Top Banner
European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of Preliminary Ruling When European “Public Policy” is at Stake Penio Penev * Alma Mater Studiorum Università di Bologna Universität Hamburg Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam April 2012 Abstract In this theoretical paper we use a functional approach of law and economics to analytically test how the case-law of the European Court of Justice (hereinafter ECJ) affects individual's ex-ante incentives to include arbitration clauses in their contracts. The ECJ denied arbitral tribunals' jurisdiction to refer cases for a preliminary ruling, under Article 267 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (hereinafter TFEU). This implies that, even if competition law is a matter of public policy and its arbitrability is undisputed in the European legal system, when a contractual party claims a EU competition law infringement, arbitrators have no power to prevent a national court of a Member State from setting the arbitral decision aside. Such shadow of uncertainty risks to impair the very essence of arbitration, at least as a mechanism of private enforcement of EU competition law. We adapt two of the existing law and economics models on litigation (i.e. Priest and Klein's model on the selection of disputes for litigation and Dari-Mattiacci and Parisi's model on dissipation of value and lost treasure in rent-seeking games, the latter inspired by Gordon Tullock's paradox) with the intent to study the merits of alternative procedural rules that affect parties ex-ante incentives to arbitrate disputes involving an issue of public policy. Our results provides an analytical argument for reverting the current ECJ's interpretation of Article 267 TFEU. The purpose is to enhance the effectiveness of arbitration as a means of private enforcement of competition law, increasing legal certainty and procedural simplification. * Address for correspondence: e-mail [email protected]; tel. +39 3298555871; skype user: peniopg PhD Researcher & Erasmus Mundus Scholar at the European Doctorate in Law and Economics, http://www.edle- phd.eu
24

European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

Apr 28, 2018

Download

Documents

lydiep
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of Preliminary Ruling When European “Public Policy” is at Stake

Penio Penev*

Alma Mater Studiorum Università di Bologna

Universität Hamburg

Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam†

April 2012

Abstract

In this theoretical paper we use a functional approach of law and economics to analytically test how the case-law of the European Court of Justice (hereinafter ECJ) affects individual's ex-ante incentives to include arbitration clauses in their contracts. The ECJ denied arbitral tribunals' jurisdiction to refer cases for a preliminary ruling, under Article 267 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (hereinafter TFEU). This implies that, even if competition law is a matter of public policy and its arbitrability is undisputed in the European legal system, when a contractual party claims a EU competition law infringement, arbitrators have no power to prevent a national court of a Member State from setting the arbitral decision aside. Such shadow of uncertainty risks to impair the very essence of arbitration, at least as a mechanism of private enforcement of EU competition law. We adapt two of the existing law and economics models on litigation (i.e. Priest and Klein's model on the selection of disputes for litigation and Dari-Mattiacci and Parisi's model on dissipation of value and lost treasure in rent-seeking games, the latter inspired by Gordon Tullock's paradox) with the intent to study the merits of alternative procedural rules that affect parties ex-ante incentives to arbitrate disputes involving an issue of public policy. Our results provides an analytical argument for reverting the current ECJ's interpretation of Article 267 TFEU. The purpose is to enhance the effectiveness of arbitration as a means of private enforcement of competition law, increasing legal certainty and procedural simplification.

* Address for correspondence: e-mail [email protected]; tel. +39 3298555871; skype user: peniopg

† PhD Researcher & Erasmus Mundus Scholar at the European Doctorate in Law and Economics, http://www.edle-phd.eu

Page 2: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

Introduction

It is widely acknowledged that private enforcement of both EU and national competition

law has been extremely limited in Europe. Competition law is mostly enforced by

competition agencies and subject to the review of courts. The European Union have not

provided yet the proper procedural incentives necessary to achieve the optimum level of

private enforcement.1

The recent European debate on how to enhance private enforcement is focused mainly on

class actions. However in the United States, where private enforcement and class actions

are much more developed, consumers are not the majority of claimants in private

enforcement proceedings. One third of the plaintiffs are defendants' competitors, more

than one third are dealers or distributors and less than 20 percent are consumers.2 This

means that the majority of competition lawsuits revolves around business-to-business

contracts between perpetrator and victim of an anticompetitive conduct. In fact, every

vertical agreement, R&D agreement, price agreement, JV agreement, merger agreement

and many others, potentially include an issue of private enforcement of EU competition

law.

