Top Banner
Growth Accounting The Solow Model Savings behaviour The Ramsey Model Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 1/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 Growth Accounting The Solow Model Savings behaviour The Ramsey Model Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical Framework TFP residual Decomposing growth in GDP per worker Results Growth Accounting: Objective 2 Many factors play role to determine output in a country Certainly, size of the labour force and capital stock do But also, education, government regulation, weather,... Any theory of economic growth chooses which of these factors to emphasize as sources of GDP growth within countries explanation for differences in levels/growth rates across countries Growth accounting: tool to evaluate relative importance of such factors Theory & Policy Implications Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 2/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 Growth Accounting The Solow Model Savings behaviour The Ramsey Model Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical Framework TFP residual Decomposing growth in GDP per worker Results Technical framework 3 Ignore the demand side for now Carefully specify the supply side Inputs: capital, K, and labour, L Output, Y State of technology, A Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 3/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 Growth Accounting The Solow Model Savings behaviour The Ramsey Model Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical Framework TFP residual Decomposing growth in GDP per worker Results Technology, F 4 Y = F(K , AL) where Y = output K = capital (input / factor) L = labour (input / factor) A = state of technology H = AL = effective labour Assumptions Marginal products positive and diminishing Constant returns to scale Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 4/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2
26

Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Mar 10, 2020

Download

Documents

dariahiddleston
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Theory: ReviewLecture 1, Exogenous Growth

Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

April 20, 2007

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 1/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Growth Accounting: Objective 2

◮ Many factors play role to determine output in a country

◮ Certainly, size of the labour force and capital stock do◮ But also, education, government regulation, weather,...

◮ Any theory of economic growth chooses which of thesefactors to emphasize as

◮ sources of GDP growth within countries◮ explanation for differences in levels/growth rates across

countries

◮ Growth accounting:tool to evaluate relative importance of such factors →Theory & Policy Implications

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 2/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Technical framework 3

◮ Ignore the demand side for now

◮ Carefully specify the supply side

◮ Inputs: capital, K , and labour, L

◮ Output, Y

◮ State of technology, A

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 3/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Technology, F 4

Y = F (K , AL) where

Y = output

K = capital (input / factor)

L = labour (input / factor)

A = state of technology

H = AL = effective labour

Assumptions◮ Marginal products positive and diminishing◮ Constant returns to scale

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 4/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 2: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Marginal products 5

◮ Marginal product of labour

◮∂F∂L = FL > 0 positive

◮∂

2F∂L2 = FLL < 0 and diminishing

◮ Marginal product of capital

◮∂F∂K = FK > 0 positive

◮∂

2F∂K 2 = FKK < 0 and diminishing

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 5/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Constant returns to scale (CRS) 6

F (λK , AλL) = λF (K , AL) for λ > 0

◮ Implications of CRS

◮ Size (of firms) does not matter → representative firm

◮ Euler’s theorem: Factor payments exhaust the output

◮ See example

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 6/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Cobb-Douglas production function 7

F (K , AL) = K α(AL)1−α 1 > α > 0

◮ CRS?

F (λK , AλL) = (λK )α(AλL)1−α

= λαK αλ1−α(AL)1−α

= λαλ1−αK α(AL)1−α

= λK α(AL)1−α

= λF (K , AL)

Yes, Cobb-Douglas production function is CRS.Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 7/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Cobb-Douglas production function 8

F (K , AL) = K α(AL)1−α 1 > α > 0◮ CRS? Yes.◮ Positive and diminishing MP?

FK (K , AL) = αK α−1(AL)1−α > 0

FL(K , AL) = (1 − α)K αA1−αL−α > 0

FKK (K , AL) = α(α − 1)K α−2(AL)1−α < 0

FLL(K , AL) = (1 − α)(−α)K αA1−αL−α−1 < 0

Yes, Cobb-Douglas production function has positive anddiminishing MPs.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 8/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 3: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Profit maximizing firm(s) 9

Π(K , AL) = F (K , AL)− rK − wL◮ Firms take prices as given and choose inputs K and L

◮ First order conditions

◮∂Π∂K = FK (K , AL) − r = 0

◮∂Π∂L = FL(K , AL) − w = 0

◮ Firm picks K and L such that

◮ FK (K , AL) = r

◮ FL(K , AL) = w

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 9/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Profit maximizing firms with CD production function 10

◮ With CD production function, FOCs become

FK (K , AL) = αK α−1(AL)1−α = r

FL(K , AL) = (1 − α)K αA1−αL−α = w

◮ Or, rearranging

FK (K , AL) = α(AL

K

)1−α= r

FL(K , AL) = (1 − α)A( K

AL

)α= w

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 10/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Euler’s Theorem with CD production function 11

rK + wL = F (K , AL)

Factor payments exhaust production.

