dalton, 2001;

Page 97: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

85

Spence, 1973). Because IPO new ventures must release their internal information in the market

through prospectus, signaling mechanisms play a major role in the IPO process Since the

potential investors make a decision based on the signal, the IPO new ventures may delay IPO

until they can provide more positive signal (e.g. demonstrating high performance) to the

potential investors (Jenkinson & Ljungqvist, 2001).

To be effective, market signal should meet the conditions that it is observable, difficult to

change, costly to produce and imitate, and persistent (Riley, 1975; Spence, 1974a). Although

market signal is difficult to imitate, IPO new ventures are more likely to imitate the strategies

practiced in past so as to gain legitimacy and enhance the value. Next, we discuss types of

strategic actions a new venture may adopt.

Performance Implications of Strategic Similarity vs. Differentiation

Scholars have discussed strategic actions in two perspectives, and each perspective

provides different conclusions. First, institutional theory (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Powell &

DiMaggio, 1991) supports the strategic similarity perspective. Incumbents or society generates

prevailing norms in the institutional environment. Additionally, a collective, particular pattern

exerts pressures on organizations to adopt legitimate structural element (Burns & Wholey, 1993).

From IPO perspective, legitimacy represents the perception that new venture would act on the

behalf of shareholder wealth generation (Cohen & Dean, 2005), and that new ventures would

meet implicitly necessary requirements in their industry. When one or more organizations use a

particular practice, inter-organizational imitation can increase the likelihood of that practice

being adopted by other organizations (Haunschild & Miner, 1997). This mimicry behavior, such

as imitating entry strategy of industry peers, is rooted in institutional theory (DiMaggio & Powell,

1983; Meyer & Rowan, 1977; Powell & DiMaggio, 1991; Scott, 2008).

Page 98: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

86

Institutional theory is a theory that explains why there is a high homogeneity of

organizational structures and practices among actors in an industry (Donaldson, 1995). The core

idea is that organizations are more likely to survive if they obtain legitimacy and approval from

actors in the surrounding institutional environment (Zucker, 1988). According to the institutional

theory, individual organizations adapt to their institutional environment via isomorphic

mechanisms. Meyer, Scott, Strang, and Creighton (1988) offered evidence of increase

institutional isomorphism by showing that increasing similarity across the different states of the

USA indicating the increased homogenization of the nation.

Scholars use a concept of mimicry to explain the strategic similarity. Mimicry, which

refers to a strategic action to respond to uncertainty through imitating other actors’ actions

(DiMaggio & Powell, 1983), is one of isomorphic mechanisms to explain the homogeneity

among organizations, and occurs when organizations imitate successful role models in order to

avoid deviation or to be perceived as rational actions (Greenwood & Meyer, 2008).

Organizations model themselves after other organizations that they perceive to be more

legitimate or successful. Thus, strategic similarity is an outcome of a standard response to

uncertainty, where new ventures adopt solutions used by others to deal with problems (DiMaggio

& Powell, 1983). Heugens and Lander (2007) found support for the effect of mimetic pressures

on organizational isomorphism. Adoption of a legitimated structure or strategic actions helps the

new venture secure funding and eases its transactions with other organizations. Overall, strategic

similarity through mimicry allows the new ventures to achieve legitimacy by adapting to

institutional environment in the industry (Van de Ven & Hargrave, 2004) and survive longer than

others which do not achieve legitimacy (Lee & Pennings, 2002). Therefore, scholars in the

institutional theory suggest that legitimacy is more important than uniqueness.

Page 99: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

87

On the other hand, resource-based view (RBV) (Barney, 1991; Penrose, 1959) supports

for strategic differentiation perspective for superior performance. RBV argues that resources are

“stocks of available factors that are owned or controlled by the firm” (Amit & Schoemaker,

1993). RBV further proposes that valuable, rare, inimitable and non-substitutable (VRIN)

resources are the genesis of competitive advantage through value creation (Barney 1991;

Mahoney and Pandian 1992; Penrose 1959; Wernerfelt 1984). Because resources consist of a

bundle of potential services that can be used for rent generation (Penrose, 1959), idiosyncratic

differences among firm-resources (e.g., technologies, knowledge base, managerial experience

and vision) and their use leads to variance in performance with some firms gaining competitive

advantage over others (Barney, 1991; Barney, 2001; Wernerfelt, 1984). In the context of new

ventures, RBV suggests that new ventures with differentiated resources have more avenues for

engaging in local and distant search and recombine such resources for developing superior

capabilities. The unique combination of technologies across organizational boundary and

technological boundary leads to higher innovation and increase the new venture’s performance

(Miller, 2006; Rosenkopf & Nerkar, 2001). Summarizing, new ventures that use differentiation

strategy developing resources and capabilities that are valuable, rare, inimitable, and non-

substitutable gain competitive advantage (Alvarez & Barney, 2004; Alvarez & Busenitz, 2001).

A new venture’s choice for differentiation also reduces resource competition in the factor

market. Moreover, such new ventures have the opportunity to create a new market or position

their differentiated products and services in a niche market (Porter, 1998; Rumelt, Schendel, &

Teece, 1994). Niche markets offer less competition as compared to generic markets. In essence,

the strategy to focus on novel technologies positions such new ventures for competitive

advantage in the industry irrespective of competition or industry characteristics (Afuah, 2001).

Page 100: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

88

The use of differentiation strategy also provides an effective signal to the potential investors

because of the inherent nature of valuable, rare, inimitable and non-substitutable resources.

We weighed the potential importance of strategic similarity and differentiation in the

context of new venture. We believe that though strategic similarity enables a new venture to

conform to the industry norms and achieve legitimacy, mimicry also has substantial

disadvantages such as high levels of competition with incumbents and other competitors, lack of

novel technology, limited scope of exploitation and lack of powerful signal to the market. On the

other hand, differentiation strategy develops a niche with the use of VRIN resources and

capabilities, lowers the levels of competition in the factor and target markets, thrives on the

benefits of exploration and pioneering novel technologies, and generates excitement in the

market sending powerful signal to the potential investors (Afuah, 2001; Deephouse, 1999;

Gimeno, Hoskisson, Beal, & Wan, 2005; Katila & Ahuja, 2002). Overall, although the effects of

differentiation strategy on performance could be debatable, our hypothesis is that the use of

differentiation strategy by new ventures should deliver above advantages to the new venture,

leading to superior performance at the time of IPO.

Hypothesis 1. New ventures’ use of differentiation strategy is more positively

associated with the new venture performance at the time of IPO rather than their

use of similarity strategy.

In the high technology industry, development of technological resources and capabilities

can provide value far in excess of the initial investments in the long run. Valuation of high

technology initiatives must be oriented towards the future revenue generation potential and

Page 101: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

89

associated risks (Nolan, 1994, p. 4). A new venture’s technological capital must be assessed by

considering its association with both the level and the risk of current and future profitability. This

is because of the following reasons: 1) The true potential of novel technology is often unknown

as it unfolds over time, 2) The antecedents of technological resources and capabilities consist of

intangibles such as knowledge base and learning curve.

