Top Banner
Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed Law and Globalization - Interdisciplinary Seminar 28.07.2006 Laura E Catton Abstract: This paper is focused on the driving and limiting factors of the movement of workers from labour rich developing countries to developed countries facing limited labour supply, and the possible solutions countries should adopt to foster more liberalized and valuable labour migration. The first section this paper concentrates on the social and economical benefits of labour migration including the positive effect of remittances to developing countries, the possibility of real wage increases within the developing country’s economy, and the ability for developed countries to meet their labour shortage demands. The problems associated with labour migration, including the brain drain, xenophobia, discrimination and cultural barriers, the intrusion on domestic labour, and the possibility of economic inefficiencies and lack of innovation, are discussed in second section of this paper. Solutions both developing and developed countries can adopt to help solve these problems are raised and discussed in third section of the paper. Finally, a concise introduction into GATS Mode 4 - the movement
32

Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Jan 13, 2015

Download

Documents

lcatton

Prepared for University St. Gallen - Law & Globalization - Interdisciplinary Seminar
Presented to: Dr. Simon Evenett (St. Gallen) & Dr. Andreas Ziegler (Lausanne)

* Detailed the driving and limiting factors affecting the movement of workers from labour rich developing countries to developed countries facing labour shortages (including an analysis on GATS Mode IV). Discussed possible solutions countries could deploy to foster more liberalized and valuable labour migration
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Law and Globalization - Interdisciplinary Seminar28.07.2006

Laura E Catton

Abstract:

This paper is focused on the driving and limiting factors of the movement of workers from labour rich developing countries to developed countries facing limited labour supply, and the possible solutions countries should adopt to foster more liberalized and valuable labour migration.

The first section this paper concentrates on the social and economical benefits of labour migration including the positive effect of remittances to developing countries, the possibility of real wage increases within the developing country’s economy, and the ability for developed countries to meet their labour shortage demands.

The problems associated with labour migration, including the brain drain, xenophobia, discrimination and cultural barriers, the intrusion on domestic labour, and the possibility of economic inefficiencies and lack of innovation, are discussed in second section of this paper.

Solutions both developing and developed countries can adopt to help solve these problems are raised and discussed in third section of the paper.

Finally, a concise introduction into GATS Mode 4 - the movement of natural persons - is presented. The final section of the paper raises the question of the usefulness of Mode 4 as it currently stands today and criticizes the vague yet restrictive nature of the text.

Page 2: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

The rise of globalization has put increasing prominence on the liberalization of services, including the liberalization of the movement of labour. It is evident that economics drives labour migration; wage differentials and labour surpluses are the most common reasons for the movement of labour abroad. These driving factors, coupled with the increasing ease of relocation with lower transportation costs, have caused an increase in labour migration over the past couple decades. According to the World Bank (2004), “globalization is driving the movement of people across borders… falling costs of transportation and communication have reduced the distance between peoples, and the drive for better lives has motivated workers to move to areas where jobs are more plentiful and pay is better”.

I. Driving forces of Migration of Labour: There is a strong push from developing countries to further liberalize the labour market for many beneficial economics reasons. Firstly, developing countries gain from higher wages abroad, which, in returns, results in the influx of money into the country’s economy from foreign workers’ remittances. The World Bank (2004) estimates that in 2001, “workers remittances alone provided some $70 billion to developing countries, nearly 40 percent more than all development assistance and significantly more than net debt flows to developing countries” and “(these) remittances represent a large proportion of the GDP and constitute a major contribution to the stability of foreign exchange”1.

Secondly, workers within developing countries also benefit from the migration of local workers as (1) the outflow of labour causes the supply of labour to decrease which, in turn, (2) causes an increase in real wages (figure 1). The labour supply decreases from the original supply (S1) to a lower supply (S2) as workers seek employment abroad. This decrease in labour supply, denoted as ∆SL, results in an increase in real wages within the country by ∆RW.

1 Labour Migration. Workshop for Policy Makers: 86th Session, 18 Nov. 2003, International Organization for Migration. <http://www.iom.int/DOCUMENTS/GOVERNING/EN/LabourWorkshops_Report.pdf>.

Page 3: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Figure 1

Assuming those in developing countries are rational actors, neoclassical economics tells us that workers from developing countries will seek employment abroad when their benefits of doing so outweigh their costs. Corresponding with the aforementioned, workers from developing countries will seek employment abroad when the benefit of the gain from the large wage differential and increased living standard outweighs the monetary and social costs of relocation. It is therefore evident that the decrease in the costs of migration will result in an increase in migration rates as one’s cost-benefit offers a higher positive net return from migration.

Furthermore, developed countries also benefit from migration of labour. Developed countries are currently faced with aging demographics and are experiencing shortages of young workers to fill these vacancies. The United Nations reports that in 10 years from now developed nations will be faced with only 87 young entrants into to the labour force for every 100 retirees while developing countries emit, “342 new labour market entrants for every 100 first world retirees”2. It is believed that, “affluent countries must import vast numbers of immigrants to maintain the age ratio between tax-paying workers and retirees to prevent the collapse of social security systems”3 (although this notion is later challenged). It is evident, however, that developed countries must embrace labour migration from developing countries to overcome their labour shortcomings.

Moreover, through hiring foreign workers, the developed countries have the reverse effect on their real wage rates as found in developing countries. With the influx foreign workers, there is a shift of the supply from S2 to S1 (change of ∆SL) causing a market reaction of decreased real wages of ∆RW from RW2 to RW1 (Figure 1). This decrease in real wages allows companies in developed

2 Lund, Michael. "A Labour Shortage Can Be a Blessing." Financial Times 8 June 2006. <www.ft.com>.3 Lund, Michael. "A Labour Shortage Can Be a Blessing." Financial Times 8 June 2006. <www.ft.com>.

SL2 SL1

RW2

RW1

∆SL

∆RW

SL2

DLS1

S2

Supply of Labour (Quantity)

Real Wages

Page 4: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

countries to achieve positive economies of scale; companies within the developed countries markets are able to produce more units of goods and services for lower input costs (lower labour costs). Later in the paper, however, I will challenge and refute the notion that the decreases in real wages are positive to the developed country’s economy by asserting that decreasing real wages will result in inefficient economies.

