Top Banner

of 21

Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

Apr 05, 2018

Download

Documents

Wan Nj
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    1/21

    The Australian Economic Review, vol. 40, no. 1, pp. 323

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    Published by Blackwell Publishing Asia Pty Ltd

    1. Introduction

    The global economy is suffering from seriousimbalances characterised by a deterioration of

    the US current account deficit, rapid increases

    in oil and raw material prices and excessive in-

    ternational liquidity. At the same time, the Chi-

    nese economy is suffering from serious

    imbalances of another kind, which is character-

    ised by rapid increases in the so-called twin

    surpluses (current account and capital account

    surpluses), persistence of excessive invest-

    ment, acute energy shortages and deterioration

    of the environment and the rapid widening of

    income gaps, while the economy is growing at

    breakneck speed. This article deals with

    Chinas adjustment of growth strategy in an en-

    vironment of global imbalances. Section 2 pro-

    vides a brief account of global imbalances,

    especially the US current account deficit and

    its causes and possible consequences. Section 3

    discusses the causes of the Asian current ac-

    count surplus. It is pointed out that there is no

    guarantee that Asian economies will continue

    to run current account surpluses so as to con-

    tinue to finance the US current account deficit.

    Section 4 discusses Chinas twin surpluses in

    detail and argues that persistently running acurrent account surplus is neither sustainable

    nor desirable for China. As a result, correction

    will be made by China, no matter what the

    United States does with its current account def-

    icit. Section 5 discusses policies that have al-ready been adopted or may be adopted by the

    Chinese government to address Chinas imbal-

    ances. Concluding remarks are presented in the

    last section.

    2. The Global Imbalances

    The Bureau of Economic Analysis of the

    United States announced on 14 March 2006

    that the US deficit reached 7 per cent of Gross

    Domestic Product (GDP) in 2005, with a cur-

    rent account deficit of $805 billion, an increase

    of $137 billion or 20 per cent over 2004. The

    deficit is expected to increase further in the fu-

    ture, due to growing consumer demand for im-

    ports, and rapid growth in interest payments to

    foreign holders of US government securities.

    Rapidly rising oil prices and imports explain

    about two-thirds of the increase. But US trade

    deficits increased with every major region of

    the world, including China (34 per cent),

    OPEC (18 per cent), Africa (15 per cent), Eu-

    rope (15 per cent), Mexico and Canada (13 per

    cent combined), Latin America (12 per cent),

    and all Asian countries besides China (5 percent). Of course, the largest increase was with

    China, from whom the United States does not

    import oil (see Scott 2006).

    There is nothing new with the US current ac-

    count deficit. The United States has run a cur-

    rent account deficit for 24 consecutive years,

    except for 1990. The rapid increase in the US

    current account deficit finally caused alarm in

    the second quarter of 2002. As a result, the US

    Global Imbalances and China

    Yu Yongding*Institute of World Economics and PoliticsChinese Academy of Social Sciences

    * This paper is the revised text of the David Finch Memo-

    rial Lecture which was delivered at the University of Mel-

    bourne on 17 October 2006.

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    2/21

    4 The Australian Economic Review March 2007

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    dollar began its strategic devaluation. Al-

    though the US dollar has fallen 11 per cent

    since then, this decline has failed to slow the in-crease in the trade deficit, let alone to correct

    the current account deficit. However, to the

    surprise of most economists, despite the further

    worsening of the current account deficit, the

    US dollar appreciated against other major cur-

    rencies in 2005. Although starting from early

    2006, the US dollar began descending again,

    nobody is quite sure whether this will continue,

    and what the direction of the development of

    the US current account deficit will be in the

    near future.

    Should we worry about the economic and fi-nancial risks that arise from the US current ac-

    count deficit? Canadas current account deficit

    averaged 2.5 per cent of GDP between 1975

    and 1998; the UK current account deficit aver-

    aged 4.1 per cent of GDP between 1984 and

    2003; and Australias current account deficit

    averaged 4.1 per cent of GDP between 1974

    and 2003 (see Royal Bank of Scotland Group

    2004). As long as international investors be-

    lieve that the deficit countries can provide a

    higher or safer return for their investment than

    in other places, capital will continue to flow

    into those countries to finance their current ac-

    count deficits. However, following the accu-

    mulation of current account deficits (that is, the

    increase in foreign debt), other things being

    equal, foreign investors will demand a higher

    return for their investment. If the demand is not

    met, they may stop financing the current ac-

    count deficit. An indefinitely large negative net

    international investment position (NIIP) as a

    percentage of GDP is inconsistent with long-

    run equilibrium. So, the key questions are as

    follows. What is the trajectory of the US NIIP

    GDP ratio? Beyond what level of the NIIP as apercentage of GDP will the NIIP no longer be

    sustainable and hence a correction of the cur-

    rent account deficit occur?

    In historical terms:

    Australias negative net investment position

    reached 60 percent of GDP in the mid-1990s, Ire-

    lands exceeded 70 percent in the 1980s, and New

    Zealand accumulated a position amounting to

    nearly 90 percent of GDP in the late 1990s. Nota-

    bly, these economies have recently been among

    the most successfulin terms of economic

    growthin the industrialized world.

    [Poole 2005]

    Since the later 1980s, as a result of the accumu-

    lation of current account deficits, the US NIIP

    GDP ratio has been increasing steadily, and by

    the end of 2005, it reached 25 per cent of US

    GDP. The trajectory of the NIIPGDP ratio canbe depicted by a simple differential equation:

    z

    = + C

    1

    e

    nt

    (1)

    where z

    is the NIIPGDP ratio, ca

    is the CA

    (current account deficit)GDP ratio, and n

    is

    the growth rate of GDP. According to a simu-

    lation made by one of my students (Sheng

    2005), assume that, starting from 2003, we

    have the following initial conditions: t

    = 0,

    NIIPGDPz

    (0) = 24.09 per cent, ca = constant

    = 4.82 per cent, and the nominal growth rate of

    GDP = constant = 4.9 per cent. The corre-

    sponding specific solution is (Sheng 2005):

    f

    = 0.98 0.74

    e

    0.049

    t

    (2)

    From the above equation, two conclusions

    can be drawn. First, other things being equal,

    the US NIIPGDP ratio will stabilise at a level

    something like 80 per cent. The steady state is

    decided by the current account deficitGDP

    ratio divided by the growth rate of nominal

    GDP. Second, there is still a long way to go for

    the NIIPGDP ratio to reach the steady state(Table 1). The real problem is whether the ex-

    ternal finance will be forthcoming, while the

    NIIPGDP ratio is on its way to the steady

    ca

    n------

    Table 1 A Simulation of the US NIIPGDP Ratio, 20032010

    2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

    Years passed 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

    NIIPGDP ratio (per cent) 24.09 27.54 30.91 34.12 37.17 40.08 42.85 45.49

    Source

    : Sheng (2005).

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    3/21

    Yu: Global Imbalances and China 5

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    state. Nobody seems quite sure about the an-

    swer. It is likely that at a certain level, before

    the NIIPGDP ratio has reached the steadystate, foreign investors will stop financing the

    US current account deficit so as to trigger a

    dramatic correction.