Further, intangible organizational resources for the development of novel technologies

include not just the presence of specific ‘technology asset (e.g., prior patent)’ but also the

knowledge and capabilities of the skilled employees continually integrate and recombine

resources for developing new technological capabilities to match or surpass market needs

(Eisenhardt & Martin, 2000; Matusik & Hill, 1998; Prahalad & Hamel, 1990). We believe that

such knowledge-based capabilities get embedded in the venture and are valuable, rare, inimitable

and non-substitutable. Moreover, we argue that such new ventures would have developed a

‘pioneering’ culture that focuses on continual exploration of new technologies with appropriate

culture along with organization structure, controls, communications, and rewards systems. In

summary, new ventures that differentiate themselves on the basis of novel knowledge and

technologies develop VRIN resources and capabilities that are generally realized over time. Such

resources and capabilities become venture-specific and are complex to acquire by competitors or

incumbents leading to competitive advantage. As the differentiation strategy may take years to

add value to a firm and its impact shows more in the long term, we propose that the use of

differentiation strategy would allows the new venture to have superior performance after IPO.

Page 102: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

90

Hypothesis 2. New ventures’ use of differentiation strategy is more positively

associated with the new venture’s market performance rather than their use of

similarity strategy.

However, stock prices may be a less reliable indicator of fundamental values for new

ventures that are smaller and less known. Extant literature suggests that shareholder returns, from

owning a portfolio of IPOs for up to five years after the companies go public, perform well

below other benchmark returns (Aggarwal & Rivoli, 1990; Loughran, Ritter, & Rydqvist, 1994;

Ritter, 1991). It has been suggested by Grinblatt and Titman (2002) that the poor performance of

firms, having recently gone public, is related to IPO markets which are not informationally

efficient. Often, inefficient IPO markets provide corporate managers the opportunity to

successfully time the market (Loughran & Ritter, 1995). This suggests that corporate managers

issue stock when it is overpriced.

Bhide (2000) argues that the really significant risk for a venture occurs not at the start-up

stage but at the point when major irreversible investment in growth is required. At this stage, an

entrepreneur puts all of his or her financial resources into “one basket.” According to Bhide,

“growth involves developing formal structures and systems that increase the firm’s fixed costs

and hence the risk of bankruptcy” (2000: 293). Whether entrepreneurs escalate their commitment

at this stage—in the face of increasing bankruptcy risk— often determines whether their firms

will eventually succeed or not. Thus, in addition to the performance, we also consider the

possibility of bankruptcy as another result of differentiation strategy of new venture. First,

differentiation strategy requires developing relatively new technologies and products. The

superior capability and resource support for radical and incremental innovation. The new

Page 103: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

91

ventures with differentiating their resources and capabilities from others are able to or have at

least more novel technological resources than others simply using mimicry. Therefore, new

venture with novel technologies are more likely to survive than are non-innovative firms (Cefis

& Marsili, 2006). It is believed that innovative firms grow faster, are more profitable, and are

survivors in shake-outs (Geroski, 1995). This is because firms with technological resources have

better odds of facing the shake-out phase of lifecycle based on the niche target market for their

innovation. These firms survive on the basis of superior technical capability developed through

process of innovation and their attempts to drive down cost (Knott & Posen, 2005; Nelson &

Winter, 1982). Second, development of novel technologies protects new ventures from ‘liability

of newness’ as they are better at: (a) exploiting their superior resources and capabilities, (b)

learning and adapting to market needs; (b) development of novel technologies based on

resources and capabilities; (c) establishment of innovation culture; and (d) some connection with

potential customers and suppliers who demand novel technologies (Klepper, 1996; Levinthal,

1991; Nelson & Winter, 1982).

Lastly, new venture with superior technological capital derived from differentiation

strategy also ward off competition by not competing with generic firms and incumbents for

common resources, thereby reducing their mortality rate (Carroll & Hannan, 1989; Hannan &

Freeman, 1989). Extant literature suggests that new ventures go bankrupt if they fail the tests of

selection and competition. New ventures with novel technologies have better odds of selection in

the presence of population density. Such firms survive in the long-term, even when there is the

threat of excess entry (Knott & Posen, 2005) as well as strong competition in the industry

(Aghion, Harris, Howitt, & Vickers, 2001).

Page 104: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

92

Hypothesis 3. New ventures’ use of differentiation strategy is more positively

associated with the new venture’s survival by avoiding bankruptcy rather than

their use of similarity strategy.

Role of Environmental Uncertainty

In general, uncertainty is the inability to predict or foresee (Anderson & Tushman, 2001).

Uncertainty arises when decision makers such as investors cannot reliably forecast future events

based on the available information. Environmental uncertainty disrupts underlying equilibrium

and renders existing resources obsolete (Leonard-Barton, 1992; Schumpeter, 1942). In the face

of uncertainty, new ventures that develop novel technologies and create new markets have

greater odds of success because these characteristics provide relative stability in terms of future

market demand, potential of success with emerging technological trajectories and likely

dominant design (Anderson & Tushman, 1990; Benner & Tushman, 2003). They continue

exploring emerging technologies and following growth patterns with better odds for providing

value proposition even in the face of difficult to predict conditions—they can maintain

technological and competitive edge or at least sustain themselves as the uncertainty resolves over

time (Anderson & Tushman, 1990; Henderson & Clark, 1990). Technological edge and novel

technologies hedge against such uncertainty by providing a window on multiple emerging

competencies and potential for market demand for emerging technologies (Folta & Miller, 2002;

Steensma & Corley, 2001). Technological resources and capabilities provide opportunities for

continual learning throughout the uncertain period that could facilitate in pioneering new

technologies during the period itself or just later (Chesbrough, 2002; Dushnitsky & Lenox, 2006).

Page 105: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

93

Additionally, extant literature suggests that for such new ventures, rate of obsolescence

for innovative new ventures is also relatively lower despite uncertainty because such firms have

developed routines and capabilities that could renew their capabilities and develop new products

(Leonard-Barton, 1992; Tushman & O'Reilly, 2002). Differentiated resources provide a source

of competitive advantage especially under uncertain environment. In the presence of uncertainty,

investors are more likely to invest in the new ventures with novel technologies (Galunic &

Eisenhardt, 2001; Gilbert, 2005) that could sustain because such ventures’ signals are relatively

safe and sound as compared to those from average firms.

Even if the uncertainty remains for a longer period of time, odds are high that the

valuation of such ventures will be higher. They are better able to retain their market base despite

uncertainty because the market put more values in their innovations and a new venture’s

technological capital provides effective signals for future profitability. Such ventures also have

superior knowledge base, absorptive capacity and capabilities of the skilled employees that could

help in further development of new technologies. A culture of continual exploration of new

technologies with appropriate culture along with organization structure, controls,

communications, and rewards systems further helps them alleviate the effects of uncertainty in

the long run. They remain better positioned as compared to their competitors in the market with

market recognizing their potential and delivering higher valuation.