◮ We have

r = FK (K , AL) = α(AL

K

)1−α

w = FL(K , AL) = (1 − α)A( K

AL

◮ Therefore,

rK + wL = FK (K , AL)K + FL(K , AL)L

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 11/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Euler’s Theorem with CD production function 12

◮ We had

rK + wL = FK (K , AL)K + FL(K , AL)L

◮ Therefore, substituting in functional forms for FK (K , AL)and FL(K , AL) from the previous slide, we get:

rK + wL =[

α(AL

K

)1−α]

K +[

(1 − α)A( K

AL

)α]

L

= αK α(AL)1−α + (1 − α)K α(AL)1−α

= K α(AL)1−α

= F (K , AL)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 12/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 4: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

One large firm or many small firms 13

◮ Since firms take prices as given,◮ and assuming A and α are the same for all firms◮ from FOCs, we get

r = FK (Ki , ALi) = αA1−α( Li

Ki

)1−α

w = FL(Ki , ALi) = (1 − α)A1−α(Ki

Li

◮ Capital-labor ratio, k∗ = LiKi

, chosen is the same for all firms(indexed by i).

◮ Using the CRS assumption, total output by many firms canbe represented by output of one firm

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 13/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Steps for growth accounting 14

◮ TFP residual, At , for K only production function

◮ TFP residual, At , across countries: K only

◮ TFP residual, At , including human capital

◮ TFP residual, At , across countries: K and H

◮ Decomposing growth in GDP per worker: K only

◮ Decomposing growth in GDP per worker: K and H

◮ Summary of results

◮ Critique

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 14/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

TFP, At , as residual for K only production function 15

◮ From the production function in year t

Yt = AtK αt L1−α

t

◮ Denoting “per worker” variables in lower case letters,i.e., output per w. yt = Yt

Ltand capital per w. kt = Kt

Lt

◮ After dividing by Lt , we rewrote production functionYtLt

= At(KtLt

)α(LtLt

)1−α as yt = Atkαt

◮ Hence, by rearranging we got

At = ytkα

t

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 15/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

TFP residual, At , across countries: K only 16

UK, South Korea and IndiaTFP

(Accounting for Physical Capital Only)

0.00

200.00

400.00

600.00

800.00

1000.00

1200.00

1400.00

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995

U.K.

Korea

India

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 16/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 5: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

CRS production function with physical and humancapital 17

◮ Now include human capital (e.g., years of education) intoproduction function (Make sure production function is CRSand positive and diminishing MP)

◮ We will use Yt = AtF (Kt , Ht , Lt) = AtK αt Hβ

t L1−α−βt ,

with α, β ∈ [0, 1] (parameters)

◮ Note: AtF (λKt , λHt , λLt) = λAtF (Kt , Ht , Lt) → CRS

◮ Homework: → Show that this production function is CRS→ Check that MP of physical capital, K , human capital, Ht

and labor Lt are positive and diminishing

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 17/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

TFP as residual for production function with K and H18

◮ From the production function in year t

Yt = AtK αt Hβ

t L1−α−βt

◮ Denoting “per worker” variables in lower case letters,i.e., output per w. yt = Yt

Lt, phys. capital per w. kt = Kt

Ltand

human capital per w. ht = htLt

◮ After dividing by Lt , we can rewrite the production functionYtLt

= At(KtLt

)α(HtLt

)β(LtLt

)1−α−β as yt = Atkαt hβ

t◮ Hence, by rearranging we get

At = yt

kαt hβ

t

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 18/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Compare At for the 2 production functions 19

◮ Residual for production function with physical capital onlyAt = yt

kαt

◮ Residual for production function with human capitalAt = yt

kαt hβ

t

◮ Difficult to measure β

◮ In data computations below, I used α = β = 0.3

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 19/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

TFP residual, At , across countries: K and H 20

UK, South Korea and India

TFP

(Accounting for Physical and Human Capital)

0.00

200.00

400.00

600.00

800.00

1000.00

1200.00

1400.00

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995

U.K.

Korea

India

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 20/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 6: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

TFP residual, At , across countries: K only 21

UK, South Korea and IndiaTFP

(Accounting for Physical Capital Only)

0.00

200.00

400.00

600.00

800.00

1000.00

1200.00

1400.00

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995

U.K.

Korea

India

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 21/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

TFP ratio: Korea and India relative to U.K. (K only) 22

TFP ratios

(Accounting for Physical Capital Only)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995

TFP Ratio Korea/UK (K only)

TFP Ratio India/UK (K only)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 22/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

TFP ratio: Korea and India relative to U.K. (K and H)23

TFP ratios

(Accounting for Physical and HumanCapital)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995

TFP Ratio Korea/UK (K only)

TFP Ratio India/UK (K only)

TFP Ratio Korea/UK (K and H)

TFP Ratio India/UK (K and H)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 23/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Decomposing GDP per worker growth: K only 24

◮ Now that we have a series for At , we want to decomposegrowth in GDP per worker into growth in the capital stockversus growth in productivity.

◮ Last time, we derived

log yt+1 − log yt = log At+1 − log At + α(

log kt+1 − log kt

)

log yt+1−log ytlog yt+1−log yt

=log At+1−log Atlog yt+1−log yt

+ αlog kt+1−log ktlog yt+1−log yt

1 = 100% =log At+1−log Atlog yt+1−log yt

+ αlog kt+1−log ktlog yt+1−log yt

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 24/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 7: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

UK, Korea and India 25

Growth Accounting with physical capital only

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 25/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Decomposing GDP per worker growth: K and H 26

◮ Now that we have a series for At , we want to decomposegrowth in GDP per worker into growth in the capital stockversus growth in human capital versus growth inproductivity (TFP).