    It seems that whether the rest of the world

    will continue to finance the US current account

    deficit is an equally important issue to whether

    the United States will reduce its investment-

    saving gap and take firm actions to reduce its

    current account deficit. The sources of capital

    inflows to the United States have been EastAsiaJapan and China in particularoil-

    exporting countries and some other parts of the

    world. According to Bernanke (2005), the

    cause of the US current account deficit is the

    saving glut in the rest of world. No matter

    whether this argument holds water, the sus-

    tainability of the US current account deficit

    Table 2 Global Current Account Balances, 1996, 2000 and 2004

    (US$billion)

    Countries 1996 2000 2004

    Industrial 41.5 331.4 400.3

    United States 120.2 413.4 665.9

    Japan 65.7 119.6 171.8

    Euro area

    a

    78.5 71.7 53.0

    France 20.5 18.3 5.1

    Germany 14.1 29.3 104.3

    Italy 39.6 5.7 13.7

    Spain 0.5 19.3 49.4

    Other 17.5 34.2 40.8

    Australia 15.8 15.4 39.6

    Canada 3.4 19.6 25.9

    Switzerland

    b

    21.3 30.6 46.0

    United Kingdom 10.8 36.2 46.9

    Developing

    b

    90.4 131.2 326.4

    Asia

    b

    40.6 86.8 179.5

    China

    b

    7.2 20.5 55.5

    Hong Kong 2.6 7.1 16.0

    Korea 23.1 12.3 27.6

    Taiwan 10.9 8.9 19.0

    Thailand 14.4 9.3 7.3

    Latin America

    b

    39.4 47.9 8.5

    Argentina 6.8 9.0 3.0Brazil 23.2 24.2 11.7

    Mexico 2.5 18.5 8.6

    Middle East and Africa

    b

    1.1 74.5 116.4

    Europe and the former Soviet Union

    b

    13.5 16.8 12.0

    Statistical discrepancy 48.9 200.2 73.9

    Notes

    : (a) Figures for 2000 and 2004 are taken from the European Central Banks Monthly Bulletin

    (various issues) and

    converted to dollars. The figure for 1996 is calculated as the sum of the member country current accounts.

    (b) The figure for 2004 is taken from the International Monetary Funds World Economic Outlook

    (April 2005).

    Source

    : Bernanke (2005).

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    4/21

    6 The Australian Economic Review March 2007

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    depends on the availability and sustainability

    of foreign capital inflows into the United States

    (Table 2).It can be seen that the bulk of the increase in

    the US current account deficit was balanced by

    changes in the current account positions of de-

    veloping countries. Among these developing

    countries, China was the most important, ac-

    counting for a sixth of the total. Developed

    countries made similar contributions. The oil

    exporters, notably the Middle East but also

    countries such as Russia, Nigeria and Venezu-

    ela, constituted the third group of important

    capital-exporting countries (Bernanke 2005).

    Will the saving glut in these three groups ofcountries continue? Will the excess savings of

    these three groups of countries continue to flow

    into the United States? China aside, East Asian

    emerging economies saving glut and current

    account surpluses are related to the aftermath

    of the Asian financial crisis. With regard to

    East Asian countries (excluding Japans) cur-

    rent account surpluses, a more detailed discus-

    sion will be given in the next section. It will be

    shown that these surpluses are likely to disap-

    pear in the near future. Developed countries,

    especially Japans and Germanys, saving glut

    is attributable to aging populations, which

    must make provision for an impending sharp

    increase in the number of retirees relative to the

    number of workers (Bernanke 2005, p. 5). It

    seems that as long as the United States can

    maintain a relatively fast rate of productivity

    growth and hence a higher interest rate, capital

    from developed countries that are ageing will

    continue to flow into the United States, until

    the dependency ratios have become so high

    that the saving rates have to drop significantly.

    In other words, Japans and Germanys current

    account surpluses may last longer than those ofEast Asian emerging economies. Oil-exporting

    countries current account surpluses are more

    likely to be temporary. When oil prices drop,

    the current account surpluses will drop. Over

    the past three decades, we have seen many such

    ups and downs. Furthermore, for some coun-

    tries, such as Arabic countries, the United

    States will no longer be a safe haven for their

    oil money and they may find other places to in-

    vest their oil revenues.

    For many US economists as well as govern-

    ment officials, the real danger does not lie in

    the US current account deficit per se, but in theperception of the deficit. Hence, for the United

    States, the foremost danger perhaps is the pos-

    sibility that owing to the waning confidence in

    the sustainability of the US current account

    deficit, Asian central banks will diversify their

    foreign reserves away from the dollar assets in

    a disorderly manner. The direct consequence of

    the increase in the US current account deficit is

    largely psychological.

    The larger the current account deficit becomes,

    the greater the number of observers who believe

    that a correction, and one with significant impli-

    cations for the U.S. economy, is imminent. Such

    expectations have contributed to, and in turn have

    been reinforced by, the slide in the dollar over the

    past few years.

    [Ferguson 2005]

    For these US officials and economists, a dra-

    matic correction of the US current account def-

    icit is not only unwarranted but also unlikely.

    For the United States, unlike almost every other

    country in the world, a hard-landing process is

    inherently self-limiting. U.S. assets owned byinternational investors are predominantly denom-

    inated in dollars and a large fraction of U.S. assets

    held abroad are denominated in foreign curren-

    cies. Dollar depreciation, should it occur in a

    hard-landing process, will be self-limiting be-

    cause the dollar value of U.S. assets abroad will

    rise, thus improving the U.S. net international in-

    vestment position. Market participants, knowing

    this fact, are therefore unlikely to drive down the

    foreign currency value of the dollar in a rapid and

    disruptive fashion.

    [Poole 2005]

    As a matter of fact, after the breakdown ofthe Bretton Woods system, a dramatic fall in

    the US dollar occurred several times in the

    middle of the 1980s and 1990s, as well as

    smaller falls. It is likely that East Asian coun-

    tries may no longer wish to continue to run

    current account surpluses and accumulate more

    foreign exchange reserves in the form of trea-

    sury bills and other US assets. It has become in-

    creasingly obvious that a further increase in

    their foreign exchange reserves means further

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    5/21

    Yu: Global Imbalances and China 7

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004-30000

    -20000

    -10000

    0

    10000

    20000

    30000

    40000

    50000 Current account

    Capital account

    1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005

    -20000

    -15000

    -10000

    -5000

    0

    5000

    10000

    15000

    20000

    25000Current account

    Capital account

    losses in their national welfare. Faced with a

    sort of prisoners dilemma, a free fall of the US

    dollar, due to coordination failure, cannot beruled out entirely.

    3. Why Asian Countries Run Current

    Account Surpluses

    From a very interesting perspective, Dooley,

    Folkerts-Landau and Garber (hereafter DFG)

    put forward a theory arguing that, in the next

    decade or two, Asian countries will continue to

    finance the US current account deficit happily,

    because Asian countries need to run trade sur-pluses against the United States so as to solve

    their employment problems. According to

    DFG (2003):

    In the Bretton Woods system of the 1950s, the

    US was the center region with essentially un-

    controlled capital and goods markets. Europe

    and Japan, whose capital had been destroyed by

    the war, constituted the emerging periphery. The

    Source

    : International Monetary Fund (2006).

    Figure 1 Koreas Current and Capital Accounts

    US$million

    Year

    Figure 2 Thailands Current and Capital Accounts

    US$million

    Year

    Source

    : International Monetary Fund (2006).

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    6/21

    8 The Australian Economic Review March 2007

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004-10000

    -5000

    0

    5000

    10000

    15000

    20000 Current account

    Capital account

    1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003

    -15000

    -10000

    -5000

    0

    5000

    10000

    15000Current account

    Capital account

    periphery countries chose a development strat-

    egy of undervalued currencies, controls on capi-

    tal flows and trade, reserve accumulation, andthe use of the center region as a financial inter-

    mediary that lent credibility to their own finan-

    cial systems. In turn, the US lent long term to

    the periphery, generally through FDI Now

    the Asian periphery has reached a similar

    weight

    Is this what has been happening in Asia? Facts

    speak for themselves. Let us check the dynam-

    ics of the current account balances of the major

    Asian economies.

    The first fact is that East Asian countries didnot chronically run current account surpluses.

    The US current account deficit has a history of

    more than two decades. In contrast, the Asian

    current account surplus is a relatively new phe-

    nomenon. Although East Asian countries have

    high savings, the propensity for investment in

    these countries is even higher. All four finan-

    cial crisis-affected countries (Korea, Thailand,

    Figure 4 Indonesias Current and Capital Accounts

    US$million

    Year

    Source

    : International Monetary Fund (2006).

    Figure 3 Malaysias Current and Capital Accounts

    US$million

    Year

    Source

    : International Monetary Fund (2006).