All the aforementioned contractual relationships, in Europe and more generally in a

globalized economy, are very likely to involve massive transfers of goods, services and

capitals between different legal systems. It is worth noting that during the last 10 to 15

years, arbitration almost gained the title of exclusive jurisdiction for international

contractual transactions. If two companies do not have their headquarters in the same

country, it is most likely that every dispute that may arise upon the performance of a

contractual obligation falls within the scope of an arbitration clause.

Unless otherwise expressed, contractual arbitration clauses include also claims based on

EU competition law. Indeed, arbitration seems to have all the characteristics necessary to

provide an efficient competition law enforcement: it is cheaper than litigation, it is faster, it

can lower collateral business risks, has flexible procedural rules, it is conducted by

professional arbitrators highly specialized in the subject matter of the dispute.

1 Speech by Mario MONTI European Commissioner for Competition matters Private litigation as a key complement to public enforcement of competition rules and the first conclusions on the implementation of the new Merger Regulation IBA – 8th Annual Competition Conference Fiesole, 17 September 2004. Available at this URL: http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/04/403&format=HTML&aged=0&language= EN&gui%20Language=en.

2 White, L., 'The Georgetown Study of Private Antitrust Litigation', Antitrust Law Journal, 1985, 54.

2

Page 3: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

Theoretically arbitration has the potential to play a leading role in the European private

enforcement framework.3 This paper is part of a wider project that uses the economic

analysis of law to solve a set of issues rising from the application of competition law in

alternative dispute resolution proceedings, provided that there is no legislative body

addressing this matter. The final goal of this wider project is to compare the merits of

alternative procedural rules that affect individual incentives to arbitrate, with the intent to

strengthen the private enforcement of international contractual transactions.

The inspiration for this paper came from two articles, the first by Eisenberg and Miller

published in 2007 entitled “The flight from arbitration: an empirical study of ex ante

arbitration clauses in the contracts of publicly held companies”.4 The second article is by

Drahozal and Wittrock publishing in 2008 with the title “Is there a flight from arbitration?”.5

Both articles are empirical studies that examine whether and how the use of contractual

arbitration clauses has changed over time in the United States. Their goal is to empirically

test the impression among practitioners of a growing dissatisfaction with arbitration, at

least in the United States. Drahozal and Wittrock found that: “in aggregate, there has been

little change in the use of arbitration clauses” but we were more interested in another

remark present in their article. Most exclusions of arbitral jurisdiction and changes to the

terms of the arbitration clauses studied by the authors were parties' response to arbitral

invalidation or disadvantageous proceedings caused by national courts' case-law.6

The European legal order is characterized by a legislative vacuum on how EU competition

law applies in international arbitration, especially on how it aspires to apply and how

practically to deal with it. The European Court of Justice's case-law provides the few

existing rules on the application of EU competition law in arbitration proceedings, and it

leads to the research question that this article tries to answer: does the case-law of

European Court of Justice have the potential to cause a shift of parties' preference

towards arbitration clauses that exclude arbitral jurisdiction on disputes involving an issue

of public policy and consequently does this case-law have the effect of depriving business

parties of an useful private enforcement tool and leading them into traditional litigation?

3 Blanke, G., 'The role of EC competition law in international arbitration: a “plaidoyer”' (2005) 16(1) European Business Law Review; Dempegiotis, S., 'EC Competition Law and International Arbitration in the Light of EC Regulation 1/2003' (2003) 25(3) Journal of International Arbitration.

4 Eisenberg, T. and Miller, G., 'The Flight from Arbitration: An Empirical Study of Ex Ante Arbitration Clauses in the Contracts of Publicly Held Companies' (2007) 56 DePaul Law Review, 335.

5 Drahozal, C. and Wittrock, Q., 'Is There a flight from Arbitration?' (2008) Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1147697.

6 Ibid.

3

Page 4: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

A hint at the importance of this issue comes from the presently shared opinion in the

arbitration community that, due to the degree of uncertainty of this subject matter,

arbitrators or parties' counsels facing a competition law issue tent to disregard it, as being

in front of a “veil of Maya”, even if it could serve the party's interest by retroactively freeing

her from a burdensome contractual provision.

A more precise appreciation of the intersection of EU competition law and international

arbitration revolve around the principle that for the EU legal order competition law needs to

be treated as a set of mandatory norms.7 Arbitrability of competition law is undisputed,

both in case law and literature.8 It is widely accepted that competition law material issues

are an arbitrable matter. And arbitrability was not opposed by ECJ and by the US Supreme

Court on the assumption that the public policy interests embodied in competition law can

be safeguarded by national courts during the award review. However this assumption has

proved largely illusory in practice. The legal system is facing a trade-off between, on one

hand, the principle that arbitral awards cannot be subject to a review on the merit of the

dispute. Because a review on the merit will practically throw away the result of the

arbitration proceeding and start the dispute all over again resembling a second instance

court. But, on the other hand is the principle that competition law is a public policy

regulation, the application of which needs to be somehow guaranteed by the legal system.

