Top Banner
DOCUMENT RESUME ED 387 624 CE 069 990 AUTHOR Macpherson, David A.; Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing the Minimum Wage to Average Wages in the U.S. Economy. INSTITUTION Employment Policies Inst. Foundation, Washington, DC. PUB DATE May 95 NOTE 24p. PUB TYPE Reports Research/Technical (143) -7 Statistical Data (110) EDRS PRICE MF01/PC01 Plus Postage. DESCRIPTORS Comparative Analysis; *Economic Impact; *Employment Level; *Employment Opportunities; Labor Economics; Longitudinal Studies; *Minimum Wage; Poverty; Public Policy; *Salary Wage Differentials; Statistical Analysis; Tables" (Data) IDENTIFIERS Current Population Survey; *Wage Indexing ABSTRACT The consequences of indexing the minimum wage to average wages in the U,S. economy were analyzed. The study data were drawn from the 1974-1978 May Current Population Survey (CPS) and the 180 monthly CPS Outgoing Rotation Group files for 1979-1993 (approximate annual sample sizes of 40,000 and 180,000, respectively). The effects of indexing on the minimum wage were analyzed, the beneficiaries of a higher minimum wage were identified, and the question of whether indexing satisfies the objectives of minimum wage policy was discussed. It was discovered that, had the minimum wage been linked to the average wage back in 1974, the minimum wage would have been seriously overindexed by 1994. The analysis of the impact of a higher minimum wage on specific groups revealed that children and other workers living with their parents would thus receive more than twice as much extra income as would all families dependent on a single minimum wage worker. Simple comr,arisons between the minimum wage and other wages in the economy were concluded to be simplistic. It was recommended that adjustments be made for changes in the composition of the work force (the baby boom generation has entered its prime earnings years; greater numbers of women have entered the workforce, working for lower wages than men; and more college degree holders with higher average wages have entered the work force) just as adjustments are made for inflation. (Contains 22 tables/figures and 15 references.) (MN) *********************************************************************** * Reproductions supplied by EDRS are the best that can be made * from the original document. ***********************************************************************
24

Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

Apr 28, 2023

Download

Documents

Khang Minh
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

DOCUMENT RESUME

ED 387 624 CE 069 990

AUTHOR Macpherson, David A.; Even, William E.TITLE The Consequences of Indexing the Minimum Wage to

Average Wages in the U.S. Economy.INSTITUTION Employment Policies Inst. Foundation, Washington,

DC.

PUB DATE May 95NOTE 24p.

PUB TYPE Reports Research/Technical (143) -7 StatisticalData (110)

EDRS PRICE MF01/PC01 Plus Postage.DESCRIPTORS Comparative Analysis; *Economic Impact; *Employment

Level; *Employment Opportunities; Labor Economics;Longitudinal Studies; *Minimum Wage; Poverty; PublicPolicy; *Salary Wage Differentials; StatisticalAnalysis; Tables" (Data)

IDENTIFIERS Current Population Survey; *Wage Indexing

ABSTRACTThe consequences of indexing the minimum wage to

average wages in the U,S. economy were analyzed. The study data weredrawn from the 1974-1978 May Current Population Survey (CPS) and the180 monthly CPS Outgoing Rotation Group files for 1979-1993(approximate annual sample sizes of 40,000 and 180,000,respectively). The effects of indexing on the minimum wage wereanalyzed, the beneficiaries of a higher minimum wage were identified,and the question of whether indexing satisfies the objectives ofminimum wage policy was discussed. It was discovered that, had theminimum wage been linked to the average wage back in 1974, theminimum wage would have been seriously overindexed by 1994. Theanalysis of the impact of a higher minimum wage on specific groupsrevealed that children and other workers living with their parentswould thus receive more than twice as much extra income as would allfamilies dependent on a single minimum wage worker. Simplecomr,arisons between the minimum wage and other wages in the economywere concluded to be simplistic. It was recommended that adjustments

be made for changes in the composition of the work force (the babyboom generation has entered its prime earnings years; greater numbersof women have entered the workforce, working for lower wages thanmen; and more college degree holders with higher average wages haveentered the work force) just as adjustments are made for inflation.(Contains 22 tables/figures and 15 references.) (MN)

************************************************************************ Reproductions supplied by EDRS are the best that can be made* from the original document.***********************************************************************

Page 2: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

EMPLOYMENT

POLICIES

INSTITUTEFOUNDATION

Do

rE) THE CONSEQUENCES OF INDEXINGTHE MINIMUM WAGE TOAVERAGE WAGES IN THE U.S. ECONOMY

DAVID A. MACPHERSONDepartment of EconomicsFlorida State University

WILLIAM E. EVENDepartment of EconomicsMiami Universi.ty

May 1995

U S DEPARTMENT OF EDUCATION

EDUCATIONAL RESOURCES INFORMATION

1?CENTER 'ERIC)

Thit, nocum ent h.15 Poen KT, ()clone sd areCewoo from !he person or organleaSonortginafing II

0 %no, rPanoes 0,1%0 heen ro,MO InImprove replodUrt.en Quably

of ;II ..1,111loCun,et,, oo nol no, ,opro,,onl

official OEM poso.on pohc,/

'PERMISSION TO REPRODUCE THISMATERIAL HAS BEEN GRANTED BY

TO THE EDUCATIONAL RESOURCESINFORMATION CENTER (ERIC).-

BEST COPY AVAILABLE2

Suite 1110, 607 14th Street, N.W. -Washington, D.C. 20005 -(202) 347-5178 -Fax: (202) 347-5250

Page 3: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

The Employment Policies Institute

Foundation is a non-profit research

organization dedicated to studying public

policy issues surrounding employment

growth. In particular, EPIF research

focuses on labor and tax issues that affect

entry-level employment levels. Among

other issues, EPIF research has quantified

the impact of new labor costs on job

creation, explored the connection between

entry-level employment and welfare reform,

and analyzed the demographic distribution

of mandated benefits. EPIF commissions

non-partisan research which is conducted

by independent economists at major

universities around the country.

Page 4: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Two consistent themes have echoed throughout the current debate over the future of the minimumwage: minimum-wage workers today have been left behind by the overall growth in wages; and,mandated wage increases are desirable because most minimum wage workers are adults and have

families to support. Both of these assertions are based on simplistic views of the workforce. Neitherstands up to close scrutiny, as this paper by David Macpherson and William Even demonstrates.