II. Driving Forces against Labour Migration: Labour migration is not a clear cut answer, however, for solving labour shortage in developed countries and labour surplus in developing countries as labour migration comes with its own set of economical and societal consequences and costs.

The Brain DrainFor the migration of skilled labour, the most prominent concern of the exporting country is the likelihood of a ‘brain drain’ occurring. The coined term ‘brain drain migration’ became popularized in the 1960’s when developing countries lost considerable invested resources by means of losing skilled labour to developed or more appealing countries4. The receiving country reaps the economic benefits of these skilled workers while the sending country “loses productive capacity due to the absence of higher skilled workers and students”5. In the case of developing countries, the emigration of skilled labour can impede the countries’ ability to industrialize.

Xenophobia, Discrimination, and other Cultural barriersSocial factors that hinder the migration of labour include family separation, xenophobia, discrimination and cultural/language barriers. With the movement of labour to countries which don’t allow for family reunification, the sending country is faced with the social costs of disunited families. Likewise, foreign workers are faced with instances of xenophobia - the contemptuousness of natives towards foreigners.

This contempt in conjunction with language and cultural barriers encumber workers to seek employment abroad and can result in prejudicial hiring of non-immigrants or poor treatment of migrant workers. In a study titled ‘Combating Discrimination against (Im)migrant and Ethnic Minority Workers in the World of Work’ launched in 1991 by the ILO, results showed that in countries such as Belgium, German, the Netherlands, and Spain one in three job applications put forth by a minority of foreign origins was rejected on the basis of racial prejudices. Outside of the work environment, foreigners are faced with further segregation and xenophobia:

…systemic discrimination may be manifested by differential access to housing --such as relegating minorities to ghettos, or distant suburbs; by provision of inferior education through

4 Cohin, Robin. Brain Drain Migration. University of Warwick. Official South African Commission on International Migration, 1997.5 International Mobility of the Highly Skilled. Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development. Paris: OECD Publications, 2001. 1-336. <http://www1.oecd.org/publications/e-book/9202011E.PDF>.

Page 5: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

under-funding and understaffing schools in minority neighborhoods, areas or regions; provision of inferior health facilities; by lack of public transportation between minority/target group living areas and places of available employment; and so on.6

Amongst local employees in jobs that can be easily filled by migrant workers (most commonly labour intensive occupations), there is the fear that importation of labour will undermine local job security and, hence, leads to contempt towards foreign workers. This contempt can also been seen by those in careers not easily overtaken by foreigners such as doctors and lawyers who require quite often country specific training and qualification. The contempt from these workers rises from the fear that foreigners are a drain on the nation’s social services; for the receiving country, language and cultural differences also pose high social and economic costs. A study within Switzerland found that these diversities,

…manifest themselves in high social and economic costs of integrating a foreign population with diverse cultural backgrounds and languages. The costs of integration are particularly large in the case of less-skilled foreign workers from less-developed countries, who not only put a strain on the Swiss educational system but also instill a feeling of alienation among some Swiss.7

Xenophobia towards foreigners is also on the rise from the increasing portrayal of foreigners in terrorist attacks. This xenophobia coupled with government fears of allowing the movement of possibly dangerous individuals into one’s country has lead to an increased tightening of labour migration policies in developed countries. According to Rubén Silié, however, this is unjustifiable:

To want to justify the campaign against immigration as a resource in the fight against terrorism makes absolutely no sense whatsoever, since the onset of terrorism is not the product of migration. Terrorism is a state of war whose motivations differ entirely from those of the workers who leave their countries in search of better opportunities for life and employment. If some causality could be established between terrorism and migration, we would find more terrorists among the Hispanic community than in the Muslim community, whose numbers are far lower than the former.

In this light the ‘fight on terrorism’ can be seen as a poor excuse for hindering the ability for migrant workers to find work in developed countries. Countries must adopt background checks similar to those being performed for permanent migrants to ensure that those coming for non-beneficial reasons are rejected.

6 Taran, Patrick, and Eduardo Geronimi. Protection is Paramount. Conferencia HemisféRica Sobre MigracióN Internacional: Derechos Humanos Y Trata De Personas En Las AméRicas, 20 Nov. 2002, International Labor Office (Geneva). <http://www.cepal.org/celade/noticias/paginas/2/11302/PTaran.pdf.>.7 Cattacin, Sandro, ed. Debate: Immigration Policy. Swiss Political Science Review 7. 2001. 95-118. <www.sscnet.ucla.edu/soc/faculty/wimmer/Konturen.pdf>.

Page 6: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

To sum up, for migrant workers factors of xenophobia from natives might hinder their decision to take advantageous work offers abroad while the increased social service costs along with pressures from national trade unions coupled with negative public opinion associated with the influx of foreign workers makes democratically elected governments hesitant to liberalize their borders to labour migration.

Intrusion on Domestic LabourThe decrease of labour costs caused by the increase of labour supply in developed countries can furthermore also be associated with negative economic outcomes. According to the International Organization of Migration, “protection of the domestic labour force is one of the principle challenges of the receiving countries and is among the main reasons for restrictive immigration policies”. Unemployment or decreased real wages of native workers can be a causal effect of over importation of labour. Simple Keynesian macroeconomics tells us that consumption depends on income. When incomes decrease, consumption will decrease. As consumption decreases, demand for consumer goods decreases. When demand for consumer goods decreases, the need for labour likewise decreases causing real wages to further plummet. Ultimately, if this process continues, a recession is born out of the multiplier effect (Figure 2).Figure 2

Wages, which were previously being re-invested into the economy, are being eradicated out of the economy by means of remittance. Further intolerance for foreigners could also arise within the nation as fears rise that foreigners will replace native workers in the labour force.

