Top Banner
Journal of Social Research & Policy, Vol. 5, Issue 1, July 2014 Ghana’s Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative? ABDULAI KUYINI MOHAMMED 1 Department of Political Science University of Ghana Abstract Ghana’s Family Planning Program (FPP), maternal mortality intervention, and HIV/AIDS control program are all health policy priorities, which are supposed to be complementary to achieve desirable reproductive health outcomes. However, it appears disproportionately less attention is being paid to the former compared to the latter two, which are relatively new health policies. This may have implications not only for the effectiveness of the FPP and the other two policies, but more broadly reproductive health outcomes. This study investigates this claim and finds that the FPP has policy merits and that its relegation to the background has led to a marginally little incentive to space births, and a marginally positive incentive to increase fecund level, with attendant negative developmental consequences. It then concludes that despite the alarming rate of maternal mortality and loss of lives through HIV/AIDS, Ghana’s population is still growing at a dangerous pace, making the FPP as relevant as ever. Keywords: Family Planning Program (FPP); Optimum population size; Development; Maternal health; Free Medical Care for Pregnant Women (FMCPW); Policy synergy. Introduction The world’s population in 2002 was estimated to be 6.2 billion; expected to be growing by 75 million per annum, with 97 percent of this increase occurring in developing countries (Goldstein & Whitworth, 2005). A disproportionate share of developing countries’ contribution to this rise is accounted for by the faster growth rate in Sub-Saharan African nations. This has raised fears of the inevitability of overpopulation in the sub region with its attendant negative consequences such as scarcity of productive resources, stress and strain on social infrastructure, environmental degradation etc. The concern about population size has also been expressed in Ghana over the years. The country’s population increased from 6 million at independence in 1957 to nearly 18 million in 1996 with a projected estimate of 27 million by 2020 (Arjun, 1996; GMHS, 2007). With the current growth rate of 2.7 percent, the population may reach 32 million by 2040. The past rapid growth of Ghana’s population was an outcome of high fertility, which until recently remained fairly constant, and declining mortality (Arjun, 1996; PPAG, 2009). Even though life expectancy at birth is low at 57.7 years and infant mortality is high at 71 per 1000 births (UNDP, 2007), this has not prevented the population from growing above annual desirable rate. This has raised fears of an imminent overpopulation, with the government responding by introducing the Family Planning Program (FPP) in 1970. The FPP was strengthened by the launching of the Road Map for Repositioning Family Planning 2006 to 2010 in 2006 (PPAG, 2009). Despite the fact that the FPP has been running for many years in Ghana it has failed to impact population in a meaningful way. The failure is attributed to factors such as dwindling government commitment in terms of advocacy and resourcing, gap 1 Postal Address: University of Ghana, Department of Political Science, P. O. BOX LG 69, Legon, Accra Ghana. E- mail Address: [email protected], [email protected]
15

Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

Feb 27, 2023

Download

Documents

Joseph A. Yaro
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

Journal of Social Research & Policy, Vol. 5, Issue 1, July 2014

Ghana’s Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

ABDULAI KUYINI MOHAMMED1

Department of Political Science University of Ghana

Abstract

Ghana’s Family Planning Program (FPP), maternal mortality intervention, and HIV/AIDS control program are all

health policy priorities, which are supposed to be complementary to achieve desirable reproductive health outcomes.

However, it appears disproportionately less attention is being paid to the former compared to the latter two, which are

relatively new health policies. This may have implications not only for the effectiveness of the FPP and the other two

policies, but more broadly reproductive health outcomes. This study investigates this claim and finds that the FPP has

policy merits and that its relegation to the background has led to a marginally little incentive to space births, and a

marginally positive incentive to increase fecund level, with attendant negative developmental consequences. It then

concludes that despite the alarming rate of maternal mortality and loss of lives through HIV/AIDS, Ghana’s

population is still growing at a dangerous pace, making the FPP as relevant as ever. Keywords: Family Planning Program (FPP); Optimum population size; Development; Maternal health; Free Medical

Care for Pregnant Women (FMCPW); Policy synergy.

Introduction

The world’s population in 2002 was estimated to be 6.2 billion; expected to be growing by 75

million per annum, with 97 percent of this increase occurring in developing countries (Goldstein

& Whitworth, 2005). A disproportionate share of developing countries’ contribution to this rise is

accounted for by the faster growth rate in Sub-Saharan African nations. This has raised fears of

the inevitability of overpopulation in the sub region with its attendant negative consequences such

as scarcity of productive resources, stress and strain on social infrastructure, environmental

degradation etc. The concern about population size has also been expressed in Ghana over the

years. The country’s population increased from 6 million at independence in 1957 to nearly 18 million in 1996 with a projected estimate of 27 million by 2020 (Arjun, 1996; GMHS, 2007).

With the current growth rate of 2.7 percent, the population may reach 32 million by 2040. The

past rapid growth of Ghana’s population was an outcome of high fertility, which until recently

remained fairly constant, and declining mortality (Arjun, 1996; PPAG, 2009).

Even though life expectancy at birth is low at 57.7 years and infant mortality is high at 71

per 1000 births (UNDP, 2007), this has not prevented the population from growing above

annual desirable rate. This has raised fears of an imminent overpopulation, with the

government responding by introducing the Family Planning Program (FPP) in 1970. The FPP

was strengthened by the launching of the Road Map for Repositioning Family Planning – 2006

to 2010 in 2006 (PPAG, 2009). Despite the fact that the FPP has been running for many years

in Ghana it has failed to impact population in a meaningful way. The failure is attributed to factors such as dwindling government commitment in terms of advocacy and resourcing, gap

1 Postal Address: University of Ghana, Department of Political Science, P. O. BOX LG 69, Legon, Accra Ghana. E-

mail Address: [email protected], [email protected]

Page 2: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

2 | JSRP Abdulai Kuyini Mohammed

between knowledge of family planning and use of contraceptives, unpredictability of donor

funding, and high unmet need (PPAG, 2009; GMHS, 2007).

Meanwhile, a seemingly conflicting initiative to the FPP, an exemptions policy for delivery

fees for pregnant women was introduced in 2004 (MoH, 2004). This was gradually phased out and was replaced by health insurance in 2008 (popularly referred to as the Free Medical Care

for Pregnant Women - FMCPW). The exemptions policy has an objective of addressing some

of the challenges hindering the attainment of one of the Millennium Development Goals

(MDG), which focuses on improving maternal health of women by 2015 (Osabutey, 2008). In

other words, the policy is meant to curb the high rate of maternal and baby deaths.