Have Minimum Wage Workers Been Left Behind?In 1974 the minimum wage stood at $2.00 and equaled 45 percent of average wages in the economy.

By 1993 the minimum wage had increased to $4.25 but had fallen to 35 percent of average wages. Thiserosion in the relative economic status of minimum wage workers has propelled the debate over mini-mum wages and even led to demands that the minimum be explicitly linked to other wages, rising when-ever economy-wide wages increase. What this simple analysis neglects, however, are the massivechanges that have taken place in the American workforce.

Over the last 20 years the baby boom generation has aged out of the entry-level workforce andmoved into its prime earnings years (working to raise average wages, since age and earnings are posi-tively associated). At the same time, American women have entered the workforce in greater numbersthan ever before (working to lower average wages, since women earn less on average than men). Ac-counting for both of these effects is complicated by the increase in the fraction of the population withhigher education (working to raise average wages)those with college degrees now represent 24 per-cent of the workforce, compared to only 15 percent twenty years ago.

This concentration of more experienced and better educated workers in their peak earnings years hasskewed measurement of average wages. Since workers' earnings rise with labor force experience, espe-cially when they have college degrees, the effect has been to raise average wages. This effect is sostrong that measured average wages would have risen even if each and every wage classification in theeconomy had remained unchanged over the last twenty years.

Consequently, had we in 1974 linked the minimum wage to the average wage, we would have seri-ously over-indexed the minimum wage by 1994. This strict indexing would require a minimum wage of$5.51 today, $1.26 over its current level. Controlling for just the three factors identified aboveage,gender and education changesdemonstrates that we would have over-indexed the minimum wage byat least 120 percent.

As attractive as indexing the minimum wage to other wages appears, this report demonstrates thatsimplistic comparisons between wage levels in different segments of the economy ignore not only im-portant economic effectsnotably changes in supply and demand conditionsbut that such compari-

14

Page 5: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

sons suffer serious flaws from a failure to account for the massive changes in the characteristics of theworkforce. The post-war baby boomarguably the mostsignificant demographic event of the 20th centurymustrank first among these omissions.

Who Benefits from a Higher Minimum Wage?Discussion of the distributional effects of the minimum

wage have most often taken place in the context of the ageof the workers. Recently, however, the debate has shifted tothe family status of the workers. This paper provides thedistribution of higher earnings from an increased minimumon these lines.

Almost one third of the added earnings from a $5.15minimum wage would flow to workers (teen and otherworkers) living with their parents. Single parents would re-ceive less than 5 percent. In contrast, single individualswithout children living at home (not including those livingwith their parents) would receive more than 20 percent ofthe increased income. For every dollar of higher earnings that this minimum wage increase would be-stow on single parents, $4.50 would go to single individuals and $6.80 would go to children and otherworkers living in their parents' home. In fact, children and other workers living with their parentswould receive more than twice as much extra income as would all families dependent on a single mini-mum wage worker.

Beneficiaries of a HigherMinimum Wage:

Worker Living with Parent(s) 32.7%

Married Female Dual Earner 16.3%

Single Female 12.6%

Single Male 9.3%

Married Male Dual Earner 6.2%

Other Relative 4.9%

Married Male Sole Earner 5.0%

Single Mother 4.4%

Married Female Sole Earner 3.8%

Related Sub Family Member 3.7%

Unrelated Sub Family Member 0.8%

ConclusionAs Macpherson and Even show in this paper, simple comparisons between the minimum wage and

other wages in the economy suffer by virtue of their simplicity. Any such comparisons must take intoaccount the vast changes in the American workforce. We must adjust for changes in the composition ofthe workforce in much that same manner as we adjust for inflation. A policy which blindly indexed theminimum wage to other wages in the economy over the last two decades would have markedly over-in-

dexed that wage.

The same data set that made it possible to understand the compositional changes in the workforcealso provides the framework in which to analyze the distribution of benefits from a higher minimumwage. Although it has become fashionable to portray the minimum wage as a means of helping familyheads, it is clear that few of the benefits flow to these parents, and even fewer flow to families depend-ent on the earnings of a single minimum wage worker.

About the DataThe data for this study are drawn from the 1974 through 1978 May Current Population Survey (CPS)

and the 180 monthly CPS Outgoing Rotation Group (ORG) files for January 1979 through December1993. An important advantage of the data sources are the large sample sizes. The approximate annual

sample sizes are 40,000 for the May CPS and 180,000 for the CPS ORG files.

Carlos BonillaEmployment Policies Institute Foundation

Page 6: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

IntroductionIn 1974 the federal minimum wage equalled 46 percent of average wages in the economy, falling to

35 percent in 1994. This relative decline has led to numerous initiatives that would link the minimumwage to other wages in the economy.1 Even proposals which do not explicitly link minimum and aver-age wages, such as President Clinton's call for a minimum wage of $5.15 an hour, have been defendedas measures which simply reverse a growing tide of inequality that has hurt lower-paid workers. (A$5.15 minimum wage today would raise the ratio of minimum to average wages by about 5 percentagepoints.)

On the surface, linking entry-level wages to other wage levels seems to a be a valid proposition. Theeconomy has historically demonstrated an ability to support a minimum wage that was a larger fractionof average earnings than it is today. Consequently, the casual observer may not expect the restoration ofthat historic relationship to cause the adverse employment consequences that opponents of higher mini-mum wages warn of. But, in its blind devotion to averages, this simplistic view of the wage structurefails to capture the fact that in a non-stable workforce the average wage is artificially skewed by changesin the composition of that workforce.

How can changes in the composition of the workforce skew simple measures of average wages? Toanticipate the results presented later in this paper, consider the effects on average wages of the post-warbaby boom, arguably the most significant demographic event in American history. In 1974, the leadingedge of the baby boom was just reaching its late 20s2, while the bulk of the baby boom had just enteredthe workforce. In that year roughly 25 percent of the workforce was aged 16-24 while 36 percent wasaged 35-54. By 1993, however, the population had aged greatly. Now, 44 percent of the workforce wasaged 35-54 and in its peak earnings years, while 16-24 year olds had shrunk to only 18 percent. This ag-ing of the population changed the skill and experience level of the total workforce and markedly af-fected the measure of average wages.

