Top Banner

of 33

Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

Apr 07, 2018

Download

Documents

Zen Low
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    1/33

    Simon Cowan

    Department of Economics and WorcesterCollege

    Thursday 27th May, 2010

    MFE Course on Industrial Organization

    Price Discrimination

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    2/33

    outline What is price discrimination, when is it feasible,

    why do firms do it?

    What types of price discrimination are there?

    What are the welfare effects?

    Price discrimination and oligopoly

    2

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    3/33

    What is price discrimination? Simple definition: discrimination means selling the

    same good at different prices

    Microsoft sets different prices for the Office suite

    Airlines charge different amounts for similar tickets

    More generally price discrimination is present

    when two or more similar goods are sold at pricesthat are in different ratios to marginal costs

    (Varian, 1989, p 598)

    So a uniform delivered price, e.g. for letters, isdiscriminatory if costs differ

    If price differences reflect cost differences thenthere is no discrimination

    3

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    4/33

    When is discrimination feasible? No arbitrage (i.e. no resale)

    Especially for services

    Firm has market power

    Can raise price above marginal cost

    Market power need not be complete

    Ability to sort or classify customers

    4

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    5/33

    Why do firms discriminate?

    The firm aims to convert consumer surplus into profit

    full conversion requires

    1. complete knowledgeof customers

    2. sufficient pricing instruments3. no competition

    Often the firm is better off with the ability to

    discriminate

    But discrimination does not always raise profits:

    1. Oligopolistic discrimination

    2. Durable-goods monopoly5

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    6/33

    Types of discrimination Pigous 1920 three-fold classification, applied here tomonopoly

    First-degree: complete information, take-it-or-leave-it offersby the firm, no competition

    Second-degree: customer self-selection Partial information, full set of pricing instruments, no

    competition Menus of tariffs; Nonlinear tariffs Airline customers can choose when to travel and whether

    to stay a Saturday night or not, phone customers can

    choose their tariffs

    Third-degree: exogenous signal that the firm uses toclassify customers Partial information, linear pricing, no competition

    Educational discounts for software Consultants paying more for conferences thanacademics

    6

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    7/33

    Simple monopoly pricing

    Price

    Quantity

    MarginalCost

    Monopolyprice

    Monopoly volume

    Demand

    MR

    7

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    8/33

    Monopoly pricing and the priceelasticity

    The monopoly mark-up, at the profit-maximizingprice, is

    Percentage change in quantity demandedPrice Elasticity of Demand =

    Percentage change in price

    Price Marginal Cost 1

    Price Price Elasticity

    8

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    9/33

    Can the firm do better? Customers with valuations above the monopoly

    price obtain a surplus

    If they could be identified then they could becharged more (as long as there is no resale)

    Customers who value the good below the priceset by the monopolist dont buy at all

    Can they be persuaded to buy, without at the sametime cutting the price(s) that existing customers

    pay?

    9

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    10/33

    The lost surpluses

    Price

    Quantity

    MarginalCost

    Monopoly volume

    Surplus of consumers who buy at the monopoly price

    Surplus lost because these customers dontbuy at all this is the loss to society from

    monopoly: the deadweight loss

    Monopoly

    profit

    Monopolyprice

    10

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    11/33

    First-degree price discrimination The firm knows the maximum amount that each

    customer is willing to pay, and charges each customerthis amount

    Marginal revenue now becomes the (inverse) demand

    function (no need to drop the price on other units) De Beers sales of rough diamonds:

    Diamonds sorted into 12,000 categories based on size,shape, quality, colour. Offered on a take-it-or-never buy

    from us again basis. With linear demand profits double: the firm grabs both

    the triangles as well as the rectangle

    Social welfare is maximized, but it all goes to the firm

    Requires too much information to be feasible in most11

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    12/33

    Third-degree price discrimination The firm sorts customers into separate markets using anexogenous signal

    E.g. students, seniors, families, income bracket, business v.domestic

    Instruments: linear pricing in each separate market

    So standard monopoly pricing in each market

    Price is higher in less elastic markets (remember the elasticity ingeneral is endogenous) Microsoft Office

    UK price of Office Standard was 329 in 2008 USA price was $399.95 (=200.98 at the exchange rate of $1.99: 1)

    The American Economic Association charges according to

    income for membership Annual income < $50,000: $64 $50,000 Annual Income $66,000: $77 $66,000 < Annual income: $90 Student member (written verification required): $32

    12

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    13/33

    discrimination good for socialwelfare? In general the effect is ambiguous

    The firm gains from extra flexibility

    Customers offered higher prices lose

    Customers offered lower prices gain

    Discrimination may open a new market

    anti-retroviral drugs are now available in Africa at

    prices much lower than in North America andEurope

    this gives a weak Pareto improvement if (but notonly if) only one market was served withoutdiscrimination, and marginal cost is not increasingin output13

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    14/33

    Price discrimination opens a newmarket

    Price

    Quantity

    MarginalCost

    Price inMarket 1

    Monopoly volume

    Market 2

    If required to sell at the same pricein both markets, the firm will just setthe best price for Market 1 and notbother to sell in Market 2Demand in 1

    Aggregatedemand

    14

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    15/33

    What about when new marketsare not opened?

