Top Banner
1 Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness Zoltán Varga 1 , Antonino Scarelli 2 , Ross Cressman 3 and József Garay 4 1 Institute of Mathematics and Informatics, Szent István University, Godollo / Hungary, [email protected] 2 Dept. of Ecology and Economic Sustainable Development, University of Tuscia, Viterbo / Italy, [email protected] 3 Department of Mathematics, Wilfrid Laurier University, Waterloo, Ontario / Canada, [email protected] 4 Ecological Modelling Research Group of the Hungarian Academy of Science, Dept. of Plant Taxonomy and Ecology, L. Eötvös University, Budapest / Hungary, [email protected] Abstract A game-theoretical model for the behaviour in a marketing cooperative is proposed. For the strategy choice an evolutionary dynamics is introduced. Considering a model with penalty for unfaithfulness and Cournot type market situation, it is shown that, if the penalty is effective then this strategy dynamics drives the players towards an attractive solution, a particular type of Nash equilibrium. A model with redistribution of penalty is also studied. For the symmetric case, on the bases of stability analysis of the strategy dynamics, in terms of the model parameters, sufficient conditions are provided for the strategy choice to converge to a strict Nash equilibrium. Keywords: marketing cooperative, oligopoly, evolutionary game dynamics. 1. Introduction In agriculture we often face the situation that producers of a given product form a marketing cooperative, for the commercialization of their product. Such a cooperative in a given region may perform several activities, ranging from product processing to complex marketing, see e.g. Cobia (1989). In this paper we consider a marketing cooperative that negotiates a contracted price with large buyers, sharing risk among members of the cooperative. By the time of the actual commercialization of the product, the market price may be higher than what the
16

Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

May 15, 2023

Download

Documents

Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

1

Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

Zoltán Varga1, Antonino Scarelli2, Ross Cressman3 and József Garay4

1Institute of Mathematics and Informatics, Szent István University,

Godollo / Hungary, [email protected]

2Dept. of Ecology and Economic Sustainable Development, University of Tuscia,

Viterbo / Italy, [email protected]

3Department of Mathematics, Wilfrid Laurier University, Waterloo,

Ontario / Canada, [email protected]

4 Ecological Modelling Research Group of the Hungarian Academy of Science, Dept. of Plant Taxonomy and

Ecology, L. Eötvös University, Budapest / Hungary, [email protected]

Abstract

A game-theoretical model for the behaviour in a marketing cooperative is proposed. For the strategy choice an

evolutionary dynamics is introduced. Considering a model with penalty for unfaithfulness and Cournot type

market situation, it is shown that, if the penalty is effective then this strategy dynamics drives the players

towards an attractive solution, a particular type of Nash equilibrium. A model with redistribution of penalty is

also studied. For the symmetric case, on the bases of stability analysis of the strategy dynamics, in terms of the

model parameters, sufficient conditions are provided for the strategy choice to converge to a strict Nash

equilibrium.

Keywords: marketing cooperative, oligopoly, evolutionary game dynamics.

1. Introduction

In agriculture we often face the situation that producers of a given product form a marketing cooperative, for the

commercialization of their product. Such a cooperative in a given region may perform several activities, ranging

from product processing to complex marketing, see e.g. Cobia (1989). In this paper we consider a marketing

cooperative that negotiates a contracted price with large buyers, sharing risk among members of the cooperative.

By the time of the actual commercialization of the product, the market price may be higher than what the

Page 2: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

2

cooperative can guarantee for members, negotiated on beforehand. (A normal form game model of a cooperative

with a constant market price was set up in Scarelli and Larbani 2004.) Some “unfaithful” members may be

interested in selling at least a part of their product outside, the cooperative, however, can punish them for it. This

conflict situation is described in terms of a game-theoretical model.

In section 2 we set up a game model of a marketing cooperative, where every single member and the cooperative

itself are the players. The strategy of a player is the proportion of the total production sold to the cooperative,

while the cooperative chooses a penalty as its strategy to punish unfaithfulness. For this game an attractive

solution, a particular NE (Nash equilibrium) is obtained. For the concept and the existence of an attractive

solution, in a more general situation see Larbani (1997), Larbani and Lebbah H. (1999).

Section 3 is devoted to a game model with penalty and with Cournot type oligopoly market with linear inverse

demand function. For this game we also find an attractive solution.