◮ Growth in output per worker is

yt+1yt

=At+1(kt+1)α(ht+1)β

At(kt )α(ht+1)β

yt+1yt

=At+1At

(kt+1kt

)α(ht+1ht

◮ Next, as before we go to logs so we have a sum.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 26/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Decomposing GDP per worker growth: K and H 27

log yt+1 − log yt =

log At+1 − log At + α(

log kt+1 − log kt

)

+ β(

log ht+1 − log ht

)

log yt+1−log ytlog yt+1−log yt

=log At+1−log Atlog yt+1−log yt

+ αlog kt+1−log ktlog yt+1−log yt

+ βlog ht+1−log htlog yt+1−log yt

1 = 100% =log At+1−log Atlog yt+1−log yt

+ αlog kt+1−log ktlog yt+1−log yt

+ βlog ht+1−log htlog yt+1−log yt

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 27/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

UK, Korea and India 28

Growth Accounting with physical and human capital

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 28/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 8: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Summary of Results 29

◮ TFP in the UK > TFP Korea AND India

→ For given inputs output in the UK is higher than in Koreaand India

◮ When accounting for higher educational attainment,differences in TFP are smaller

→ Adding H as input shows that India is not that much lessproductive than the UK; educational attainment (onaverage) is lower

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 29/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Summary of Results 30

◮ GDP growth accounting:

increase in human capital (average years of education)accounts for a major part of growth in India

◮ Hence, omitting human capital in growth accounting canlead to erroneous conclusions

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 30/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Growth Accounting: Objective and Technical FrameworkTFP residualDecomposing growth in GDP per workerResults

Critique 31

◮ Interpretation of TFP?◮ Technological change?◮ Deregulation?◮ Regulation??◮ Why did trend change?

◮ Other factors◮ Human capital? → Done◮ Capital-skill complementarities?◮ Quality of capital?

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 31/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

From Growth Accounting to the Solow Model 32

◮ In growth accounting

→ link of inputs in period t to output in period t→ no link of inputs or output across periods (t versus t + 1)

◮ Solow model links

→ population/labor force, productivity and, in particular,capital stock in year t

to→ labor force, productivity and capital stock in year t + 1

◮ Solow (1956), Solow (1957) and Solow (1960)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 32/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 9: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

From Growth Accounting to the Solow Model 33

◮ Solow’s story about how the capital stock evolves over time

◮ Households save → investment◮ Households save a (constant) fraction s ∈ [0, 1] of their

income every period/year◮ Households consume the rest, i.e., fraction (1 − s) of

income◮ Aggregate income : Yt◮ Aggregate investment = It = sYt

◮ Law of motion of aggregate capital (δ ∈ [0, 1])

Kt+1 = (1 − δ)Kt + It

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 33/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Kaldor facts: Stylized facts of economic growth 34

1. The labor share and the capital share are almost constantover time.

2. The ratio of aggregate capital to output is almost constantover time.

3. The return to capital is almost constant over time.

4. Output per capita and capital per worker grow at a roughlyconstant and positive rate.

5. Different countries and regions within a country that startout with a different level of income per capita tend toconverge over time.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 34/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Understanding growth differences across time andacross countries 35

◮ Why do (developed) countries grow?

◮ Will developing countries catch up to developed countries?

◮ Solow model:a first attempt to explain the mechanics of growth

◮ Implications of Solow’s theory:differences in initial condition, effectiveness of labor andpopulation growth matter

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 35/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Assumptions of the Solow model 36

◮ Assumptions

◮ Inputs: capital, Kt and labor Lt

◮ Production function: neo-classical production function

◮ Depreciation:capital depreciates at rate δ ∈ [0, 1] from t to t + 1

◮ Evolution of technology:At+1 = (1 + g)At ,

◮ Evolution of population (labor force*):Lt+1 = (1 + n)Lt

◮ where δ, g and n are exogenously given parameters

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 36/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 10: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Assumptions of the Solow model 37

◮ Last Assumption

◮ Consumption and savings:

consumers save a constant fraction s of their income, yt ,consume fraction (1 − s) (s parameter)

◮ Per person income is: yt = rtkt + wtℓt

◮ Labor is supplied inelastically & normalized to ℓt = 1

◮ Savings per person are: syt

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 37/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Aggregating consumers 38

◮ Savings per person are: syt = rtkt + wt

◮ Multiplying by the number of people in period t

Aggregate Savings/Investment

= It = Ltsyt = Lts(rtkt + wt) = s(rt Kt + wtLt)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 38/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Firm’s problem (see above) 39

max Π(Kt , AtLt) = max[

F (Kt , ALt) − rtKt − wtLt

]

◮ Firms take prices as given and choose inputs K and L

◮ First order conditions

◮∂Πt∂Kt

= FK (Kt , AtLt ) − rt = 0

◮∂Πt∂Lt

= FL(Kt , At Lt) − wt = 0

◮ Firm picks Kt and Lt such that

◮ FK (Kt , At Lt) = rt

◮ FL(Kt , At Lt ) = wt

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 39/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Law of motion of aggregate capital stock 40