From the above exposition, it appears the FPP with its emphasis on limiting the number of

children per woman, has an anti-natal intent (reducing fertility), while the FMCPW, which

focuses on safe delivery, has a pro-natal motive. However, the government has prioritized the

unacceptable level of maternal deaths as a national emergency and has diverted much attention

and resources to dealing with the problem. The questions that then arise are: Has the

prioritizing of the FMCPW left the FPP unattended to? What are the implications of this

apparent neglect of the FPP for population growth and development of Ghana? These questions can be answered by providing responses to three further questions:

1. Does Ghana need a Family Planning Program?

2. Will the Family Planning Program reduce fertility?

3. Is the FPP a neglected policy initiative?

Methodology

Data for the study was obtained from both primary and secondary sources. The primary

information was obtained by interviewing 21 key personnel from relevant organizations including

the Ghana Health Service, hospitals, and the Planned Parenthood Association of Ghana (PPAG). These respondents were originally identified because of their role connected directly to the

development and implementation of the FPP and FMCPW policies. The secondary information

was derived from content analysis of published works on both policy initiatives.

Theoretical Framework

It seems to be the case that, policy-makers in developing countries believe that

overconcentration on getting the content and administration of public policies right is most

critical in exacting desirable outcomes. In so doing, they totally neglect or pay little attention to

ensuring that synergy exists between related public projects and programs that are trying to

achieve the same macro level objectives. Yet the literature demonstrates that complementarities of efforts (cooperation, collaboration and coordination as well as mutual reinforcement of

related initiatives) of change agents whose separate program of activities ultimately lead to the

same endpoint, is extremely crucial in not only achieving the objectives of the individual

projects concerned, but also the ends of the bigger whole to which they all contribute their

quota (Brislin, 1981; Pressman & Wildavsky, 1984). As Walt & Gilson observe (1994), the

traditional focus on the content of policy neglects the other dimensions of process, actors and

context which can make the difference between effective and ineffective policy choice and

implementation (Walt & Gilson, 1994). Thomas & Gilson (2004) and Cassels (1995) make

similar comments in relation to the apparent neglect of these other dimensions of reality of

policy making in the Third World.

Grindle & Thomas’ (1991) research on the political economy of reform in developing countries has been cited by many scholars. Grindle & Thomas (1991) based their analysis of

policy and organizational reform in recent decades from several developing countries to

propose a multivariate framework for understanding the emergence, discussion,

implementation and sustainability of policy reform in developing countries. They placed

premium on the role of policy elites in shaping policy agendas, weighting policy options and

Page 3: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

3 | JSRP Ghana’s Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

managing political and bureaucratic challenges of policy reform. They define policy elites as

those who have official positions in government and whose responsibilities include making or

participating in making and implementing authoritative decisions for society. The main factors

in their framework are environmental context of reform, the agenda setting circumstances, and international context, as well as policy characteristics. A fifth factor that also affects policy

success or failure, but that has not been mentioned by Grindle & Thomas (1991) is synergy

between related public social projects and programs. The first three of their factors together

with synergy are adopted here and discussed in turn below.

Elements of the environmental context include the individual characteristics of policy elites

such as their ideological predispositions, professional expertise and training, experiences of

similar policy situations, position and power, political and institutional commitments, loyalties,

and personal attributes and goals. It also enfolds the context of policy choice such as societal

pressures, historical and economic context.

The agenda setting circumstances embrace whether there is a perception of a crisis situation

or not. According to Grindle & Thomas (1991), in a perceived crisis situation there is strong

pressure for reform and immediate action, the stakes are considered high, change is seen as innovative and high level decision-makers are involved in the reform process. The behavior of

policy stakeholders is different in situations that are perceived as non crisis. In non crisis

scenarios the agenda setting circumstances are “politics as usual”. Policy makers, without

pressure and without extreme limit on their time, select the agenda items. The stakes are seen

as low and decisions are often left to middle level decision-makers; incremental change is

acceptable and there is flexibility in timing. Decision-making in perceived crisis situations

tends to be dominated by concerns about macro political relationships whereas in politics as

usual, decision-making tends to be preoccupied by concerns about political and bureaucratic

relationships (Grindle & Thomas, 1991, Bridgman & Davis, 2004).

The international context or environment refers to the forces that surround and influence the

life and development of domestic policies from outside the borders of a country. An increasing body of literature contends that states are increasingly constrained and shaped by global forces

(Ohmae, 1995; Falk, 1997). Recognition of the international system’s influences on public

policy has opened up an interesting field of studies in the policy discipline. The international

system, not only affects policy sectors that are clearly international – examples, trade and

defense – but also sectors with no immediately apparent international connection, such as

health care. The influence comes from the overall structure of the international system, and a

country’s place in it (Howlett & Ramesh, 2003).

The influence of the international system is probably not a novel phenomenon, what

distinguishes the current movement is that its scope and intensity have greatly increased. This

has resulted in what is generally referred to as globalization or, more precisely,

internationalization (Hirst & Thomson, 1996). Although originally, internationalization was

thought of as a somewhat simple concept, the recent policy literature acknowledges its highly complex nature, the different forms it takes across space and time, and the varying impacts it

has on different policy sectors and states (Bernstein & Cashore, 2000; Bennett, 1997; Brenner,

1999). This recognition has prompted scholars to research more curiously into the means,

manner, and mechanisms through which domestic policy processes are connected to the

international system (Coleman & Perl, 1999; Finnemore & Sikkink, 1998; Bridgman & Davis,

2004). Thus, it could be argued that the domestic healthcare system and policies in Ghana are

more international than can be assumed because a proportion of the health budget is funded by

donor agencies such as USAID, DANIDA, and the World Bank. These donors dictate health

projects and programs that may not fit neatly into the domestic healthcare agenda.

Synergy in policy development and implementation

Another issue that determines the success or failure of public policies is synergy between

related public social projects and programs. According to Brislin (1981), synergy is a behavior

of whole systems that cannot be predicted by the behavior of any parts taken separately. In

Page 4: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

4 | JSRP Abdulai Kuyini Mohammed

order to really understand what is going on, the individual parts should be examined in their

relationships to the other components as well as the whole system.

In their book entitled “Managing Cultural Synergy”, Moran and Harris reflect that ‘the very

differences in the world’s people can lead to mutual growth and accomplishment that is more than the single contribution of each party to the intercultural transaction’ (Moran & Harris, 1981, p. 3).

In terms of the FPP and FMCPW, one can infer from Brislin, Moran & Harris’ thoughts on

cultural synergy that both policies are part of a system or a bigger whole called reproductive

health of women. So in order to improve reproductive health of women we cannot start by

working separately on the FPP and FMCPW as this approach will not give us the opportunity to

determine their effects on each other and their implications for the broader goal of improving

women’s reproductive health. Rather we must act on them as a joint project in order to ensure

they are mutually supportive and generate consistent reproductive health outcomes. If they are

managed as a joint project it will lead to mutual growth and realization of not only their

respective objectives, but also the broader goal of attaining a high standard of reproductive health.

