Top Banner
Health State Unable to perform some tasks at home and/or at work Able to perform all self care activities (eating, bathing, dressing) albeit with some difficulties Unable to participate in many types of leisure activities Often moderate to severe pain and/or other complaints
42

Health State

Feb 01, 2016

Download

Documents

Kumiko

Health State. Unable to perform some tasks at home and/or at work Able to perform all self care activities (eating, bathing, dressing) albeit with some difficulties Unable to participate in many types of leisure activities Often moderate to severe pain and/or other complaints. Exercise. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Health State

Health State

• Unable to perform some tasks at home and/or at work

• Able to perform all self care activities (eating, bathing, dressing) albeit with some difficulties

• Unable to participate in many types of leisure activities

• Often moderate to severe pain and/or other complaints

Page 2: Health State

Exercise

• Rating scale

• (Q, 60y) ~ (FH, X)

• (Q, 60y) ~ ((FH, 60y), p; Death)

Page 3: Health State

Determination of QALY Weights

• Three Methods– Rating Scale– Time Trade-Off– Standard Gamble

Page 4: Health State

Question

• Methods give systematically different results– SG > TTO > RS

• Which one is best?

Page 5: Health State

Old Belief

• SG is best

• Based on EU

• EU is normative theory of decision under risk

• risk important in medical decision making

Page 6: Health State

Problem

• People violate EU

• Inconsistencies in SG utilities

Page 7: Health State

Llewellyn-Thomas et al. (1982)

• Two ways of determining U(X)

– One-stage: X ~ (FH,p; Death)• U(X) = p

– Two-stage:• X ~ (FH, q; Y)• Y ~ (FH, r; Death)• p = q + (1 q) r

Page 8: Health State

Result

• Two-stage method gives systematically higher utilities than one-stage method

• Confirmed in Bleichrodt (2001) which used different experimental design

Page 9: Health State

Dilemma

• Methods give different results

• Do not know which method is best

Page 10: Health State

Attempt to Solve Dilemma

• Bleichrodt and Johannesson (1997)

• Idea: Utility model should explain choices

• Examine which method produces QALY weights that are most consistent with choices over health profiles.

Page 11: Health State

Approach

• Valued BP by SG, TTO, and RS.

• Defined 7 health profiles• 20 y. BP• 18 y. FH• 16 y. FH• 14 y. FH• 12 y. FH• 8 y. FH + 8 y. BP• 6 y. FH + 11 y. BP

Page 12: Health State

• Computed QALYs for each of 7 profiles based on SG, TTO, RS

• Led to ranking of profiles according to SG-QALYs, TTO-QALYs, and RS-QALYs

• Also asked subjects to rank profiles directly

• Compared ranking through Spearman rank-correlation coefficient

Page 13: Health State

Results

Method Utility

SG 0.67

TTO 0.58

RS 0.40

Page 14: Health State

Rank correlations

Method Utility

SG 0.73

TTO 0.84

RS 0.75

Page 15: Health State

Conclusions

• TTO most consistent with individual preferences

• But why?

Page 16: Health State

Rating Scale

• Easiest to use

• But,– No economic foundation (not choice based)– Response spreading (Bleichrodt and

Johannesson (1997))

Page 17: Health State

Hence

• Focus on SG and TTO

• Will explain why they differ and why TTO is “best”

Page 18: Health State

Empirical Research

• SG > TTO

• Explanation based on EU:

• Difference due to utility curvature

• Concave utility for duration

– risk aversion

– time preference

– decreasing marginal utility

Page 19: Health State

Puzzling for EU

• SG consistent with EU

• TTO imposes restrictions

• But TTO more consistent with preferences

Page 20: Health State

Will argue

• Common explanation is not complete because it is based on EU

• People violate EU

• Violations bias SG and TTO utilities

• Indication: results on consistency with

Page 21: Health State

Reasons for violations

• Probability distortion

• Loss aversion

• Scale compatibility

Page 22: Health State

Will show

• SG biased upwards

• TTO contains upward and downward biases

• This explains higher descriptive validity of TTO

Page 23: Health State

Assumptions

• U(Q,T) = H(Q)G(T)