◮ Using the solution to the firm’s problem, we showed that

rtKt + wtLt = F (Kt , AtLt) = Yt (lecture 2)

◮ Using the aggregation over consumers, we saw earlier

It = s(rtKt + wtLt)

◮ Therefore, It = sYt = sF (Kt , AtLt)

◮ Law of motion of aggregate capital

Kt+1 = (1 − δ)Kt + It

◮ Consider Kt+1 as a function of Kt

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 40/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 11: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Law of motion: simple case n = 0 and g = 0 41

◮ Consider Kt+1 as a function of Kt :

Kt+1 = (1 − δ)Kt + It

Kt+1 = (1 − δ)Kt + sYt

Kt+1 = (1 − δ)Kt + sF (Kt , AL)

◮ Since marginal product of K positive,→ law of motion: increasing function

◮ Since marginal product of K diminishing→ law of motion: concave function

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 41/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Solow’s law of motion 42

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

0 10 20 30 40 50K_t

K_

t+1

Kt+1 = Kt (45 degree line)

Kt+1 = (1-delta) Kt + s F(Kt,AL)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 42/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Solow’s law of motion 43

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

0 10 20 30 40 50K_t

K_t+

1

Kt+1 = Kt (45 degree line)

Kt+1 = (1-delta) Kt + s F(Kt,AL)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 43/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Steady state 44

The state variable of this economy is capital Kt

◮ We say that the economy is at a steady state if the statevariable remains constant.

◮ That is capital is constant at K ∗,K ∗ = Kt = Kt+1

◮ Using the C-D production function, we getKt+1 = (1 − δ)Kt + sK α

t (AL)1−α

K ∗ = (1 − δ)K ∗ + s(K ∗)α(AL)1−α

◮ Solving this equation for K ∗ yields*

K ∗ = (sδ )

11−α AL

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 44/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 12: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Comparative statics 45

K ∗ = (sδ )

11−α AL

◮ If s increases, → K ∗ increases *

◮ If δ increases, → K ∗ decreases*

◮ If A increases, → K ∗ increases*

◮ If L increases, → K ∗ increases*

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 45/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Comparative dynamics 46

◮ Suppose the level of the capital stock in some economy(country) at time t is at its steady state level

Kt = K ∗ = (sδ )

11−α AL

◮ That is, there is no more growth, i.e. Kt+1 = Kt .

◮ In t + 1, s suddenly increases to s′ > s,

→ sF (Kt , AL) increases to s′F (Kt , AL)

→ K ∗ increases to K ∗′

> K ∗

◮ On the graph, we can see that now, the economy startsgrowing again, i.e. Kt+2 > Kt+1

◮ ...until the capital stock reaches the new steady state...K ∗′

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 46/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Homework 47

◮ Derive the same reasoning for *

◮ If δ decreases or increases

◮ If A decreases or increases

◮ If N decreases or increases*

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 47/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Balanced growth: n 6= 0 and g 6= 0 48

◮ Evolution of technology:At+1 = (1 + g)At ,

◮ Evolution of population (labour force*):Lt+1 = (1 + n)Lt

◮ Law of motion of aggregate capitalKt+1 = (1 − δ)Kt + sF (Kt , AtLt)

◮ Want to find growth rate of capital per worker, kt = KtLt

and

GDP per capita yt = YtLt

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 48/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 13: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Balanced Growth: Steady state in units of effectivelabour 49

◮ Letyt = Yt

At Ltoutput per unit of effective labour

kt = KtAt Lt

capital per unit of effective labour

◮ Then we can writeytAtLt = Yt

ktAtLt = Kt

◮ Law of motion becomesKt+1 = (1 − δ)Kt + sYt or,kt+1At+1Lt+1 = (1 − δ)kt AtLt + sytAtLt

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 49/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

→ Law of Motion 50

◮ Law of motion becomes

Kt+1 = (1 − δ)Kt + sYt or,

kt+1At+1Lt+1 = (1 − δ)kt AtLt + sytAtLt or,

kt+1(1 + g)At(1 + n)Lt = (1 − δ)kt AtLt + sytAtLt

kt+1(1 + g)(1 + n) = (1 − δ)kt + syt

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 50/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

→ Law of Motion 51

◮ Law of motion for capital per unit of effective labour

kt+1 = 1(1+g)(1+n)

[

(1 − δ)kt + syt

]

◮ Note that yt = YtAt Lt

= F (Kt ,At Lt )At Lt

= kαt

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 51/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Steady state in detrended variables(i.e. per unit of effective labour) 52

◮ Using yt = kαt , law of motion for kt

kt+1 = 1(1+g)(1+n)

[

(1 − δ)kt + skαt

]

◮ Show that kt+1 is an increasing and concave function of kt

if α, δ ∈ [0, 1], g, n ∈ [−1, 1]

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 52/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 14: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Solow’s law of motion (capital per u. of eff. labour) 53

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

0 10 20 30 40 50K_t

K_

t+1

Kt+1 = Kt (45 degree line)

Kt+1 = (1-delta) Kt + s F(Kt,AL)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 53/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Balanced Growth: Per capita/worker var’s 54

◮ Steady state ito capital per u. of eff. labour

kt+1 = 1(1+g)(1+n)