I argue that policy synergy, as an approach to designing, implementing and managing the

diverse major social policies and programs in developing countries should involve a process in which policy makers and administrators form organizational strategies, structures and practices

based on, but not limited to, the workings of individual policies. They need to create linkages

between related policies and programs to ensure that their activities are mutually reinforcing.

Synergetic policy organizations create new forms of management and transactions that

transcend the distinct operations of individual policies to align and harmonize with related

initiatives. The harmonization will contribute to the achievement of not only the respective

objectives of the individual programs but also the ends of a broader policy domain to which

they all belong. This approach recognizes both the similarities and differences between the

policies and suggests that we neither ignore, nor minimize the dissimilarities, but that we view

them as a resource in designing organizational systems that engender complementarities of

efforts across individual policies so that we achieve system-wide objectives. Literature on the technical and political challenges of implementing health policies in

developing countries exists and is growing (examples, Carrin, 2003; Carrin & James, 2004;

Preker, 2002; Adjei & Agyeapong, 2008). However, work on the challenges of creating synergy

between related public social policies and programs, is scanty or non-existent. This article is a

modest contribution toward filling this gap in the literature by examining the problem of lack of

synergy between the FPP and the FMCPW in Ghana. It also looks at the difficulty of managing

the environmental, agenda setting, and international contexts in the development and

implementation of the two initiatives. I do this by using some of the elements of Grindle &

Thomas’ (1991) framework as well as ideas from Brislin, Moran & Harris’ thoughts on cultural

synergy in the analysis. Further, I evaluate the outcomes of the implementation of the FPP based

on what some scholars refer to as the six criteria of evaluation (Ayee, 2000; Dunn, 1994; Howlett

& Ramesh, 2003). These criteria are efficiency, effectiveness, adequacy, equity, responsiveness and appropriateness. These six criteria of evaluation have been adopted without consenting that

they are yardsticks on which all stakeholders in policy making agree. They are criteria from the

policy analyst’s perspective rather than those which take into account the various interested

individuals and groups who also evaluate public policies and programs. Nevertheless, they

provide a useful starting point for examining the facets of policy success and failure. Lessons are

then drawn that will be useful for policy reform.

Is an FPP policy necessary?

A legitimate question to ask about the FPP is: Is it an appropriate policy? Appropriateness refers to the value or worth of a program’s objectives and the tenability of assumptions underlying these

objectives (Ayee, 2000; Dunn, 1994). In relation to the FPP, the policy could be justified on the

grounds that Ghana’s population is rising rapidly due to high fertility rate and immigration. The

fertility rate is said to be rising perhaps at above replacement level and there is a foreseeable

chance of Ghana’s population actually increasing. An above replacement fertility means a rising

Page 5: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

5 | JSRP Ghana’s Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

population level in Ghana because a natural increase is augmented by the uncontrolled migrant

arrivals. Even when we consider the situation with the lowest fertility rate (4.4 in 1998 compared

with the current 4.6) and the lowest migration level (75,843 in 1999 compared with the current

estimate of 3 million), Ghana’s population will rise by 2020 to 26,516 million because the natural increase will be augmented by an appreciable immigration to Ghana, mostly other Africans who

are undocumented (Nigerians, Ivoirians, Burkinabe, etc.), for example, there are an estimated 1

million Malians and 26, 0000 Liberians in Ghana (RIPS, 2009).

Granting that there is a foreseeable risk of Ghana’s population overgrowing we must find

reasons for FPP policies. Government interference in the private decisions of individuals, and one

cannot get more private than the decision to have a child, has to be made on grounds of market

failure. In other words, it has to be demonstrated that the private decisions lead to sub-optimal

outcomes from the point of view of society. In the context of FPP policy then, the question that

easily comes to mind is: What is the optimum population size of Ghana? We might also ask: Are

the unfettered choices of parents likely to put us on a path to the optimum population?

It certainly is an elusive exercise to search for the optimum population size. Unlike The

Hitchhikker’s Guide to the Galaxy where the answer to the ultimate question was revealed as 42 (Guest, 2007), there is no undisputable figure for a country’s optimum population size. There are

no certainties and there are many unresolved ethical issues. The Jones Report on Australia’s

population carrying capacity put the difficulty this way: ‘they search for a magic figure (for

optimum population) or a Rubicon between safety and danger’ (Australian Parliament, 1994, p.

129). In a similar fashion, McDonald & Kippen (1999), contend that it is not sensible to specify

particular population targets because of uncertainty about fertility, mortality rates, environmental

issues and other circumstances. They posit that in any case our choices of a population target

would be very limited due to demographic realities of past fertility rates and achievable future

rates, and of a limited range of immigration levels that would be both desirable and achievable.

On the basis of the above analysis it will be contentious to state an exact figure for Ghana’s

optimum population size. However, what cannot be disputed is that the current high level of population growth rate of 2.7 percent clearly puts the country on an inappropriate demographic

path. This argument wins favor from the Planned Parenthood Association of Ghana (PPAG)

which estimates that Ghana’s current population growth rate of 2.7 percent is not optimal for the

country’s income per capita (PPAG, 2009). It is reasonable to suggest that the optimum rate of

growth of Ghana’s population should be below that of Australia, which has almost the same

population size as Ghana (24 million), but which boasts of a bigger land size (compare Ghana’s

land area of 238,537 sq km to Australia’s 7,617,930 sq km). Moreover, Australia has a bigger per

capita income than Ghana ($28,900 as against $584) and is technologically more advanced than

Ghana – an advantage which can enable it to better deal with the challenges to higher productivity

associated with finite land size. Neville (1990) reveals that the optimum rate of growth of

Australia’s population is equal to 1.3 percent per annum but that anywhere in the range of 1.1

percent to 1.6 percent would be close to the optimum that is, it generates close to the optimum growth of income per capita. This implies that Ghana with a smaller per capita income and land

area should have an optimum population growth rate far lower than that of Australia, rather than

the current alarming rate of 2.7 percent. To further understand the dangerous demographic path

Ghana is walking, we need to examine, even if briefly, the merits of a policy aimed at reducing

the fertility rate. This area of analysis is known as population economics.