The matter is how to strike the balance between these two principles in the second-look by

national courts.

In this theoretical paper we adapt the Priest-Klein's model9 on the selection of disputes for

litigation and integrate it within Dari Mattiacci-Parisi's model on dissipation of value and

lost treasure in rent-seeking games.10 The purpose is to analytically test how the case-law

of the European Court of Justice (hereinafter ECJ) on a specific procedural rule affects

individual's ex-ante incentives to exclude competition law form a contractual arbitration

clause. The rule under examination is the ECJ interpretation of Article 267 of the Treaty on

the Functioning of the European Union. Denying arbitral tribunals jurisdiction to refer cases

for a preliminary ruling, under Article 267, risks to deprive of effectiveness an arbitral

awards based on provisions declared by the ECJ as EU public policy rules.

7 Radicati di Brozolo, L.G., ' Antitrust: a Paradigm of the Relation Between Mandatory Rules and Arbitration – A Fresh Look at the “Second Look”' (2004) International Arbitration Law Review.

8 Artwood, J.R., ' The Arbitration of International Antitrust Disputes: A Status Report and Suggestions' (1994) 21 Fordham Corporate Law Institute.

9 Priest, G.L., and B. Klein, ‘The selection of disputes for litigation’ (1984) 13 The Journal of Legal Studies, 1.10 Dari-Mattiacci, G., and F. Parisi, ‘Rents, dissipation and lost treasures: Rethinking Tullock’s paradox’ (2005) 124

Public Choice, 411.

4

Page 5: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

The paper is divided in three parts: the first one is a (I) legal and historical overview of the

problem, which sets the preliminary remarks necessary to understand both the problem

and also the general assumptions of the economic analysis; the second part is the (II)

participation constraint analysis, a fundamental building block for describing how the legal

rule stated in ECJ's case-law on Article 267 TFEU affects plaintiff's expected utility function

when he has to decide whether to file or not to file an arbitration proceeding that potentially

involves European “public policy” issues; and the third part is (III) the parties' effort

analysis, testing how parties' level of effort in winning a dispute is affected by the ECJ's

case-law on Article 267 TFEU. The intent is to find whether, the rule created by the ECJ's

case-law can cause an increase in lost treasure in comparison with the opposite

interpretation of Article 267 TFEU supported by legal scholars. The existence of a potential

higher lost treasure in arbitration could provide parties with the incentive to run away from

arbitration and back to traditional litigation, losing all the advantages of arbitration and

sinking into a dispute resolution mechanism that proved itself unsatisfactory for the private

enforcement of competition law.

(I) Legal and historical overviewThere are three preliminary remarks we need to address to justify our economic analysis.

The first (a) is the functioning of Article 267 TFEU in the light of ECJ's interpretation; the

second (b) regards the limitations to the recognition and enforcement of an arbitral award

by a national court and the third (c) describes why denying arbitral tribunal authority to

request preliminary ruling may impair the effectiveness of arbitration when European

competition law is involved.

(a) The functioning of Article 267 TFEU

Under Article 19 of the Treaty on European Union the function of the European Court of

Justice is to “ensure that in the interpretation and application of the Treaties the law is

observed” and in doing so the ECJ shall “give preliminary rulings, at the request of courts

or tribunals of the Member States, on the interpretation of Union law”.11 The procedure for

requesting a preliminary ruling is described by Article 267 TFEU: “The Court of Justice of

the European Union shall have jurisdiction to give preliminary rulings concerning: (a) the

interpretation of the Treaties; (b) the validity and interpretation of acts of the institutions,

bodies, offices or agencies of the Union; Where such a question is raised before any court

11 See Article 19 of the Treaty on European Union.

5

Page 6: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

or tribunal of a Member State, that court or tribunal may, if it considers that a decision on

the question is necessary to enable it to give judgement, request the Court to give a ruling

thereon. Where any such question is raised in a case pending before a court or tribunal of

a Member State against whose decisions there is no judicial remedy under national law,

that court or tribunal shall bring the matter before the Court.”