When the bulk of the workforce moves into peak earnings years, the undeniable effect is to raise theaverage wage. (Note that this would be true even if absolute wages had remained unchanged in the inter-vening years.) Yet such a demographic shift tells us nothing about the relative well-being of other work-ers. If the population seems "richer" simply because it is older and earning more both absolutely andrelative to young workers then an argument to index the minimum wage to average wages is effec-

1 In 1995 Senators Ted Kennedy and Paul Wellstone introduced a bill (S203) to raise the minimum wage to$5.75, arguing that it would restore the minimum wage to "roughly half the hourly wage." Senator Wellstonereserved the option to re-introduce a bill he had introduced in the prior Congress (S562) which would haveexplicitly linked the minimum wage to equal half of average wages. (Congressional Record, January 11,1995, page S801). The state of Massachusetts this year considered a measure (H4070) that would havelinked the state's minimum wage to 50 percent of average non-agricultural wages in the state.

2 In 1974 the minimum wage was at its highest level relative to average wages.

0

Page 7: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

uvely an argument to speed up the aging process, that younger workers are entitled to the higher wagesthat older workers have earned through their continued presence in the workforce.

In this paper we examine the relationship between the minimum wage and average wages in the econ-omy, but do so by controlling for the changes in the American workforce, changes in the age and genderdistributions as well as the educational attainment of the workforce. These changes in the workforce re-flect changes in "labor quality" and will be referred to as such in this paper.

Had we begun indexing the minimum wage to average wages in 1974 we would now have a mini-mum of $5.51 (it currently stands at $4.25). However, due to changes in labor quality, this would be asignificantly over-indexed entry-level wage. Controlling for just the three factors identified earlierage composition, education and gender changes would reduce that indexed value from $5.51 to$4.82. That is to say, the minimum wage, under strict wage indexing, would be $1.26 higher than today,with 55 percent of that higher amount representing an over-indexing of the minimum wage. Sixty-ninecents of this increase would arise solely from ignoring the changes in the workforce. In effect, we wouldhave over-indexed the minimum wage by 120 percent. The minimum wage, compared to its relativevalue against other wages, would be far too high. Moreover, even though the $4.82 minimum wage isderived from the constant labor quality index, it cannot be assumed that this level is the "proper" one forthe minimum wage. Any determination along these lines must also reflect changes in the relative de-mand and supply conditions for workers at this pay level, a topic beyond the scope of this paper.

In conjunction with the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), a $5.51 minimum wage would translateinto an effective minimum wage of between $6.53 and $6.77 (for families with one, or more than one,child respectively). In 1996 these effective minimum wage rates would increase (due to scheduled in-creases in the EITC) tci $6.53 and $7.20, respectively.

In addition, this study takes issue with the efficacy of a policy that increases the minimum wage toimprove income distribution. We demonstrate that the majority of benefits from a higher minimum wageaccrue to children living with their parents. Only a small portion of an increase to $5.15 would accrue tosingle parents (less than 5 percent) or to married couples with a single earner (less than 9 percent).

Finally, this study also takes issue with the desirability of automatically raising the minimum wagewith an indexing mechanism. Assuming that the objective of minimum wage policy is to balance theanti-poverty effects against the potential loss of employment, we argue that the discretionary balance be-tween higher wages and employment losses can be overwhelmed under a policy of minimum wage in-dexing.

A Comparison of the Minimum Wage Since 1974 With and Withouc IndexingIn Figure 1, the minimum and average wages are presented for the years 1974 through 1994. Be-

tween 1974 and 1993, the minimum wage increased from $2.00 per hour to its current level of $4.25.Over the same period, the average wage in the economy rose from $4.35 to $12.11. In Figure 2, we pre-sent the ratio of the minimum to average wage (RMA) for each year between 1974 and 1993. The ratiostarted at .46 in 1974 and, due to six separate increases in the minimum wage between 1974 and 1981,the RMA was virtually unchanged. Between 1981 and 1989, the minimum wage was frozen at $3.35and the RMA fell to .32. Between 1989 and 1993, the minimum was increased to its new level of $4.25,generating an RMA of .36 in 1994.

To understand the consequences of indexing the minimum wage to the average wage in the economy,

we calculate what the minimum wage would be for each year since 1974 if the RMA were held at its1974 value of .46. The results, presented in Figure 3 and contrasted with the actual minimum wage, indi-cate that the minimum wage in 1993 would be $5.51 if indexing had started in 1974.

2

Page 8: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

Figure 1

The Minimum and Average Wage for the U.S. Workforce

Dollars per Hour

12Average Wage

2

Minimum Wage

74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92

One consequence ofthe decline in the RMAthat occurred during the1980s is that the percent-age of workers earning theminimum wage declinedprecipitously during thedecade. In Figure 4a, thepercentage of workersearning the minimumwage is presented for theyears 1974 through 1993.In 1974, 6.0 percent of thework force was earningthe minimum wage, and14.7 percent was earningthe minimum wage orless. The 8.7 percent earn-ing less than the minimumcould arise from workers

in industries not covered by minimum wage laws, non-compliant firms in covered industries, or meas-urement error in the wage variable. Despite the fact that the RMA was stable from 1974 to 1981, thoseearning the minimum fell to 4.5 percent by 1981, and the percent earning the minimum or less fell to10.3 percent. This decline in the percentage of workk.:c earning the minimum or less might indicate thatthe earnings commanded by workers at the bottom end of the skill distribution was rising faster than av-

erage wages in the econ-omy during this period.Alternatively, it may indi-cate that the number ofworkers at the bottom ofthe skill distribution wasshrinking during the1970s. This might be dueto a declining labor forceparticipation rate amongthe less skilled, or themovement of the leadingedge of the baby boommovinf out of its teenageyears.'

Between 1981 and1993, the percentage ofworkers earning the mini-mum wage fell to a mea-ger 1.9 percent of the

Figure 2

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

0.3

0.25

The Ratio of the Minimum to the Average Wage

Minimum Wage/Average Wage

L.L111..11_Li74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92

3 Juhn (1992) presents evidence that the labor force participation rate has fallen among less educated malesduring the 1970s and 1980s.