The starting point to an economic analysis of optimum population is to understand the

principle that optimum population size must balance two dramatically opposed forces: those

that bring advantages to size and those that yield disadvantages to size (Guest, 2007; Galor &

Zang, 1997). Advantages that accrue to economies of scale include those issuing from public

goods (such as national defense and public order and safety) where the total cost of the good is

not affected by an increase in population up to a point, thereby permitting a higher population to reduce the cost per capita. It is also argued that a larger market can compel innovation in the

sense of making it more profitable. A bigger population would also mean greater probability of

knowledge breakthroughs which produce multiplier effects on productivity (a process of so-

called endogenous growth) (Guest, 2007; PPAG, 2009).

Page 6: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

6 | JSRP Abdulai Kuyini Mohammed

There are disadvantages to a bigger population size which derive from the exhaustible supply of

natural resources (land for example), which lead to congestion and environmental costs and

diminishing marginal productivity of labor. A large population size can also mean cheaper labor

which can discourage innovation in labor saving technology (Guest, 2007). There is growing evidence that productivity and fertility are negatively correlated, and perhaps in both directions

(Becker & Barro, 1998; Galor & Zang, 1997; Gillespie et al., 2009; Guest & Swift, 2006). One of

the determinants of this is a situation, where parents with more children spend less on education per

child. This suggests that population growth compelled by high fertility may lower productivity.

Weighing the advantages against the disadvantages of bigger populations in order to ascertain

the net effect is an indeterminate or unresolved issue, both in theory and in practice. A point

emphasized in the seminal work of Cutler et al. (1990). But for a country like Ghana, with an

alarming population growth rate of 2.7 percent and low technology to mitigate the challenges to

productivity increases, the specter of overpopulation looms high. If this fear materializes then

foreseeable variations in population size are going to impact productivity significantly. Majority

of the respondents agree, arguing that the population size is a concern and if it is not controlled it

will not only lead to productivity decline but also reduction in quality of life. It would be an incomplete exercise if an analysis of optimum population considers only

population size (or its growth) to the neglect of dependency. Analysis should take account of

the consumption needs of dependent young and dependent old people and the fact that the

proportions of young and old in the population are changing (Guest, 2007; RIPS, 2009). Two

points have to be questioned here.

First, a movement to a path of higher fertility rate necessarily reduces consumption per capita

for a number of decades. This will come about because the youth dependency rate increases while

it takes some decades for this to be offset by a fall in the old dependency rate. When the old age

dependency rate eventually falls, consumption per capita recovers (Gillespie et al., 2009; Guest,

2007; Well, 1999).

Second, once the population has become stable at a higher fertility rate after many decades, the total dependency rate (youth plus old age) is likely to be higher than a lower fertility stable

population. Thus, the difference in living standards would be much different. Hence we suffer

the consequences of an increase in population size for many decades which may not be

reversible without government intervention, since private decisions are yielding sub-optimal

outcomes (Guest, 2007; Well, 1999). However, examining the dependency effects on living

standards only provides us with half of the picture.

A further consideration is that a transition to a higher fertility path has implications for

intergenerational equity because of productivity growth overtime. The continuous effects of

productivity growth through technological growth and technological transfer will mean that

living standards will continue to grow irrespective of the fertility rate (Guest & McDonald,

2002; Productivity Commission, 2005). However, this analysis is truer for a developed country

than a developing nation. This is because the creation and/or transfer, and application of new technology to improve productivity, are at lower levels in developing countries to bring about

the enhanced standard living.

It has already been explained in the preceding sections that an increase in fertility would

impose a cost on people alive now and in the near future, which will be reversed in several

decades later, boosting the living standards of people who would in any case have been

probably twice as well off as people today (Productivity Commission, 2005). But this is a

description of the scenario in advanced industrial countries like the US, UK and Germany or

Australia, whose standards of living are expected to be nearly double their current levels

(Productivity Commission, 2005). For developing nations, where the creation of new

technology is at a lower level, it is unlikely that their people will enjoy standards of living

comparable to the developed world. This means that a transition to a higher fertility rate in Ghana would yield an enhanced standard of living for neither present, nor future generations.

One of the respondents, the Director of the Family Health Division of the Ghana Health

Service agrees, when she asserts that the ‘FPP brings benefits to the family, benefits to the

society and benefits to the country and the world at large’. She adds that, ‘Without FPP Ghana

cannot attain the entire 8 Millennium Development Goals’.

Page 7: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

7 | JSRP Ghana’s Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

Will the FPP reduce fertility?

Effectiveness is the degree to which a policy or program attains its objectives. It is concerned

about whether the valued outcome of a policy has been achieved (Ayee, 2000; Dunn, 1994; Howlett & Ramesh, 2003). It has already been demonstrated at length that Ghana does need the

FPP. The next question to pose is: will this initiative work? In other words, will it achieve its

objectives? Findings internationally indicate that public policies do reduce fertility, albeit part

of the calculated effect may be traced to the timing impact where mothers delay childbirth in

their lifecycle rather than decrease or increase the number of children they prefer to have over

their lifetimes (Gillespie et al., 2009; Guest, 2007). Evidence from China shows that its “One

Child Policy” has reduced fertility rate drastically. Rwanda, one of the poorest, most densely

populated countries in the world, demonstrates the potential for family planning success in

Africa. The country documented one of the most rapid increases in contraceptive use ever

recorded, from 10 percent to 27 percent of women of reproductive age (Gillespie et al., 2009).

Between 1965 and 2005, use of family planning by women of reproductive age in the

developing world (excluding China) rose from less than 10 percent to 53 percent. The actual numbers grew from 30 million users in 2008, a dramatic increase. The result: a significant

decline in the average number of children born to each woman during her lifetime, from more

than six children to just over three (Gillespie et al., 2009).

In Ghana efforts at promoting family planning have yielded modest, but significant results.

Knowledge of family planning is almost universal, annual population growth rate has slowed

down from a peak of 3 percent in the 1970s to the current 2.7 percent (DHS, 2008; PPAG,

2009). The number of women using modern methods of family planning rose steadily from 6

percent in 1988 to 19 percent in 2003, but reduced to 17 percent in 2008. Total fertility rate

consequently reduced from 6.4 in 1988 and stagnated at 4.4 in 2003, and then decreased to 4.0

percent in 2008 (DHS, 2008).

However, caution should be exercised in reading too much into these statistics, because the total fertility rate does jump around a bit. For example, the Ghana Maternal Health Survey

recorded an increase in the total fertility rate from 4.4 in 2003 to 4.6 in 2008 (PPAG, 2009).

The Ghana Health Service (GHS) notes that the average Ghanaian woman marries at the age of

19 years, has her first child a year later and has an average of 4.5 children in her lifetime.