[

(1 − δ)kt + skαt

]

◮ This again can be solved for k∗, the value for which capitalper unit of effective labour does not change anymore, i.e.kt = kt+1 = k∗

* k∗ =(

sg+n+ng+δ

)1

1−α

◮ Higher population growth implies lower level of capitalstock per unit of effective labor in the long run, but growthrate of per capita variables unaffected

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 54/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Capital per worker and GDP per capita 55

◮ When the capital stock per unit of effective labour, kt ,reaches its steady state level k∗, we get:

◮ Growth rate of capital per worker:

kt+1

kt=

Kt+1Lt+1

KtLt

=

At+1Kt+1At+1Lt+1

At KtAt Lt

=At+1k∗

At k∗

= (1 + g)

◮ Growth rate of output per capita:

yt+1

yt=

t+1A1−α

t+1

kαt A1−α

t

=(kt+1

kt

)α(At+1

At

)1−α

= (1 + g)α(1 + g)1−α

= (1 + g)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 55/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Model SetupSteady state (simple case)Balanced Growth (with popul. and prod. growth)

Balanced Growth: Wage and rental rate of capital 56

◮ Growth rate of wages

wt+1

wt=

FK (t + 1)

FK (t)=

(1 − α)K αt+1(At+1Lt+1)

−αAt+1

(1 − α)K αt (AtLt)−αAt

=( k∗

k∗

)α(At+1

At

)

= (1 + g)

◮ Show that the rental rate on capital, rt ,is constant along the BGP

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 56/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 15: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Solow model and Savings Behaviour 57

Recall that in the Solow model

◮ the savings rate was an exogenous constant (parameter)

◮ therefore aggregate investment was a constant fraction ofoutput/aggregate income

Suppose you know that whatever you save, the government willtax at 100% next year. How much would you save versusconsume this year? About nothing – unless you can hide itreally well...

Hence questions such as: What is the effect of capital gainstaxes? cannot seriously be addressed in the Solow model.

However, the Solow model DID teach us that the savings rate isimportant for growth.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 57/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

The Model 58

Income

◮ Consider a household that receives an exogenous flow ofincome in each period of time

◮ We restrict the number of periods to be 2: t and t + 1

◮ Denote income in each period by yt and yt+1

◮ Assume there are perfect financial markets where thehousehold can freely borrow and lend by holding assets ordebt, at+1, at an interest rate r

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 58/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

The Model 59

Preferences

◮ Preferences of the household are defined over sequencesof consumption {ct , ct+1}

◮ We assume that instantaneous utility can be representedby a standard utility function: u(c) [i.e. u(.) is increasing,twice differentiable, concave and satisfies Inadaconditions*]

◮ Life-time utility is the discounted sum of instantaneousutilities → The agent has a subjective rate of timepreference ρ so that the discount factor is 1/(1 + ρ) < 1→ high ρ means impatient→ low ρ means patient

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 59/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

The Model 60

Preferences

◮ Life-time utility is

V (ct , ct+1) = u(ct) +1

1 + ρu(ct+1)

◮ Sometimes we will define β ≡ 11+ρ and write utility as

V (ct , ct+1) = u(ct) + βu(ct + 1)

β is the discount factor

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 60/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 16: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

The Model 61

Budget constraint

◮ The agent faces two period-by-period constraints

ct + at+1 = yt

ct+1 = yt+1 + (1 + r)at+1

◮ The assumption of perfect financial markets means thatconsumption is not restricted to equal income

◮ Agent can allocate consumption in many different ways

◮ In fact, he faces a single constraint:

the intertemporal budget constraint

◮ It follows from aggregating over time as follows:

ct + 11+r ct+1 = yt + 1

1+r yt+1Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 61/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

The Model 62

Budget constraint

◮ It follows from aggregating over time that:

ct + 11+r ct+1 = yt + 1

1+r yt+1

◮ In other words, the present value of consumption cannotexceed the present value of income (or wealth)

◮ This can be represented graphically*

◮ Only at the point corresponding to the endowment, saving(borrowing (-) or lending (+)) is zero

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 62/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Household’s optimization problem 63

Given yt , yt+1 and r

maxct ,ct+1

u(ct) + βu(ct+1)

s.t. ct +1

1 + rct+1 = yt +

11 + r

yt+1

or, equivalently,

maxct ,ct+1

u(ct) + βu(ct+1)

s.t. ct + at+1 = yt

ct+1 = (1 + r)at+1 + yt+1

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 63/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Solution to the optimization problem 64

Graphical solution*

◮ Using the first formulation, the problem and the solutioncan be represented in the typical indifference-curvediagram on the (ct , ct+1) - space

◮ The optimal choice is characterized by the allocation wherethe intertemporal budget constraint (with slope −(1 + r)) istangent to an indifference curve

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 64/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 17: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Solution to the optimization problem 65

Analytical solution

◮ This solution is characterized by a FOC and the budgetconstraint (2 equations for 2 unknowns (ct , ct+1))

◮ The FOC reads,

u′(ct) =1 + r1 + ρ

u′(ct+1)

= β(1 + r)u′(ct+1)

◮ This is called the Euler equation

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 65/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Consumption smoothing 66

◮ The FOC implies that the change in consumption over timedepends entirely on the form of the utility function, u(.), ρand r

◮ The time-profile of income does not matter for thetime-profile of consumption (holding present value oflife-time income fixed)

◮ The present value of income is only important indetermining the level consumption in the two periods, butnot the steepness of the consumption path

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 66/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Consumption smoothing 67

◮ Consider in particular the situation where interest rateequals the rate of time preference: r = ρ

◮ In this case, consumption is the same in the two periodseven if income is not

◮ This captures the implication of concave utility functions forconsumption: agents tend to prefer smooth consumptionpaths

◮ They can do that because they can borrow and lend

◮ To see more specifically how the interest rate can alter theoptimal path of consumption, it proves convenient to use aspecific yet fairly general form for the utility function...