In section 4 an evolutionary dynamics for the strategy choice of the players is given. This dynamics (the so-

called partial adaptive dynamics) is known in multispecies evolutionary game theory, see Garay (2002). (We

note that in Cressman et al. (2004), in a different situation, another dynamic evolutionary game model was

applied to the analysis of economic behaviour.) It is shown that, if the penalty is effective then this strategy

dynamics drives the players towards an attractive solution.

In section 5 a model with redistribution of penalty is studied. For the symmetric case when the members of the

cooperative produce the same quantity and faithfulness is rewarded proportionally to the product sold to the

cooperative, for different values of the penalty parameter, a strict NE is obtained. A stability analysis of the

strategy dynamics, in terms of the model parameters, provides sufficient conditions for the strategy choice to

converge to the strict NE.

2. Game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty and constant market price

Let us consider a marketing cooperative of n members producing the same product with per-unit of production

cost c . The cooperative guarantees to buy the whole production of its members at a contracted unit price cp > .

However, by the time the product is available (e.g. a crop is harvested) the market may offer a better price, and a

member may have a propensity to sell a part of his product on the market. Assume the total production of

member i ( ni ,1∈ ) in a given time period is iL , and he sells the ix -part ( ]1,0[∈ix ) of his production to the

Page 3: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

3

cooperative at the contracted unit price p , and the ix−1 -part on the market, at a unit price pq > . Then the

profit of the thi member is

])[()]1)(()[( cqxqpLxcqxcpL iiiii −+−=−−+− .

This attains a maximum at 0:=ix , risking the collapse of the cooperative.

Suppose now the cooperative decides to set a penalty for unfaithfulness, proportional to the extra profit gained

from selling outside the cooperative. Then we have a conflict situation that can be modelled by the following

normal form game:

the thi player is the thi member of the cooperative ),1( ni∈ ,

the thn )1( + player is the cooperative,

]1,0[ is the strategy set of each player,

nx ]1,0[∈ is the strategy vector of the members,

]1,0[∈y is the strategy of the cooperative (penalty rate).

For any multistrategy ]1,0[]1,0[),( ×∈ nyx , the payoff (profit = revenue – cost – penalty) of the thi player is

])1)(()1)(()[(:),( iiiiiii LxpqyLxcqLxcpyxf −−−−−+−=

)]}()[1(){( pqycqxxcpL iii −−−−+−= , ),1( ni∈

and for the thn )1( + player the payoff is

∑ −−==

+

n

jjjn xLpqyyxf

11 )1()(:),( .

With notation ),...,,(: 121 += nffff , for the description of the cooperative we have a normal form game

( )],1,0[]1,0[ fn × .

Solution of the game

Page 4: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

4

In terms of vector n]1,0[)1,...,1,1(: ∈=1 , consider the multistrategy )1,(1 . Here the choice 1=:x means that

each member sells all his production to the cooperative, 1:=y means that the cooperative sets the maximum

penalty rate for unfaithfulness.

It is easy to see that for any ,,1 ni∈ nx ]1,0[∈ and ]1,0[∈y we have

0)()]}()[1(){()1,()1,( =−−−−−−+−=− cpLpqcqxxcpLfxf iiiiii 1 , (2.1)

and

=− ++ )1,(),( 11 11 nn fyf 0)11()()11()(11

=−∑−−−∑−==

n

jj

n

jj LpqLpqy . (2.2)

Equality (2.1) means that, if the cooperative decides to set the maximum penalty rate 1:=y , then the

(independent) decision of any member to sell outside can not increase his own payoff, whatever the other

members do. An interpretation of (2.2) is the following: if all members sell all their production to the

cooperative, the latter can not improve its payoff deviating from the maximum penalty.

Now we will see that multistrategy )1,(1 turns out to be an attractive solution (see e.g. Larbani, 1997) of the

game (in particular, a Nash equilibrium), in the sense of following definition. Consider an N -player game

where

iX is the strategy set of the thi player,

∏==

N

iiXX

1: the set of multistrategies,

R→XFi : the payoff of the thi player, ),...,(: 1 NFFF = .