Moreover, there are regional variations in total fertility rate, ranging from 3 in Greater Accra

Region to about 7 children in the Northern region (DHS, 2003; GMHS, 2007). In addition,

there has been a slowing of the pace of decline in fertility rate, with little change demonstrated

in the past ten year period. Furthermore, there is the element of an announcement effect of

family planning programs. Barberis & Harvey (2001) contend that after the first few years of

the implementation of family planning programs the birth rate decreases somewhat, but rises

many years later. There is evidence that parents respond to advertisements in making family

planning decisions. But when these advertisements are scaled down or are withdrawn altogether a lapse in incentive to stay the course occurs.

The general consensus among experts in the 1960s when organized family planning

programs were introduced in Africa was that population growth in excess of 2 percent per year

is among the structural factors inhibiting the achievement of a wide range of development

objectives (PPAG, 2009). This implies that the current rate of growth of Ghana’s population of

2.7 percent is above the standard, and therefore sub-optimal from a developmental standpoint.

The analysis implies that the family planning program even though has achieved modest, but

significant gains, has failed to drastically reduce the total fertility rate to a level deemed

optimal from a developmental point of view. In other words, the adequacy of the FPP is

questionable. Adequacy refers to the extent to which a given level of effectiveness satisfies the

needs, values, or opportunities that gave rise to a problem. As a summary, it can be stated that on the basis of international evidence, family planning programs reduce fertility, but the Ghana

results are mixed or indeterminate.

Page 8: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

8 | JSRP Abdulai Kuyini Mohammed

Expensive policy

From a policy evaluation perspective it is not sufficient to ask whether the FPP will reduce

fertility rate. Like any public spending program the FPP must be ultimately financed by taxation, which imposes a deadweight loss on society by distorting private choices, in

particular the work/leisure choice. Hence, public spending programs should be delivered as

efficiently and effectively as possible, meaning with minimum deadweight loss for a given

outcome. This coincides with Howlett & Ramash’s (2003) view that public policy should

achieve the public interest by the best possible means. In other words, public policy has to

achieve its goals and do so in a way that yields the greatest possible benefit at the least possible

cost (Curtain, 2000). Put in another way, we need to determine whether the FPP is an efficient

policy. Efficiency refers to the relationship between inputs and outputs. It asks whether we

have accomplished more with little.

This is where the statistics on the funding of Ghana’s FPP is relevant. Ghana has been

heavily reliant on donor funding for implementing the program since its inception in the 1970s.

USAID, DFID, DANIDA, the World Bank, IPPF and Engender Health have provided strong financial and technical support for the FPP and other reproductive health programs (see Table

1). The table shows the contributions of the Ghanaian Government (GoG) represented by the

Ministry of Health (MoH) and development partners towards funding the FPP. The figures

reveal that the contributions of donor agencies far exceed that of the GoG. Donor contribution

to the FPP’s budget from 2003 to 2009 was 83.3 percent, whilst the share of Ghana’s

Government made up the remaining 16.7 percent. In terms of absolute figures, development

partners provided Ghana a total of US$35.25 million, with the GoG contributing a mere

US$7.08 million over the same period. The total funding for the FPP therefore stood at

US$42.33 million from 2003 to 2009.

The implications of these funding shares, by donors and the GoG, are quite obvious. First,

since the development partners fund the bulk of the FPP budget it leads to the erosion of policy ownership by the Ghanaian Government. The loss of policy ownership occurs because

development partners determine not only when the money will flow to the FPP fund, but also

the categories of FPP service repertoire that should be emphasized. These categories may not

necessarily be the priority areas the Government of Ghana wishes to promote to harmonize

with, and accelerate the pace of its development agenda

Table 1: Historical Funding from donors and Ghanaian Government of FPP (in US $

millions)

YEAR USAID

(US$)

DFID

(US$)

DANIDA

(US$)

UNFPA

(US$)

MOH

(US$)

TOTAL

(US$)

%

Donor

Cont.

%MOH

(GOG)

cont.

2003 2.57 1.56 - 0 1.57 5.69 72.4 27.6

2004 2.55 1.86 - 0 0.66 5.07 87.0 13.0

2005 1.72 0.90 - 0 1.85 4.47 58.6 41.4

2006 3.90 0.50 - 1.0 1.0 6.4 84.4 15.6

2007 4.95 0.30 - 2.5 1.0 8.75 88.6 11.4

2008 3.21 - 0.6 2.0 1.0 6.81 85.3 14.7

2009 2.44 - 0.6 2.1 0 5.14 100 0

TOTAL 21.34 5.11 1.20 7.60 7.08 42.33 83.3 16.7

Source: Deliver/RHI/UNFPA Reports 2007/2008/2009 Cited in PPAG (2009)

Secondly, the inability to determine when funds will flow to the FPP account distorts planning

and execution of family planning programs with the consequent inefficiencies and

ineffectiveness of policies.

Thirdly, the sustainability of this funding arrangement, whereby donors provide a

disproportionately large share of the money is questionable because there are inconsistencies in

the flow of contributions, from both the GoG and development partners. This makes it difficult

for program designers and implementers to predict how much it will be donated as the years go

Page 9: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

9 | JSRP Ghana’s Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

by. Added to this is the specter of default in contributions by all or any of the development

partners. And indeed, as Table 1 indicates, UNFPA for three consecutive years from 2003 to

2005 did not donate to the program. The GoG also could not contribute to the FPP in 2009. The

uncertainty about the quantum and timing of the flow of funds into the FPP account has created a funding gap. Forecasting up to 2011 depicts the existence of significant gaps in funding that

need to be filled urgently if the FPP is to succeed (see Table 2). In the highly likely event of

donors either contributing marginally or not at all, to the FPP, the GoG cannot make up for the

shortfall, considering that already about 40 percent of the country’s annual budget is funded by

development partners (CDD-Ghana, 2003). As commentators note, the surest way to kill a

policy is to starve it of funds. The policy lesson to draw from the above statistics is that even if

the response of FPP is strong, the cost can be high and unaffordable in Ghana’s case.