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 67/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Constant-elasticity-of-substitution utility 68

◮ We use the following,

u(c) =c1−σ

1 − σif σ 6= 1

= log c if σ = 1

◮ It turns out that σ determines the household’s willingnessto shift consumption across periods:→ the smaller is σ,→ the more slowly marginal utility ↓ as consumption ↑→ the more willing is the household to allow itsconsumption to vary over time (if r differs from ρ)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 68/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 18: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Constant-elasticity-of-substitution utility 69

◮ This can be seen from the FOC,

u′(ct ) =1 + r1 + ρ

u′(ct+1)

◮ Using the CES utility function*,

ct+1

ct=

(1 + r1 + ρ

)1σ

◮ If σ is close to zero, then utility is close to linear and thehousehold is willing to accept large swings in consumptionto take advantage of small differences between ρ and r

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 69/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Constant-elasticity-of-substitution utility 70

◮ In fact the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, IES, isclosely related to σ

◮ The IES is defined as

θ(c) = − u′(c)u′′(c)c

◮ This is essentially a measure of the curvature of the utilityfunctions and, therefore, of the willingness to acceptswings in consumption over time

◮ With the CES utility function, the IES becomes*

θ(c) = − u′(c)u′′(c)c = 1/σ

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 70/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Constant-elasticity-of-substitution utility 71

◮ With the CES utility function, the IES becomes*

θ(c) = − u′(c)u′′(c)c = 1/σ

◮ That is σ is the inverse of θ: θ = 1/σ

◮ Since σ is constant, θ is constant and u(.) is said to be ofCES type

◮ Note that with uncertainty σ characterizes the degree ofrisk-aversion and this type of utility functions are alsoknown as constant-relative-risk-aversion (CRRA) utilityfunctions (see that later)

◮ Clearly, θ = 1/σ determines the responsiveness of theslope of the consumption path to changes in the interestrate

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 71/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Intertemporal-substitution and wealth effects 72

Intertemporal substitution and r

◮ θ = 1/σ determines the responsiveness of the slope of theconsumption path to changes in the interest rate

◮ Higher r implies that optimal consumption grows fasterover time

◮ This does not depend on the time path of income

◮ This is the intertemporal-substitution effect of a change inthe interest rate → (1 + r) is just the relative price of ct interms of ct+1

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 72/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 19: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Intertemporal-substitution and wealth effects 73

Intertemporal substitution and r

◮ Thus intertemporal substitution is the standard substitutioneffect when the relative price of two commodities changes

◮ This effect of an increase in r tends to increase savinga = yt − ct

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 73/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Intertemporal-substitution and wealth effects 74

Wealth effect and r

◮ But, as usual, there is also a wealth effect

◮ Here, it is useful to draw the indifference-curve diagram

◮ If initially saving is zero, then the wealth effect is nil and thesubstitution effect dictates an increase in saving

◮ If initially the household is borrowing, both the wealth andsubstitution effects go in the direction of increasing saving(or reducing borrowing)

◮ If the household is initially saving, then the wealth effecttends to reduce saving and the net effect is ambiguous

◮ Follow graphical analysis and discussion in D.Romer(1996,p325-327)].

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 74/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Intertemporal-substitution and wealth effects 75

Savings is a = yt − ct

Suppose r increases

◮ Substitution effect ⇒ a ↑

◮ Income effect ⇒ a ?

◮ If initially a = 0, no wealth effect ⇒ a ↑

◮ If initially a > 0, positive wealth effect ⇒ a ?

◮ If initially a < 0, negative wealth effect ⇒ a ↑

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 75/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Capital gains taxes in the two-period model 76

Budget constraint

◮ The agent faces two period-by-period constraints

ct + at+1 = yt

ct+1 = yt+1 + (1 + r(1 − τ))at+1

◮ The intertemporal budget constraint

ct + 11+r(1−τ)ct+1 = yt + 1

1+r(1−τ)yt+1

Note: preferences unchanged → optimal choice may changebecause the budget set and relative price of consumption in tversus t + 1 changes.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 76/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 20: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Household’s optimization problem with taxes 77

Given yt , yt+1, r and τ

maxct ,ct+1

u(ct) + βu(ct+1)

s.t. ct +1

1 + (1 − τ)rct+1 = yt +

11 + (1 − τ)r

yt+1

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 77/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Preferences, Budget constraint, Optimal choiceConsumption smoothingIntertemporal-substitution and wealth effectsTaxes in the two-period model

Euler equation with taxes 78

Euler equation with capital-gains tax

ct+1

ct=

(1 + r(1 − τ)

1 + ρ

)1σ

Let r = (1 − τ)r denote the after tax interest rate(effective interest rate)

→ Higher tax rate, τ , implies lower effective interest rate, r

→ Increasing taxes affects consumers in the same way asa decrease in the interest rate(substitution of consumption from t + 1 to t & wealth effect)

Side question: In light of the Solow model for example, shouldwe increase or decrease taxes?