Such ventures will also be able to avoid bankruptcy in the face of uncertainty because

they have better odds of facing the shake-out phase of lifecycle due to the presence of niche

target market for their innovation. Even in the face of uncertainty, these firms survive on the

basis of superior technical capability developed through process of innovation and their attempts

to drive down cost. Such firms also save themselves from ‘liability of newness’ by exploiting

Page 106: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

94

their superior resources and capabilities, learning and continual development of novel

technologies based on resources and capabilities.

Overall, we propose that environmental uncertainty strengthen the relationship between

technological differentiation and performance of new ventures after IPO. That is, in the presence

of uncertainty, new ventures following differentiation strategy would deliver higher performance

both in the short-term and in the long-term.

Hypothesis 4. There is a stronger, positive relationship between the use of

differentiation strategy and the new venture performance at the time of IPO when

uncertainty is high.

Hypothesis 5. There is a stronger, positive relationship between the use of

differentiation strategy and new venture’s market performance as measured by

Tobin’s q when uncertainty is high.

Hypothesis 6. There is a stronger, positive relationship between the use of

differentiation strategy and new venture’s survival by avoiding bankruptcy when

uncertainty is high.

Page 107: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

95

METHOD

Data

The initial sample consists of all U.S. IPO firms between 2001 and 2005 in the U.S. high

technology industry, which is defined as those in 2digit SIC of 28 (chemicals and allied

products), 35 (industrial machinery and computer equipment), 36(electronics and other electric

equipment), 38 (instruments and related products), 48 (communications), and 73 (Business

services-software) (Bradley, Jordan, Yi, & Roten, 2001; Carpenter & Petersen, 2002; Loughran

& Ritter, 2004). The primacy data sources include Securities Data Company (SDC) Platinum,

COMPUSTAT, the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) Patent Citation data file and

Securities and Exchange Commission (SDC) filing (424b). The time window of 2001-2005 was

selected to avoid the effect of internet bubble and to match the initial sample with patent data

which is available in the 1975-2006. Firms are excluded from sample if financial data is not

available in the database and if firms are not listed in SDC platinum, COMPUSTAT, and patent

data. After matching process, the final sample was 114 IPO firms in 35 four digit SIC industries.

The new NBER patent data project updated information about patent, technological class,

application year, citation, and assignee in the period 1975 -2006. Though many scholars have

used patent data as a proxy measure for innovation and strategic behavior in the

internorganizational relationships (see Argyres & Silverman, 2004; Miller, Fern, & Cardinal,

2007; Rosenkopf & Nerkar, 2001), patent data is not without limitations in that not all

technological innovation is patented (Hall, Jaffe, & Trajtenberg, 2001). Patent activities vary

from industry to industry, and patents are a way to protect intellectual property rights rather than

measuring the innovation output directly (Rodriguez-Duarte, Sandulli, Minguela-Rata, & Lopez-

Sanchez, 2007). However, these concerns are mitigated by the benefits of using patent data.

Page 108: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

96

NBER patent data allows scholars to measure a firm’s technological capital, flow of knowledge,

and interfirm relationships for knowledge building. Additionally, since this paper focuses on the

level of strategic differentiation, patent data would be an appropriate source to measure the

degree of which firms imitate other’s technologies in the same category or different categories.

Measures

Dependent variables. The short-term and long-term performance was measured by three

different variables. First, we measured the short-short term IPO performance using IPO

underpricing, which was calculated by the difference between the offer price and the stock price

at the first date of transaction divided by the offer price. This measure was used by many

scholars in the IPO literature (e.g. Arthurs, Busenitz, Hoskisson, & Johnson, 2009; Nelson, 2003;

Pollock & Rindova, 2003).

Second, the market-based performance of IPO firms was measured by Tobin’s Q, which

refers to the ration of the firm’s market value to the replacement cost of its assets (Chung &

Pruitt, 1994). Tobin’s Q is employed as IPO firms’ performance from long-term perspective. It is

expected that the lower value of Tobin’s Q indicates low value (or performance) because the

firm is poorly managing its resources, while higher value indicates high value of the firm

because the firm is effectively using resources, creating value. Use of this measure allows us to

measure a new venture’s future performance potential while avoiding some of the problems

associated with the accounting measures. We use this measure to capture the new venture’s

technologies’ intangible value because the use of Tobin’s Q for measuring intangible value is

based on the assumption that the long-run equilibrium market value of a firm must be equal to

the replacement value of its assets, giving a Tobin’s Q value close to unity. Deviations from this

relationship (where q is significantly greater than "1") are interpreted as signifying an

Page 109: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

97

unmeasured source of value, and generally attributed to the intangible value enjoyed by the firm.

In using this measure, we follow similar studies (e.g., Bharadwaj, Bharadwaj, & Konsynski,

1999) that explored the relationship between intangible value created by constructs such as brand

equity, R&D, and advertising and Tobin’s q.

Third, we use the level of bankruptcy to test the long-term effect of mimicry behavior on

the IPO firms. Distance from bankruptcy is measured by Altman Z score (Chen & Miller, 2007).

A firm that is experiencing significant operational and financial trouble and is on the verge of

bankruptcy is said to be in financial distress (Chen & Miller, 2007). Altman’s (1968, 1993) Z-

score is used to measure the degree of which a firm is from bankruptcy. A high Altman’s Z

represents that firms are at risk of bankruptcy, vice versa. We measure Altman’s Zs using firms’

accounting information regarding their working capital, retained earnings, earnings before

interest and taxes, market value of equity, and sales in the end of year of IPO event. The equation

is (1.2 X working capital divided by total assets) + (1.4 X retained earnings divided by total

assets) + (3.3 X income before interest expense and taxes divided by total assets) + (0.6 X

market value of equity divided by total liability) + (1.0 X sales divided by total assets). It is

expected that the higher value of Altman Z score, the lower change of bankruptcy.

Independent variable. Most research on interorganizational imitation has tended to adopt

indirect measures of the existence of mimetic behavior, such as the use of the percentage of

adoptions of some organizational change or innovation, branching behavior (Barreto & Baden-

Fuller, 2006), or the relationship between adoption and density of previous adoptions

(Haunschild, 1993). To be consistent with this approach and apply it to IPO context, this study

measured the level of strategic differentiation regarding technology using patent citations before

IPO. Firms may cite either patents developed by competitors in the same technological class, or

Page 110: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

98

those developed by firms in the different technological classes. Strategic differentiation was

calculated by inversed value of the number of cited patents in the same technological class

divided by the total number of cited patents before going public. It represents firm’s strategic

behavior regarding the extent to which the firm focuses on technologies outside of its core

industry. Using patenting measures as proxies for similarity or differentiation is appropriate

because firm’s capability of innovation is one of the critical competences in the high

technological industry (Matraves, 1999; Rothaermel & Boeker, 2008). Patents as innovation

output are more appropriate than R&D expenses which should be treated as input for innovation

(Ahuja, Lampert, & Tandon, 2008). The higher value indicates higher level of strategic

differentiation and more novel technologies.