Table 2: FP Forecast/Commodity funding commitment gap (2008-2011) in millions

YEAR TOTAL

REQUIREMENT

(US$)

COMMITMENTS FUNDING GAP

(US$)

2008 9.95 6.81 3.14

2009 9.48 5.14 4.34

2010 8.85 0 8.85

2011 7.80 0 7.8

TOTAL 36.08 11.95 24.13

Source: Deliver/RHI/UNFPA Reports 2007/2008/2009 cited in PPAG (2009)

A neglected policy

The FPP seemed to have been ignored as a public health priority in Ghana because its services

are being increasingly underfunded for a number of reasons. First, the emergence of the

HIV/AIDS epidemic in Ghana has pushed FPP activities into the background, in terms of

visible political support and funding (GHS, 2006). Evidence indicates that population reduction

as a result of the epidemic (1.6 million deaths), in demographic terms, and in the context of the

Ghanaian situation, has no major impact on current population growth levels. This means

despite current proactive preventive and management programs to combat the epidemic, family

planning will remain as relevant as ever, as a key demographic policy instrument, but this is not receiving the needed attention (GHS, 2006). This means the government of Ghana is not

managing the agenda setting stage very well, as the FPP should have been maintained despite

the current salience of the HIV/AIDS epidemic. This finding is consistent with Grindle &

Thomas’ (1991) reflection on the agenda setting circumstances. They note that whether a

public policy problem will be treated with dispatch or not, hinges on whether it is labeled as a

crisis issue or not. The HIV/AIDS epidemic has been perceived by government and the citizens

as a crisis matter that deserves urgent attention. The epidemic also became a topical issue on

the international front, with governments being called upon by international bodies, like the

UN, to expedite action to control the spread of the disease. Seeing the number of people dying

by the disease in hospitals and in the communities, and the consequent drastic loss of

productive hands, there was societal pressure for government’s intervention to nip the problem

in the bud. The same cannot be said about the problem of the rapid growth of the population, which agenda status has shifted to the bottom of the priority list of not only the Ghanaian

government, but also world bodies like the UN. Some people in Ghana particularly, in the rural

areas, do not even see the rapid growth of the population as a problem and are therefore less

inclined to put pressure on the government to arrest the situation.

Second, family planning services are currently not being covered as part of the National Health

Insurance Scheme (NHIS), which conspicuously excluded these services from the benefits package

when it was launched in 2003. Family planning was determined to be an “essential public good”,

such as immunization, and should be offered free through the Ghana Health Service. However,

because constrained budgets are unable to cover all basic operational costs at the facility level, in

Page 10: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

10 | JSRP Abdulai Kuyini Mohammed

actual practice, almost every public facility and all private facilities charge fees for family planning

services (PPAG, 2009). This evidence conflicts with Brislin (1981), Moran and Harris’ thoughts

on synergetic policy making, which calls for linkages and mutual support for related social policies

and programs. By excluding the FPP from the funding arrangement we are literally saying that: “deliver free of charge at any facility, but pay at the same facility to control your births:” In other

words, government is creating marginal incentives for women to have more children and marginal

disincentive to space their births. This scenario will not augur well for the reproductive health of

women, which is the broader goal of government.

A cost-benefit analysis of adding coverage of long term and permanent contraceptives, as well

as injectables, to the NHIS benefits package revealed that including family planning would cause

a decrease in fertility and would avert births that would otherwise have cost the NHIS

considerable expenditures. Adding this benefit would lead to an annual savings to the NHIS that

would increase over time. The size of the net savings depends on a number of variables, which

may change over time. According to the consultant’s assumptions, if family planning had been

covered in 2009, by 2011 the NHIS will realize almost GH₡ 11 million in net savings in that year

alone. This increases to over GH₡ 18 million in 2017 (USAID/Banking on Health, 2008). In

other words, excluding the FPP from the NHIS has generated significant inefficiencies.

In contrast, funding is increasingly being made available to support the FMCPW as part of

an international effort to improve progress towards the Millennium Development Goals

(MDGs). Achieving the MDGs is an international policy agenda that was mooted by the UN

and subscribed to by all member nations, including Ghana. Advanced industrialized countries

are promoting the agenda by supplying funds to developing countries and monitoring their

performance in achieving these goals. Ghana has accordingly included the achievement of the

MDGs as part of its domestic policy agenda, with a priority tag attached to it, but has relegated

the FPP to the background. This confirms Ohmae (1995) and Falk’s (1997) assertion that

nations are increasingly constrained and shaped by global forces. Out of pocket spending for family planning services and commodities is roughly estimated

to be $2 million per year. The replacement of these in the light of stagnating donor support and

government funding, despite recent increases in need, is woefully inadequate (PPAG, 2009). In

2008, forecast demand for family planning products exceeded the amount allocated in the

health budget for family planning by $7 million (PPAG, 2009). Counseling for family planning

is free, but reproductive health supply has to be paid for.

This findings corroborate the views of Brislin (1981), Moran & Harris (1981) that we are

developing and implementing the FPP and FMCPW in Ghana as separate programs; that

instead of working on the policies as a joint initiative, we are treating them as separate parts

and privileging the former over the latter, and that handling them this way will not bring

mutual growth and accomplishment of their respective objectives and the broader goal of achieving a high standard of reproductive health of women. In other words, there is no synergy

between the FPP and FMCPW.

Policies at odds with each other

While FPP is not covered under the National Health Insurance Scheme (NHIS) the FMCPW is

well placed on it. The question that arises is: Are the FPP and FMCPW at odds with each

other? In answer, it does appear financial incentives now favor more, rather than fewer births.

Expanded NHIS coverage for pregnant women makes the medical care costs of additional

births zero for women, which provides a marginal incentive to increase average total fertility

per woman. Lack of NHIS coverage for family planning services disadvantageous in delaying or limiting births, providing a marginally negative incentive to delay or limit births (PPAG,

2009). This point of view, however, does not win favor from Ghana’s Eastern Regional

Population Officer. He contends that rather than increasing the fertility rate, the FMCPW could

result in a decrease in birth rates as it focuses on comprehensive management of pregnancies

that include mother and child survival, promotion of family planning and health practices. He

added that uptake of education opportunities by girls and women, and the lengthening of their

Page 11: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

11 | JSRP Ghana’s Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

time in educating up to the tertiary level has reduced fecund level or the number of children

born per woman during her lifetime to 2, although the Eastern Region’s average is still above

four (Abinah, 2008).

His assessment should be treated with caution since the fertility rate has not dropped for the past several years. It should also be noted that the FPP has a yawning funding gap, and there is

a potential for donor support to dwindle and dry up in the future. In contrast, funding for the

FMCPW is assured for many years to come, this implies there is a real danger of the FPP being

crowded out of government priorities.

The consequences of this lack of synergy between the programs is that family planning

services and commodities have become more costly to access since parents will have to fully

finance these services and products out of their pocket. On the other hand, couples who would

have been reluctant to have more children due to the cost of antenatal and post-natal medical

care would have an incentive to have them. Perhaps the only way to make the FMCPW cost-

effective is to limit it to expectant mothers who will be having their first, second or third

children. Then from the fourth child onwards a co-contribution from government and couples

will apply. The contribution from parents should be means tested where progressively those in the lower income bracket pay less. The idea is that if parents bear part of the cost it will

influence their decisions in favor of fewer children.