Definition 1. A multistrategy 0x is said to be an attractive solution of the normal form game ( FX , ), if there

exists a player Ni ,1∈ such that the following conditions are satisfied:

A) ),...,,...,( 01 Nij xxxF ≤ )( 0xFj , ( Nj ,1∈ \{i}, kk Xx ∈ , Nk ,1∈ \ }{i );

Page 5: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

5

B) ),...,,...,( 001 Nii xxxF ≤ )( 0xFi , ( ii Xx ∈ ).

Remark 1. If in condition A), for each Nj ,1∈ \{i} we choose kkk Xxx ∈= 0: for Nk ,1∈ \ },{ ji , and an

arbitrary jj Xx ∈ , we obtain that any attractive solution is a NE, too.

3. A game model with penalty and Cournot type oligopoly market

Let us consider now a generalization of the previous case, supposing that the market environment is determined

by the offer of the unfaithful members of the cooperative, in terms of a Cournot type oligopoly model, and the

penalty may exceed the actual extra profit of the unfaithful member.

Maintaining the notation of the previous section, let us suppose that on the outside market a Cournot type

oligopoly situation with a linear inverse demand function takes place: with appropriate constants 0, >ba , for

nx ]1,0[∈ the unit price is ∑ −−==

n

iii xLbaxq

1)1()( , and pq >)0( is also supposed, implying 0)( >xq

)]1,0[( nx∈ . Notice that under this condition, also for the case of oligopoly, the members would be absolutely

interested in selling outside the cooperative. (The degenerate case pq =)0( will not be considered.) Now, the

question again is whether a penalty is able to stabilize the cooperative.

Let 1≥β be a penalty parameter in the sense that on calculating the penalty, instead of y , the extra profit is

multiplied by yβ . Then the payoffs of the corresponding players are the following: for any multistrategy

]1,0[]1,0[),( ×∈ nyx , we have

])1)()(()1)()(()[(:),( iiiiiii LxpxqyLxcxqLxcpyxf −−−−−+−= β

= )]})(()()[1(){( pxqycxqxxcpL iii −−−−+− β , ),1( ni∈ ,

and

∑ −−==

+

n

jjjn xLpxqyyxf

11 )1())((:),( β .

Page 6: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

6

Now for any ,,1 ni∈ nx ]1,0[∈ and ]1,0[∈y we easily obtain that

0))()(1)(1( )1,()1,( ≤−−−=− pxqxLfxf iiii β1 ,

and

0)11())(()11())(()1,(),(11

11 =∑ −−−∑ −−=−==

++

n

jj

n

jjnn LpxqLpxqyfyf ββ11 .

Furthermore, in case 1>β , for ( ni ,1∈ ), nx ]1,0[∈ with 1<ix , the inequality is strict. Indeed, the above

condition pq >)0( implies for all nx ]1,0[∈ we have

0)0()1()(11

>−=−∑−≥−∑ −−=−==

pqpLapxLapxqn

jj

n

jjj .

Hence we obtain

Theorem 1. Multistrategy )1,(1 is an attractive solution of the oligopoly game.

Remark 2. Apart from being an attractive solution, for any 1≥β multistrategy )1,(1 also has the following

particular property. Suppose that the cooperative sets a penalty rate different from the maximum, [1,0[∈y .

Then using any strategy vector nx ]1,0[∈ with 1<ix for some ni ,1∈ , we have

>><=>

−−−=−;/1y and 1 if 0,

1, if 0,))()(1)(1()1,(),(

βββ

β pxqxyLfyxf iiii 1

and

>><=>

∑ −−−−=−=

++ ./1y and 1 if 0,1, if 0,

)1())()(1()1,(),(1

11 βββ

βn

jjjnn xLpxqyxfyxf

The above inequalities can be interpreted as follows: Suppose the cooperative sets a penalty rate 1<y and the

thi player deviates from his equilibrium strategy (i.e. becomes unfaithful). Then, whatever the other members do,

the payoff of the thi player will

a) increase, if 1=β and

Page 7: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

7

b) decrease, if 1>β and β1y > ;

whilst the payoff of the cooperative will

a) decrease, if 1=β and

b) increase, if 1>β and β1y > .

4. Evolutionary dynamics for the strategy choice and its asymptotic properties

Evolutionary dynamics

We suppose the dynamic (time-dependent) strategy choice of the players can be described by an evolutionary

dynamics. This is a variant of the so-called partial adaptive dynamics) known in multispecies evolutionary game

theory, see Garay (2002). We note that in Cressman et al. (2004), in a different situation, another dynamic

evolutionary game model has been applied to the analysis of economic behaviour. We will show that, if the

penalty is effective then this strategy dynamics drives the players towards an attractive solution.