Moderator. Environmental uncertainty can be broken into three dimensions (e.g.

complexity, munificent, and dynamism) (Dess & Beard, 1984). To capture the uncertain and

volatile characteristics of environment, we used environmental dynamism dimension and

measured it as the natural logarithms of sales figures in the 4-digit industry during five years

before IPO year were entered into quasi-time series regressions with time serving as the

independent variable. The antilog of the standard errors of the resulting regression slope

coefficients resulting regression slope coefficients were then used to capture volatility of

environment (Dess & Beard, 1984; Keats & Hitt, 1988).

Control Variables. We include several control variables to avoid alternative explanation.

First, NASDAQ index on the day before IPO was used to control for the market effect. In a good

market climate, firm may enjoy higher value since investors are more willing to pay for higher

premium (Ritter, 1991). Second, the log-transformed values of years since founding and the

number of employees at the time of IPO were used to measure firm age and firm size,

Page 111: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

99

respectively. Strategic actions of larger and older organizations are easily observed and paid

attention to by potential investors. Third, since the characteristics of mimicry patterns vary

industry by industry, we control for the industry effect by including dummy variables. The

primary 2-digit SIC code was categorized into one of three major industry groups according to

Dun & Bradstreet classification (e.g. 20-39: manufacturing, 40-49: transportation,

communications, electric, gas and sanitary services, and 70-89: service and software) and

included in the analysis. In results, industry variables were coded into 2 SIC dummy variables.

Forth, the venture capital backing was dummy coded as controls: 1 if IPO firm uses venture

capital; 0 if the firm does not use venture capital (Hsu, 2006). Literature in IPO research suggests

that monitoring and certification by venture capitalist may increase IPO performance (Brav,

Geczy, & Gompers, 2000). Fifth, the effect of non-compete clause in the state of headquarter

was controlled. Each state in the U.S. has different agreement about non-compete clause. When a

firm writes an employment contract with non-compete clause that prohibits an employee from

direct competition with its employer after leaving the firm, the citation activities and knowledge

sharing are less likely to occur (Liebeskind, 1996). The effect of non-compete clause was

dummy-coded 1 if the headquarter of IPO firm is located in the state without non-compete clause

and 0 if the headquarter is located in the state that support non-compete clause. Sixth, we

controlled the underwriter reputation by using scores developed by Carter and colleagues (1990;

1998). The underwriter reputation has 0-9 scale (Loughran & Ritter, 2004). Seventh, our model

included lockup provision as control. The lockup dummy was coded 1 where there is an

agreement between managers of the issue and exiting shareholders not to sell their holding for a

prescribed period after the date of IPO and 0 where there is no agreement on lockup provision.

Eighth, we also controlled the amount of net proceeds. Offer size was measured as the natural

Page 112: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

100

logarithm of total proceeds raised at IPO (Cohen & Dean, 2005). Ninth, to distinguish the pure

offer from other purpose, the empirical model controlled for the spin-off firms which was

measured as dummy variable. Lastly, we also included year dummies to control for potential

influences associated with yearly trends regarding IPO performance.

Analysis

Since we tested the effect of strategic differentiation on three different measures of

performance, Multivariate Regression Analysis was used to test our hypotheses. Differentiation

was measured on the basis of citation behavior before IPO, while the performance measures

were calculated at the end of IPO year. This lagged measurement allows testing the performance

consequence resulted from the strategic differentiation before IPO.

Three models with each dependent variable were specified in the analysis. The first

model includes the control variables with the short-term performance measure and the long-term

performance measures as DV. The second model includes the controls as well as the variables

used to test the main effect of strategic differentiation on the performance. The third model adds

the interaction terms between environmental uncertainty and differentiation strategy in order to

examine the moderating effect of environmental uncertainty on the relationship between strategic

differentiation and performance. To reduce multicollinearity, all continuous variables in the

model were centered using the mean value of each variable.

Page 113: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

TABLE 4.1 Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Matrix

Mean S.D. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 1. Underpricing 0.1 0.2

1 2. Tobin’s Q 3.6 2.3

0.18 1

3. Altman Z 14.4 18.0

0.19 0.59 1 4. Differentiation 2.8 2.3

0.06 0.27 0.46 1

5. NASDAQ index 1990.9 214.7

0.13 -0.15 0.03 -0.08 1 6. Firm age 2.2 0.6

-0.07 0.09 -0.07 -0.02 -0.10 1

7. Firm size 5.4 1.5

0.15 0.13 -0.21 -0.22 -0.15 0.48 1 8. Reputation 7.5 2.9

0.03 0.00 -0.10 -0.38 0.04 0.01 0.24 1

9. Net proceeds 138.5 260.4

0.03 0.42 0.18 -0.08 -0.12 0.26 0.61 0.09 1 10.Non-compete 0.6 0.5

0.10 0.10 0.21 0.18 -0.06 -0.21 -0.07 0.06 -0.08 1

11.Lockup 0.9 0.3

-0.01 0.08 0.07 0.01 -0.17 -0.05 -0.20 -0.04 -0.19 0.03 1 12.Venture-back 0.7 0.5

0.06 -0.04 0.13 -0.03 0.06 -0.34 -0.43 0.05 -0.32 0.09 0.11 1

13. Uncertainty 1.1 0.2 -0.13 0.09 0.09 -0.02 -0.02 0.01 -0.01 0.06 0.08 -0.08 -0.11 -0.11 1

101

Page 114: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

102

TABLE 4.2 Results of Multivariate Regression Analysis Estimating Short-Term and Long Term Performance

of New Ventures

Underpricing Tobin’s Q Altman’s Z

Model1 Model2 Model3 Model1 Model2 Model3 Model1 Model2 Model3

Stock index 0.17

0.20 † 0.21 † -0.17

-0.13

-0.13

0.17

0.23 † 0.24 † Venture-back 0.01 *** -0.04 *** -0.01 *** 0.02 *** 0.03 *** 0.03 *** -0.04 *** -0.05 *** -0.04 *** Sic1 0.06