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    7/21

    Yu: Global Imbalances and China 9

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005

    -150

    -100

    -50

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200Current account

    Capital account

    Malaysia and Indonesia) ran big current ac-

    count deficits for a long time before the Asian

    financial crisis. Only after the Asian financialcrisis have all these four countries begun to run

    current account surpluses (see Figures 1, 2, 3

    and 4). It is obvious that the saving glut is

    both a cause and effect of the increase in

    the current account surpluses. Crisis-affected

    Asian countries were forced to run twin sur-

    pluses (capital account and current account sur-

    pluses) after the financial crisis to build up their

    foreign exchange reserves. The current account

    surpluses in these economies are achieved by

    significant devaluation and tight monetary and

    fiscal policies. There is nothing inherent inthese economies that predetermines that these

    countries must run current account surpluses. It

    is highly unlikely that these countries will con-

    tinue to build up their foreign exchange re-

    serves, after the reserves have reached a certain

    level or a proportion of GDP. What has hap-

    pened in Thailand recently is a case in point

    (Figure 2). In short, it is difficult to draw a firm

    conclusion on whether the saving glut of East

    Asian economies will persist and whether the

    United States will continue to be the only recip-

    ient of these surplus funds.

    The second fact is that Japanthe most im-

    portant surplus country in Asiais an outlier

    in Asia. It is an advanced country; it has run a

    current account surplus every year since the

    early 1980s (Figure 5), no matter what has

    happened to the Japanese economy. In 2004,while Chinas current account surplus ac-

    counted for 20 per cent of the US current ac-

    count deficit with Asia, Japan accounted for 48

    per cent.

    1

    Certainly, the DFG hypothesis is ir-

    relevant to Japan. Hence, at least a half of the

    Asian current account surplus against the

    United States is left unexplained by the DFG

    theory. I believe that the current account sur-

    plus is more intrinsic in nature in Japan than in

    any other Asian country. Following the recov-

    ery of the Japanese economy, the Japanese

    trade surplus may reoccupy the central stage inthe US current account deficit fray in the near

    future.

    The third fact is that Chinas running of a

    large trade surplus is a relatively new phenom-

    enon. While Japan has been running a trade

    surplus of more than US$100 billion since the

    early 1990s, China ran a small trade account

    surplus, averaging US$10 billion annually.

    Chinas trade surplus peaked in 1997, surpass-

    ing US$30 billion. After the Asian financial

    crisis, it fell back conspicuously. Before late

    2002, the renminbis (RMBs) overvaluation

    rather than undervaluation was the mot du jour

    .

    Chinas trade account surplus has surged since

    2003. It surpassed US$102 billion in 2005.

    Figure 5 Japans Current and Capital Accounts

    US$billion

    Year

    Source

    : International Monetary Fund (2006).

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    8/21

    10 The Australian Economic Review March 2007

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    However, few people in China are sure

    whether Chinas current account surplus is a

    long-term phenomenon, and even fewer peopleare sure whether running a large current ac-

    count surplus is desirable for China. In fact, ac-

    cording to the eleventh five-year program

    formulated by the National Reform and Devel-

    opment Commission, formerly the State Plan-

    ning Commission, in the next five years,

    Chinas aim is to run a basically balanced

    current account.

    Based on the above observations, it can be

    said that the DFG hypothesis is too simplistic

    and the generalisation is too hasty. There is

    nothing intrinsic that will guarantee that Asiancountries will continuously finance the US cur-

    rent account deficit by running current account

    surpluses. Of course, there may be exceptions,

    among the exceptional economiesJapan

    rather than China is the most obvious candi-

    date.

    4. Chinas Twin Surpluses

    It is assumed in development economics that

    developing countries should run current ac-

    count deficits and capital account surpluses, so

    as to utilise foreign saving to obtain an invest-

    ment rate higher than their domestic saving ratecan support (see Figure 6).

    In Figure 6, the vertical axis and horizontal

    axis represent resources (domestic saving and

    domestic investment) and the period of devel-

    opment; II is investment; SS is savings; BR is

    the trade deficit; BB is the current account def-

    icit (old definition); and BD is the foreign debt

    balance.

    A developing country that borrows from

    abroad should first run a trade deficit and cur-

    rent account deficit (in periods I and II). After

    becoming a matured country, it will reduce itsdebt liability (in period III). Finally, it becomes

    a country with a positive NIIP (in period IV).

    However, China has a very different pattern

    of international balance of payments. Although

    as a developing country, with a very large cap-

    ital account surplus for every year since the

    early 1980s,

    2

    China started running a current

    account surplus consistently since the early

    1990s (Figure 7). The persistent twin sur-

    pluses have resulted in the continuous increase

    in foreign exchange reserves. In the next

    Figure 6 The Four-Stage Development of the International Balance of Payments

    Note

    : This graph is about debt finance rather than FDI.

    Source

    : Thirlwall (1983).

    D

    I

    S

    B

    O X Y Z

    RB

    I II III IV

    S

    I

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    9/21

    Yu: Global Imbalances and China 11

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004

    -20000

    0

    20000

    40000

    60000

    80000

    100000

    120000Current account

    Capital account

    month, China will become the largest foreign

    exchange reserve holding country in the world;

    by the end of 2006, its foreign exchange re-serve will surpass US$1 trillion.

    In the past, the main contributor to Chinas

    accumulation of foreign exchange reserves was

    the capital account surplus, more precisely, for-

    eign direct investment (FDI) inflows. How-

    ever, since 2005, the current account surplus

    has superseded FDI to become a more impor-

    tant contributor to the increase in the foreign

    exchange reserves.

    The twin surpluses imply that though China

    has obtained foreign funds through FDI, the

    funds thus obtained have failed to be used tobuy foreign capital goods, technology or man-

    agerial skills. In fact, the funds have flown

    back to the US government bond market, and

    no real resources have been utilised by China.

    As a current account surplus country, China not

    only fails to utilise foreign resources but also

    fails to utilise a part of domestic savings. In

    fact, China has long been a capital-exporting

    rather than importing country. In 2005, China

    was the third largest capital-exporting country

    in the world, while at the same time its per cap-

    ita income ranked 138th in the world.

    To analyse the nature of the twin surpluses

    more carefully, we can use the following iden-

    tity:

    3

    Household savings of residents

    + government

    savings

    + reinvested profit

    + investment

    income

    = investment by domestic enterprises

    +government investment

    + reinvested profit

    +

    new FDI

    + trade surplus

    (3)

    Based on the above accounting identity, we

    have (Yu and Qin 2006):

    (

    I

    e

    S

    p

    ) + (

    I

    g

    S

    g

    ) + (

    I

    f

    CA

    ) = 0 (4)

    where I

    e

    ,

    I

    g

    , I

    f

    ,

    S

    p

    , S

    g

    and CA

    represent

    domestic private (non-governmental) invest-

    ment, government investment, FDI, domestic

    private savings, government savings, and thecurrent account deficit, respectively. In the fol-

    lowing discussions, we assume away the dis-

    tinction between the government sector and the

    private sector. Hence, for a typical developing

    country, under ideal conditions, there should

    be:

    I

    f

    CA = 0 (5)

    The above equation implies that FDI is fi-

    nanced by foreign savings. The utilisation of

    foreign savings is reflected by the existence of

    the current account deficit

    .

    After rearrangement of equation (4), we

    have:

    Figure 7 Chinas Current and Capital Accounts

    US$million

    Year

    Source

    : International Monetary Fund (2006).

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    10/21

    12 The Australian Economic Review March 2007

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003

    30

    32

    34

    36

    38

    40

    42

    44

    46

    48Gross national saving rate

    Investment rate

    (

    S

    e

    I

    e

    ) + (

    S

    g

    I

    g

    ) =I

    f

    CA

    (6)

    Because China fails to translate FDI into thecurrent account deficit, I

    f

    not only represents

    FDI but also the amount of the increase in for-

    eign exchange reserves in the form of US trea-

    sury bills;

    CA

    is the current account surplus,

    representing another portion of the increase in

    foreign exchange reserves that is created by the

    surplus. The above identity (6) implies that

    while foreign investors obtain equity assetsI

    f

    ,

    the hosting country obtains an equal amount of

    foreign debt assets (treasury bonds). This is

    why we say that foreign funds obtained

    through FDI have flown back to the US bondmarkets.

    It can be seen that ifI

    f

    CA > 0, the hosting

    country is accumulating foreign exchange re-

    serves. In contrast, ifI

    f

    CA < 0, the hosting

    country is depleting foreign exchange reserves.

    In China,I

    f

    > 0,

    CA

    > 0 and henceI

    f

    CA > 0.