This need for the protection of domestic labour can be exclusive, however, to particular types of labour migration. Conventionally, North – North migration is more commonly accepted by those in developed nations. Firstly, “In North-North migration, the sending country or region is relatively developed so the question of the migration being detrimental to the sending region tends not to arise”8 while those involved in North-North migration are seen have similar

8 Ellerman, David. "Policy Research on Migration and Development." World Bank Policy

Decrease in consumption of

consumer products

Decrease in demand for consumer products

Decrease in demand for labour

Decrease in real wages and/or

unemployment of native workers

Page 7: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

lifestyles and religious backgrounds which makes them easier to integrate into receiving countries’ culture. In South-South migration, referring to the flow of migrant workers between or within relatively underdeveloped regions or countries, even if the migration occurs in the geographical north, is usually associated with the movement of low or unskilled skilled workers out of inhabitable lands or the movement of workers from the rural to urban regions. In some cases the influx of migrant workers from one developing country to another leads to the strain on the receiving country’s already limited resources. This, amongst other factors, leads to the reluctance for developing countries to allow for migration of foreign low-skilled workers, who bare no applicable skills for the development of the receiving country, into their nation. This fear of workers being a drain on a country’s resources likewise arises from South-North migration which refers to the flow of migrant workers from developing to developed nations (this also includes the movement of workers from developing Eastern Europe to developed Western Europe). South-North migration also sees prominent xenophobia as those from developed nations feel as if those from developing nations won’t be able to integrate into their society easily causing a drain on social services. It can be seen that xenophobia towards foreign workers is based on one’s opinion of whether they feel the foreign workers are able to easily adapt to the receiving country’s culture and society. Similarly, the degree of xenophobia is proportional to the sense of whether the foreign workers are beneficial or a drain on the receiving country’s economy. Unfortunately, this xenophobia stems off stereotypes which makes citizens feel as if North-North migration is always good while South-North migration is always bad (which can be easily refuted).

The mercantilist ideology of ‘zero-sum’9, correspondingly, is often adopted by those against the migration of foreigner workers; those who follow this ideology believe that the gain by the foreign workers results in a loss by national workers.

The Development of Inefficient EconomiesThe development of inefficient economies is an additional economic concern as the availability of cheap labour from foreign markets can have a detrimental effect on the innovative nature of domestic companies. When faced with labour shortages, “businesses have an incentive to invest in labour-saving technology, which boosts productivity growth by enabling fewer workers to produce more.”10 When countries can just import more low-priced labour there is little vigour for companies to invest into innovative technologies. Furthermore, according to Michael Lund of the Financial Times, the perception that it is necessary to import labour to maintain a ratio between tax-payers and retirees in order to sustain the social security is false. Lund believes that, “productivity growth can solve much or all of the pension funding problem”. To support this, the United States labour pool went

Research Working Paper 3117 (2003).9 Zero-sum describes a situation in which a participant's gain or loss is exactly balanced by the losses or gains of the other participant(s). (Wikipedia.org)10 Lund, Michael. "A Labour Shortage Can Be a Blessing." Financial Times 8 June 2006. <www.ft.com>.

Page 8: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

from eighteen workers per one retiree in the 1950s to three workers per retiree in 2006 without complications. The US avoided a failure in the social security system by increasing its productivity per worker by means of technological advancements. The importation of low-cost labour can be seen as the ‘quick-fix’ but not the ultimate solution to sustain innovative economic growth.

III. Solutions to Driving Factors against Labour Migration:Although there are some compelling arguments challenging the migration of labour, it is impossible to deny that labour migration is vital to both stakeholders - the developing and the developed nations. The question is not whether labour migration should be endorsed but rather how labour migration should be endorsed.

Mitigating the Brain DrainFirstly, the sending country of labour must be able to combat the problem of the ‘brain drain’ in order to sustain its own national economic growth. The brain drain is seen as a significant misuse of a country’s resources. In many Latin American nations, for example, enrolment for medical school is significantly high, but the nation faces a shortage of doctors11. Jagdish Bhagwati, a professor in Law and Economics at Columbia University, New York, proposed an initiative to develop a brain drain tax making it mandatory for skilled workers who emigrate from developing nations to developed nations to “share a part of their brain-drain gains with their country-men and -woman who have not been able to improve their economic fortunes by emigration”12.

Although good in theory, Bhaqwait’s proposal lacks real credence in the real world. There are many complexities that coincide with Bhagwati’s proposal: most arising in the logistics of implementation. Since developing countries would be levying this tax from its emigrated workers while abroad, the sending country would require the support of the host country to help enforce the payment. In countries, such as the United States of America, assistance with enforcement would almost certainly be denied as the tax would been seen as unconstitutional for it discriminates against aliens. According to Bhagwati, a multilateral lateral agreement would need to be developed among nations to impose such a tax although no such initiative has been raised at world forums because the tax brings rise to conflicting interests. Developing countries could, however, try to impose such a ‘brain-drain tax’ on the world forum by claiming the tax is a ‘support payment’ for remaining family members much like a parent must pay child-support payments for their children. The dilemma arises however in conflicting interests between developing and developed countries as money would be extradited from the developed country’s economy which, in turn, would have a negative impact

11 "Labour Migration." Wikipedia.Org. <www.wikipedia.org>.12 Bhagwati Jagdish, Ed. (1976). The Brain Drain and Taxation - Theory and Empirical Analysis.

Amsterdam, North-Holland Publishing Company.

Page 9: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

on their economy. For this reason, the developing countries would have extremely tough resistance to the agreement of a ‘brain-drain tax’ from developed countries.

Developing nations should conversely concentrate their focus on developing incentives to retain and return highly skilled workers back into their economy. The International Labour Office in Geneva developed a rubric of the 6 R’s developing countries should adopt to mitigate the effects of the brain drain:

1. Return of migrants to their source country2. Restriction of international mobility to own nationals and foreign workers3. Recruitment of international migrants4. Reparation for loss of human capital (compensation)5. Resourcing expatriates (Diaspora options)6. Retention: through educational sector policies and through economic development

Source: Wickramasekara, International Labour Office

Focusing on the ILO’s solutions of return and retention, sending countries must first analyze the reasons their workers decided to acquire employment abroad and then rectify these problems. As seen previously, the two most prominent reasons for the migration of labour is better work and pay opportunities abroad. These variables, however, are quite difficult for developing countries to influence. Likewise, the alternative solution of straight out banning migration to counter the brain problem goes against Human Rights conventions. Developing nations must instead encourage the retention of current skilled workers through generating ‘rapid economic growth’ within their own nation - although this is easier said than done according to Devan and Tewari: “… the hard reality is that few emerging markets have any hope, in the foreseeable future, of creating the type and volume of economic opportunities needed to reverse or even substantially slow the brain drain.”