0.04

0.03

-0.36 * -0.37 * -0.37 * 0.10

0.13

0.12

Sic2 -0.02

-0.02

-0.02

-0.21

-0.23

-0.23

0.12

0.13

0.13 Year01 0.31 ** 0.37 *** 0.32 ** 0.11

0.03

0.03

0.16

0.08

0.07

Year02 0.05

0.12

0.11

-0.22 * -0.22 * -0.22 * 0.07

0.08

0.08 Year03 0.21 * 0.22 * 0.19 † 0.03

-0.02

-0.02

0.29

0.21 * 0.20 *

Year04 0.17

0.20

0.15

-0.01

0.03

0.03

0.18

0.21 * 0.20 † Spin flag -0.21 * -0.19 † -0.18 † -0.14

-0.17

-0.17

-0.16 † -0.09

-0.08

Non-compete 0.10

0.07

0.08

0.11

0.07

0.07

0.20 * 0.12

0.12 Lockup 0.15

0.13

0.10

0.14

0.07

0.07

0.13

0.15 * 0.14 †

Firm age -0.10

-0.08

-0.07

0.19

0.14

0.14

0.14

0.02

0.03 Firm size 0.31 * 0.29 † 0.31 † -0.22

-0.06

-0.06

-0.46 *** -0.33 ** -0.33 **

Reputation -0.11

-0.10

-0.10

0.02

-0.01

-0.01

-0.07

-0.08

-0.08 Net proceeds 0.03

0.05

0.05

0.53 * 0.50 * 0.50 * 0.52 *** 0.49 *** 0.49 ***

Dynamism

-0.16 * -0.11 †

0.09

0.09

0.05

0.06 Differentiation

0.18 ** 0.23 ***

0.25 ** 0.26 *

0.44 *** 0.44 ***

Differentiation X Dynamism

0.18 *** 0.01 0.04

N 114

112

112

102

100

100

102

100

100 F statistics 2.50 ** 3.63 *** 4.65 *** 2.60 ** 2.81 *** 2.62 ** 2.29 ** 3.25 *** 2.96 ***

R2 0.19

0.24

0.26

0.35

0.43

0.43

0.31

0.47

0.47 ∆R2 0.05 * 0.02 † 0.08 *** 0.00 0.15 *** 0.00

† p < .10 * p < .05 ** p < .01 *** p < .001

Page 115: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

103

RESULTS

Table 1 provides the descriptive statistics among all variables. There was not a strong

correlation between a pair of variables. To further diagnose the presence of multicollinearity, we

checked the value of variance inflation factors and found all independent variables below the

commonly accepted threshold of 10. This suggests that there is no harmful collinearity.

Hypothesis 1 proposed that there is positive association between differentiation strategy

and IPO performance, and hypotheses 2 and 3 also suggest the positive relationship with the

long-term performance and survival. The coefficient for differentiation in model 2 of each DV in

Table 2 was positive and strongly significant (p<0.01). As expected, hypotheses 1, 2, and 3 were

supported. That is, the differentiation strategy before IPO increases the firm’s IPO performance,

market-based performance and the possibility of survival in the later stage.

Hypotheses 3, 4, and 5 proposed that environmental uncertainty make stronger the

relationship between differentiation and both short-term and long-term performance. It was

argued that new venture with differentiation strategy is more positively related with performance

after IPO when IPO firm face highly uncertain environment rather than when the future is more

predictable. The coefficient of the interaction terms in Table 2 was positive and significant only

in the model 2 of underpricing (p<0.001). Thus, the hypothesis 4 was supported, but hypotheses

5 and 6 testing interaction effect on the long-term performance were not supported. It appeared

that under uncertain environment, differentiation strategy is more beneficial in the short-term,

but it does not have consistent effect on the long-term performance (see Figure 1).

Page 116: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

104

FIGURE 4.1

Interaction Effects between Differentiation and Environmental Dynamism on the Short-Term Performance

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

This study sought to examine the nature and extent of influence that a new venture’s

strategic choices before IPO have on its short- and long-term performance after the IPO. The

argument that new ventures’ short and long term performance is influenced by its strategic

choice of differentiation versus similarity strategies is central to research in strategic

entrepreneurship—the use of novel technologies by combining VRIN resources and capabilities

develop an initial setting for competitive advantage both in the short- and long run for a new

venture. Understanding how this process works can help direct researchers to more carefully

High

Low

Short-term performance (Underpricing)

Differentiation

Low environmental dynamism High environmental dynamism

Low High

Page 117: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

105

examine the role of VRIN resources and capabilities in relation to IPO performance, valuation

and avoiding bankruptcy and provide some guidelines to managers for estimating new venture’s

potential for creating higher return on investment.

Our results confirm the importance of the technological differentiation strategy on the

short- and long-term performance, specifically IPO performance, valuation and avoiding

bankruptcy. The differentiation strategy of a new venture is shown to have a positive effect on

new venture performance at the time of IPO because differentiation strategy develops a niche

with the use of VRIN resources and capabilities, lowers the levels of competition in the factor

and target markets, thrives on the benefits of exploration and pioneering novel technologies, and

generates excitement in the market sending powerful signal to the potential investors. Such a

strategy also helps in the superior valuation of the new ventures because such ventures can

differentiate themselves in the long run on the basis of novel knowledge and technologies

derived from VRIN resources and capabilities, and valuation of high technology initiatives is

based on the future revenue generation potential of these novel technologies. We also find that

the use of differentiation strategy also result in greater survival by avoiding bankruptcy in the

long run.

Further, our findings suggest that in the presence of uncertainty, higher level of

differentiation strategy is more positively related with new venture performance at the time of

IPO, however, our prediction that such a strategy would be as effective with long term valuation

and avoidance of bankruptcy was not supported. It is plausible that uncertain environment

enhances short term performance by giving powerful and positive signal as well as resolving

information asymmetry but over a period of time, the value of signal subsides. Uncertainty is not

beneficial in the long run.

Page 118: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

106

Theoretical Contributions and Implications

Prior literature has discussed the value of technological capital from the lens of resource-

based view. However, the effects of novel technology based differentiation strategy on the short-

and long term performance, particularly in the presence of uncertainty have not been examined

in past research. Our research highlights the role of novel technology based differentiation

strategy on the new venture performance at the time of IPO, firm valuation and survival avoiding

bankruptcy.

We contribute to the strategic entrepreneurship literature by applying the concepts of

VRIN resources and capabilities in the context of new ventures and their performance at

different stages of their lifecycle. We also contribute to the new venture creation and

performance literature by finding that exploratory strategy such as differentiation plays an

important role in providing right signals to the investors and this in turn, results superior

performance in the short- and long-term. Exploration provides greater opportunities for

generating more recombinations that result in the development of novel technologies which, in

turn have the potential to deliver competitive advantage. We illustrate how a new venture can

choose to differentiate by focusing on novel knowledge and deliver superior returns as compared

to firm that just mimic.

We apply resource-and capabilities based theories of the firm to the context of new

venture performance. We demonstrate that new ventures’ choice in terms of differentiation

versus mimicry results in performance differential. While institutional theory argues that

legitimacy determines firm’s survival and overall performance in the market, our results provide

support for the RBV perspective in that initial uniqueness derived from differentiation is more

important, especially for new ventures who are preparing for IPO. Lastly, this research also have

Page 119: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

107

implications for the technology strategy of new ventures. A high level of technological

differentiation delivers superior performance at least in the short-term even under high uncertain

environment.