3

Page 9: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

work force. The percent-age earning the minimumor less fell to 4,4 percent.This tremendous declinein the percentage of thework force earning theminimum wage could bedue to either the decline inthe minimum relative tothe average, a decline inthe number of workers atthe bottom end of the skilldistribution, or further im-provements in the earn-ings commanded byworkers at the bottom endof the skill distribution.Given the wealth of recentevidence indicating the de-mand for less-skilled

Figure 3

$6

The Minimum Wage if Indexed to the Average Wage

Dollars per Hour

Minimum if Indexed to Average

4

3 Legislated Minimum

II III 11;11,174 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92

workers fell during the 1980s, however, it is not likely that the last explanation is the source of the de-cline.4 Figure 4b shows this data in terms of the number rather than percentages of workers.

To isolate the effect of a declining RMA on the percentage of workers earning the minimum duringthe 1980s, we calculate the percentage of workers that would earn the minimum if it had been indexedbeginning in 1974. For ex-

Figure 4aample, in 1993, the mini-mum wage would havebeen $5.51 if indexinghad begun in 1993. Tocompute how many peo-ple would be at the mini- 1.mum with indexing, wecalculate the percentage 12

of workers in 1993 that 10

have an hourly wagegreater than or equal tothe actual minimum of$4.25, but less than or

4equal to the indexed mini-mum of $5.51. A similar 2

calculation is made foreach year back to 1974. 74 76 78 80 82 84 86

The results are in figures5a-b.

Percentage of Workforce Earning the Minimum Wage or Less

% at or Below Minimum

% at.Minimum

. 1 1 _ _ L J 1 _

4 See Levy and Murnane (1992) for a review of relevant studies.

88 90 92

4

Page 10: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

1111111111

Figure 4b

Number of Workers Earning the Minimum Wage or Less

12

10

Millions of Workers

At or Below Minimum

At Minimum

74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92

The consequences of in-dexing the minimum forthe percentage of workersearning the minimum isquite striking. If the 1993minimum wage were in-creased from the legislated$4.25 to an indexed valueof $5.51, the percentage ofworkers earning the mini-mum wage would increasefrom 1.9 to 14.0 percent.The percent earning at orbelow the minimumwould increase from 4.4 to16.5 percent. This impliesthat the number of peopleearning the minimumwould rise from 2.0 mil-lion to 14.7 million. The

number at or below the minimum would increase from 4.6 million to 17.3 million. This considerable in-crease in the number of workers at or below the minimum has important implications for the cost of in-dexing the minimum. For example, we estimate that increasing the minimum wage from $4.25 to $5.51

would cost firms $20.3 bil-lion per year. This as-sumes that increasing theminimum wage does notcause any employmentlosses, that minimumwage workers are em-ployed 4.2 weeks permonth at their reportedweekly hours, and thatthose earning less than theminimum wage realize awage increase equal to theincrease in the minimumwage. Alternatively, if weassume that only thoseearning the minimumwage would realize an in-crease in earnings and thatall those below the mini-

mum are unaffected, the cost of increasing the minimum wage falls to $14.7 billion.

Figure 5a

14

12

10

6

Percentage of Workforce at Actual versusIndexed Minimum Wage

% at Minimum Indexedto Average Wage

% at Legislated Minimum

2

82 84 86 92

The Impact of Improving Labor Force Quality on an Indexed Minimum.To illustrate the significance of improving labor force quality on the average wage, we compute what

wages would be for each year since 1974 if labor force quality were frozen at its 1974 level, but the

,

5

Page 11: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

wage structure underwentthe observed changes. Tocontrol for labor forcequality, we divide the la-bor force into 7 agegroups, 4 educationgroups, and the two gen-ders.'

Before turning to theresults of our simulation,it is useful to considerhow the labor force has 6

changed over time and4

how the wages of the vari-ous sub-groups compare. 2

The results are presentedin figures 6 through 8.

In figure 6a, it is clearthat the percentage of thework force that is female has been rising over time. It started at 41.1 percent in 1974 and rose to approxi-mately 47.9 percent by 1993. This has contributed to a decline in the average wage in the economysince, as seen in figure 6b,women earn less than menon average. The impact ofincreased female participa-tion on the average wage,however, has been damp-ened somewhat by the factthat women's wages haverisen relative to men overthe past two decades. Be-tween 1974 and 1993,women's wages rose from66 to 77 percent of men'swages. Several recent stud-ies have examined the ex-planations for theconvergence of male andfemale wages over time.°

In figure 7a, it is madeapparent that the average

Figure 5b

Number at Adual versus Indexed Minimum Wage

Millions16

14

12

10

8

Number at MinimumIndexed to Average

Number at Legislated Minimum. ........

82 84 86 88 90 92

Percent of Labor Force that is Female

5 The seven age groups are 16-19, 20-24, 25-34, 35-44, 45-54, 55-64, and 65 or over. The education groupsare according to years of education: less than 12, 12, 13-15, and 16 or more.

6 See, for example, O'Neill and Polachek (1993) and Blau and Kahn (1994), Wellington (1993), andMacpherson and Hirsch (forthcoming).

/t

6

Page 12: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

Figure 6b

Male and Female Wages

level of education in theeconomy is improving.Between 1974 and 1993,the percent of the labor

$16Pollars per Hour

force with less than 1214 years of education fell

froth 30.7 to 13.4 percent12 and the percent with ex-10 actly 12 years of educa-

tion fell slightly from 36.2to 34.5. In contrast, the

6 percentage of workerswith 13-15 years of educa-tion rose from 18.5 to

2 28.2 and the percent with16 or more years of educa-

74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 97 tion rose from 14.7 to24.2 percent. This hasvery clearly contributed toan increase in the average

wage in the economy since, as shown in figure 7b, wages rise with education. It is also worth noting thegrowing returns to a college degree. Between 1974 and 1993, a high school drop-out's wage fell from56 to 43 percent of a college graduate's wage. This is consistent with the aforementioned evidence thatthe returns to skill are increasing over time. Moreover, the rising returns to education will magnify theeffect of improving educational levels on the average wage in the economy.