    Schmalensee (AER, 1981): a necessarycondition fordiscrimination to raise welfare is that total output rises

    Misallocation effect: Inefficient distribution of the givenoutput across markets with discrimination

    Output effect: An output increase is good for welfarewhen prices exceed marginal cost

    15

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    16/33

    output is constant, so welfarefalls Suppose q1 = 1p1 and q2 = 2p2; c= 0 Discriminatory prices and quantities:

    Profit in 1, p1(1p1), is maximized with p1 = 0.5, q1 = 0.5

    Profit in 2, p2(2p2), is maximized with p2 = 1, q2 = 1

    With non-discriminatory pricing, the profit function isp(1p+ 2p) = p(3 2p) for p 1 and

    p(2p) for p> 1

    Best non-discriminatory price is p= 0.75 and

    q1 + q2 = 3 20.75 = 1.5 Total output is the same with and without

    discrimination when demand functions are linear

    16

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    17/33

    A generalization Define the curvature(or convexity) of demand as pq(p)/q(p) The non-discriminatory price is pN Call the low-price market L and the high-price market H For a very large set of demand functions a sufficient

    conditionfor social welfare to fall with discrimination isH(pN) L(pN)

    The linear example is a special case So a necessary conditionfor discrimination to raise welfare

    is thatL(pN) > H(pN)

    Aguirre, Cowan and Vickers (AER, forthcoming) giveadditional conditions

    17

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    18/33

    Second-degree: two-part tariffs Conventional pricing is known as linear pricing

    Price per unit = p, total payment for qunits = pq

    The total payment is proportionalto the quantity

    Tariffs need not be linear

    A two-part tariffis the simplest form of nonlinearpricing

    Total payment = fixed fee + price

    quantity; T(q) =A + pq

    E.g. utility tariffs, gym membership, warehouseclubs, railcards to obtain discounts, mobile phone

    tariffs

    18

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    19/33

    Individual two-part tariffs Suppose (i) the firm knows each customers

    demand function (and therefore their consumersurplus) and (ii) it can use individual two-parttariffs {Ai, pi}

    The profit-maximizing strategy is to set the samemarginal price, equal to marginal cost, for all i: pi= c

    The lump-sum fees are individual, Ai

    , and are setto extract each consumers surplus

    Equivalently the firm sets total payment-quantitybundles: {Ti, qi}={Ai+ cqi(c), qi(c)}

    This is first-degree discrimination again19

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    20/33

    its total payment-quantitypackage

    Price

    Quantity

    pi=c

    Ai

    20 qi(c)

    cqi(c)

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    21/33

    second-degree: nonlinear pricing Now assume the firm cannot identify each

    customers type

    Large customers are willing to pay more thansmall customers, and want to buy more

    First-degree discrimination is not incentive-compatible

    The firm offers alternative packages that specify

    the quantity and total payment. Customers canchoose.

    The key is to extract as much profit as possiblefrom the large customers, while still selling to the

    small customers21

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    22/33

    First-degree discrimination is notincentive-compatible

    Price

    Quantity22

    c

    B

    D

    E

    With first-degree discrimination the largecustomer pays B + D + Efor qH while the smallcustomer pays Bfor qL.When given a choice the large customerwill pay Bfor qL, giving a surplus of D.Profit = 2B.

    More profitable: offer a choice between:{B, qL} and {B + E, qH}Profit = 2B+ E

    qL qH

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    23/33

    Dupuit and incentive compatibility

    On railway tariffs and classes (1849)It is not because of the few thousand francs which

    would have to be spent to put a roof over the third-class carriages or to upholster the third-class seatsthat some company or other has open carriages withwooden benches...What the company is trying to do isprevent the passengers who pay the second-classfare from travelling third-class; it hits the poor, notbecause it wants to hurt them, but to frighten the

    rich...And it is again for the same reason that thecompanies, having proved almost cruel to third-classpassengers and mean to second-class ones,becomes lavish in dealing with first-class passengers.Having refused the poor what is necessary, they give

    the rich what is superfluous.Source: Tirole 15023

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    24/33

    Nonlinear pricing: distorting thequantity to capture more surplus

    Price

    Quantity24

    c

    B

    D

    E

    qL

    qHq*

    Now the firm offers q*at B x, andqHat B + E + y .Profits rise by y x.