According to these provisions the ECJ is the exclusive judicial authority with the power to

provide a legally binding interpretation of the European Union law through its preliminary

ruling.12 However such power can be exercised only when a court or tribunal of a Member

State decides that a preliminary ruling is necessary to give its judgement. Moreover the

ECJ has no power to affect this decision nor to act as an appellate court assessing the

merit of the dispute.13 It just provides the correct interpretation of the Union law in the case

at stake. Using the words of the ECJ: “The objective of the reference procedure is to retain

the independence of the national courts, while at the same time preventing a body of

national case law not in accord with the rules of [the European Union] law from coming

into existence in any Member State” guaranteeing an uniform application of EU law

throughout the Union.14 It is worth noting that the preliminary ruling procedure accounts for

over 50% of all cases heard by the ECJ, making Article 267 TFEU a key feature in the

development and enforcement of the European Union law.

After this description of Article 267 TFEU our attention can shift on ECJ's case-law on

Article 267 TFEU. More specifically, how this provision works, according to the ECJ, when

private arbitral tribunals are handling a dispute that requires a preliminary ruling on articles

101 and 102 of the TFEU. Namely, whether an arbitral tribunal can be considered “court or

tribunal of a Member State” in the meaning of Article 267 TFEU and if it is not the case

how arbitration proceedings are supposed to act in such circumstances to solve the

dispute.

12 Actually the ECJ ruling is legally binding only for the court that made the request of preliminary ruling. However the whole European legal system takes under deep consideration ECJ's case-law.

13 As correctly argued in Hartley, T., ‘The Foundations of European Community Law’ (2010) Oxford 7th edn., 287; “There are two major differences between an appeal and a reference. First, in the case of an appeal the initiative lies with the parties: the party who is dissatisfied with the court’s judgment decides whether to appeal and then take the necessary procedural steps. The court a quo normally has no further say in the matter and cannot prevent the appeal from being lodged. Secondly, the appeal court decides the case, even though the appeal may be on limited grounds only, and it has the power to set aside the decision of the court a quo; normally it can then substitute its own decision for that of the lower court. These features are not found in the procedure for a preliminary reference: the court a quo decides whether the reference should be made, and only specific issues are referred to the European Court. Once it has decided these, the European Court remits the case to the national court for a decision.”

14 Judgment of the Court of 24 May 1977, Hoffmann-La Roche AG v Centrafarm Vertriebsgesellschaft Pharmazeutischer Erzeugnisse mbH, Case 107/76.

6

Page 7: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

The first decision on this matter is the Nordsea case, dated 1982.15 Here, the ECJ denied

private arbitral tribunals jurisdiction to refer for preliminary rulings stating that: “An

arbitrator who is called upon to decide a dispute between the parties to a contract under a

clause inserted in that contract is not to be considered as a 'court or tribunal of a Member

State' within the meaning of Article 177 of the Treaty [now called Article 267 TFEU]”.16

However, the ECJ did not leave a procedural gap for such circumstances. In fact, it also

explained how the preliminary ruling shall be requested: “If in the course of arbitration

resorted to by agreement between the parties questions of community law are raised

which the ordinary courts may be called upon to examine either in the context of their

collaboration with arbitration tribunals or in the course of a review of an arbitration award,

it is for those courts to ascertain whether it is necessary for them to make a reference to

the Court of Justice under Article 177 of the Treaty [now called Article 267 TFEU]”.17

Substantially, this decision entitles national courts to have a second look on arbitral

tribunals' award and to examine their application of European Union Law in the context of

any method of recourse available under the relevant national legislation. It also totally

deprives arbitral tribunal of jurisdiction on the necessity to refer to the Court of Justice for a

preliminary ruling.

Legal scholars started a debate on the ECJ's interpretation of Article 267 TFUE and

strongly argued both pro and against it. From this debate it is clear that the issue is

controversial and there are good legal arguments for reversing the ECJ case-law.18

However, in 1994 the ECJ confirmed its previous interpretation and build further in the

case Municipality of Almelo.19 The ECJ stated that: “It follows from the principles of the

primacy of Community law and of its uniform application, in conjunction with Article 5 of

the Treaty, that a court of a Member State to which an appeal against an arbitration award

is made pursuant to national law must, even where it gives judgment having regard to

fairness, observe the rules of Community law, in particular those relating to competition

15 Judgment of the European Court of Justice of 23 March 1982, Nordsee Deutsche Hochseefischerei GmbH v Reederei Mond Hochseefischerei Nordstern AG & Co. KG and Reederei Friedrich Busse Hochseefischerei Nordstern AG & Co. KG., Case 102/81.