Average Male Wage

Figu 7a

Educational Attainment of U.S. Workforce

100%Share of Workforce

80%

60%

40%

20%

t t t

74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92

CollegeGraduate

Some College

High SchoolGraduate

No Degree

and theage wage since, as illustrated in 8b, wages tend to rise with

In figure 8a, the age dis-tribution of the populationis presented for fourgroups: 16-24, 25-34, 35-54, and 55 or over. The im-pact of the baby boom andsubsequent baby bust is ap-parent in the diagram. Be-tween 1974 and 1993, thepercent of the work force24 or under feli from 24.9to 16.4 percent. Also, thepercent of workers aged35-54 rose from 36.1 to44.8 percent. The othertwo age groups were rela-tively stable over the pe-riod, changing less than 3percentage points each.The declining numbers ofyoung (16-24) workers

rising numbers of experienced (35-54) workers has clearly contributed to an increase in the aver-age.

7

Page 13: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

In the American econ-omy, however, all of theseforces have changed simul-taneously. Not only hasthe portion of the work-force with higher educa-tion increased, so has theoverall age structure.Since increases in agewiden the gap between theearnings of educationgroups, these two effectsmagnify each other. To de-termine the effect of thesecompositional changes onthe wage rate, we calcu-late a "constant quality"wage rate. Such a calcula-tion permits us to isolatethe effect of age, genderand education changes, as well asing wage structure.

To perform the calculation, wein a given year if the aver-

Figure 7b

Wage Rates by Educational Attainment

Dollars per Hour

15

10

. _ .

16 or More Years

Less than 12 Years

80 82 84 86 88 90 92

age wage for each sub-group of the populationwere equal to the ob-served vkfige for that year,but the relative size of thesub-groups were frozen atthe 1974 level. That is, de-fine wit as the wage ratefor group i in year t andnit as the percentage of theworkforce in group i dur-ing year t. Then the aver-age wage for the economyis:

the interaction among these components, from changes in the underly-

estimate what the average v age rate for the entire economy would be

Figure 8a

100%

80%

60%

40%

20%

Age Distribution of U.S. Workforce

Share of Workforce

74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92

65-90

55-64

45.54

35 44

25-34

16-74

There are 56 groups (2sexes times 4 education groups times 7 age groups) for which average wages are computed. To calculatethe constant quality wage rate, we hold the relative size of the 56 groups at their 1974 levels. That is, theconstant quality wage rate is calculated as:

Li

8

Page 14: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

56

-**t=111-7Vi1ni74i=1

A comparison of actual and constant quality wages is provided in figure 9. (Given that the constantquality wages are calculated holding labor quality at the 1974 level, the actual and constant qualitywages are both $4.40 in that year.) By 1993, the average wage in the economy had risen to $12.11whereas the constant quality wage rate rose to only $10.61.

Finally, we index the 1974 minimum wage to the constant quality average wage. This series is con-trasted with the legislated minimum and the minimum indexed to the actual wage in figure 10. Between1974 and 1993, indexing to a constant quality wage rate causes the minimum to increase from $2.00 to$4.82 between 1974 and 1993; indexing to the average wage causes an increase to $5.51 by 1993.Hence, a failure to account accurately for the effect of improving labor market quality on average wageswould have caused the minimum to increase by $.69 more than desired, over-indexing by 120 percent.

To determine the cost of over-indexing, we calculate how much it would cost employers to increasethe minimum from $4.25 to $4.82, and from $4.82 to $5.51. The calculation imposes the same assump-tions as earlier (i.e., no employment effects). If those earning between $4.25 and $4.82 have their wagesincreased to $4.82, it would cost employers $3.5 billion per year. On the other hand, increasing the mini-mum wage to $5.51 increases the cost to 14.7 billion. Thus, the $.69 increase in the minimum that wouldhave resulted from a failure to account for improving labor force quality would have cost employers anadditional $11.2 billion annually.7

In summary, improving labor force quaiity has been an important source of the growth in averagewages over the past 20 years. Indexing the minimum wage to the average wage would cause the balancebetween employment losses and income distribution to be distorted whenever demographic changes dis-tort the average. Moreover, the cost to business of relatively modest increases in the minimum wage arequite substantial.

Who are the Beneficiaries of a Higher Minimum Wage?One of the most often-cited arguments in favor of increasing the minimum wage is that it would bene-

fit the "working poor." While it is true that a worker earning the minimum wage would have a fairly lowstandard of living if that were one's only source of income, there may be less concern for such workersif there are other earners in the family. Hence, to understand the validity of the argument that an increasein the minimum wage would help combat poverty, it is important to determine what types of peoplehold minimum wage jobs, and what types of households they reside in.

To address this issue, we first calcrilate the age distribution of minimum wage workers (those earningthe minimum wage) for 1993. The results, presented in figure 11, reveal that the majority' of minimumwage workers are young. In fact, 35.3 percent of minimum wage workers are between 16 and 19 yearsof age, and an additional 20.4 percent are between 20 and 24 years of age. Thus, 55.7 percent of theminimum wage work force is 24 or younger.

In figure 12, we provide an alternative perspective on the distribution of beneficiaries by classifyingworkers according to family status. In this example, we break the minimum wage work force into the fol-lowing 12 sub-groups.

7 If one makes the alternative assumption that those earning below the minimum will receive a wage increaseequal to the size of increment in the minimum, the cost of raising the minimum is $6.1 billion for an increaseto $4.83, and $20.3 billion to $5.51.

9

Page 15: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

In 1993, 42.2 percent ofminimum wage workerswere children and workersof any age living with par-ents. The next largest cate-gory of minimum wageworkers (12.9 percent)were married women withemployed husbands. Singlewomen and men withoutchildren in the householdcomprise 12.7 and 7.5 per-cent of minimum wageworkers. Single mothersand single fathers consti-tute only 3.8 and 0.4 per-cent of minimum wageworkers.

In figures 13a-c, thebeneficiaries of a minimumwage increase are pre-sented according to bothfamily type and the level ofthe minimum wage. In 13a,we present the conse-quences of increasing the

Single Male

Single Female

Single Mother.

Single Father

Married Male,Sole Earner

Married Female,Sole Earner

Married Male,Dual Earner

Married Female,Dual Earner

Child at home

Other relative

Related Sub-Family Member

Unrelated Sub-Family Member

Family CategoriesMale living by himself, or male living with roommate(s). The room-mates may or may not be related to the male. He cannot be livingwith his parent(s).