This raises one of the foremost problems associated with the brain drain: the multiplier effect it causes. As workers leave the country the economy suffers resulting in more workers seeking employment abroad. Developing nations need desperately to break this negative cycle in order to have any hopes to reclaim a growing economy. Hope seems to exists, however. As per the International Labour Office’s Philippines Study, new communications technology such as the internet might be the key to break the cycle and keep laborers in the country:

The pervasive use of the internet as real time communications media has effectively closed the gap between users and suppliers of high skill work without actual physical dislocation. In particular, programming and software services are being transacted through the internet without the necessity of worker migration.13

13 Alburo, F. and D. Abella (2002). Skiller Labour Migration from Developing Countries: Study on

Page 10: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Beyond promoting the use of emergent technologies that allow laborers to provided services abroad without the necessary movement abroad, developing countries should also focus on shifting their educational resources from higher education to primary education to increase the average productivity of the non-skilled to low-skilled workers who are left to support the economy.

Combating Xenophobia and Other Cultural BarriersThe practice of exclusion and ‘racialization’ can hinder a foreigner’s ability to integrate into the receiving country’s social sphere and further promotes alienation and xenophobia. Likewise, limiting the ability for foreign workers to reunite with their family can further feelings of alienation amongst foreign workers.

To combat this racial intolerance, receiving countries should educate natives about the importance and necessity for foreign workers to sustain a growing economy and separate the image of the ‘media’s foreigner’ (as media normally dwells on the negative subject matters relating to foreigners such as illegal immigration, terrorism, etc.) and the larger majority of migrant workers who are beneficial to the country.

Furthermore, the adoption of national laws that protect non-nations, the promotion of diversity and multiculturalism, and the promotion of business to implement non-discriminatory hiring policies can help divert the xenophobia associated with foreign labourers and further promote the integration of migrant labour into society. Canada, a country that highly relies on the influx of foreign workers for seasonal temporary work, requires both the employer and migrant worker to sign an agreement which “… specifies the employer’s responsibility to cover the worker’s return travel costs, to provide accommodation at no extra charge, and to pay workers the highest applicable minimum wage”14 with sanctions for employers who knowingly breech the terms. The entry of foreign labour for seasonal employment helps Canada foster higher productivity gains than would be impossible with the otherwise limited native population while the agreement ensures that migrant workers receive full national treatment and protection with respect to working conditions and wages.

Allowing for family unification, although requiring strict definitions on what constitutes ‘family-member’ to avoid the over emigration of non-workers (that are costly to the host country), will help with integration of migrant workers into their new surroundings. According to the International Organization for Migration, “social integration of migrants and their families is essential for increasing social cohesion and combating xenophobia in host countries.”15

the Philippines, International Migration Papers No. 51, International Labour Office, Geneva14 Background Paper. Trade and Migration Seminar, 4 Oct. 2004, IOM / World Bank / WTO. <www.wto.org>.15 Labour Migration. Workshop for Policy Makers: 86th Session, 18 Nov. 2003, International

Page 11: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Protecting the Domestic LabourerThe policies and practices of countries concerning the admittance of foreign workers via visa, quotas, and/or work permits have not been subjective to international or multilateral regulation as “the ability to determine which non-nationals enter its territory and under what conditions are considered one of the fundamental attributes of state sovereignty”16. There are currently many methods imposed by countries to ensure the protection of domestic employment: “To protect domestic labour, receiving countries conduct labour market assessments/tests, establish yearly quotas or number of admissions of temporary cards, determine the length of stay and conditions of stay, including family reunion and permit renewal, specify the terms of occupational mobility, and monitor migrant workers’ obligations to their employers.”17 Countries such as Germany, Switzerland, South Africa, the United States of America, and Canada (among others) have established such quotas based on market forecasts entitling a finite number of foreign workers per sector to be allowed to seek employment within the country in order to preserve a balance between native and foreign workers.

Likewise, ‘economic needs tests’ have also been used to determine whether the needs of certain employees can be fulfilled by a native worker within the country. Employers in countries that implemented the economic needs tests must prove that they cannot find a skilled native labourer to fill the position before looking to import foreign labourers. Sixty-seven of the one hundred and thirty-four WTO members have used economic needs test to regulate the flow of services including labour migration18 (labour migration being defined under MODE 4 of GATS). Although these measures promote the protectionism of native labourers they are also criticized for enabling market inefficiencies. Quota systems, which are generally regulated by governments, are criticized for being too static for the dynamics of markets as: “… governments do not react quickly enough to labour market changes”19. To resolve this predicament, an alternative is to have governments construct a framework to allow companies to determine the number of foreign workers required within their industry.

Restrictive quota systems, on the other hand, are criticized for the promotion of illegal migration; in the recent decade as legal immigration has been restricted the European Union has seen illegal migration soar to half a million people annually while the United States has approximately 300 000 workers

Organization for Migration. <http://www.iom.int/DOCUMENTS/GOVERNING/EN/LabourWorkshops_Report.pdf>.16 Background Paper. Trade and Migration Seminar, 4 Oct. 2004, IOM / World Bank / WTO. <www.wto.org>.17 Background Paper. Trade and Migration Seminar, 4 Oct. 2004, IOM / World Bank / WTO. <www.wto.org>.18 LISTS OF ECONOMIC NEEDS TESTS IN THE GATS SCHEDULES OF SPECIFIC COMMITMENTS. UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT, 17 Aug. 1999, TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT BOARD. <www.unctad.org/en/docs/poitcdtsbd8.pdf>.19 Background Paper. Trade and Migration Seminar, 4 Oct. 2004, IOM / World Bank / WTO. <www.wto.org>.

Page 12: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

enter illegally each year20. With the influx of illegal workers due to the decrease of legal labour migration, countries are ultimately worse off than liberalizing their immigration policies as “…(illegal) immigration will lower the wage more if immigrants are prepared to work for less than natives, as seen plausible in the case of illegal immigrants, for example. An influx of such immigration not only shifts labour supply, but makes it more elastic”21.

Illegal labour migration not only contributes to the increase in wage differentials in the receiving country but also strains social institutions such as schools, hospitals, and law enforcement and removes the term “temporary” out of “temporary labour” as the government is unable to track when these workers have stayed beyond their allotted time since they have no legal record of the citizens.