    This is what is meant by the twin surpluses.

    Under normal conditions, twin surpluses as a

    pattern of international balance of payments are

    abnormal and should not exist persistently. In

    fact, in history, there is no country in the world

    like China that has run twin surpluses persis-

    tently for more than one and a half decades.

    The first question to be asked is whether this

    pattern is beneficial to China. This question can

    be discussed within the framework of dynamic

    optimisation at another time. Here we only re-

    write equation (4) as:

    I

    e+I

    f

    = S+ CA (7)

    where Sis domestic saving and here the gov-

    ernment sector is assumed away.

    Based on the above equation, there are sev-

    eral cases that are worth discussing. The first

    case is when the current account deficit is zero

    and domestic savings are initially equal to

    planned domestic investment, which implies

    that the economy is initially operating at full

    capacity. In this case, the increase in FDImeans domestic investment is crowded out.

    Because the current account deficit is zero, at

    final analysis, FDI is financed by domestic sav-

    ings. The second case is when the current ac-

    count deficit is zero and domestic savings are

    initially greater than domestic investment,

    which means that the economy is initially oper-

    ating below capacity and there is no crowding

    out. But in this case, FDI is also actually fi-

    nanced by domestic savings.4 The third case is

    when the current account is in surplus. In this

    case, after having financed FDI, the remaining

    excess domestic savings are used to buy US

    treasury bills. In any of the above three cases,

    FDI has failed to be translated into the current

    Figure 8 Chinas Saving and Investment Rates

    Per cent

    Year

    of GDP

    Source: National Statistics Bureau (2005).

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    11/21

    Yu: Global Imbalances and China 13

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    account deficit and ends up as an increase in

    foreign exchange reserves.

    In developing countries, it is assumed, theprofitability of investment is much higher than

    the yield of treasury bills. As pointed out by the

    late Professor Rudi Dornbusch, it is certainly

    not reasonable for residents of poor countries

    to buy US treasury bills in preference to invest-

    ing resources in their own countries so as to

    raise their productivity and standard of living

    (see Dornbusch and Helmers 1988). William-

    son (1995, p. 8) pointed out that, [t]he strate-

    gic decision is whether to allow the capital

    inflow to be translated into a current account

    deficit so as to finance increased domestic in-vestment and/or consumption. Therefore, by

    running a current account surplus, a developing

    country is misallocating resources. Running a

    large capital account surplus while running a

    current account surplus is a misallocation of re-

    sources. It is obvious that twin surpluses mean

    a double misallocation of resources. Then why

    does China as a developing country run a large

    current account surplus and why does China

    with excess savings attract so much FDI?

    The first and most popular explanation for

    Chinas current account surplus is the saving-

    investment gap. In contrast to the United

    States, while Chinas investment rate is very

    high, its saving rate is even higher. Especially

    after the mid-1990s, Chinas saving rate has

    become persistently higher than its investment

    rate (Figure 8).

    It seems that there is a strong correlation orco-movement between current account sur-

    pluses and the saving-investment gap (see

    Feldstein 1983). However, it is still not that

    easy to decide whether the saving-investment

    gap is the cause or effect of the current account

    surplus in China. If the saving-investment gap

    is indeed the cause, and the saving-investment

    gap is structural, Chinas current account sur-

    plus will not disappear any time soon. How-

    ever, we cannot rule out the possibility that, to

    a certain extent, the current account surplus has

    led to the occurrence of the saving-investmentgap. For example, the export promotion policy

    has definitely impacted on households saving

    behaviour and has made them less willing to

    spend money on imported consumer goods and

    travel abroad.

    The second possible explanation is the eco-

    nomic cycles, global as well as domestic.

    China tends to run a current account surplus (or

    bigger surplus) when the economy is weak, and

    a deficit when the economy is overheating. In

    China, not only imports but exports also are

    sensitive to the growth of the domestic econ-

    omy. When the economy was overheating,

    growth of exports tended to fall, because more

    products were used for domestic consumption.

    Chinas current account deficit in 1993, the

    1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    600

    700

    800

    900

    -400

    -300

    -200

    -100

    0

    100

    200

    300Exports Imports

    Growth in trade balance

    Figure 9 Chinas Exports, Imports and the Growth Rate of Net Exports

    US$billion

    Year

    Source: National Statistics Bureau (2005).

    Per cent

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    12/21

    14 The Australian Economic Review March 2007

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    only one since 1990, obviously was a result of

    overheating. In 1993, the growth rate of GDP

    was 14 per cent and that of fixed assets invest-ment was 61.8 per cent. Since 1997, China en-

    tered a period of deflation. As a result, demand

    for imports was weak until the turn of the cen-

    tury. However, during roughly the same pe-

    riod, due to the Asian financial crisis and its

    aftermath, demand for Chinas exports was

    also weak. Hence, during this period, Chinas

    current account surplus was not big and the

    growth rate of net exports was low (Figure 9).

    In 2005, owing to overcapacity in China and

    strong growth of the world economy, Chinas

    running of a large current account deficit wasquite natural.

    The third factor contributing to Chinas cur-

    rent account surplus is the governments export

    promotion policy, which includes the so-called

    self-balancing regulation, exchange rate policy

    and tax rebate. In the early stages of reform and

    opening up, the main concern of the govern-

    ment was how to avoid a balance of payments

    crisis caused by excessive borrowings and per-

    sistent trade deficits. Therefore, the govern-

    ment demanded foreign investors guarantee the

    self-balancing of foreign exchange for impor-

    tant foreign investment projects. In other

    words, FDI must be export-oriented. As a re-

    sult, while FDI was introduced, corresponding

    trade deficits were minimised.5 It is also unde-

    niable that Chinas exchange rate policy is con-

    ducive to its trade surplus and current account

    surplus. Before the Asian financial crisis,

    Chinas exchange rate policy was characterised

    by the real targeting approach (Zhang 2003).

    The exchange rate was set according to the pro-

    duction costs of exports with the aim of main-

    taining the competitiveness of exports. During

    the Asian financial crisis, RMB was pegged tothe US dollar. The peg was dropped in July

    2005. However, the exchange rates influence

    on the current account should not be exagger-

    ated. In 1997, in support of the Chinese govern-

    ments policy of no devaluation, I pointed out

    that Chinese exports foreign content was as

    high as 57 percent, the competitive edge

    achieved by devaluation would be offset imme-

    diately to a large extent by the price increases

    in foreign inputs of export goods (see Yu

    2000, p. 5). The same logic may also be appli-

    cable to RMB appreciation. Besides a rela-

    tively weak currency, the tax rebate is anothervery important policy instrument. When the tax

    rebate rates are correctly calculated, they do

    not constitute subsidies. However, in practice,

    the policy is full of flaws. Many enterprises ex-

    port just to obtain tax rebates. Tax rebate-

    related frauds are rampant.

    The fourth factor is Chinas position in the

    global division of labour. Until quite recently,

    the economic relationship in East Asia was

    characterised by the so-called flock formation

    of flying wild geese pattern. Based on the ver-

    tical division of labour, products and capitalflow in and out across borders in the flying

    geese formation. Generally speaking, the fly-

    ing geese formation would not necessarily lead

    a country in the formation to running a current

    account surplus or deficit, though most East

    Asian economies ran current account deficits

    against Japan which led the formation.

    In the later 1980s, a new pattern of the re-

    gional division of labour began to take shape.

    The lowering of communication and transpor-

    tation costs, and the liberalisation of trade and

    investment regimes, enabled corporations to

    fragment and internalise the production process

    (Ando and Kimura 2003) and made distance a

    less important factor in their location deci-

    sion. The clustering effect reduced the impor-

    tance of comparative advantage, but increased

    the importance of agglomeration in choosing a

    production location. As a result of the develop-

    ment of international production networks,

    processing trade became the dominant form of

    trade among less-developed countries.

    Chinas current account surplus coincided

    with the formation of international production

    networks, and its trade pattern was shaped to alarge extent by FDI that flowed in as vehicles

    of the formation of international production

    networks. The pattern of FDI inflows to China

    was in turn facilitated by the Chinese govern-

    ments policy in favour of processing trade,

    which was motivated by the Chinese govern-

    ments fear of a current account deficit and its

    desire to allow Chinas comparative advantage

    in labour-intensive products to have full play.