Female living by herself, or female living with roommate(s). Theroommates may or may not be related to the female. She cannot beliving with her parent(s).

Single female living with one or more of her own children.

Single male living with one or more of his own children.

Married male with spouse present. Spouse is not employed.

Married female with spouse present. Spouse is not employed.

Married male with spouse present. Spouse is also employed.

Married female with spouse present Spouse is also employed.

Child living at home with one or both parents. May be of any age.

Relative other than own child living with primary family. Exampleswould include Cousins, Uncles, Aunts, Nephews, Grandchild, etc.

Member of blood-related subfamily. An example would be if anUncle had a child and they were living with the primary family.

Member of unrelated subfamily. For example, if a maid had a childand they were living with the primary family.

minimum wage to the mini-mum, indexed with respect to the constant quality wage of $4.82. In figure 13b, the calculation is pre-sented for an increase to $5.15. Figure 13c presents the calculation for an increase to $5.51. Each calcu-

lation adjusts for the factthat work hours differacross the various sub-groups and that the num-bers of workers betweenthe legislated and pro-posed minimum differs.

Assuming no employ-ment effects, a minimumwage increase to $4.82would cost employers $3.5billion per year. Of thiscost, 34.6 percent wouldgo to children and otherworkers living with theirparents. The next largest re-cipient groups would bemarried women whose hus-bands work (15.3 percent),

1 0 15

Page 16: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

Figure 9

$14

12

10

The Effect of Changing Labor ForceComposition on the Average Wage

Average Wage

Average Wage withConstant Quality Workforce

1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92

Note: 'Constant quality workforce assumes constant distribution by age. education and gender.

(16.3%), single women without children (12.6%) and singlemothers receive only a small portion of the benefits (4.4%).

Finally, if the minimum wage had been indexed to the average wage beginning in 1974, the currentminimum would be $5.51. The cost of increasing the minimum to $5.51 would be $14.7 billion annuallyassuming that those currently earning less than the minimum receive no wage gains from the higherminimum. The distribution of earnings gains across the different types of families is virtually unchangedfrom the increase to $5.15, though obviously, the dollar values of the gains are larger for each group.

single women without chil-dren (12.7%), and singlemen without children(8.8%). Single motherswould receive only 4.4 per-cent of the benefits.

If the minimum wagewere increased to the$5.15 currently proposedby the Clinton Administra-tion, the cost increases to$7.7 billion. The distribu-tion of beneficiaries byfamily type is quite similarto that mentioned above.The largest groups of bene-ficiaries are workers livingwith their parents (32.7%),married women whosehusbands are employed

men without children (6.2%). Again, single

Does Indexing Satisfy the Objectives of Minimum Wage Policy?In recent debates regarding the desirability of increasing the minimum wage, it becomes clear that the

overriding objective of minimum wage legislation is to fight poverty. However, the efficacy of such leg-islation in fighting poverty is controversial for at least two reasons. First, a higher minimum wage cancause employment losses. Thus, while some workers will benefit from a higher wage rate, others willlose their jobs. This point has received a good deal of attention in the past several years among econo-mists, and there is a good deal of disagreement on the magnitude of the employmenteffects.8

A second controversy regarding the efficacy of a higher minimum wage in fighting poverty is thatmany minimum wage workers are members of families that are not in poverty. For example, Horriganand Mincy (1992) demonstrate that when families are categorized into income quintiles based on familyincome, minimum wage workers are evenly distributed across the five quintiles. Hence, a higher mini-mum wage is not very effective at targeting low income families.

8 Some recent studies on the impact of the minimum wage on employment include the work by Katz andKrueger (1992), Card (1994a, 1994b), Neumark and Wascher (1992), Neumark and Wascher (1995), andTaylor and Kim (1995).

It)

Page 17: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

When considering thedesirabiiity of indexingthe minimum wage to theaverage wage in the econ-omy, one must considerthe trade-offs faced whenincreasing the minimum.Presumably, the task oflegislators is to balancethe positive effect on earn-ings for less skilled work-ers against the possibleemployment losses. Index-ing to average wages inthe economy may keep abalance between theseconcerns, if the population is stable in its charac-teristics and demandchanges are uniformacross different workers. That is, if there is an increase in labor demand in the entire economy, then theemployment losses from a given level of the minimum wage would be reduced. Thus, to keep the appro-priate balance, legislators would choose to increase the minimum. This automatically occurs with index-ing to the average wage, since an increase in the demand for labor will cause the average wage to rise inthe economy.

Similarly, if there is anincrease in labor supply inthe economy, the employ-ment losses from a givenlevel of the minimumwage are enlarged. Tocompensate, legislators.should cut the minimum.Again, this automaticallyoccurs with wage index-ing since the increase in la-bor supply causes areduction in the averagewage.

At the same time, it isimportant to recognizethat indexing will fail tobalance the competingconcerns of employment vs. earnings under several circumstances. First, the above discussion presumesthat changes in the average wage reflect equal changes in labor supply or demand for all skill levels. If,however, labor demand is rising for high skill workers but falling for low skill workers, it is entirely pos-sible that the average wage will be unaffected. Nevertheless, obtaining the appropriate balance betweenemployment losses and income distribution would necessitate a cut in the minimum wage. In fact, there

Figure 10

The Effect of Changing Workforce Qualityon an Indexed Minimum

$6 Dollars ser Hour

5

4

3

Minimum Indexed to Average Wage

Minimum Indexed toConstant Quaky Wage

Legislated Minimum

74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92

Figure 11

The 1993 Age Distribution of Minimum Wage Workers

age 20-24

20 4%

age 16.19

35 3%

age 654-3 4%

age 55-64

5 5%

age 45-54

age 25-34 6 3%

17 7%age 35-44

11 4%

1 2 17

Page 18: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

Figure 12

The 1993 Distribution of Minimum Wage Workersby Family Type

Married FemaleDual Earner

1 2.cf-t

Worker Living with Parent(s)42.2%

Single Female

1 2 7%

is substantial evidence thatthe demand for low skillworkers fell during the1980s while it increasedfor high skill labor.