Governments must be willing to increase expenditures into enforcement and create tougher sanctions on employers hiring illegal workers in order to combat the problem of illegal labour migration. Nevertheless, some countries, such as the USA, are economically dependent on illegal workers to meet labour needs. Between the 1996 through 2000, the US economy generated the need for 14.3 million new jobs while the US population increased by only 12.3 million people, including legal migrant workers22. As an American journalist cleverly put it, “if we manage to expel all the illegal immigrants from south of the border, who's going to build the fence to keep them out?”23 Turning a blind eye to illegal migration is often easier for publicly elected governments than going against public wishes and providing provisions for further liberalized national borders to migrant workers. Such conflicts of interest further undermine the success of labour migration liberalization.

Through liberalizing strictly certain service sectors, conversely, the concept of liberalizing the movement of natural persons could be more seen as more appealing to developed nations as they would be able to protect particular sectors of their domestic labour force while allowing the influx of foreign labourers into sectors such as IT and health care which are in large demand for labourers. Yet the inhibiting of certain labour migration raises the following problems mentioned above: the inefficiency of dictating constraints instead of letting the market determine its own equilibrium and the possibility of increasing illegal migration through restricting legal migration.

20 Labor Mobility and the WTO. World Bank, 2004. Liberalizing Temporary Movement. <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTRGEP2004/Resources/chapter4.pdf>.

21 The Impact of Immigrants on Host Country Wages, Employment and Growth

Rachel M. Friedberg; Jennifer Hunt The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9, No. 2. (Spring, 1995), pp. 23-44. <http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=08953309%28199521%299%3A2%3C23%3ATIOIOH%3E2.0.CO%3B2-S>

22 Gans, Judith. (Illegal) Immigration: Global and National Context and Prospects for Reform. University of Arizona. <http://udallcenter.arizona.edu/programs/immigration/publications/illegal_immigration_overview.pdf.>

23 Thomasson, Dan K. "Our Unhealthy Dependence on Illegal Workers." Scripps Howard News Service 28 May 2006.

Page 13: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Keeping Efficiency in the EconomyAs discussed earlier, the opportunity of low-priced labour can influence companies to utilize labour intensive methods of production instead of investing into innovative production methods. As renowned economist Henry George explains:

… truth is, that a low rate of wages does not mean a low cost of production, but the reverse. The universal and obvious truth is, that the country where wages are highest can produce with the greatest economy, because workmen have there the most intelligence, the most spirit and the most ability; because invention and discovery are there most quickly made and most readily utilized. The great inventions and discoveries which so enormously increase the power of human labor to produce wealth have all been made in countries where wages are comparatively high. 24

A Prisoner’s dilemma arises however as, …an individual producer gains an advantage when he can force down the wages of his employees below the ordinary level, or can import laborers who will work for him for less, and that he may by this means be enabled to undersell his competitors, while the employer who continues to pay higher wages than other employers about him will, before long, be driven out of business.

As table 1 illustrates, there is a first-mover advantage if either company takes advantage of low wages as it might be able to undercut its competitor. If both companies (assuming this trend is followed on a national level) choose to do so, the economy becomes over reliant on inexpensive labour and little incentives arise from companies to invest in more efficient methods of production. If both companies retain their normal wages, conversely, the companies will search for labour cost-cutting measures through innovative technologies.

Table 1Company B exploits lower wages

Company B retains normal wages

Company A exploits lower wages

Economy reliant on inefficient labour intensive production methods

Company A can temporarily undercut Company B with lower production costs

Company A retains normal wages

Company B can temporarily undercut Company A with lower production costs

Economy remains innovative and invests in efficient productive methods

Since the economy is argued to be better off when both companies choose to retain normal wages, how can governments influence both companies to

24 George, Henry. Protection or Free Trade: an Examination of the Tariff Question, with Especial Regard to the Interests of Labor. New York: Doubleday, Page & Co, 1905.

Page 14: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

choose this equilibrium result? One method adopted by almost all developed countries is minimum wage requirements - a price floor is set to which employers cannot legally offer wages below. Such practice persuades companies to invest into labour-saving technologies when cost-benefit analysis deems that the initial costs are surpassed by the future savings in labour costs.

Wage minimums, however, also criticized for creating a prisoners dilemma amongst other nations as nations who employ lower wage minimums, or no wage minimum wages at all, are able to produce for less ultimately undercutting competing nations. The Heckscher-Ohlin model, however, states that the liberalization of trade does not create an unfair advantage over those employing low-waged employees. The Heckscher-Ohlin model concludes that nations with low-wages produce goods requiring labour intensive production methods while capital intensive nations, facing high wage prices, produce goods requiring high capital inputs for production and, correspondingly, the two nations trade the two goods amongst each other. The Heckscher-Ohlin model, however, is based on the assumption that capital and labour are not interchangeable between nations. What happens when labour becomes interchangeable? When a positive cost-benefit position arises from migration, neoclassical economics theory concludes that workers will see it initially advantageous to go to countries with higher set wages (capital intensive nations) resulting in what is commonly referred to as ‘social dumping’. Much like the fear of product ‘dumping’ with the liberalization of trade between nations, the fear of the dumping of people is associated with the liberalization of labour migration. Social dumping, however, is only seen as a short term problem with the liberalization of temporary labour migration as the movement of workers to developed/higher-wage nations will result in the increase of wages in the sending country as labour supply decreases while the migrant workers will be faced with either decreased wages or unemployment in the receiving country as labour supply increases. Overtime it would be expected that real wage differentials, keeping in mind that one wage might be monetarily the same but hold significantly less buying power in the country of residence, would be eliminated as wages get equalized with the free movement of labour. The market will dictate a labour supply and demand equilibrium which ultimately eliminates wage differentials.

To further prevent the American economy from becoming inefficient by the over relying on labour intensive production methods, United State’s Government published a report, ‘Expanding Economic Opportunities’, in May 2006 stressing the importance of insuring the USA’s economy focused on continuing its labour productivity growth. The White House proposed four basic sources of labour productivity - growth-capital investment, technological innovation, education and training, and enhancing basic efficiency25. The US government aims to increase national capital investment by decreasing taxes levied on the investment’s returns. Likewise, technological innovation is encourage vis-à-vis the American Competitiveness Initiative (ACI) “which makes Research and Experimentation (R&E) tax credit

25 United States of America. Office of Management and Budget. EXPANDING ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITY. <http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/fy2007/opportunity.html>.