    Because of the increasingly important role

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    13/21

    Yu: Global Imbalances and China 15

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    played by multinationals from developed coun-

    tries, and Taiwanese Original Equipment Man-

    ufacturer firms, the bulk of FDI flowed intomanufacturing sectors, such as electronics, au-

    tomobiles, family appliances, office machines,

    measuring and checking instruments, telecom-

    munications equipment, pharmaceuticals and

    chemicals. These products were more closely

    related to international production networks.

    As a result of changes in the regional and sec-

    toral distribution of FDI, China was more and

    more deeply locked into the international pro-

    duction networks and became a processor and

    assembler in these networks. While Chinas

    trade has expanded with accelerating speed, itis increasingly being dominated by processing

    trade. The domination of processing trade in

    Chinas trade means that it must run a current

    account surplus. As a matter of fact, in 2005,

    Chinas total trade surpassed US$1 trillion, and

    accounted for more than 70 per cent of GDP.

    At the same time, processing trade accounted

    for 54.6 per cent of Chinas total exports of

    US$762 billion, and foreign-funded enter-

    prises (FFEs) share in processing trade ac-

    counted for more than 80 per cent of the

    exports (Business Watch Weekly 2006, p. 40).

    China had a US$102 billion trade surplus of

    which US$57 billion was created by FFEs

    (China Customs Office 2006), and US$140 bil-

    lion was created by processing trade (which

    means that Chinas general trade ran a deficit

    of US$38 billion).

    In the sense that China has established itself

    as a processor and assembler in the value-chain

    of international production networks, its cur-

    rent account surplus is structural and cannot be

    changed in a short period of time. After

    Chinas WTO entry, FDI from multinationals

    has increasingly been concentrated in capital-intensive heavy chemistry, large-scale infra-

    structure, high technological industry and the

    service industry, which are less international

    production network-related. At the same time,

    multinationals are increasingly more interested

    in Chinas domestic market rather than using

    China as a platform for re-export. However,

    these new developments may not be able to

    change the dominant position of processing

    trade in China in the near future.

    In summary, four factors have been identi-

    fied as possible causes for Chinas current ac-

    count deficit. These four factors are the saving-investment gap, a certain combination of do-

    mestic and global cyclical movement, the gov-

    ernments trade promotion policy, and Chinas

    specific position in the global division of la-

    bour, especially its specific position in interna-

    tional production networks. Without having

    conducted some solid empirical tests, it is dif-

    ficult to provide definite answers to the ques-

    tion of the relative importance of each of the

    four factors. However, it seems that the saving-

    investment gap and the domination of process-

    ing trade are trend factors. The domestic andexternal macroeconomic situation is cyclical

    by definition. The export promotion policy is a

    factor of history whose importance will be ta-

    pering off, though its consequences will con-

    tinue to be felt in years to come.6

    According to Corden (2006, pp. 67):

    It seems perfectly rational to invest some of the

    extra savings abroad given the inefficiency so far

    of the financial system in allocating funds as re-

    flected in the high volume of non-performing

    loans held by the banks. The public sector also has

    yet to improve the efficiency of public invest-ment. It seems extremely reasonable therefore to

    park a proportion of funds abroad until effi-

    ciency in domestic investment allocation im-

    proves.

    Besides this parking theory, another explana-

    tion offered by Corden (2006, p. 7) is the de-

    liberate pursuit of export-led growth. In my

    view, both explanations are relevant to Chinas

    situation and are interrelated. Put simply, the

    deliberate pursuit of export-led growth is the

    cause of Chinas current account surplus and

    the parking, extremely reasonable or not, isa reflection of the inefficiency and hence un-

    sustainability of export-led growth. If China

    runs a current account surplus only, parking

    can be regarded as a second-best solution, be-

    cause China does not have the ability either to

    translate its current account surplus into a cap-

    ital account deficit or to use the funds for do-

    mestic investment. In other words, China has to

    settle with low-yield but safe treasury bills.

    However, Chinas situation is worse than that,

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    14/21

    16 The Australian Economic Review March 2007

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    because it not only runs a current account sur-

    plus but also a capital account surplus.

    Now let us turn to the question of why, as a

    country with excess savings, China has at-

    tracted so much FDI.7 It is worth emphasising

    that capital inflow is attributable to the opti-

    mism of foreign investors about Chinas eco-

    nomic prospects. We need to analyse the

    impact of capital inflows on Chinas current

    account. Assuming that China initially runs a

    balanced current account, which implies that

    there is neither a saving glut nor a saving short-

    age, and further assuming that there is no mar-

    ket distortion of any form, one can ask the

    following: what will happen if capital flows in-

    crease suddenly, owing to the surge of opti-

    mism, and what will be its impact on the

    current account balance? There are two major

    channels via which the surge of capital inflows

    can affect the international balance of pay-

    ments: the interest rate (Figure 10) and the ex-change rate (Figure 11).

    In China, the influences of an increase in

    capital inflows through the interest rate channel

    can be seen most clearly from the rise in stock

    and real estate prices, which means a fall in the

    interest rate. The impact on FDI is not that di-

    rect and clear-cut, but the end result is the

    same. How will the lowering of the interest rate

    impact on the current account? The lowering of

    the interest rate tends to create or increase the

    saving-investment gap and this gap in turn will

    lead to a current account deficit. Changes in the

    interest rate will equilibrate the demand for and

    supply of Chinese assets and at the same time

    Chinas international balance of payments will

    be balanced, after a series of interactions

    among numerous variables, at a corresponding

    level, with increases in capital inflows and the

    current account deficit.

    Now let us check the exchange rate channel.

    Under the fixed exchange rate, the amount of

    capital inflows will be greater than under the

    floating exchange rate. If the interest rate has

    played the role of equilibrating international

    balance of payments, the end result will be an

    increase in the current account deficit as well as

    the capital account surplus as described in the

    previous case. The only difference is that both

    the current account deficit and capital account

    surplus are greater.

    Under a flexible exchange rate, the surge ofcapital inflows will lead to appreciation of the

    RMBthe appreciation will reduce the in-

    crease in demand for foreign capital inflows (d

    d). Therefore, the appreciation will have a

    negative impact on the current account balance.

    It can be seen that under a flexible exchange

    rate, the exchange rate as well as the interest

    rate work to translate capital inflows into a

    current account deficit. It seems that if there is

    no market distortion of any form, exogenous

    A A

    Demand

    Demand

    Supply

    P

    P

    Price of assets

    Chinese

    Figure 10 Capital Inflow and the Price of Assets

    assets d

    Demand

    Supply

    e

    e

    Exchange rate

    Dollar

    Figure 11 Capital Inflow and the Exchange Rate

    Supply

    d d

    yuan/dollar

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    15/21

    Yu: Global Imbalances and China 17

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    capital inflows always automatically translate

    into a current account deficit. In contrast to the

    case of a fixed exchange rate, because there isno market distortion, the magnitudes of both

    capital inflows and the current account balance

    should be in line with an optimum allocation of

    resources.

    How can a current account surplus exist side

    by side with a capital account surplus? Do the

    twin surpluses necessarily mean misallocation?

    For each individual transaction, if foreign ex-

    change fails to be used to buy foreign goods and

    managerial skills, it is certainly a misuse of re-

    sources. But is it necessarily so for the combi-

    nation of all transactions at a given point intime? Now we can imagine a country that is di-

    vided into two parts: a special economic zone

    and the rest of the country. The special eco-

    nomic zone has entered the second stage of de-

    velopmentthat is, the zone has achieved great

    export capacity as a result of capital inflows in

    the first stage of the development and hence

    runs a large current account surpluswhile the

    rest of the country is still in the first stage of de-

    velopmentthat is, it still needs to build up ex-

    port capacity for the future by attracting foreign

    capital inflows and hence runs a capital account

    deficit. Would it not be natural for the twin sur-

    pluses to coexist? For the special economic

    zone and the rest of the country, respectively,

    there is nothing wrong with their individual

    balance of payments. However, for the country

    as a whole, there is something wrong. Suppose

    the current account surplus of the special eco-

    nomic zone is greater than the capital account

    deficit of the rest of the country, the current ac-

    count surplus of the special economic zone

    should be used to finance investment of the rest

    of the country. If this is the case, the country as

    a whole will run a current account surplus anda capital account deficit. If the special eco-

    nomic zones current account surplus is smaller

    than the capital account deficit of the rest of the

    country, the country as a whole should run a

    current account deficit and a capital account

    surplus. In short, under any circumstances, in-

    evitable or not, the twin surpluses always mean

    something has been wrong with resource allo-

    cation. The larger the twin surpluses, the more

    wrong the resource allocation.8

    In the following paragraphs, we specifically

    discuss how market distortion or imperfection

    has led to excess capital inflows to China,while it has to park its excess domestic sav-

    ings abroad as foreign exchange reserves.