A second situation inwhich indexing to the aver-age wage fails is if the sup-ply and demand of low

Single Father0 4% skill workers are un-

Unrelated Sub-Family Member changed, but the qualifica-0 8%

Related Sub-Family Member tions of the more skilled3.2%

Married Female Sole Earner workers improve over35% time. This causes the aver-Single Mother

3 7% age wage in the economyMarried Male Sole Earner

3 8% to rise over time but thereSingle Male Other Relative

75% 4.0% is no change in the bal-Married Male Dual Earner

ance between employmentlosses associated with a

5 3%

minimum wage increase.Thus, if average labor force quality is rising but the number of low skill workers is unchanged, mini-mum wage indexing will generate an undesirable increase in the minimum wage.

Summary and ConclusionsThe consequences of indexing the minimum wage to the average wage in the economy have been ex-

amined. If indexing had begun in 1974 and the ratio of the minimum to average wage been maintainedat .46 since then, we esti-mate that the minimumwage would currently be$5.51. Assuming that thishigher minimum wagegenerates no employmentlosses, this would costbusinesses between 14.7and 20.3 billion dollars an-nually. Moreover, itwould increase the per-centage of the work forcethat earns the minimumwage from 5.9 to 14.0 per-cent of the work force.

Figure 13a

The Beneficiaries of a Minimum Wage Increase to $4.82(Total Cost43.5 Billion per Year)

Marned FemaleDual Earner

1 5 3%

Worker living with Parent(s)34 6%

--Single Female

2 7%

Single Male

8 8%

Married Male Other Reiative

Dial Earner 5 2%

5 6%

Single Father0 4%

Unrelated Sub-Family Member0 8%

Related Sub-Family Member3 8%

Married Female Sole Earner

3 8%

Single Mother4 4%

Married Male Sole Earner

4 6%

minimum wage on income distribution and the negative effects

Under restrictive condi-tions, minimum wage in-dexing can maintain abalance between the posi-tive effects of a higher

associated with employment losses. One

Page 19: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

case in which indexingwill create an imbalancebetween the two effects iswhen labor force quality isimproving over time. Inparticular, minimum wageindexing will cause theminimum wage to increasetoo much when labor forcequality is improving. Be-tween 1974 and 1993, weestimate that failure to ac-count for the effect of im-proving labor force qualityon the average wagewould have caused theminimum wage to over-ad-just by at least $.69. More-over, the additional $.69would have cost busi-

Figure 13b

The Beneficiaries of a Minimum Wage Increase to $5.15(Total Cost47.7 Billion per Year)

Married Female

Dual Earner16.3%

Single Female

I 2.6%

Worker living with Parents32 7%

Single Male

9.3%

Single Father0.4%

Unrelated Sub-Family Member0 8%

Related Sub-Family Member3.7%

Married Female Sole Earner3.8%

Single Mother4.4%

Marned Male Sole Earner

5.0%

Married Male Other RelativeDual Earner 4.9%

6.2%

nesses between 10.2 and 14.2 billion dollars annually.

The effect of increas-ing the minimum wage onpoverty in the UnitedStates could be quite mini-mal. In fact, we estimatethat 42 percent of mini-mum wage workers areworkers living with theirparents. An additional 13percent are marriedwomen whose husbandsare employed, and 21 per-cent are single women orsingle men without chil-dren in the household.Only 3.8 percent of mini-mum wage workers aresingle women with chil-dren. Hence, increasingthe minimum wage mayvery well increase the in-comes of high and low income families by similar amounts.

Figure 13c

The Beneficiaries of a Minimum Wage Increase to $5.51(Total Cost414.7 Billion per Year)

Marned FemaleDual Earner

17.0%

Single Female12.7%

Worker living w1th Parents31 0%

Single Male

9.8%

Married MaleDM] Earner

6.7%

Single FatherZ 0.4%

Unrelated Sub Family Member0.8%

Related Sub-Family Member3.5%

Married Female Sole Earner

3 8%

Single Mother4.3%

Marrled Male Sole Earner5.3%

Other Relative

4.8%

1 3

1 4

Page 20: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

ABOUT THE DATA

The data for this study are drawn from the 1974 through 1978 May Current Population Survey (CPS)and the 180 monthly CPS Outgoing Rotation Group (ORG) files for January 1979 through December1993. An important advantage of the data sources are the large sample sizes. The approximate annualsample sizes are 40,000 for the May CPS I 180,000 for the CPS ORG files.

The sub-sample of the CPS data employed here includes wage and salary workers that are 16 orolder. Observations with missing data on usual weekly earnings, usual hours worked per week, educa-tion, gender, or age are deleted from the sample. For hourly workers, the hourly wage rate is calculatedas the maximum of two available wage measures: the hourly wage reported by the worker, or the hourlywage calculated by dividing usual weekly earnings by usual hours worked per week. The reason we donot rely solely on the hourly wage rate reported is that it excludes tips, commissions, and overtime andthus, average hourly earnings would be understated. We take the maximum of the two measures to re-duce measurement error.9 Also, we are forced to impute an hourly wage rate for salaried workers thatare not paid by the hour.

Prior to the 1989 CPS, weekly earnings are top-coded at $999. Since 1989, earnings are top-coded at$1,923. For workers at the cap, we assign a mean earnings estimate based on the assumption that the up-per tail of the earnings distribution follows a Pareto distribution. The parameters of the Pareto distribu-tion are estimated separately by year and gender. The source for these estimates is Hirsch andMacpherson (1994).

All estimates of wages and employment are calculated using the weights available in the CPS. For1979 forward, the ORG earnings weights are utilized. For the years 1974 through 1978, the populationweights are used, since earnings weights are not included. A potential incompatibility exists between thepopulation weights and the earnings weights when calculating employment level estimates since thepopulation weights are not adjusted for missing values on earnings and hours but the earnings weightsare altered for this Problem. As a solution, we generate employment estimates from the 1974 to 1978CPS using population weighs but make no deletions for missing observations on weekly earnings orweekly hours. To calculate the earnings estimates, we use population weights appropriately inflated to re-flect the deletion of observations with missing data on earnings or hours.

9 Card (1992a) utilizes the same technique in his minimum wage study.

2015

Page 21: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

REFERENCES

Blau, Francine D., and Kahn, Lawrence M. "The Impact of Wage Structure on Trends in U.S. Gen-der Wage Differentials: 1975-1987." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No.4748, May 1994.