Page 15: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

permanent, increasing Federal research and development spending, and increased funding for math and science education”26. By providing better access to quality education and by influencing monetary policy the US government hopes to achieve the last two factors they deem important to increase labour productivity growth within the nation - education and basic efficiency. Measures such as these can be adopted by countries to mitigate the probability of inefficient economies emerging as a result of the influx of low-cost labour.

IV. Introduction to GATS Mode 4: The service sector is the fastest growing part of the global economy and it is estimated that the service sector accounts for 60% of global output, 30% of employment and nearly 20% of global trade27. This considerable growth caught the attention of policymakers and the General Agreement on Trades in Services (GATS) was negotiated under the World Trade Organization in the Uruguay Rounds and was implemented in January 1995. The GATS ultimate goal, according to its preamble is to:

"…(develop) a multilateral framework of principles and rules for trade in services with a view to the expansion of such trade under conditions of transparency and progressive liberalization, and as a means of promoting the economic growth of all trading partners and the development of developing countries."

The GATS agreement breaks services into four modes (figure 3):

Figure 3

The movement of natural persons (individuals travelling from their home country to supply services in another country) is classified under Mode 4 of the GATS agreement. Annex 3 of the GATS on the Movement of Natural Persons, however, states that the agreement does not apply to “measures affecting natural persons seeking access to the employment market" nor does it apply "to measures regarding citizenship, residence or employment on a permanent basis". The Annex also clarifies that regardless of their obligations under the agreement, members may regulate the entry of natural persons and their temporary stay in their territory28. This exclusion allows countries to enforce visa requirements and labour quotas to ensure the 26 United States of America. Office of Management and Budget. EXPANDING ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITY. <http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/fy2007/opportunity.html>.

27 GATS Mode 4: How Trade in Services Can Help Developing Countries. Development Research Centre on Migration, Globalisation & Poverty. 2004. 1-4. <http://www.migrationdrc.org/publications/briefing_papers/BP4.pdf>.

Page 16: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

protection of their domestic labour. Although the definition on what is defined as a natural person is not limited to any particular skill level, in practice it has been limited to high skilled workers. The relationship to the services provided by the natural person, on the other hand, is clearly defined. Mode 4 only applies to a natural person who is either self-employed/independent service supplier, an employee of a foreign company who has sent the worker to fulfill a contract for the host country, an employee of a foreign company who has established its business within the host country (intra-corporate transferee), or a business visitor. Not clearly explained, conversely, is the definition, or rather the lack of definition, for the term ‘temporary’. The only clarification of the length of stay a natural person can remain is the exclusion of the migrant worker to claim permanent migration via residence, citizenship, or employment on a permanent basis (see Table 2 for summary of GATS 4).

Table 2 Summary of GATS mode 4 coverage:Included Excluded Borderline

Duration of stay

Temporary presence

Permanent migration (GATS does not apply to measures affecting residence, citizenship or employment on a permanent basis)

Temporary is undefined

28 United Nations, Department Of Economic An. BACKGROUND NOTE ON GATS MODE 4 AND ITS INFORMATION NEEDS. Meeting of the Technical Subgroup on Movement of Natural Persons – Mode 4, 31 Jan. 2005, World Trade Organization and OECD. <http://unstats.un.org/unsd/tradeserv/TSGdocuments/tsg0502-8.pdf>.

Page 17: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Purpose of Stay

Presence of natural persons for the supply of commercial services

Persons seeking to access the employment market. Natural persons working in non-service sectors - e.g., agriculture, manufacturing Services supplied under governmental authority

Scope of certain sectors, e.g. “services incidental to agriculture, hunting and forestry” (e.g. agricultural workers or suppliers of fruit-picking services?) etc. Lack of certainty over precisely what would fall under the carve out for “services in the exercise of governmental authority” (e.g. education or health services)

Skill Level All skill-levels included

Categories of Natural Persons

Business visitors Contractual service suppliers (self employed or as employee of a foreign service supplier) Intra-corporate transferees (foreign employees of foreign companies established in the host country)

Employees of all domestic companies -locally owned - established in the host country

Source: United Nations, Department of Economics and Social Affairs

V. Does MODE 4 of GATS really Liberalize Migration of Labour?One criticism of GATS is it over emphasises migration of only highly skilled workers. Since the comparative advantage of developing countries lies in the supply of low to middle skilled service workers, the developing countries are

Page 18: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

ultimately marginalized in trade negotiations. The World Bank estimates that developing countries stand to gain 6 trillion dollars between 2005 and 2015 from liberalization of trade in services yet are ultimately suppressed by the restrictive nature of Mode 4. Further research by economist Alan Winters suggests that the global economy can benefit from gains over $300 billion per year when the migration of labour is further liberalized allowing for easier labour mobility29.

Yet mode 4 “… is by far the smallest mode of service delivery in terms of both trade flows and the volume of scheduled concessions recorded under the GATS” and only accounts for “less than 1.5 percent of total trade in services”30. With such large economic gains forecasted by further labour migration liberalization, why has Mode 4 not foster greater free trade of labour services amongst nations?

One theory is that people fear the unknown. The inclusion of Mode 4 is often criticized for it vague nature; as the Organization for Economic Corporation and Development recently reported, “If the economic impact of Mode 4 is difficult to assess, it is essentially because the definition of this mode, and the instruments used to measure it, are very imprecise”. Initial fears of the problems associated with the labour migration resurface with talk of liberalizing it on a multilateral level. Qualms of the brain drain, xenophobia and other cultural costs, protectionism of domestic labour, and economic inefficiencies are reborn with talks of Mode 4.

VI. Mode 4 - Part of the Problem or Part of the Solution?Mode 4 could be the solution to these doubts and fears of labour migration liberalization. Enforcing strictly temporary movement of labour would return skilled workers to developing countries with new beneficial skills acquired from their work abroad countering the fear of the brain drain. It must be noted, however, that Mode 4 is not an effective measure to mitigate the brain drain problem if applied solely on a country by country basis; workers could simply move from one country to another as their temporary migration visas expire. This, in turn, keeps the skilled labour from returning to their home country. It is for this reason that the topic of labour migration must be imposed on the world forum; agreements on topics such as the maximum amount of time for foreigner workers can be employed abroad should be reached amongst all participating nations of Mode 4.