Namely, for the time-dependent strategies )(txi and )(ty let us consider the following system:

),()1( yxfDxxx iiiii −=& ( ni ,1∈ ), (4.3)

),()1( 11 yxfDyyy nn ++−=& . (4.4)

The intuitive background of this dynamics is the hypothesis that each player will increase (or decrease) his

strategy (quantity sold to the cooperative, or penalty rate), if the corresponding strategy change results in the

increase (or decrease) of his payoff; provided the rest of the players stick to their actual strategies. This means

that the sign of the corresponding partial derivative will determine the process of the strategy choice.

For the model with penalty and Cournot type oligopoly market, let us calculate this dynamics:

For all ]1,0[]1,0[),( ×∈ nyx we obtain

)]1()()[1()1( iiiiii xbLpxqyLxxx −−−+−−= β& ( ni ,1∈ ), (4.5)

∑ −−−==

n

jjj xLpxqyyy

1)1())(()1( β& . (4.6)

Page 8: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

8

Asymptotic properties of the strategy dynamics

Multistrategy )1,(1 is obviously an equilibrium for dynamics (4.5)-(4.6). For the long term outcome of the game

let us analyze the stability of this equilibrium for different values of the penalty parameter β .

Theorem 2. In case of limited penalty ( 1=β ) the attractive solution )1,(1 of the “static game” is unstable. If

the penalty is effective ( 1>β ), any solution of the strategy dynamics starting from ))0(),0(( yx in

[1,/1][1,0] β×n close enough to { } ]1,/1[ β×1 , tends to the attractive solution ),( 0y1 with some

]1,/1]0 β∈y . (The latter statement means that in case of an effective penalty ( 1>β ), according to the strategy

dynamics, the players are driven towards an attractive solution of the game.)

Proof. Case 1=β

Let [1,0][1,0]),( ×∈ nyx . Since pxq −)( is greater than a fix positive number, from (4.6) function y is

strictly increasing. For the right-hand side of equation (4.5) we get 0)1( <+− y , and near )1,(1 , term

0)( >− pxq is dominant in factor )]1()([ ii xbLpxq −−− , implying ix is strictly decreasing. Therefore,

the attractive solution )1,(1 is unstable. (Note that this is also true for the constant price case, when 0:=b )

Case 1>β

Again, (4.6) implies y is strictly increasing. Now in equation (5), for β1y > we obtain 0)1( >+− yβ ,

implying ix is strictly increasing. Hence, for every initial value [1,/1][1,0]))0(),0(( β×∈ nyx close enough

to { } ]1,/1[ β×1 , the boundedness of the corresponding solution ),( yx implies there exist

),(lim:),( 00 yxyx∞

= . It is easily seen that ),( 00 yx must be an equilibrium of dynamics (4.5)-(4.6). From the

above sign discussion it is clear that 1=0x must hold, but for 0y we have only ]1,/1]0 β∈y .

Now we show that for all ]1,/1]0 β∈y , multistrategy ),( 0y1 is an attractive solution of the oligopoly game

with penalty. Indeed, for all ,,1 ni∈ nx ]1,0[∈ and ]1,0[∈y , an easy calculation gives

){()])(()()[1(){( ),(),( 000 cpLpxqycxqxxcpLyfyxf iiiiii −−−−−−+−=− β1

0)1)()()(1( 0 <−−−= ypxqxL ii β ,

Page 9: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

9

0),(),( 011 =− ++ yfyf nn 11 ,

implying ),( 0y1 is an attractive solution.

5. Model with redistribution of penalty

In the previous theorem we have seen how an effective penalty can stabilize the cooperative. In this section we

show the stabilization is even stronger, if the collected effective penalty is partly distributed among the faithful

members. In particular, for the symmetric case when all members produce the same amount, sufficient

conditions are obtained for the existence and asymptotic stability of a strict NE. Suppose a part of the total

penalty collected

)1(])([:),(1

in

ii xLpxqyyxP −∑−=

is redistributed amongst the members i with 0>ix , according to the proportions 0)( ≥xiα , with

0)( =xiα , if 0=ix ; 1)(01

<∑<=

n

ii xα and 0)( >xD iiα ( nxni [1,0 ,1 ∈]∈ ).