However, majority of the respondents do not agree with the above point that the FPP and

FMCPW are conflicting. On the contrary, they think they are complementary. However,

minority views put these initiatives at odds with each other. One of these respondents alludes

that ‘If you say free maternal care, then the woman should also come for free family planning

of her choice’. She adds, ‘Without free family planning, the message seems to be that the

government will pay for you to have a baby, but will ask you to pay from your pocket to

practice family planning’. She concludes by implying that, ‘the Slogan is: you are encouraged

to have more babies but discouraged to limit your birthrate’.

Discussion

Based on the analytical framework of Grindle & Thomas (1991), the agenda setting

circumstances of Ghana’s FMCPW initiative were such that there was a strong perception of a

crisis and a need for action among political, as well as technical and bureaucratic actors and

civil society. There was strong pressure for change from a “Cash and Carry” system to a

national health insurance scheme (NHIS), which would enfold the FMCPW, to make health

care costs less burdensome for the masses. The stakes for reform were therefore high. High

level decision makers, including the president, were concerned about getting national health

insurance and the FMCPW in particular to work in Ghana and made this clear in public

statements. The then National Patriotic Party (NPP) government was keenly interested in materializing NHIS and the FMCPW to pride itself that it had delivered on an election promise

so as to bolster its electoral advantages in the next elections. For the then opposition National

Democratic Congress (NDC) – which sees itself as a social democratic party, it did not want to

be seen as opposing a major policy reform that would support the underprivileged and the

vulnerable and therefore approved of the policy, but with reservations. These reservations

compelled the party to continue to criticize the government on implementation bottlenecks.

Thus, the policy decision making focus seemed to have been centered on concerns about

political relationships and stability.

The priority tag the government attached to the FMCPW was prompted by international

bodies like the UN, which had already declared maternal mortality as an international health

crisis, and adopted MDG Goal 5 to stem it. As a member of this world body, Ghana accordingly conformed by also placing it high on its policy agenda. Unlike the FMCPW, the

FPP has been running in Ghana since the 1970s and even though it was repositioned in 2006 to

achieve its goals, it was not perceived as a crisis issue, both internationally and domestically,

the stakes were therefore low, and incremental decision making by low and middle level policy

makers was acceptable. This confirms Grindle & Thomas’ (1991) contention that the crisis or

Page 12: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

12 | JSRP Abdulai Kuyini Mohammed

non crisis nature of an issue, and whether the problem is topical or otherwise on the

international scene, would determine whether or not it would have placement on a

government’s policy agenda.

Conclusion The study set out to determine whether the FPP has policy merits and whether it is a neglected

government priority. This question has been answered through responses to three further

questions. The first question related to whether Ghana needs an FPP. In other words, is the FPP

an appropriate policy? The answer to this question is, yes. It is clear from the study that there is a

need for it because we are already on or close to an inappropriate or even dangerous demographic

track. I have also demonstrated that a higher population growth rate will increase total

dependency in the long run and along the transition path. The consequences will be suffered by

the present and future generations. Issues about the net effect of economies versus diseconomies

of bigger populations are salient to mention, but they remain indeterminate. Yet we cannot ignore

them when they are considered against the current demographic trends in Ghana. It thus appears in the Ghanaian situation that the diseconomies of population size are weighing more than the

advantages and intervention is certainly needed to at least, restore a balance.

The second question demanded an answer as to whether the FPP is efficacious in reducing

fertility. The evidence shows that even though the FPP has made modest, but significant gains, it

has failed to drastically reduce the total fertility rate to a level deemed optimal from a

developmental point of view. Looking at it from another side, the FPP is not adequate because the

given level of effectiveness from it has not significantly tamed the rapid rate of growth of

Ghana’s population. In terms of equity, both the rich and the poor pay the same amounts to

procure family planning products, meaning there is no equity in the provision of family services.

The third question probed about whether the FPP is a neglected policy. The answer is in the

affirmative, because the salience of the HIV/AIDS epidemic and the FMCPW has pushed the FPP to the background. The evidence shows that unless family planning services and

commodities are included for funding under the NHIS, there will be a cost for delaying or

limiting births, providing little incentive to delay or limit births. And that the current free

maternal health care without a family planning component is serving as an incentive to reduce

birth spacing and increase pregnancies, thereby undermining the impact of family planning. In

other words there is no synergy between the FPP and FMCPW. A situation appalled by Brislin,

Moran and Harris as not engendering mutual growth and accomplishment of broader overall

objectives. The FPP appears to be a neglected government policy.

References

1. Abinah, K. (2008). Free Medical Care for Pregnant Women Would not Lead to

population Explosion. Modern Ghana, Retrieved 30 July, 2010, from

www.modernghana.com/news/167603/1/free-medical-care-for-pregnant-women-

would-not-lea.html.

2. Adjei, S., & Agyeapong, I. K. (2008). Public Social Policy Development and

Implementation: A Case Study of the Ghana National Health Insurance Scheme,

Health policy and Plannning, 23, pp. 150-160.

3. Arjun, A. (1996). Population Trends: Ghana, United States Department of Commerce.

4. Australian Commonwealth Parliament (1994). The Jones Report on Australia’s

population Carrying Capacity: One Nation Two Ecologies, report by the House of

Representatives Standing Committee on Long Term Strategies, Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service.

Page 13: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

13 | JSRP Ghana’s Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

5. Ayee, J. R. A. (2000). Saints, Wizards, Demons and Systems: Explaining the Success

or Failure of Public Policies and Programmes. Accra: Ghana Universities Press.

6. Barberis, M., & Harvey, P. D. (2001). Costs of Family Planning Programmes in

Fourteen Developing Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

7. Becker, G., & Barro, R. (1998). A Reformulation of the Economic Theory of Fertility.

The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103(412), pp. 1-25

8. Bennett, C.J. (1997). Understanding Ripple Effects: The Cross-National Adoption of

Policy Instruments for Bureaucratic Accountability. Governance, 10(3), pp. 313-33.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0952-1895.401997040

9. Berstein, S., & Cahoe, B. (2000). Globalization, Four Paths of Internalisation and

Domestic Change: The Case of EcoForestry in British Colombia, Canada. Canadian

Journal of Political Science, 33(1), pp. 67-100.

10. Brenner, N. (1999). Beyond State Centrism? Space Territoriality and Geographical

Scale in Globalisation Studies. Theory and Society, 28(1), pp. 39-78.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1006996806674

11. Bridgman, P., & Davis, G. (2004). The Australian Policy Handbook. 3rd edition. Crow’s Nest NSW: Allen and Unwin.

12. Brislin, R. W. (1981). Cross Cultural Encounters. New York: Pergamon.

13. Ghana Centre for Democratic Development (CDD-Ghana) (2003). The Funding of

Key Governance Institutions in Ghana, Report of a Diagnostic Study (Accra: National Governance Program).