Limitations and Future Research

An important limitation of this study is our reliance on patent-based data to evaluate the

differentiation strategy—the limitations of patent-based data as indicators of technological

differentiation are well-documented (Alcacer & Gittelman, 2006; Benner & Waldfogel, 2008).

However, use of such data is appropriate and usually most accurate and comprehensive for

measuring novel technologies and technological resources (Ahuja, 2000; Miller et al., 2007).

Nevertheless, we would like to see future research use survey and interview methodologies to

capture differentiation strategy. Additionally, this paper mainly discusses technological

differentiation of a new venture, and investigates its implication for performance. Since our

fining provides support for capability perspective, scholars may find an interest in comparing

institutional theory and resource based view directly by investigating strategic factors that

supports legitimacy and uniqueness separately, and their implication for performance. Lastly,

longitudinal data could also be used to address questions regarding the role of differentiation and

performance through various stages of new ventures’ life cycle.

Page 120: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

108

REFERENCES

Ahuja, G. 2000. Collaboration networks, structural holes, and innovation: A longitudinal study. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45(3): 425-455.

Afuah, A. 2001. Dynamic boundaries of the firm: are firms better off being vertically integrated in the face of a technological change? Academy of Management Journal, 44(6): 1211-1228.

Aggarwal, R., & Rivoli, P. 1990. Fads in the initial public offering market? Financial Management, 19(4): 45-57.

Aghion, P., Harris, C., Howitt, P., & Vickers, J. 2001. Competition, imitation and growth with step-by-step innovation. Review of Economic Studies, 68(3): 467-492.

Ahuja, G., Lampert, C. M., & Tandon, V. 2008. Chapter 1: Moving beyond Schumpeter: Management research on the determinants of technological innovation. Academy of Management Annals, 2(1): 1-98.

Alcacer, J., & Gittelman, M. 2006. Patent citations as a measure of knowledge flows: The influence of examiner citations. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4): 774-779.

Altman, E. I. 1968. Financial ratios, discriminant analysis and the prediction of corporate bankruptcy. Journal of Finance, 23(4): 589-609.

Altman, E. I. 1993. Corporate financial distress and bankruptcy: a complete guide to predicting & avoiding distress and profiting from bankruptcy. New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons Inc.

Alvarez, S. A., & Barney, J. B. 2004. Organizing rent generation and appropriation: Toward a theory of the entrepreneurial firm. Journal of Business Venturing, 19(5): 621-635.

Alvarez, S. A., & Busenitz, L. W. 2001. The entrepreneurship of resource-based theory. Journal of Management, 27(6): 755.

Amit, R., & Schoemaker, P. J. H. 1993. Strategic assets and organizational rent. Strategic Management Journal, 14(1): 33-46.

Anderson, P., & Tushman, M. L. 1990. Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(4): 604-633.

Anderson, P., & Tushman, M. L. 2001. Organizational environments and industry exit: The effects of uncertainty, munificence and complexity. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(3): 675-711.

Page 121: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

109

Argyres, N. S., & Silverman, B. S. 2004. R&D, organization structure, and the development of corporate technological knowledge. Strategic Management Journal, 25(8/9): 929-958.

Arthurs, J. D., Busenitz, L. W., Hoskisson, R. E., & Johnson, R. A. 2009. Signaling and initial public offerings: the use and impact of the lockup period. Journal of Business Venturing, 24(4): 360-372.

Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1): 99-120.

Barney, J. B. 2001. Is the resource-based" view" a useful perspective for strategic management research? Yes. Academy of Management Review, 26(1): 41-56.

Barreto, I., & Baden-Fuller, C. 2006. To conform or to perform? Mimetic behaviour, legitimacy-based groups and performance consequences. Journal of Management Studies-Oxford, 43(7): 1559.

Baum, J. A. C., & Haveman, H. A. 1997. Love thy neighbor? Differentiation and agglomeration in the Manhattan hotel industry,1898-1990. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42(2): 304-338.

Benner, M. J., & Tushman, M. L. 2003. Exploitation, exploration, and process management: The productivity dilemma revisited. The Academy of Management Review, 28(2): 238-256.

Benner, M., & Waldfogel, J. 2008. Close to you? Bias and precision in patent-based measures of technological proximity. Research policy, 37(9): 1556-1567.

Bharadwaj, A. S., Bharadwaj, S. G., & Konsynski, B. R. 1999. Information technology effects on firm performance as measured by Tobin's q. Management Science, 45(7): 1008-1024.

Bhide, A. 2000. The origin and evolution of new businesses: Oxford University Press, USA.

Bradley, D. J., Jordan, B. D., Yi, H. C., & Roten, I. C. 2001. Venture capital and IPO lockup expiration: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Research, 24(4): 465-494.

Brau, J. C., & Fawcett, S. E. 2006. Initial public offerings: An analysis of theory and practice. Journal of Finance, 61(1): 399-436.

Brav, A., Geczy, C., & Gompers, P. A. 2000. Is the abnormal return following equity issuances anomalous? Journal of Financial Economics, 56(2): 209-250.

Burns, L. R., & Wholey, D. R. 1993. Adoption and abandonment of matrix management programs: Effects of organizational characteristics and interorganizational networks. Academy of Management Journal, 36(1): 106-138.

Page 122: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

110

Carpenter, R. E., & Petersen, B. C. 2002. Capital market imperfections, high-tech investment, and new equity financing. The Economic Journal, 112(477): 54-72.

Carroll, G. R., & Hannan, M. T. 1989. Density delay in the evolution of organizational populations: a model and five empirical tests. Administrative Science Quarterly, 34(3): 411-430.

Carter, R., & Manaster, S. 1990. Initial public offerings and underwriter reputation. Journal of Finance, 45(4): 1045-1067.

Carter, R. B., Dark, F. H., & Singh, A. K. 1998. Underwriter reputation, initial returns, and the long-run performance of IPO stocks. Journal of Finance, 53(1): 285-311.

Cefis, E., & Marsili, O. 2006. Survivor: The role of innovation in firms' survival. Research policy, 35(5): 626-641.

Certo, S. T., Daily, C. M., & Dalton, D. R. 2001. Signaling Firm Value through Board Structure: An Investigation of Initial Public Offerings. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 26(2): 33-51.

Certo, S. T., Holcomb, T. R., & Holmes Jr, R. M. 2009. IPO Research in Management and Entrepreneurship: Moving the Agenda Forward. Journal of Management, 35(6): 1340.

Chatterji, A. K. 2009. Spawned with a silver spoon? Entrepreneurial performance and innovation in the medical device industry. Strategic Management Journal, 30(2): 185-206.

Chen, W. R., & Miller, K. D. 2007. Situational and institutional determinants of firms R&D search intensity. Strategic Management Journal, 28(4): 369-381.