Then the resulting payoffs are

)]1)()(()1)(([:),( iiiii xpxqycxxqpxLyxf −−−−−+= β ),()( yxPxiα+ ),1( ni∈ (5.7)

and

∑ −−∑−===

+

n

jjj

n

iin xLpxqyxyxf

111 )1())(())(1(:),( βα .

(5.8)

First we consider the problem, how to localize a NE in the case of limited penalty.

Theorem 3. Assume 1=β . Then

a) ),( y1 is not a NE for any ]1,0[∈y ;

b) if ),( yx is a NE with 1<ix for some i , then .1=y

Proof. a) Suppose ]1,0[∈y . Then for every nx ]1,0[ ∈ \ }{1 and ,1 ni∈ with 1<ix we have

.0)],(),()[()1))(()(1( ),(),( <−+−−−=− yxPyPxxxqpyLyxfyf iiiii 11 αβ

Page 10: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

10

b) Let ),( yx be a NE with 1<ix for some i . Then for all [1,0[∈y we obtain

0)1())(())(1)(1(),()1,(11

11 >∑ −−∑−−=−==

++

n

jjj

n

iinn xLpxqxyyxfxf α ,

a contradiction with the Nash condition.

The rest of this section is devoted to the symmetric case when all members of the cooperative not only formally

share the same strategy set (in our case [0,1]), but the redistribution factors iα have the same form, implying the

payoff functions if have the same form, too.

5.1. Symmetric case with 1=β

Assume that all iL -s are equal, i.e., LLi = ),1( ni∈ for some positive L , and, nx

x ii =:)(α for all

nx ]1,0[∈ , ni ,1∈ , and set 1:=β . Then for all nx ]1,0[∈ and ),1( ni∈ we have

∑ −−∑ −−+−=j

jj

ji

i xLpxbLanxcpLxf )1(])1([)()1,( ,

and for the corresponding partial derivatives

)].)1(()1([

)1(])1([1)1,(

2 pxbLaLxbLnx

xLpxbLan

xfD

jj

jj

i

jj

jjii

−∑ −−−∑ −+

∑ −−∑ −−=

Hence we get

=<=>

=1. if ,00, if ,0

)1,(λλ

λ1ii fD

Since )1,(xfi is cubic in ix with negative leading coefficient, there exists a unique [1,0]∈∗λ such that

0)1,( =∗1λii fD , and this is true for all i by symmetry.

Theorem 4. )1,( 1∗λ is a strict NE.

Proof . Let ix1∗λ be the strategy such that player i uses ix and all other players use ∗λ . Then

)()1,0( cpLfi −=∗1λ and )()1,1( cpLfi −>∗1λ . By the above cubic argument

Page 11: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

11

)1,()1,1( iii xff 11 ∗∗ > λλ for all [ ]1,0∈ix with ix≠∗λ . Furthermore, since [1,0]∈∗λ , for all [1,0[∈y

we have

0)1())()(1)(1(),()1,( 11 >−−−−=− ∗∗∗+

∗+ λλλλ nLpxqyyff nn 11

Therefore, )1,( 1∗λ is a strict NE.

The stability analysis of this NE is considered with respect to the partial adaptive dynamics

),()1( yxfDxxx iiiii −=& ( ni ,1∈ ), (5.9)

),()1( 11 yxfDyyy nn ++−=& . (5.10)

Denote the right-hand side of (5.9) and (5.10) by iΦ and 1+Φn , respectively. By the choice of ∗λ , a simple

substitution shows 0)1,(1 =Φ ∗+ 1λn and 0)1,( =Φ ∗1λi ( ni ,1∈ ), i.e. )1,( 1∗λ is an equilibrium of

dynamics (5.9)-(5.10). Analyzing the stability of this equilibrium by linearization, first we note that

=Φ ∗++ )1,(11 1λnnD 0)1())()(1()1,(11 <−−−−=− ∗∗∗

++ λλλ nLpxqfD nn 1 , (5.11)

and

0)1,(1 =Φ ∗+ 1λniD ( ni ,1∈ ). (5.12)

Therefore a stability analysis of this equilibrium it will be enough to consider the nn× Jacobian ][ ijJJ = ,

with

ijJ := )1,()1( 1∗∗∗ − λλλ iij fD .