14. Carrin, G. (2003). Community Based Health Insurance Scheme in Developing

Countries: facts, problems and perspectives. Discussion Paper No. 1, Geneva, World

Health Organization.

15. Carrin, G., & James, C. (2004). Reshaping Universal Coverage via Social Health

Insurance: Key Design Features in the Transition Period. Discussion Paper No. 2,

EIP/FER/DP 042, Geneva, World Health Organization.

16. Cassells, A. (1995). Health Sector Reform: Key Issues in Less Developed Countries.

Forum on Health Sector Reform, Discussion paper No. 1 (WHO: SHS/NHP/954).

Geneva, World Health Organization.

17. Coleman, M. M., & Perl, A. (1999). Internationalized Policy Environment and Policy

Network Analysis. Political Studies, 47(4), pp. 691-709.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1467-9248.00225

18. Curtain, R. (2000). Good Policy Making: How Australia Fares? Agenda, 8(1), pp. 33-46.

19. Cutler, D., Poterba, J., Sheiner, l., & Summers, L. (1990). An Aging Society:

Opportunity or Challenge? Brookings Papers in Economic Activity, Spring, pp. 1-74.

20. Dunn, J. E. (1994). A Systems Analysis of political Life. New York: Wiley.

21. Falk, R. (1997). State of Seige: Will Globalization win out? International Affairs,

73(1), pp. 124-36. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2623553

Page 14: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

14 | JSRP Abdulai Kuyini Mohammed

22. Finnemore, M., & Sikkink, K. (1998). International Norm Dynamics and Political

Change. International Organization, 52(4), pp. 887-917.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/002081898550789

23. Galor, O., & Zang, H. (1997). Fertility, Income Distribution, and Economic Growth:

Theory and Cross-Country Evidence. Japan and World Economy, 9(2), pp. 197-229.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0922-1425(96)00245-9

24. Ghana Health Service (DHS) (2008). Ghana Demographic and Health Survey Report.

25. Ghana Health Service (DHS) (2003). Ghana Demographic and Health Survey Report.

26. Ghana Maternal Health Study (GMHS) (2007). Report, Ghana Health Service.

27. GHS (2006). A Road Map for Repositioning Family Planning in Ghana (2006-2010).

Accra: Duke and Duke Inc.

28. Goldstein, J. S., & Whitworth, S. (2005). International Relations, Canadian ed.

Toronto: Pearson Longman.

29. Gillespie, D., Maguire, E., Neuse, M., Sinding, S., & Speidel, J. J. (2009). Making the

Case for US International Family Planning Assistance. The Bill and Melinda Gates

Institute for Population and Reproductive Health. Baltimore, MD

30. Grindle, M. S., & Thomas, J. W. (1991). Public Choice and Policy Change: The

Political Economy of Reform in Developing Countries, Baltimore, MD: John Hopkins

University Press.

31. Guest, R. (2007). The Baby Bonus: A Dubious Policy Initiative. Policy, 23(1), pp. 11-15.

32. Guest, R., & McDonald, I. (2002). Would a Decrease in Fertility be a Threat to Living

Standards in Australia? Australian Economic Review, 35(1), pp. 29-44.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1467-8462.00221

33. Guest, R., & Swift, R. (2006). Fertility, Income Inequality and Labour Productivity,

Brisbane: Griffith University.

34. Hirst, P., & Thompson, G. (1996). Globalization in Question, Oxford: Polity Press.

35. Howlett, M. & Ramesh, M. (2003). Studying Public Policy: Policy Cycles and Policy

Systems. UK: Oxford University Press.

36. McDonald, P., & Kippen, R. (1999). Population Futures for Australia: the Policy

Alternatives, Parliament of Australia, research paper No. 5, Canberra: APH. October

12. Retrieved June 20, 2009, from http://www.aph.gov.au/library/pubs/rp/1999-2000/2000rp05.htm

37. Ministry of Health (MoH) (2004). Guidelines for Implementing the Exemption Policy

on Maternal Deliveries, Accra, Ministry of Health. Report No: MoH/policy, planning,

Monitoring and Evaluation 59.

38. Moran, R. T., & Harris, P. R. (1981). Managing Cultural Synergy, Houston, Tex: Gulf

Publishing Company.

39. Ohmae, K. (1995). The End of the Nation State, London: Harper-Collins.

Page 15: Ghana's Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

15 | JSRP Ghana’s Family Planning Program: A Neglected Policy Initiative?

40. Planned Parenthood Association of Ghana (PPAG) (2009). The Case for Adding

Family Planning on the National Health Insurance Scheme. Position Paper.

41. Productivity Commission (2005). Economic Implications of an Aging Australia,

Canberra: PC, April.

42. Neville, J, (1990). The Effect of immigration on Australian Living Standards, Bureau

of Immigration Research, South Carlton: Commonwealth of Australia

43. Osabutey, P. D. (2008). Ghana: Achieving MDG5 through Free Medical care for

Pregnant Women, The Chronicle, July 25.

44. RHI/UNFPA Reports (2007, 2008, 2009). Cited in Planned Parenthood Association of

Ghana (PPAG) (2009). The Case for Adding Family Planning on the National Health

Insurance Scheme. Position Paper.

45. Preker, A. S. (Ed.) (2002). Health Care Financing for Rural and Low Income

Populations: The Role of Communities in Resource Mobilization and Risk Sharing.

Washington DC: IBRD/World Bank.

46. Pressman, J., & Wildavsky (1984). Implementation, 3rd ed., Berkeley: California

University Press.

47. Productivity Commission (2005). Economic Implications of an Aging Australia,

Canberra: PC, April.

48. Regional Institute for Population Studies (RIPS) (2009). Measuring Economic and

Social Impact of Migration in Ghana, Mid-Grant Presentation to CDN/JPPR.

49. Thomas, S., & Gilson, L. (2004). Actor Management in the Development of Health

Financing Reform: Health Insurance in South Africa, 1994-1999. Health Policy and

Planning, 19(5), pp. 279-291. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/heapol/czh033

50. UNDP (2007). Ghana Human Development Report, United Nations Development

Programme, Ghana. Retrieved 13 May, 2014, from

www.undp.org/sites/default/files/nhdr_2007_ghana.pdf.

51. USAID/Banking on Health (2008). An Analysis of the Costs and Benefits to the

National Health Insurance Scheme in Adding Family planning Products and Services

to the Coverage Package.

52. Walt, G., & Gilson, L. (1994). Reforming the Health Sector in Developing Countries:

The Central Role of Policy Analysis. Health Policy and Planning, 9, pp. 353-370.

http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/heapol/9.4.353

53. Well, D, (1999). Population Growth, Dependency and Consumption. American

Economic Review, 89(2), pp. 251-255 (Papers and proceedings).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.2.251