Chesbrough, H. W. 2002. Making sense of corporate venture capital. Harvard Business Review, 80(3): 90-99.

Chung, K. H., & Pruitt, S. W. 1994. A simple approximation of Tobin's q. Financial Management, 23(3): 70-74.

Cohen, B. D., & Dean, T. J. 2005. Information asymmetry and investor valuation of IPOs: Top management team legitimacy as a capital market signal. Strategic Management Journal, 26(7): 683-690.

Daily, C. M., Certo, S. T., Dalton, D. R., & Roengpitya, R. 2003. IPO Underpricing: A Meta-Analysis and Research Synthesis. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 27(3): 271-296.

Deeds, D. L., DeCarolis, D., & Coombs, J. 2000. Dynamic capabilities and new product development in high technology ventures:: An empirical analysis of new biotechnology firms. Journal of Business Venturing, 15(3): 211-229.

Page 123: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

111

Deeds, D. L., Mang, P. Y., & Frandsen, M. L. 2004. The influence of firms' and industries' legitimacy on the flow of capital into high-technology ventures. Strategic Organization, 2(1): 9-34.

Deephouse, D. L. 1999. To be different, or to be the same? It's a question (and theory) of strategic balance. Strategic Management Journal, 20(2): 147-166.

Dess, G. G., & Beard, D. W. 1984. Dimensions of organizational task environments. Administrative Science Quarterly, 29(1): 52-73.

DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American sociological review, 48(2): 147-160.

Donaldson, L. 1995. American anti-management theories of organization: A critique of paradigm proliferation: Cambridge University Press.

Downes, D. H., & Heinkel, R. 1982. Signaling and the valuation of unseasoned new issues. Journal of Finance, 37(1): 1-10.

Dushnitsky, G., & Lenox, M. J. 2006. When does corporate venture capital investment create firm value? Journal of Business Venturing, 21(6): 753-772.

Eisenhardt, K. M., & Martin, J. A. 2000. Dynamic capabilities: what are they? Strategic Management Journal, 21(10-11): 1105-1121.

Folta, T. B., & Miller, K. D. 2002. Real options in equity partnerships. Strategic Management Journal, 23(1): 77-88.

Galunic, D. C., & Eisenhardt, K. M. 2001. Architectural innovation and modular corporate forms. Academy of Management Journal, 44(6): 1229-1249.

Geroski, P. 1995. Markets for technology: knowledge, innovation and appropriability. Handbook of the economics of innovation and technological change: 90-131.

Gilbert, C. 2005. Unbundling the structure of inertia: Resource versus routine rigidity. Academy of Management Journal, 48(5): 741-763.

Gimeno, J., Hoskisson, R. E., Beal, B. D., & Wan, W. P. 2005. Explaining the clustering of international expansion moves: A critical test in the US telecommunications industry. Academy of Management Journal, 48(2): 297-319.

Greenwood, R., & Meyer, R. E. 2008. Influencing ideas: a celebration of DiMaggio and Powell (1983). Journal of Management Inquiry, 17(4): 258-264.

Page 124: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

112

Grinblatt, M., & Titman, S. 2002. Financial Policy and Corporate Strategy. New York, NY: Irwin McGraw Hill.

Gulati, R., & Higgins, M. C. 2002. Which ties matter when? The contingent effects of interorganizational partnerships on IPO success. Strategic Management Journal, 24(2): 127-144.

Hall, B. H., Jaffe, A. B., & Trajtenberg, M. 2001. The NBER patent citations data file: lessons, insights and methodological tools. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau Economic Research.

Hannan, M. T., & Freeman, J. 1989. Organization ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

Haunschild, P. R. 1993. Interorganizational Imitation: The Impact of Interlocks on Corporate Acquisition Activity. Administrative Science Quarterly, 38(4): 183-206.

Haunschild, P. R., & Miner, A. S. 1997. Modes of Interorganizational Imitation: The Effects of Outcome Salience and Uncertainty. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42(3): 472-500.

Henderson, R. M., & Clark, K. B. 1990. Architectural innovation: the reconfiguration of existing product technologies and the failure of established firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1): 9-30.

Heugens, P., & Lander, M. W. 2007. Testing the Strength of the Iron Cage: A Meta-Analysis of Neo-Institutional Theory: Rotterdam School of Management (RSM) Erasmus University Working paper.

Higgins, M. C., & Gulati, R. 2003. Getting off to a good start: The effects of upper echelon affiliations on underwriter prestige. Organization Science, 14(3): 244-263.

Higgins, M. C., & Gulati, R. 2005. Stacking the deck: The effects of top management backgrounds on investor decisions. Strategic Management Journal, 27(1): 1-25.

Hsu, D. H. 2006. Venture capitalists and cooperative start-up commercialization strategy. Management Science, 52(2): 204-219.

Jenkinson, T., & Ljungqvist, A. 2001. Going public: The theory and evidence on how companies raise equity finance. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

Katila, R., & Ahuja, G. 2002. Something old, something new: a longitudinal study of search behavior and new product introduction. Academy of Management Journal, 45(6): 1183-1194.

Keats, B. W., & Hitt, M. A. 1988. A causal model of linkages among environmental dimensions, macro organizational characteristics, and performance. Academy of Management Journal, 31(3): 570-598.

Page 125: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

113

Klepper, S. 1996. Entry, exit, growth, and innovation over the product life cycle. The American Economic Review, 86(3): 562-583.

Knott, A. M., & Posen, H. E. 2005. Is failure good? Strategic Management Journal, 26(7): 617-641.

Lee, K., & Pennings, J. M. 2002. Mimicry and the market: Adoption of a new organizational form. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 144-162.

Leonard-Barton, D. 1992. Core capabilities and core rigidities: A paradox in managing new product development. Strategic Management Journal: 111-125.

Levinthal, D. A. 1991. Random Walks and Organizational Mortality. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(3): 397-420.

Lieberman, M. B., & Asaba, S. 2006. Why do firms imitate each other? Academy of management review, 31(2): 366-385.

Liebeskind, J. P. 1996. Knowledge, strategy, and the theory of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 17: 93-107.

Loughran, T., & Ritter, J. 2004. Why has IPO underpricing changed over time? Financial Management, 33(3): 5-37.

Loughran, T., & Ritter, J. R. 1995. The new issues puzzle. Journal of Finance, 50(1): 23-51.

Loughran, T., Ritter, J. R., & Rydqvist, K. 1994. Initial public offerings: International insights* 1. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 2(2-3): 165-199.

Mahoney, J. T., & Pandian, J. R. 1992. The resource-based view within the conversation of strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 13(5): 363-380.

Matraves, C. 1999. Market structure, R&D and advertising in the pharmaceutical industry. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 47(2): 169-194.

Matusik, S. F., & Hill, C. W. L. 1998. The utilization of contingent work, knowledge creation, and competitive advantage. Academy of management review, 23(4): 680-697.

Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83(2): 340-363.

Meyer, J. W., Scott, W. R., Strang, D., & Creighton, A. L. 1988. Bureaucratization without centralization: Changes in the organizational system of US public education, 1940-80. In L. G. Zucker (Ed.), Institutional patterns and organizations: Culture and environment: 139-168. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

Page 126: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

114

Miller, D. J. 2006. Technological diversity, related diversification, and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 27(7): 601-619.

Miller, D. J., Fern, M. J., & Cardinal, L. B. 2007. The use of knowledge for technological innovation within diversified firms. Academy of Management Journal, 50(2): 308-326.

Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.

Nelson, T. 2003. The persistence of founder influence: Management, ownership, and performance effects at initial public offering. Strategic Management Journal, 24(8): 707-724.

Nolan, R. 1994. Note on estimating the value of the IT asset. Harvard Business School Note #9-195-197. Cambridge, MA.

Pagano, M., Panetta, F., & Zingales, L. 1998. Why do companies go public? An empirical analysis. Journal of Finance, 53(1): 27-64.

Penrose, E. T. 1959. The theory of the growth of the firm. New York, NY: Wiley.

Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. R. 2003. The external control of organizations: A resource dependence perspective. New York, NY: Stanford Business Books.

Phillips, D. J. 2002. A Genealogical Approach to Organizational Life Chances: The Parent-Progeny Transfer among Silicon Valley Law Firms, 1946-1996. Administrative Science Quarterly, 47(3): 474-508.

Pollock, T. G., & Rindova, V. P. 2003. Media legitimation effects in the market for initial public offerings. Academy of Management Journal, 46(5): 631-642.

Porter, M. E. 1991. Towards a dynamic theory of strategy. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 95-117.

Porter, M. E. 1998. Competitive strategy. New York, NY: Free press

Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, P. J. 1991. The new institutionalism in organizational analysis. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press

Prahalad, C. K., & Hamel, G. 1990. The core competence of the organization. Harvard Business Review, 68(3): 79-91.

Riley, J. G. 1975. Competitive signalling. Journal of Economic Theory, 10(2): 174-186.

Ritter, J. R. 1991. The long-run performance of initial public offerings. Journal of Finance, 46(1): 3-27.

Page 127: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

115

Rodriguez-Duarte, A., Sandulli, F. D., Minguela-Rata, B., & Lopez-Sanchez, J. I. 2007. The endogenous relationship between innovation and diversification, and the impact of technological resources on the form of diversification. Research policy, 36(5): 652-664.

Rosenkopf, L., & Nerkar, A. 2001. Beyond local search: Boundary-spanning, exploration, and impact in the optical disk industry. Strategic Management Journal, 22(4): 287-306.

Rothaermel, F. T., & Boeker, W. 2008. Old technology meets new technology: complementarities, similarities, and alliance formation. Strategic Management Journal, 29(1): 47-77.

Ruef, M., Aldrich, H. E., & Carter, N. M. 2003. The structure of founding teams: Homophily, strong ties, and isolation among US entrepreneurs. American sociological review, 68(2): 195-222.

Rumelt, R. P., Schendel, D. E., & Teece, D. J. 1994. Fundamental issues in strategy: A research agenda. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

Schumpeter, J. A. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Hamper & Row.

Scott, W. R. 2008. Institutions and organizations: Ideas and interests: Sage Publications, Inc.

Spence, M. 1973. Job market signaling. The quarterly journal of Economics, 87(3): 355-374.

Spence, M. 1974a. Competitive and optimal responses to signals: An analysis of efficiency and distribution. Journal of Economic Theory, 7(3): 296-332.

Spence, M. 1974b. Market signaling: Harvard Univ. Press.

Steensma, H. K., & Corley, K. G. 2001. Organizational context as a moderator of theories on firm boundaries for technology sourcing. Academy of Management Journal, 44(2): 271-291.

Stuart, T. E., Hoang, H., & Hybels, R. C. 1999. Interorganizational endorsements and the performance of entrepreneurial ventures. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44(2): 315-349.

Sutton, D., & Benedetto, M. W. 1988. Initial public offerings: A strategic planner for raising equity capital. Chicago, Il: Probus Publication Co.

Tushman, M., & O'Reilly, C. A. 2002. Winning through innovation: A practical guide to leading organizational change and renewal. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

Van de Ven, A. H., & Hargrave, T. J. 2004. Social, technical, and institutional change: A literature review and synthesis. In M. S. Poole, & A. H. Van de Ven (Eds.), Handbook of Organizational Change and Innovation: 259-303. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

Page 128: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

116

Vesper, K. H. 1990. New venture strategies. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2): 171-180.

Zucker, L. G. 1988. Institutional patterns and organizations: Culture and environment. New York, NY: Ballinger Publication Co.

Page 129: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

117

CHAPTER FIVE

DISSERTATION SUMMARY AND GENERAL CONCLUSION

This dissertation investigated the issue of innovation and entrepreneurship with three

different concepts: diversification, boundary expansion, and differentiation. The first essay looks

into the conditions under which the diversified firm improves their innovation output. By

integrating the insights of organizational search and contingencies literature, we argues that there

is a strategic fit among diversification, search scope, and technological capital, and the fit leads

to higher innovation productivity. With the longitudinal data analysis, it is found that related

diversification strategy increase innovation productivity when the firm pursues local search,

while the unrelated diversification strategy increase innovation output when the firm pursues

distant search. Also, the empirical results provide support for that argument that the

technological capital is important factors to take advantage of opportunities from broader

corporate scope. Our findings mainly contribute to the diversification literature in that the effect

of diversification on innovation is not simple.

The second essay investigates organizational boundary expansion activities in the early

stage. We focus on young firm’s preference between internal market and external market to

search and renew their competencies. The main argument is that young firms’ boundary choice is

influenced by both their resource portfolio and external factors, which are the characteristics of

environment and industry. The analysis of U.S. sample provides evidence of our argument.

Theoretically, it implies not only that the nature of potential value of resources should be

Page 130: NPDF jajsjjsdsdksdksdnsdk

118

understood differently in the life cycle, but also that capability perspective derived from resource

based view is useful to explain young firms’ boundary expansion.

Finally, the third essay explores the performance implication of differentiation strategy.

Using signaling theory, we address how the patterns of differentiation in the pre-IPO influence

the new venture’s short-term and long-term performance in the post IPO stage. It is found that

the external investors perceive that new firms with differentiation strategy will better compete

with others in the industry, especially under uncertain environment. Thus, this finding support

for our argument that differentiation is more beneficial than similarity to the new venture who is

preparing for IPO.

In sum, three essays contribute to the literature in the strategic management field by

showing that a particular strategy and resource have different implications for performance,

boundary expansion, and innovation. Additionally, we suggest scholars to use contingency

approach in that the organizational and environmental contingencies may provide better lens to

understand the behavior of the firms.