16 Ibid.17 Ibid.18 Biavati, P., ‘Pregiudiziale comunitaria e arbitrato’ (1995) Rivista dell’arbitrato, 421; Tizzano, Antonio, ‘Arbitrato

privato e competenza pregiudiziale della Corte comunitaria’ (1983) Rassegna dell’arbitrato, 153; Bebr, G. ‘Arbitration Tribunals and Article 177 of the EEC Treaty’ (1985) Common Market Law Review, 489-504; Friend, M. ‘EEC Law, Preliminary Rulings and Arbitrators’ (1983) The Law Quarterly Review, 356-360.

19 Judgment of the European Court of Justice of 27 April 1994, Municipality of Almelo and others v NV Energiebedrijf Ijsselmij., Case 393/92.

7

Page 8: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

[law].”20 In this specific case it was possible to appeal the award but the national court had

to decide the case not using the body of national legislation but having regard to the

principle of fairness. The fundamental legal principle implied in Municipality of Almelo is

that no matter what is the substantial law, freely chosen by the parties to regulate the merit

of the dispute, the national court has to guarantee that the EU law is observed and in

particular that European competition law is observed.

This is a ground breaking principle for the review of arbitral awards by national courts. And

it was clarified five years later in the Eco Swiss case.21 In Eco Swiss the ECJ starts quoting

its Nordsea decision but, in light of scholars' criticisms that followed the too wide principle

expressed in Municipality of Almelo, it proceeds specifying how “it is in the interest of

efficient arbitration proceedings that review of arbitration awards should be limited in

scope and that annulment of or refusal to recognize an award should be possible only in

exceptional circumstances”22 but then, the ECJ states that: “according to Article 3(g) of the

EC Treaty (now, after amendment, Article 3(1)(g) EC), Article 85 of the Treaty [now called

Article 101 TFEU, a competition law provision] constitutes a fundamental provision which

is essential for the accomplishment of the tasks entrusted to the Community and, in

particular, for the functioning of the internal market.”23 For this reason, according to the

ECJ, a national court must set aside an arbitral award if the court considers that the award

is in fact contrary to Article 101 TFEU, where its domestic procedural rules allow the court

to set it aside on the ground of failure to observe national rules of public policy. 24 The ECJ

also states that: “the provisions of Article 85 [now called Article 101 TFEU] of the Treaty

may be regarded as a matter of public policy within the meaning of the New York

Convention.”25 To clarify the extent and fully understand the importance of this statement

we have to shift our attention on the limitations to validity of arbitral award.

(b) Limitations to the recognition and enforcement of an arbitral award

All the European Union Member States are among the 142 United Nations Member

States, that have signed and adopted the New York Convention of 10 June 1958 on the

20 Ibid., par. 23.21 Judgment of the European Court of Justice of 1 June 1999 , Eco Swiss China Time Ltd v Benetton International NV -

(Case C-126/97) available at this URL address: http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=CELEX:61997J0126:EN:HTML.

22 Ibid., par. 35.23 Ibid., par. 36.24 Ibid., par. 37.25 Ibid., par. 38; The New York Convention of 10 June 1958 on the Recognition and Enforcement of Foreign Arbitral

Awards.

8

Page 9: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

Recognition and Enforcement of Foreign Arbitral Awards.26 The object of the New York

Convention is to guarantee that an award granted by a foreign arbitral tribunal can be

recognized and enforced in all the countries that have adopted the Convention. There is

no need to explain why a widely enforceable arbitral award is a fundamental aspect for the

functioning and efficiency of arbitration. In fact, as already mentioned in Eco Swiss, the

ECJ acknowledges the general principle of limited review of arbitral awards: “ it is in the

interest of efficient arbitration proceedings that review of arbitration awards should be

limited in scope and that annulment of or refusal to recognise an award should be possible

only in exceptional circumstances”.27 In Article V(1)(c) and (e) and II(b) of the New York

Convention we can find the limitation to the general principle of recognition and

enforcement of arbitral awards. More specifically, under letter b), any national court has

the power to set an arbitral award aside, under the condition that the recognition or

enforcement of the arbitral award would be contrary to the public policy of that country.