An easy calculation shows that with the Kronecker δ we have

nbLpnbLa

nLfD ijiij

22])1(2)[1()1,(∗

∗∗ −−−−+−=λλδλ 1 .

Hence, with notation

pnbLaH −−−= ∗)1(2: λ ,

nbLH

nLc

22:∗

−−=λ

, HnLd −=: ,

matrix J can be written in the form DCJ += , where C has all entries equal to c, and D is diagonal

having all diagonal entries equal to d . Thus, for the quadratic form generated by J we obtain

Page 12: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

12

∑+∑>=<i

ii

i xdxcJxx 22)(, .

Now fix a nonzero vector nv R∈ with ∑ =i

iv 0 . Then dvJv = . Hence we immediately obtain the following

implications

a) 0>H implies that J is negative definite,

b) 0<H implies that J has a positive eigenvalue HnL

− .

So we have proved the following

Theorem 5

a) 0>H implies )1,( 1∗λ is asymptotically stable,

b) 0<H implies )1,( 1∗λ is unstable.

Remark 3. Condition 0)1(2 >−−−= ∗ pnbLaH λ means that the “oligopoly effect” is not too strong: if

each member doubles his production at the equilibrium, the market price still remains above the contracted price.

5.2. Symmetric case with 1>β

In case of an effective penalty ( 1>β ), depending on β , a strict NE exists:

Let us consider first

∑ −−∑−===

+

n

jjj

n

iin xLpxqyx

nyxf

111 )]1())(([)11(:),( β .

We see that 0),(11 >++ yxfD nn (unless 1=ix for all ),1( ni∈ ). Assuming 1=y , we obtain

))1()1)(1)(()1(()()1,( ∑∑ −+−−−−−+−=j

ji

ij

ji xnxLLxpxbLacpLxf ββ

and

).)1()1()()1((

])1()1)(1[()1,(

Ln

LLpnbLa

LLbLfD ii

βλλββλ

λλββλλ

−−+−−−−−+

−+−−=1

Now we distinguish two cases:

Page 13: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

13

Case A) 1−

>n

nβ .

We then have )1,0()1,1( 11 λλ ii ff > for all ]1,0[∈λ , in particular, (0,1) is not a NE.

Furthermore, a simple calculation gives )1,()1,( iii xff 11 > for all [1,0[∈ix ; in fact, (1,1) is the only

symmetric NE.)

Case B) 1−

<n

Now we additionally suppose that for the model parameters the following condition holds:

Ln

pab)1( +

−< . (5.13)

Then by a straightforward calculation we obtain

=<=>

1. if ,0 0 if ,0

)1,(λλ

λ1ii fD .

Hence, applying again the cubic argument used in the case 1=β , there exists a unique [1,0]∈∗λ such that

)1,1( ∗λ is a strict NE (i.e. )1,()1,( iii xff 11 ∗∗ > λλ for all ]1,0[∈ix with ∗≠ λix . In fact )1,( 1∗λ is the only

symmetric NE.

Hence we have the following

Theorem 6.

α ) If 1−

>n

nβ , then )1,(1 is the only symmetric strict NE,

β ) If 1−

<n

nβ and condition (5.13) holds, then there exists a [1,0]∈∗λ such that )1,( 1∗λ is the

unique strict NE.

Remark 4. Condition (5.13) can be interpreted in the following way. Either given the production of each

member, the oligopoly effect in the inverse demand function is not too strong; or given the inverse demand

function, the production of the members of the cooperative is not too large.

Page 14: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

14

Next, for the case 1

1−

<<n

nβ , under condition (5.13), we consider the problem of stability of the strict NE

)1,( 1∗λ with respect to the corresponding partial adaptive dynamics. Now in system

),()1( yxfDxxx iiiii −=& ( ni ,1∈ ), (5.14)

),()1( 11 yxfDyyy nn ++−=& . (5.15)

the payoffs are

])1()1)(1][()1([)(:),(11

∑ −+−−−∑ −−+−===

n

jj

ii

n

jji x

nx

yxpxbLaLcpLyxf ββ

),1( ni∈ , (5.16)

and

∑ −−∑ −−∑−====

+

n

jjj

n

jj

n

iin xLpxbLayx

nyxf

1111 )]1())1(([)11(:),( β

( ]1,0[]1,0[),( ×∈ nyx ). (5.17)