    First, due to the underdevelopment of the fi-

    nancial markets, though there may be excess

    savings for the economy as a whole, it is very

    difficult for many potential importers of capital

    goods to raise funds domestically for imports.

    On the other hand, due to the preferential pol-

    icy towards FDI, attracting FDI as a way to

    raise funds is much easier. Sometimes enter-

    prises simply sell their foreign exchange ob-

    tained via FDI to the Peoples Bank of China(PBOC), and use RMB to buy capital goods

    produced locally. As a result, there are in-

    creases in FDI and foreign exchange reserves,

    but there are no changes in the current account.

    Essentially, Chinas domestic savings often

    have to be intermediated by foreign capital

    markets for domestic investment.

    Second, even if funds can be obtained do-

    mestically, due to capital control, it is difficult

    for potential importers to convert the RMB

    funds into foreign exchange so that foreign

    goods can be bought, and hence attracting FDI

    is still a better option.

    Third, despite the fact that the returns re-

    quired on FDI are much higher than the yields

    of US treasury bills, FDI is the cheapest form

    of foreign capital for the myopic enterprises

    and local governments. In other words, under

    current governance arrangements, from the

    point of view of local governments and indi-

    vidual state-owned enterprises, FDI is a free

    lunch. Who cares about payments if the pay-

    ments are due in five to ten years time? Faced

    with excessively lavish concessional condi-

    tionslow tax rates, long tax holidays, hiddensubsidies in energy use, lax regulations of en-

    vironmental protection, free infrastructure and

    low or negative rents on land usewhat more

    can foreign investors hope for? So the inter-

    ests of local governments in attracting FDI

    and foreign investors in investing coincide

    perfectly.

    Fourth, Chinas fiscal system and institu-

    tional arrangements also give local govern-

    ments great incentive to attract FDI. FDI is

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    16/21

    18 The Australian Economic Review March 2007

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    indispensable for increasing tax revenues at

    local levels. More importantly, FDI attraction

    is one of the most important criteria, if not themost important criterion, for good local gov-

    ernment performance. It is a common practice

    in China that all chief officials at all levels of

    government are assigned targets for FDI attrac-

    tion. Those who attract the largest amount of

    FDI are the most likely candidates for further

    promotion. To attract as much FDI as possible

    at any cost may not lead to the maximisation of

    the long-term welfare of the nation; it certainly

    will maximise local governments utility func-

    tion with a time horizon of four years.

    Fifth, recently, in order to give new impetusto the reform of state-owned enterprises and

    commercial banks, the merging and acquisition

    of Chinese firms by foreign investors and the

    acquirement of shares by international strate-

    gic investors in Chinas commercial banks

    have been encouraged. Consequently, capital

    flows have been attracted and added to the ex-

    isting stock of foreign exchange reserves. In

    2005 alone, US$32 billion of capital has been

    attracted as a result of selling bank shares of in-

    ternational strategic investors, even though

    China has already piled up more than US$800

    billion of foreign exchange reserves, without

    knowing how to invest them with a higher re-

    turn.

    Sixth, the single biggest FDI provider is

    Hong Kong and the second largest is the Virgin

    Islands. The latter accounted for more than 19

    per cent of Chinas total attraction of FDI in

    2005. Although difficult to verify, anecdotal

    evidence shows that a very large proportion of

    Chinas FDI is rent-seeking round-tripping

    FDI.

    There is no question about the fact that China

    needs foreign capital goods in which new tech-nology is embodied. Should China buy these

    capital goods or obtain the rights to use these

    capital goods via greenfield investment? Or

    should there be some limit in inviting FDI? In

    an efficient capital market, there should be an

    equilibrium state where there is no difference

    in costs between buying and acquiring via FDI.

    In other words, there should be an optimum

    amount of FDI that China should attract, no

    more and no less.

    5. Chinas Possible Actions in Correcting

    Imbalances

    As mentioned in the second section, sustain-

    ability of global imbalances not only depends

    on whether the United States can reduce its cur-

    rent account deficit but also on how the rest of

    the world, including China, will respond to the

    further worsening of the US current account

    deficit. Consensus has almost been reached

    that the twin surpluses are neither desirable nor

    sustainable for China. Therefore, China will

    take actions to correct its imbalances. Chinas

    future correction undoubtedly will have an im-

    portant impact on the global imbalances.First, as already mentioned, persistently run-

    ning a current account surplus by a developing

    country means a poor country is exporting cap-

    ital to finance rich countries consumption and

    investment. Indeed, [t]here is a more insidious

    connection between the saving postures of

    China and the U.S.: Chinese savers are, in ef-

    fect, subsidizing the spending binge of Ameri-

    can consumers (Roach 2006). According to

    some calculations, Chinas subsidies to the

    United States by providing cheap goods and

    buying treasury bills so as to lower US interest

    rates amounted to US$80 billion a year. Unfor-

    tunately, Chinas good deeds fail to achieve

    much appreciation from the Americans. The

    Chinese have long been wondering why. Now

    a US scholar has provided an answer. In a short

    article, Phillip L. Swagel (2005) of the Ameri-

    can Enterprise Institute stated:

    why pressure China to revalue? U.S. policy-

    makers surely understand the downsides of a yuan

    revaluation for the U.S. economy. And they cer-

    tainly must realize that their very public campaign

    only makes it more difficult for the Chinese to

    take action. Could it be that this is the point? Acynic might hope that the push for a Chinese

    exchange-rate change is not a response to mis-

    guided political pressures, but is instead a devious

    attempt to prolong the enormous benefits the

    United States derives at Chinas expense from the

    fixed dollar-yuan exchange rate. Or perhaps this

    is accident, not design. Either way, the adminis-

    tration has come up with a brilliant strategy to

    keep the good times rolling.9

    Very enlightening indeed!

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    17/21

    Yu: Global Imbalances and China 19

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    As already shown, Chinas current account

    surplus (and twin surpluses) is achieved under

    serious market distortion. For example, thecompetitiveness of energy-intensive export

    products is achieved through hidden subsidies

    in the form of underpricing of energy re-

    sources. The same is true of land-intensive

    export products. Many of Chinas export prod-

    ucts are produced at the expense of Chinas en-

    vironment. Furthermore, following the rapid

    increase in Chinas export scale and current ac-

    count surplus, Chinas terms of trade is wors-

    ening.

    Second, the over-dependence on processing

    trade for the current account surplus, which inturn is based on Chinas disciplined cheap la-

    bour, is risking the Chinese economy being

    permanently locked into the lower ladder of the

    division of labour. With trade being dominated

    by processing trade, Chinas economy can be

    very vulnerable to external shocks.

    Third, trade frictions will be worsening as a

    result of the increase in the current account sur-

    plus. Chinas exports are already targeted by

    the United States, European Union and many

    developing countries, such as Mexico and Bra-

    zil. The damage made to Chinas economic

    growth by protectionism will be very grave in-

    deed.

    Last but not least,10 the accumulation of for-

    eign exchange reserves, as a result of the twin

    surpluses, is making the Chinese economy vul-

    nerable to US adjustment. According to some

    US economists, the US dollar should further

    devalue by 20 to 30 per cent. If that happens,

    Chinas losses in its foreign exchange reserves

    will be tremendous. The wobbly dollar is spell-

    ing big trouble for Asian countries. Among

    them, China is the most vulnerable. More than

    half of Chinas foreign exchange reserves arein US dollars. As pointed out by some observ-

    ers, all policy options for the PBOC are unat-

    tractive. If the PBOC does nothing and simply

    holds on to the dollars, the losses will increase.