    Optimal q* balances marginal yagainstmarginal x.The large customer consumes the efficientquantity, but the quantity for the smallcustomer is distorted below qL.

    y

    x

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    25/33

    Optional two-part tariffs: a simpleform of nonlinear pricing

    total payment

    volume of calls

    tariff designed for households

    tariff designed for businesscustomers

    Household chooses here

    Business customer chooses here

    25

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    26/33

    Damaging goods Another way to encourage customers to self-

    select is to damage ones good, in order artificially

    to provide a range of qualities

    The Intel 486 chip came in two versions

    The main version had the math-coprocessorworking

    The secondary version had the math-coprocessorswitched off

    IBM sold a printer which came in two versions

    The main version worked at 12 pages per minute

    The other version included an instruction to slowdown the rate of printing, so that it printed 8 pages

    per minute26

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    27/33

    Oligopoly: no discrimination Hotelling model, consumers uniformly distributed

    along [0, 1]

    Firm A located at 0, price pA; firm B at 1, pB Consumer at xpays pA+ txwhen buying from A,pB+

    t(1x) from B. t =unit transport cost When pA+ tx = pB+ t(1x) the consumer at xis

    indifferent:

    qA = x = + (pB pA)/2t

    qB

    = 1x = + (pA

    pB

    )/2t

    A = (pAc)[ + (pB pA)/2t]

    B= (pBc)[ + (pA pB)/2t]

    Bertrand-Nash equilibrium in prices: pA = pB= c +t

    Profit per firm is t/227

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    28/33

    Oligopoly Discrimination I Now both firms know the location of each consumer,

    i.e. x, and can offer individual prices

    Consider a consumer located near A with x<

    Given the price that Boffers, pB(x), A could offer a

    price that gives just as good a deal defined bypA(x) + tx= pB(x) + t(1 x)

    So pA(x) = pB(x) + t(1 2x) > pB(x)

    The firms compete for this customer until the less-favoured firm, B, just makes zero profit, i.e. p

    B

    (x) = c

    At this point A can win by pricing a penny lower thanthe price implied by the equally good deal equation: tofind this set pB(x) = cin the equation, giving pA(x) = c+ t(12x)

    28

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    29/33

    Oligopoly Discrimination II

    The discriminatory price schedules are:pA(x) = c + t(1 2x) for x 0.5

    pA(x) = c for x> 0.5

    pB(x) = c for x< 0.5pB(x) = c + t(2x 1) for x 0.5

    Apart from the consumers at 0 and 1, every

    consumer pays less when there is pricediscrimination

    Profits per firm drop from t/2 to t/4 withdiscrimination

    29

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    30/33

    Prices and profits

    0 1

    c+ t c+ t

    0.5c

    30

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    31/33

    Oligopoly discrimination III The model has assumed best-response

    asymmetry, so the firms do not share the same

    view about which market will have the higherprice once discrimination is allowed

    I want to price high in my back-yard, while youwant to price low in my back-yard

    Alternatively there may be best-responsesymmetry: e.g. when the demand functions foreach firm in a large market are both higher thanthose in a small market

    In this case price rises in the large market andfalls in the small market

    31

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    32/33

    Summary Price discrimination is very common, and takes

    many forms

    The main aim of the discrimination analyzed hereis to extract more surplus from consumers

    This usually has ambiguous welfare effects

    Discrimination is of antitrust concern, particularlyin intermediate goods markets, when it is a sign

    of something else: excessive market power

    predatory pricing

    market foreclosure and exclusion

    32

  • 8/4/2019 Lecture 5 - Price Discrimination

    33/33

    Reading, with annotations

    J. Tirole, Theory of Industrial Organization, 1988, Ch 3

    excellent textbooksurvey

    H. Varian, Ch 10 in Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol 1, edited by R.Schmalensee and R. Willig, 1989 the main survey of monopolisticdiscrimination

    M. Motta, Competition Policy, CUP, 2004, Ch 7.4 (discrimination) emphasis oncompetition policy implications

    L. Stole, Ch 34 in Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol 3, edited by M.Armstrong and R. Porter, 2007, especially Section 3.4, available athttp://econpapers.repec.org/bookchap/eeeindchp/3-34.htm verycomprehensive on discrimination and competition.

    Iaki Aguirre, Simon Cowan and John Vickers, "Monopoly Price Discriminationand Demand Curvature", American Economic Review, forthcoming, available atthe AER website and athttp://www.economics.ox.ac.uk/members/simon.cowan/PapersandFiles/WelfareEffects10Sep.pdf new results on the welfare effects of third-degreediscrimination

    33

    http://econpapers.repec.org/bookchap/eeeindchp/3-34.htmhttp://www.economics.ox.ac.uk/members/simon.cowan/PapersandFiles/WelfareEffects10Sep.pdfhttp://www.economics.ox.ac.uk/members/simon.cowan/PapersandFiles/WelfareEffects10Sep.pdfhttp://www.economics.ox.ac.uk/members/simon.cowan/PapersandFiles/WelfareEffects10Sep.pdfhttp://www.economics.ox.ac.uk/members/simon.cowan/PapersandFiles/WelfareEffects10Sep.pdfhttp://econpapers.repec.org/bookchap/eeeindchp/3-34.htmhttp://econpapers.repec.org/bookchap/eeeindchp/3-34.htmhttp://econpapers.repec.org/bookchap/eeeindchp/3-34.htm