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 78/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

The Ramsey Model 79

Main Ingredients

◮ Neoclassical model of the firm

◮ Consumption-savings choice for consumers

◮ “Solow model + incentives to save”

(recall example with taxes)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 79/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

The Model 80

Markets and ownership

Agents◮ Firms produce goods, hire labor and rent capital◮ Households own labor and assets (capital),

receive wages and rental payments, consume and save

Markets◮ Inputs: competitive wage rates, w , and rental rate, R◮ Assets: free borrowing and lending at interest rate, r◮ Output: competitive market for consumption good

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 80/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 21: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

The Model 81

Firms / Representative Firm

Seeks to maximize profits

Profit = F (K , L) − RK − wL

The FOCs for this problem deliver

∂F∂K

= R∂F∂L

= w

In per unit of labor terms, let f (k) ≡ F (k , 1)

f ′(k) = R f (k) − kf ′(k) = w

Recall Euler’s Theorem: factor payments exhaust outputLecture 1, Exogenous Growth 81/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

The Model 82

Households / Representative household

Preferences

U0 =

∞∑

t=0

βtu(ct)

Budget constraint

ct + at+1 = wt + (1 + r)at ,

for all t = 0, 1, 2, ...

a0 given

Note: labor supplied inelastically, lt = 1

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 82/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

The Model 83

Households / Representative household

Intertemporal version of budget constraint

∞∑

t=0

t∏

s=0

(

11 + rs

)

ct = a0 +

∞∑

t=0

t∏

s=0

(

11 + rs

)

wt

We rule out that debt explodes (no Ponzi games)

at+1 ≥ −B for some B big, but finite

More compactly, PDV (c) = a(0) + PDV (w)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 83/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

The Model 84

Household’s problem

max(at+1,ct )

t=0

∞∑

t=0

βtu(ct)

s.t.

ct + at+1 = wt + (1 + r)at , for all t = 0, 1, 2, ...

at+1 = −B for some B big, but finite

a0 given

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 84/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 22: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

The Model 85

Euler equationIn general,

u′(ct) = β(1 + rt+1)u′(ct+1)

From here on, CES utility, u(c) = c1−σ

1−σ , Euler eqn. becomes,

(

ct+1

ct

= β(1 + rt+1)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 85/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

The Model 86

Transversality conditionHH do not want to “end up” with positive values of assets

limt→∞

βtu′(ct)at ≥ 0

HH cannot think they can borrow at the “end of their life”

limt→∞

βtu′(ct)at ≤ 0

Hence,

limt→∞

βtu′(ct)at = 0

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 86/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Definition of Equilibrium 87

A competitive equilibrium is defined by sequences of quantitiesof consumption, {ct}, capital, {kt}, and output, {yt}, andsequences of prices, {wt} and {rt}, such that

◮ Firms maximize profits

◮ Households maximize U0 subject to their constraints

◮ Goods, labour and asset markets clear

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 87/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Characterizing Equilibrium Quantities* 88

kt+1 + ct = f (kt) + (1 − δ)kt

ct+1

ct= [β(1 + f ′(kt+1) − δ)]1/σ

limt→∞

βtu′(ct )kt = 0

k0 > 0

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 88/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 23: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Characterizing Equilibrium Quantities* 89

From the equilibrium conditions derived before, we find:

◮ There cannot be arbitrage opportunities in equilibrium

Rt − δ = rt

In equilibrium it does not pay to invest in capital directly.The riskless asset and capital have the same payoff.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 89/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Characterizing Equilibrium Quantities* 90

From the equilibrium conditions derived before, we find:

◮ Substituting out all the prices leads to the following set ofnecessary and sufficient conditions for an equilibrium interms of quantities only.

kt+1 + ct = f (kt) + (1 − δ)kt

ct+1

ct= [β(1 + f ′(kt+1) − δ)]1/σ

limt→∞

βtu′(ct )kt = 0

k0 > 0

Prices can be determined from the firm’s problems FOCs.Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 90/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Benevolent planner’s problem* 91

What is the allocation of resources that an economy shouldfeature in order to attain the highest feasible level of utility?

Central Planner’s optimal choice problem

max(kt+1,ct)

t=0

∞∑

t=0

βtu(ct)

s.t.

ct + kt+1 = f (kt) + (1 − δ)kt , for all t = 0, 1, 2, ...

k0 > 0 given

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 91/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Benevolent planner’s problem 92

Welfare

Socially optimal allocation coincides with the equilibriumallocation.

The competitive equilibrium leads to the social optimum.

Not surprising: no distortions or externalities→ Welfare Theorems hold

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 92/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 24: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Notes: simplifying features* 93

◮ We are considering an economy without population growth.