– Common assumption in health utility measurement

– Empirical support

• People prefer more years in full health to less

Page 24: Health State

Standard Gamble

• (Q1,T) ~ ((FH,T), p, Death)

• H(FH) = 1, U(Death) = 0

• H(Q1)G(T) = pH(FH)G(T) + (1p)U(Death)

• H(Q1) = p

Page 25: Health State

Time Trade-Off

• (Q1,T1) ~ (FH, T2)

• G(T) = T

• H(Q1)T1 = H(FH)T2

• H(Q1) = T2 / T1

Page 26: Health State

Utility Curvature

• If G is concave/convex then the TTO weights are biased downwards/upwards

• Empirical Research:– G is concave both under EU and under nonEU

• TTO biased downwards, SG unbiased

Page 27: Health State

Utility Curvature

Duration

Uti

lity

T2

G(T2)

G(T1)=T1

T2 T1

Page 28: Health State

Probability distortion

• Empirical research: people do not evaluate probabilities linearly but weight probabilities

• Formal theory: Rank-dependent utility (RDU)

– V((Q1,T1), p, (Q2,T2)) = w(p) U(Q1,T1) + (1w(p)) U(Q2,T2)

– U = a + bU, a real, b > 0

Page 29: Health State

Impact

• TTO riskless, hence no impact probability distortion

• SG: (Q1,T) ~ ((FH,T), p, Death)

• H(FH) = 1, U(Death) = 0

• H(Q1)G(T) = w(p) H(FH)G(T) + (1w(p))U(Death)

• H(Q1) = w(p)

Page 30: Health State

Implication

• Suppose w(p) < p for all p

• Suppose (Q1,T) ~ ((FH,T), 0.70, Death)

• Then H(Q1) = w(0.70) < 0.70

• But SG: H(Q1) = 0.70

Page 31: Health State

Probability Weighting

We

igh

t

Probability

0.50

0.70

0.70

Page 32: Health State

Empirical research

• w has inverse S-shape

• w(p) > p for p < 0.35, w(p) < p on [0.35, 1]

• p in SG generally exceeds 0.35

• Hence, SG generally biased upwards

Page 33: Health State

Probability

We

igh

t

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

Page 34: Health State

Loss Aversion

• Prospect Theory: people evaluate outcomes as gains and losses relative to a reference point

• People are loss averse: they are more sensitive to losses than to gains

• Much empirical evidence for loss aversion/status quo bias/endowment effects.

Page 35: Health State

Loss Aversion

HealthStatus

DurationT TLA

Q1

FH

T1

Page 36: Health State

TTO

• (Q1,T1) ~ (FH,T)

• Gain in health status from Q1 to FH weighted against loss in duration from T1 to T.

• T will rise by loss aversion

• Hence TLA/T1 > T/T1

• And thus TTO biased upwards by loss aversion

Page 37: Health State

Standard Gamble

• (Q1,T) ~ ((FH,T), p, Death)

• Individual trades-off possible gain from (Q1,T) to (FH,T) against possible loss from (Q1,T) to death

• p > p

• Loss Aversion induces upward bias in SG utilities

Page 38: Health State

Scale Compatibility

• Attribute gets more weight if it is used as a response scale

• Formal theory: Tversky, Sattath & Slovic (1988)

• Empirical evidence: Tversky et al., Delquié (1993, 1997), Bleichrodt & Pinto (2002)

Page 39: Health State

Scale Compatibility

HealthStatus

DurationT TSC

Q1

FH

T1

Page 40: Health State

TTO

• (Q1,T1) ~ (FH,T)

• Response scale is duration

• TSC > T

• Hence TSC/T1 > T/T1

• And thus TTO biased upwards by scale compatibility

Page 41: Health State

Standard Gamble

• (Q1,T) ~ ((FH,T), p, Death)

• Scale compatibility predicts: overweighting of probability

• There are three probabilities in the SG– Probability p of good outcome (FH,T)– Probability 1 p of bad outcome Death

– Probability 1 of (Q1,T)

• Effect scale compatibility on SG utility ambiguous

Page 42: Health State

Conclusion

• SG generally upward biased

• In TTO both upward and downward biases

• Hence, TTO utility lower and more consistent with individual preferences

– Do not correct TTO for utility curvature

– B&J: TTO most consistent when no discounting