By the choice of ∗λ )1,( 1∗λ is an equilibrium for dynamics (5.14)-(5.15). For the stability analysis of this

equilibrium we apply the same method as in Section 5.1. Also in the present case each entry of the last row of

the )1()1( +×+ nn Jacobian at )1,( 1∗λ is zero, except the last one which is negative, therefore we can again

restrict ourselves to the nn× Jacobian ][ ijJJ = , with

ijJ := )1,()1( 1∗∗∗ − λλλ iij fD .

An easy calculation shows that

n

bLbnLpnbLanLfD ijiij

22)]1())1(2()[1()1,(∗

∗∗ −−+−−−+−=βλβλβδλ 1 .

Defining

)1())1(2(: βλβ −+−−−= ∗ bnLpnbLaK

and applying the same method as for 1=β , we obtain the following implications

(i) 0>K implies that J is negative definite,

Page 15: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

15

(ii) 0<K implies that J has a positive eigenvalue KnL

− .

From inequality (5.13) we get

)(1

)1( pan

nbnL −+

−>− ββ ,

implying

)1(21

)()(1

))1(2( ∗∗ −−+−

=−+

−−−−> λβββλβ nbLn

papan

npnbLaK

Note that by the choice of ∗λ , for β close to 1−n

n, ∗λ is close to 1, implying asymptotic stability of )1,( 1∗λ .

In particular, for such β condition (ii) can not hold. Our results can be summarized in

Theorem 7. Under condition (5.13) there exists )[1/(,1]0 −∈ nnβ such that for all 10 −

<<n

nββ , the NE

)1,( 1∗λ in Theorem 6 is an asymptotically stable equilibrium of the strategy dynamics.

In other words, if the oligopoly effect in the inverse demand function is not strong, the existing NE is

dynamically stable against small changes.

6. Conclusion

The conflict between a marketing cooperative and its unfaithful members can be described by a multiplayer

normal form game, in which the strategy of a member is the proportion of his product sold to the cooperative

(the rest of his product is sold on the market). For the cooperative to set a maximum penalty rate and for the

members to sell all their product to the cooperative provides an attractive solution of the game.

The partial adaptive dynamics introduced in evolutionary game theory turned out to be an appropriate tool for

the description of the dynamic strategy choice of the players. Using this dynamics, a penalty for unfaithfulness

has a stabilizing effect. Indeed, if the market price is determined by a Cournot type oligopoly, in case of an

effective penalty, the players are driven towards an attractive solution of the game, according to this evolutionary

strategy dynamics. For the members this attractive solution is to sell all their products to the cooperative, which

may guarantee the long-term survival of the cooperative.

Page 16: Evolutionary game model for a marketing cooperative with penalty for unfaithfulness

16

For the symmetric case, when all members produce the same amount, the stabilization is even stronger, if the

collected effective penalty is partly distributed among the faithful members. In particular, if the effective penalty

is not too high and the oligopoly effect is not too strong, then a unique strict Nash equilibrium exists which is

asymptotically stable for the strategy dynamics.

References

Cobia, D. (1989): Cooperatives in Agriculture. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ

Cressman, R., Garay, J., Scarelli, A. and Varga, Z. (2004): “The dynamic stability of coalitionist behaviour for

two-strategy bimatrix games,” Theory and Decision, Vol. 56, No. 1-2, 141-152.

Garay, J. (2002): “Many Species Partial Adaptive Dynamics,” BioSystems 65, 19-23.

Larbani, M. ( 1997): “`About the existence of the N-S equilibrium for a non cooperative Game under

Uncertainty''. In Caballero R. and Steur R. ed., Advances en Multiobjective Programmig and Goal

Programming”, Springer Verlag, 255-262.

Larbani, M. and Lebbah, H. (1999): “A Concept of Equilibrium for a Game under Uncertainty,” European

Journal of Operational Research, 117, N°1, 145-156.

Scarelli, A., and Larbani, M., (2004): “The Dynamic Control of the Unfaithfulness in a Cooperative,” 35th

Annual Conference of the Italian Operations Research Society, September 7-10, 2004, Lecce, Italy