◮ There is no exogenous technological change, either.

We include these two at the end of these notes.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 93/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Steady state* 94

Definition

A balanced growth path (BGP) is a situation in which output,capital and consumption grow at a constant rate.

If this constant rate is zero, it is called a steady state.

We can usually redefine the state variable so that the latter isconstant (i.e. the growth rate is zero)

Recall from the Solow model:

capital per unit of labor for (n > 0, g = 0)capital per unit of effective labor for (n > 0, g > 0)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 94/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Steady state 95

From the Euler equation,

ct+1

ct= [β(1 + f ′(kt+1) − δ)]1/σ , for all t

If consumption grows at a constant rate (BGP), say γ

1 + γ = [β(1 + f ′(kt+1) − δ)]1/σ , for all t

Thus RHS must be constant→ kt+1 = kt = k∗ must be constant along the BGP

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 95/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Steady state 96

But then, from the resource constraint with kt = kt+1 = k∗:

ct + kt+1 = f (kt) + (1 − δ)kt , for all t

i.e.,ct = f (k∗) − δk∗

ct+1 = f (k∗) − δk∗

We find that consumption must be constant along the BGP,→ ct+1 = ct = c∗ or γ = 0

Hence we have a steady state in per capita variables.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 96/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 25: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Steady state* 97

Hence from the Euler equation

1 + γ = 1 = [β(1 + f ′(k∗) − δ)]1/σ

or, simplified

f ′(k∗) =1β− (1 − δ) = ρ + δ

we can solve for k∗and from the (simplified) resource constraint

c∗ = f (k∗) − δk∗

we can solve for c∗

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 97/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Modified golden rule* 98

The capital stock that maximizes utility in steady state is calledthe modified golden rule level of capital

f ′(k∗) = ρ + δ

Using f (k) = kα, we get

k∗ = kMGR =

[

α

ρ + δ

]1

1−α

Compare to golden rule level of capital(max conso in st. st.)

kGR =[α

δ

]1

1−α

(see Problem set 1, Q 3.3, assume A = 1 and set s = α (from Q 3.4))Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 98/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Modified golden rule 99

Since ρ > 0 and α ∈ (0, 1),

kMGR =

[

α

ρ + δ

]1

1−α

<[α

δ

]1

1−α= kGR

This result reflects the impatience of agents.

As long as ρ > 0, they’d always prefer to consume earlier ratherthan later, thereby reducing investments for next period andhence the steady state level of capital (and consumption)!

One of Ramsey’s points was that this is the steady state that weshould aim at because it makes people the happiest - not theone that maximizes consumption per se.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 99/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Off steady state dynamics* 100

Off the steady state, consumption and capital adjust to reachthe steady state eventually.

To analyze these dynamics, consider the movements of c and kseparately.

Let ∆c = ct+1 − ct and ∆k = kt+1 − kt . See graphical analysis.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 100/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Page 26: Growth Theory: Review - Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth · Growth Theory: Review Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2 April 20, 2007 Lecture 1, Exogenous

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Off steady state dynamics* 101

◮ Consider the set of points such that ∆c = 0, then from theEuler eqn, the optimal k satisfies f ′(k) = ρ + δ

→ draw vertical line at k∗(< kGR)

To the left: kt < k∗ ⇒ f ′(kt) > f ′(k∗) ⇒ ∆c > 0 ⇒ c ↑To the right: kt > k∗ ⇒ f ′(kt) < f ′(k∗) ⇒ ∆c < 0 ⇒ c ↓

◮ Consider the set of points such that ∆k = 0, then from theResource cstrt, the optimal c satisfies c = f (k) − δk

→ draw hump-shaped line from origin, maximized at kGR

cross 0 again for k such that f (k) = δk

Above: ct > f (kt) − δkt ⇒ ∆k = f (kt ) − δkt − ct < 0 ⇒ k ↓Below: ct < f (kt) − δkt ⇒ ∆k = f (kt) − δkt − ct > 0 ⇒ k ↑

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 101/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Adding population and productivity growth 102

◮ Evolution of technology:At+1 = (1 + g)At ,

◮ Evolution of population (labour force*):Lt+1 = (1 + n)Lt

◮ Resource constraint in units of effective labourct + (1 + n)(1 + g)kt+1 = (1 − δ)kt + f (kt)

◮ Euler equation in units of effective labour becomes

ct+1ct

=[β(1+f ′(kt+1)−δ)]

(1+n)(1+g)

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 102/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2

Growth AccountingThe Solow Model

Savings behaviourThe Ramsey Model

Main Ingredients of the ModelDefinition of EquilibriumCharacterizing Equilibrium QuantitiesSteady state and Dynamics

Balanced Growth: St. state in units of effective labour103

◮ In steady state:ct+1ct

= 1 and kt+1

kt= 1

◮ Solving the Euler Equation for k∗ gives

k∗ =

[

βα

((1 + n)(1 + g))σ − (1 − δ)β

]

decreasing in population growth rate. But long run growthrates of per capita variables are independent of n

◮ Thus, in terms of population growth rates, Ramsey modelgives same conclusions as Solow model.

Lecture 1, Exogenous Growth 103/103 Economic Policy in Development 2, Part 2