    If it buys more to prop up the dollar, it will only

    have a bigger version of the same problem in

    the future. If, on the contrary, the PBOC diver-

    sifies into other currencies, it will drive down

    the dollar faster and create greater losses. The

    dilemma facing Chinas central bank is not un-

    paralleled in history. With such a huge amount

    of foreign exchange reserves, it is extremely

    difficult for China to protect itself.All this means that Chinas excessive current

    account surplus together with its capital ac-

    count surplus is a gross misallocation of re-

    sources. It is very telling that, in contrast to the

    United States, with a large positive NIIP,

    Chinas net investment income on NIIP was

    negative until 2005.11

    Currently, the Chinese economy is suffering

    from excessive investment and the economy

    has been heating up while facing the possibility

    of deflation due to overcapacity in the longer

    run. The twin surpluses have compromisedChinas macroeconomic management and are

    harbingers of inflation and asset bubbles. Since

    the middle of the 1990s, the increase in foreign

    exchange reserves has become one of the most

    important contributing factors to the increase in

    reserve money. In order to control the increase

    in reserve money, large-scale open market op-

    erations (OMOs) have been carried out to ster-

    ilise the increase in reserve money by selling

    government bonds held by the PBOC. How-

    ever, in just a couple of years since 2002,

    owing to the enormous scale of OMOs aimed at

    neutralising the expansionary impact of the in-

    crease in foreign exchange reserves, the PBOC

    sold out all the government bonds it had accu-

    mulated as a result of the previous OMOs

    aimed at increasing money supply to stimulate

    the economy. In 2003, the PBOC was forced to

    sell central bank bills to mop up the liquidity.

    Due to the enormous scale of increase in for-

    eign exchange reserves, in a short period of

    three years, the total balance of central bank

    bills issued reached about 3 trillion yuan RMB.

    In contrast, the total balance of government

    bonds was just 3 trillion yuan RMB after 10years issuance. Most of the central bank bills

    are short-term bills of three months. One im-

    portant question is whether sterilisation can be

    implemented unlimitedly. This is a debatable

    question. Theoretically speaking, as long as the

    interest rates paid by the central bank on its

    bills are lower than corresponding interest rates

    of US assets, say, the yields of treasury bills,

    the central bank should be able to carry on with

    full sterilisation infinitely, and hence maintain

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    18/21

    20 The Australian Economic Review March 2007

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    an effective control of the monetary base.

    However, there are several obstacles to the

    continuation of full sterilisation. One of the ob-stacles is that the continuous purchase of low-

    yield central bank bills and the increase in the

    share of low-yield assets in the total assets will

    worsen commercial banks profitability, which

    in turn will create a long-term negative impact

    on the fragile banking system. Therefore, faced

    with a continuous increase in foreign exchange

    reserves, the central bank has to make a choice

    among three contradicting objectives: a tight

    monetary policy, a healthy financial system

    and exchange rate stability. Faced with an ex-

    tremely high growth rate of fixed assets invest-ment and a steady increase in the investment

    rate, there is no choice for the PBOC but to

    tighten monetary policy significantly. At the

    same time, comprehensive policy measures

    will be taken to reduce the increase in foreign

    exchange reserves. This means that the twin

    surpluses must be reduced.

    On the surface, faced with persistence of the

    twin surpluses, sustainability of Chinas bal-

    ance of payments is a non-issue. However, the

    question of sustainability does exist for China

    in the long run, due to Chinas accumulation of

    FDI. Following the increase in FDI, investment

    income outflows will increase too. If China

    fails to utilise foreign capital effectively and to

    obtain a decent return on its outbound invest-

    ment and lending, it may suffer from a current

    account deficit as a result of ballooning of in-

    vestment income. To adjust Chinas abnormal

    pattern of international balance of payments, so

    as to reduce the twin surpluses, comprehensive

    measures should be taken, which include mac-

    roeconomic policy, trade and FDI policy, deep-

    ening of financial reform and capital account

    liberalisation. The adjustment will be a longprocess and the adjustment should be imple-

    mented with great care.

    To reduce the current account surplus, the

    saving-investment gap should be reduced. To

    narrow the saving-investment gap either con-

    sumption or investment should be increased.

    Because of Chinas current investment rate al-

    ready being too high, the focus should be on in-

    creasing consumption. In order to do so,

    government expenditures on public goods must

    be increased. The major areas of expenditure

    increase should be social security, the medical

    care system and the education system. Thegovernments recent decision to increase funds

    to support rural development will achieve the

    result of killing two birds with one stone. Fur-

    thermore, government investment in infra-

    structure, such as railways, expressways,

    airports and harbours, and government-

    supported R&D should also be increased. It is

    worth noting that the most important source of

    high saving is not the household sector but the

    enterprise sector. State-owned mega-firms

    have parked huge amounts of money in banks.

    On the other hand, they have not been requiredto pay dividends to their ownersthe public

    for a long period of time. The government

    should demand a fair share of dividends and

    use these dividends to improve its social secu-

    rity system.

    Preferential policies towards FDI should be

    abolished so that domestic investment and FDI

    are given equal treatment in terms of credit ac-

    cess, taxation, environmental requirements and

    so on. As a result, round-tripping FDI will be

    reduced and FDI that is not viable without all

    sorts of subsidies will stop flowing into China.

    Especially, policies in favour of processing

    trade should be adjusted.

    Export promotion policy should be abolished

    gradually. More money should be spent on

    buying more foreign goods, especially strategi-

    cally important goods and materials. Of course,

    while doing so, international markets should

    not be rocked.

    Financial reforms should be sped up. Small

    and medium sized enterprises should not be

    discriminated against. Corporate bond markets

    should be developed and stock markets should

    be made more effective and less speculative.The reform should be aimed at allowing do-

    mestic savings to be channelled effectively to

    enterprises so that they will have less need to

    attract FDI for the purpose of obtaining credit.

    FFEs should be allowed to tap Chinas do-

    mestic capital market, so that there will be less

    need for new cross-border FDI. The govern-

    ment should provide the bulk of the funds nec-

    essary for the mergers and acquisitions aimed

    at enterprise reorganisations.

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    19/21

    Yu: Global Imbalances and China 21

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    Chinese enterprises should be encouraged to

    invest abroad both in the form of greenfield in-

    vestments and mergers and acquisitions. How-ever, the outflows should be strictly monitored

    by the government.

    Capital account liberalisation should be car-

    ried out smoothly and in an orderly manner.

    However, the completion of financial reform

    and the revitalisation of Chinas financial insti-

    tutions and banks in particular must precede

    the final liberalisation of the capital account,

    that is, to make the RMB convertible.

    The RMB exchange rate should continue to

    appreciate gradually. This is a more efficient

    way of correcting Chinas imbalances. How-ever, empirical evidence has shown that the so-

    called expenditure-switching effect of nor-

    mal exchange rate changes is small in China as

    well as in the United States. Due to the domi-

    nation of processing trade in China, the effect

    of exchange rate changes should be even

    smaller. To use the exchange rate change as an

    instrument to achieve trade balance might lead

    to great exchange rate fluctuation. Abundant

    experience also shows that overemphasis on

    the importance of exchange rate policy in the

    correction of current account imbalances may

    not only fail to achieve the goal of correcting

    trade imbalances, but also cause tremendous

    hardship to the countries concerned. After the

    Plaza Accord, despite the dramatic revaluation

    of the Japanese yen and the slide of the US dol-

    lar, the US trade deficit failed to improve in any

    significant way, but succeeded in causing tre-

    mendous hardship to the Japanese economy.

    However, while recognising the limitation of

    exchange rate policy, personally, I am for more

    action on the exchange rate front. Current de-

    velopment of Chinas domestic economy has

    made the adjustment of exchange rate policyeven more urgent.

    6. Concluding Remarks

    Over the past 26 years, China has achieved tre-

    mendous success in reform and opening up.