Furthermore, Winters affirms that, “Host countries fear cultural and integration problems because the unskilled are less likely to adapt to Western culture; they fear drains on the public purse; the jobs that unskilled immigrants take do not command immediate respect and appear to be at the expense of the employment of local unskilled workers”. Nonetheless, temporary labour movement poses little cultural or integration costs as the workers are not needed to be integrated into society as their stay is

29 Winters, Alan L. et al. "Negotiating the Liberalisation of the Temporary Movement of Natural Persons." Discussion Papers in Economics. (2002) No. 87. Brighton: University of Sussex.30 Winters, Alan L. et al. "Negotiating the Liberalisation of the Temporary Movement of Natural Persons." Discussion Papers in Economics. (2002) No. 87. Brighton: University of Sussex.

Page 19: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

temporary. Furthermore, regulations regarding the use of social services by migrant workers or the requirement that hiring firms pay a ‘foreigner-tax’ per foreign worker employed would further alleviate the reservations of foreigners being costly to incoming countries social service systems. The fear that foreign workers could impede on domestic labour is still a viable threat with the introduction of further liberalization of Mode 4. The economic gains coupled with the growing labour shortages, however, are said to counteract this threat:

… in general, there is little evidence that native workers are harmed by immigration. On the contrary there is considerable support for the view that migration creates new business and jobs and fills labour market gaps. Migrants have little impact on native wages or employment, because their work is concentrated in areas and sectors where there are unfilled vacancies.31

To combat the fear of inefficient markets from the over-reliance on labour intensive production methods, nations should adopt domestic policy and taxes incentives to promote further investment by companies into more efficient production capital as seen in the ‘Expanding Economic Opportunities’ report published by US Government.

Fears of the inclusiveness yet non-transparent nature of GATS Mode 4 has countries turning more frequently to bilateral agreements for the temporary movement of labour for purposes such as seasonal work, cross-border workers, contract workers, etc. In 2004 there were over 176 bilateral agreements for temporary labour migration in OECD countries.32 For the receiving country bilateral agreements create cross-border labour markets, offset, labour shortages, promote cultural/political ties and exchanges and encourage co-operation in managing migration. For the sending country, on the other hand, bilateral agreements help ensure the protection of labours’ rights, employ surplus labour, and enhance welfare of the country through remittances33. Bilateral agreements are far easier for developed countries to manage as a systematic process ensues to fill seasonal/temporary labour shortages the longer the relationship endures. With the increasing number of labour shortages, however, “in some specific sectors and occupations, some countries have developed multilateral recruitment schemes that target a large group of sending countries”34 while “the similarities in labour demand across receiving countries, as well as the emerging competition for labour from sending countries, may support a multilateral approach, or at least co-ordinate policies among receiving countries”.

Although bi-lateral agreements are a temporary fix, it is evident that a multilateral agreement is needed. The question arises is whether the current

31 Winters, Alan L. et al. "Negotiating the Liberalisation of the Temporary Movement of Natural Persons." Discussion Papers in Economics. (2002) No. 87. Brighton: University of Sussex.32 Lemaitre, George. Bilateral Labour Mobility Agreements. Managing the Movement of People: What Can Be Learned for Mode 4 of the GATS, 4 Oct. 2004, OECD.33 Lemaitre, George. Bilateral Labour Mobility Agreements. Managing the Movement of People: What Can Be Learned for Mode 4 of the GATS, 4 Oct. 2004, OECD.34 Garson, Jean-Pierre. BILATERAL AGREEMENTS AND OTHER FORMS OF LABOUR RECRUITMENT: SOME LESSONS FROM OECD COUNTRIES’ EXPERIENCES. Workshop on International Migration and Labour Market in Asia, 17 Feb. 2006, OECD.

Page 20: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

GATS Mode 4 is the response to this need? At the present time Mode 4 is not part of the solution. Its ambiguous and limiting nature makes it only relevant to the big players, the developed countries trading labourers amongst themselves, and ignores those who really need it - the developing countries.

How can GATS Mode 4 be part of the solution? Alan Winters et al. suggest that the following actions should be immediately discussed and implemented under GATS Mode 4:

· negotiating new sub-contracting schemes to include the movement of lower-skilled service providers under Mode 4,· separating temporary movements of people from permanent ones, and, once national security clearance has been achieved, granting multi-entry GATS visas to temporary workers to provide their services,· uniform definitions and coverage of service personnel categories and expanding the coverage to include middle and lower skilled workers and professionals,· accelerating the mutual recognition of qualifications,· codifying of economic needs, and· separating out social security contributions into short-run (work-related accident and health) and long-term (pension) social protection.

In the long run, Mode 4 should focus on further liberalizing temporary migration by:

· confirming that the GATS does cover domestically employed-service providers and liberalising these schemes as well,· setting up auctions for any remaining numerical quotas,· abolishing economic needs tests, and· addressing the wage-parity issue in a way that recognises the comparativeadvantage of developing countries.35

Yet, as it stands today, GATS MODE 4 is not part of the solution; can we therefore assume Mode 4 is part of the problem? Such a blithe agreement could be seen as merely spot holder, diverting attention away from developing a pertinent agreement that liberalizes between the developing and the developed.

Luckily, this has not been the case. Since the introduction of the GATS Mode 4, six nations (three developed nations including the US, the EU, Canada, and three developing including India, Columbia, and Pakistan) have submitted proposals to the WTO for negotiating changes to Mode 4. Amongst the requests of India include the request for a broader designation of natural person to include low-middle level workers:

(India’s request includes the) further expansion in the scope of categories to include middle and lower level of professionals into the existing coverage of ‘other persons’ and ‘specialists’. This clearly addresses the concern of many developing countries. They feel that their comparative advantage lies, not in highly skilled professionals, but in middle and lower level professionals.36

35 Winters, Alan L. et al. "Negotiating the Liberalisation of the Temporary Movement of Natural Persons." Discussion Papers in Economics. (2002) No. 87. Brighton: University of Sussex.36 Winters, Alan L. et al. "Negotiating the Liberalisation of the Temporary Movement of Natural

Page 21: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Expanding the classification of the type of labourer covered by Mode 4 in conjunction with pronouncing that GATS Mode 4 also includes domestically employed-service providers, a natural persons from Member A (the sending territory) employed by a service firm of Member B (the receiving territory), developing countries will be able to seek greater liberalization of their service workers abroad through Mode 4.