Card, David. "Using Regional Variation in Wages to Measure the Effects of the Federal MinimumWage." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46 (October 1992): 22-37 (a).

. "Do Minimum Wages Reduce Employment? A Case Study of California, 1987-1989." In-dustrial and Labor Relations Review 46 (October 1992): 38-54 (b).

Ehrenberg, Ronald G., and Smith, Robert S. "Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy."Fifth Edition. New York: Harper Co llins.-1993.

Hirsch, Barry T., and Macpherson, David A. "Union Membership and Earnings Data Book 1993:Compilations from the Current Population Survey." Washington, D.C: Bureau of National Af-fairs, 1994.

Horrigan, Michael W. and Mincy, Ronald B. "The Minimum Wage and Earnings and Income In-equality." in UnevenTides, edited by Sheldon Danziger and Peter Gottschalk, NY: Russell SageFoundation, 1993.

Juhn, Chinhui. "Decline of Male Labor Force Participation: The Role of Declining Market Opportu-nities." Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (February 1992): 79-121.

Katz, Lawrence F., and Krueger, Alan B. "The ,ffect of the Minimum Wage on the Fast-Food Indus-try." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46 (October 1992): 6-21.

Levy, Frank and Murnane, Richard J. "U.S. Earnings Levels and Earnings Inequality: A Review ofRecent Trends and Proposed Explanations." Journal of Economic Literature 30 (September1993): 1333-1381.

Macpherson, David A., and Hirsch, Barry T. "Wages and Gender Composition: Why Do Women'sJobs Pay Less?" Journal of Labor Economics (forthcoming).

Neumark, David, and Wascher, William. "Employment Effects of Minimum and SubminimumWages: Panel Data on State Minimum Wage Laws." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46(October 1992): 55-81.

. "The Effects of New Jersey's Minimum Wage Increase on Fast Food Employment:A Re-Evaluaiion Using Payroll Records." Mimeograph, March 1995.

O'Neill, June, and Polachek, Solomon. "Why the Gender Gap in Wages Narrowed in the 1980s."Journal of Labor Economics II (January 1993): 205-228.

Taylor, Lowell, and Kim, Taeil. "The Employment Effect in Retail Trade of California's 1988 Mini-mum Wage Increase." Journal of Business and Economics Statistics, (April 1995).

Wellington, Allison. "Changes in the Male/Female Wage Gap, 1976-1985." Journal of Human Re-sources 28 (Spring 1993): 383-411.

21

16

Page 22: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

BIOGRAPHIES

David Macpherson is Associate Professor in the Department of Economics and Research Associateat the Pepper Institute on Aging and Public Policy at Florida State University.

William Even is Associate Professor of Economics and Associate Director of the Center for Pensionand Retirement Research at Miami University.

6 2

Page 23: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

RECENT PUBLICATIONS

Earnings Growth and Employment Stability of Workforce Entrants, by Frederick J. Tannery, University ofPittsburgh, April 1995.

Jobs Taken by Mothers Moving from Welfare to Work: And the Effects of Minimum Wages on thisTran-sition, by Peter D. Brandon, Institute for Research on Poverty, University of Wisconsin Madison, Febru-ary 1995.

Minimum Wage Laws and the Distribution of Employment, by Kevin Lang, Boston University,

January 1995.

The Low-Wage Workforce. Statistical analysis of the low-wage workforce from the 1992 Current PopulationSurvey. December 1994.

Mandates in Employment: A History of Added Burdens on the Unskilled, by SimonRottenberg, Universityof Massachusetts, Amherst, August 1994.

The Use of Strike Replacement in Union Contract Negotiations: Experience from the U.S. and Canada, byPeter Cramton, University of Maryland, and Joseph S. Tracy, Columbia University, May 1994.

The Effects of High School Work Experience on Future Economic Attainment, by Christopher J. Ruhm,University of North Carolina at Greensboro, May 1994.

The Early Careers of Non-College-Bound Men, by Jeff Grogger, University of California, Santa Barbara,

May 1994.

Effects of the Employer Mandate in the Clinton Health Plan, by June E. O'Neill and Dave M. O'Neill,Baruch College, City University of New York, March 1994.

The Effect of Recent Increases in the U.S. Minimum Wage on the Distribution of Income, by John T. Ad-dison and McKinley Blackburn, University of 'South Carolina at Columbia, March 1994.

Public Policies for the Working Poor: The Earned Income Tax Credit vs. Minimum Wage Legislation, byRichard V. Burkhauser, Syracuse University, and Andrew J. Glenn, Vanderbilt University, March 1994.

The Impact of a He Ath Insurance Mandate on Labor Costs and Employment, by June E. O'Neill and DaveM. O'Neill, Baruch College, City University of New York, September 1993.

Health Insurance Benefits and Income Support for Poor Families: Report on National Survey of LeadingEconomists. Conducted by the University of New Hampshire Survey Center, this survey presents over-whelming agreement among economists on the effects of mandated health insurance or a higher minimum

. wage. June 1993.

The Minimum Wage and the Employment of Teenagers: Recent Research, by Bruce Fallick, University ofCalifornia-Los Angeles, and Janet Currie, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, June 1993.

The Employment Effect in Retail Trade of a Minimum Wage: Evidence from California,by Lowell J. Taylor, Carnegie Mellon University, June 1993.

The Minimum Wage: Good Social Policy? A landmark guide to understanding the minimum wage,Employment Policies Institute, April 1993.

Employment Effects of Minimum and Subminimum Wages: Recent Evidence, by David Neumark, Univer-

sity of Pennsylvania, February 1993.

Higher Wages, Greater Poverty: Trapping Americans in Poverty, by Carlos E. Bonilla, Employment Poli-cies Institute. Examination of the interaction between minimum wage hikes, earnings, transfer Llid tax pro-

grams in California, February 1992.

Survey of Service Employees, prepared by Frederick/Schneiders Inc. Survey of current and former hospitalityindustry employees, exploring the development of important job skills, February 1992.

Page 24: Even, William E. TITLE The Consequences of Indexing ... - ERIC

EMPLOYMENT POLICIES INSTITUTE FOUNDATION607 14th Street, N.W. Suite 1110 Washington, D.C. 20005 (202) 347-5178

24