    Now China has become the fourth largest econ-

    omy, the third largest trading nation and the

    largest foreign exchange reserve holding coun-

    try. However, China is facing increasingly se-

    rious structural problems. Its investment rate is

    approaching 50 per cent of GDP and rising. Its

    dependence ratio is approaching 70 per cent ofGDP and rising. Its current account surplus sur-

    passed US$102 billion in 2005, and will prob-

    ably be higher in 2006. Chinas foreign

    exchange reserves have reached US$920 bil-

    lion and will surpass the threshold of US$1 tril-

    lion very soon. Chinas environment is

    deteriorating continuously. Its energy shortage

    is acute.

    To correct the imbalances, the Chinese gov-

    ernment has adopted a comprehensive program

    aimed at achieving a more balanced and sus-

    tainable growth pattern. Whether Chinas newstrategy for a more balanced and sustainable

    growth will be successful is dependent on how

    well the Chinese government is able to balance

    the short-run necessity for high growth and the

    long-run necessity for structural adjustment.

    On the one hand, Chinas twin surpluses are a

    result of long-term imbalance and the events

    which have evolved over the past 26 years. The

    pattern of twin surpluses cannot be changed

    overnight. On the other hand, caution is not an

    excuse for inaction.

    Global imbalances are not sustainable in the

    sense that imbalances are not in the long-term

    interests of Asian countries, and the imbal-

    ances should be and will be corrected, no mat-

    ter what the US government says and does.

    However, a drastic correction is neither inevi-

    table nor desirable. The key task faced by gov-

    ernments in the world is to coordinate their

    policies to guarantee a smooth correction. Oth-

    erwise, something unexpected may trigger a

    dramatic meltdown of the world economy. At

    present, the most undesirable thing for Asian

    countries is a panic exit from dollar assets by

    the major central banks faced with a prisonersdilemma situation. To achieve an orderly cor-

    rection, more international consultation and

    coordination are needed.

    October 2006

    Endnotes

    1. Bergsten, Fred, IIE Conference on IMF Re-

    form, 17 October 2005.

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    20/21

    22 The Australian Economic Review March 2007

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    2. As an aftermath of the Asian financial crisis,

    China ran a capital account deficit in 1998, due

    to capital flight.

    3. In this identity, we ignore other forms of cap-

    ital inflow, which is not that important in China.

    4. In this case, there is no crowding out and

    again FDI is essentially financed by domestic

    savings and the end result is also the increase in

    foreign exchange reserves. In this case, due to

    the lack of demand, macroeconomic policy

    will be taken to stimulate demand and a current

    account surplus will be encouraged.

    5. This policy was abolished as part of Chinas

    commitments for WTO entry in 2001.

    6. There are also problems with the current ac-

    count statistics. The current account surplus

    may have been overestimated in recent years.

    7. China also attracted a large amount of indi-

    rect investment. But FDI is the dominant form

    of capital inflows to China. The question of

    why China chooses this form of foreign capital

    is a question discussed elsewhere.

    8. The only exception is when a country has to

    build up foreign exchange reserves after a fi-

    nancial or currency crisis.

    9. According to Swagel (2005), if Chinas cur-

    rency is undervalued by 27 per cent, as some

    have claimed, US consumers have been getting

    a 27 per cent discount on everything made in

    China, while the Chinese have been paying 27

    per cent too much for treasury bonds. One

    might wonder why the United States is com-

    plaining in the first place. Revaluation wouldend the Chinese fire sale. Americans will pay

    more for everything from shoes to electronics.

    Other global investors will buy up US bonds

    the Chinese no longer wantand Americans

    might even save a bit morebut the treasury

    and the public will have to pay higher interest

    rates. A stronger yuan will mean not just a

    steeper cost of financing government debt, but

    also higher payments for US homeowners on

    those frothy interest-only mortgages. And do

    not expect US job gains from revaluation.

    Chinas undervalued currency has cost jobs,

    but they were lost in Malaysia, Honduras, andthe other low-cost countries from which US

    clothing and toys will be sourced as Chinese

    exports slow.

    10. During the 1920s, some of the official hold-

    ers of sterling grew nervous about Britains

    weak foreign trade performance. Foreign cen-

    tral banks were told there was no intention of

    abandoning Britains link to gold by the Bank

    of England. When the inevitable British deval-

    uation came on 2021 September 1931, many

    foreign central banks were hit hard and wereblamed for mismanaging their reserves. The

    Dutch central banker, Gerard Vissering, re-

    signed and eventually killed himself as a result

    of the destruction wrought on his institutions

    balance sheet by the pounds collapse. See

    James (2005).

    11. This is related to the appreciation expecta-

    tions of the RMB exchange rate.

    References

    Ando, M. and Kimura, F. 2003, The formation

    of international production and distribution

    networks in East Asia, National Bureau of

    Economic Research Working Paper no.

    1016, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Bernanke, B. S. 2005, The global saving glut

    and the U.S. current account deficit, re-

    marks at Homer Jones Lecture, St Louis,

    Missouri: updates speech given on 10 March

    2005 at the Sandridge Lecture, Virginia As-

    sociation of Economists, Richmond, Vir-

    ginia, 14 April, Federal Reserve Board,

    .

    Business Watch Weekly (Shang Wu Zhou Kan)

    2006, vol. 131, no. 7.

    China Costumes Office 2006, China Trade Sta-

    tistics Database, unpublished.

    Corden, W. M. 2006, Those current account

    imbalances: A sceptical view, Melbourne

    Institute of Applied Economic and Social

    Research Working Paper no. 13/06, Univer-

    sity of Melbourne.

  • 7/31/2019 Global Imbalances and China by Yu Yongding

    21/21

    Yu: Global Imbalances and China 23

    2007 The University of Melbourne, Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research

    Dooley, M. P., Folkerts-Landau, D. and Gar-

    ber, P. 2003, An essay on the revived Bret-

    ton Woods system, National Bureau ofEconomic Research Working Paper no.

    9971, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

    Dornbusch, R. and Helmers, F. L. C. H. (eds)

    1988, The Open Economy, Oxford Univer-

    sity Press, Oxford.

    Feldstein, M. 1983, Domestic saving and in-

    ternational capital movements in the long

    run and the short run,European Economic

    Review, vol. 21, pp. 12951.

    Ferguson, R. W. Jr 2005, U.S. current account

    deficit: Causes and consequences, remarks

    to Economics Club of the University of NorthCarolina at Chapel Hill, Chapel Hill, North

    Carolina, 20 April, Federal Reserve Board,

    .

    International Monetary Fund 2006, Interna-

    tional Financial Statistics Database, .

    James, H. 2005, Wobbly dollar spells big

    trouble for central bankers, 1 January,

    .

    National Statistics Bureau 2005, China Statis-

    tical Yearbook, China Statistics Press,

    Beijing.

    Poole, W. 2005, How dangerous is the US cur-

    rent account deficit?, Economic Policy Lec-

    ture Series, Lindenwood University, St

    Charles, Missouri, 9 November, .

    Roach, S. 2006, Save more! Save less!, For-

    tune, 16 March, .

    Royal Bank of Scotland Group 2004, Global

    imbalances and the dollar: Where next?,

    2 December, .Scott, R. 2006, U.S. current account deficit

    breaks record at 7% of GDP, Current Ac-

    count Picture, Economic Policy Institute, 14

    March, .

    Sheng, H. 2005, American current account

    deficit, unpublished dissertation, Post-

    Graduate School of Chinese Academy of So-

    cial Sciences.

    Swagel, P. L. 2005, Yuan answers?,AEI On-

    line, 22 June, .Thirlwall, A. P. 1983, Growth and Develop-

    ment, Macmillan, London.

    Williamson, J. 1995, The management of cap-

    ital inflows, Pensamiento Iberoamericano,

    JanuaryJune, .

    Yu, Y. 2000, Opinions on structure reform and

    exchange rate regimes against the backdrop

    of the Asian financial crisis, paper prepared

    for the meeting organised by the Council on

    Foreign Exchange and Other Transactions,

    Ministry of Finance, Japan, 6 March, .

    Yu, Y. and Qin, D. 2006, Chinas twin sur-

    pluses: Nature, causes and solutions, in

    Searching for a Development Strategy of In-

    ternal and External Balances, eds F. He and

    B. Zhang, Shanghai Financial and Economic

    University Press, Shanghai.

    Zhang, Z. 2003, Revisit RMBs exchange rate

    movement, International Economic Re-

    view, nos 1112, pp. 911.