Developed countries have also showed interest in furthering the substance of Mode 4. Canada suggest in their filing that trade policy, immigration and labour market officials should discuss collectively the issues involved to open transparency into the matter. Likewise, as their supply of labour continues to decrease, developing countries are realizing that they must seek further liberalization of labour migration to sustain their labour demands.

The following changes, along with the suggestions made by Alan Winters et al., to Mode 4 could make it a more influential and operational text instead of the trivial document it is today. Continued pressures, however, by developing countries to include further liberalization within Mode 4 have caused a stalemate between developed and developing countries on Mode 4 reform. With little in the way of changes of Mode 4, however, countries are continuing to rely on bilateral agreements to liberalize the movement of non-professional workers. The further continuation of reliance on bilateral agreements could, however, ultimately undermine Mode 4’s importance.

Whether GATS Mode 4 will ever be liberalized is uncertain and left open to speculation - whether GATS Mode 4 should be liberalized is obvious as greater liberalization under Mode 4 is in the interest of both developing and developed countries when executed correctly.

Persons." Discussion Papers in Economics. (2002) No. 87. Brighton: University of Sussex.

Page 22: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Bibliography:

Alburo, F. and D. Abella (2002). Skiller Labour Migration from Developing Countries: Study on the Philippines, International Migration Papers No. 51, International Labour Office, Geneva

Background Paper. Trade and Migration Seminar, 4 Oct. 2004, IOM / World Bank / WTO. <www.wto.org>.

Bhagwati Jagdish, Ed. (1976). The Brain Drain and Taxation - Theory and Empirical Analysis.

Amsterdam, North-Holland Publishing Company.

Cattacin, Sandro, ed. Debate: Immigration Policy. Swiss Political Science Review 7. 2001. 95-118. <www.sscnet.ucla.edu/soc/faculty/wimmer/Konturen.pdf>.

Cohen, Robin. Brain Drain Migration. University of Warwick. Official South African Commission on International Migration, 1997.

Ellerman, David. "Policy Research on Migration and Development." World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3117 (2003).

Gans, Judith. (Illegal) Immigration: Global and National Context and Prospects for Reform. University of Arizona. <http://udallcenter.arizona.edu/programs/immigration/publications/illegal_immigration_overview.pdf.>.

Garson, Jean-Pierre. BILATERAL AGREEMENTS AND OTHER FORMS OF LABOUR RECRUITMENT: SOME LESSONS FROM OECD COUNTRIES’ EXPERIENCES. Workshop on International Migration and Labour Market in Asia, 17 Feb. 2006, OECD.

Page 23: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

GATS Mode 4: How Trade in Services Can Help Developing Countries. Development Research Centre on Migration, Globalisation & Poverty. 2004. 1-4. <http://www.migrationdrc.org/publications/briefing_papers/BP4.pdf>.

George, Henry. Protection or Free Trade: an Examination of the Tariff Question, with Especial Regard to the Interests of Labor. New York: Doubleday, Page & Co, 1905.

International Mobility of the Highly Skilled. Organization of Economic Co-operation and Development. Paris: OECD Publications, 2001. 1-336. <http://www1.oecd.org/publications/e-book/9202011E.PDF>.

Labor Mobility and the WTO. World Bank, 2004. Liberalizing Temporary Movement. <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTRGEP2004/Resources/chapter4.pdf>.

"Labour Migration." Wikipedia.Org. <www.wikipedia.org>.

Labour Migration. Workshop for Policy Makers: 86th Session, 18 Nov. 2003, International Organization for Migration. <http://www.iom.int/DOCUMENTS/GOVERNING/EN/LabourWorkshops_Report.pdf>.

Lemaitre, George. Bilateral Labour Mobility Agreements. Managing the Movement of People: What Can Be Learned for Mode 4 of the GATS, 4 Oct. 2004, OECD.

LISTS OF ECONOMIC NEEDS TESTS IN THE GATS SCHEDULES OF SPECIFIC COMMITMENTS. UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE ON TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT, 17 Aug. 1999, TRADE AND DEVELOPMENT BOARD. <www.unctad.org/en/docs/poitcdtsbd8.pdf>.

Lund, Michael. "A Labour Shortage Can Be a Blessing." Financial Times 8 June 2006. <www.ft.com>.

Page 24: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed

Silié, Rubén. "TERRORISM. MIGRATION. EXCUSE." TERRORISM. MIGRATION. EXCUSE (2006). <http://www.acs-aec.org/column/greatCarib01232006_en.htm>.

Taran, Patrick, and Eduardo Geronimi. Protection is Paramount. Conferencia HemisféRica Sobre MigracióN Internacional: Derechos Humanos Y Trata De Personas En Las AméRicas, 20 Nov. 2002, International Labor Office (Geneva). <http://www.cepal.org/celade/noticias/paginas/2/11302/PTaran.pdf.>.

The Impact of Immigrants on Host Country Wages, Employment and Growth

Rachel M. Friedberg; Jennifer Hunt The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9, No. 2. (Spring, 1995), pp. 23-44. <http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=08953309%28199521%299%3A2%3C23%3ATIOIOH%3E2.0.CO%3B2-S>

Thomasson, Dan K. "Our Unhealthy Dependence on Illegal Workers." Scripps Howard News Service 28 May 2006.

United Nations, Department Of Economic An. BACKGROUND NOTE ON GATS MODE 4 AND ITS INFORMATION NEEDS. Meeting of the Technical Subgroup on Movement of Natural Persons – Mode 4, 31 Jan. 2005, World Trade Organization and OECD. <http://unstats.un.org/unsd/tradeserv/TSGdocuments/tsg0502-8.pdf>.

United States of America. Office of Management and Budget. EXPANDING ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITY. <http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/budget/fy2007/opportunity.html>.

Winters, Alan L. et al. "Negotiating the Liberalisation of the Temporary Movement of Natural Persons." Discussion Papers in Economics. (2002) No. 87. Brighton: University of Sussex.

Page 25: Labour Migration between the Developing and the Developed