The same limitation is often present within national procedural regulations and it reflects

the French general principle of “ordre public”.28 To some extent this principle allows a form

of action or review of a national arbitral award with the purpose to control how national

mandatory norms are applied in arbitration and most importantly to impede the

enforcement of a decision which is challenging the national public policy.29 However, the

legal literature on arbitration acknowledges that the purpose of this limitation is not to

provide an appeal judgement in front of national courts. It represents the last resort

mechanism to avoid enforcing an award that results incompatible with the fundamental

principles of a national legal system and that can be considered against the the national

public policy provisions.30

(c) The importance of preliminary ruling for arbitration, when EU competition law is at stake

In light of what said in (a) and (b) above, we can now understand the importance of the

aforementioned Eco Swiss case.31 The ECJ substantially declared Article 101 TFEU a 26 As of October 1, 2009.27 See footnote 13, above.28 See for instance: Article 1064 and 1064 of the Dutch Code of Civil Procedure; Article 829 and Article 839 of the

Italian Code of Civil Procedure; Article 1502 of the New French Code of Civil Procedure; Article 187 and 190, paragraph 2, lett. e) of the Swiss “Loi fédérale sur le droit International privé”.

29 The concepts of mandatory norms and public policy rules are two different concepts but in the legal practice sometimes for judges is difficult to set the boundary.

30 Derains, Y., 'Public Policy and the Law Applicable to the Dispute in International Arbitration' (1987) ICCA Series No. 3

31 Judgment of the Court of Justice dated 1 June 1999 - Eco Swiss China Time Ltd v Benetton International NV - (Case C-126/97) available at this URL address: http://eur-lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?

9

Page 10: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

matter of public policy, in respect both to the review of national arbitration and to

recognition-enforcement of foreign arbitral awards under the New York Convention.

Therefore, given that an arbitral award involves European competition law, a national court

may inquiry whether a preliminary ruling is necessary to decide the case and set the award

aside just because the arbitral tribunal gave its decision without being able to refer for a

preliminary ruling. In order to render this problem of a more general interest, it is worth

noting that, beyond competition law, it is uncertain which other articles of the EU Treaties

are eligible to be considered European “public policy”. At any time, the ECJ may declare

an EU law provision to be of fundamental importance for the EU legal order casting a

shadow of uncertainty on all arbitration proceedings involving that provision.

When an arbitral tribunal is denied jurisdiction on reference for preliminary ruling and the

same tribunal is facing a legal dispute that involves the private enforcement of European

competition law, the effectiveness of the arbitral award is on the edge. Arbitrators have no

way to make sure that their decision will not be set aside. In fact when the arbitral tribunal

thinks a preliminary ruling is needed, it has no jurisdiction on the point, and no matter how

the tribunal applies the EU law any national court may deem that a preliminary ruling was

indeed necessary and refer the case at the ECJ. It is worth repeating that the procedure in

front of a national court cannot represent an appeal procedure. Namely, an assessment on

how arbitrators applied the law to the merit of the case is out of the scope of the national

court's second-look procedure. On the contrary, national courts have just to guarantee that

European competition law was duly taken into consideration in the arbitration proceeding

and if it is not the case to set aside the award. However, the uncertainty created on this

point by ECJ's interpretation is reflected on the national courts' case-law and should be

object of further studies.

On the ground of these three preliminary remarks we can now move to the economic

analysis.

(II) Participation Constraint AnalysisIn the second part of the paper we structure the definition of the problem and outlines the

general assumptions necessary for the economic analysis. Then we study how parties'

expected utility changes from the Priest-Klein model introducing a new definition of

plaintiff's participation constraint, in line with the ECJ's interpretation of Article 267 TFEU.

uri=CELEX:61997J0126:EN:HTML.

10

Page 11: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

Description of the structure of the problem

Our interest focuses on cases involving European competition law rules, when the arbitral

tribunal considers necessary a preliminary ruling from the ECJ to be able to correctly

interpret and apply EU law to grant an enforceable award. This is a problem of application

of EU competition law within arbitration proceedings. Our intention is to test and compare

the two legal solutions that are theoretically available in the European legal system under

Article 267 TFEU. One is the ECJ's current interpretation of Article 267 TFEU and the

other is what it could be according to the legal scholars.32 We call them “legal rules” but

they are actually the two possible interpretations that can be given of Article 267 TFEU in

respect to private arbitration proceedings:

1. if, according to legal scholars' opinion, the arbitral tribunal should have authority to

request a preliminary ruling, it will suspend the procedure and requests the

preliminary ruling to the ECJ. After receiving the ECJ's decision the tribunal can

grant an award in compliance with the application of the European “public policy”

rules. Such award should not be overruled by national courts in the enforcement

phase on the ground of European “public policy” issues. In fact, national courts'

review will concern only whether the issue of preliminary ruling was duly taken into

consideration;

2. alternatively, as per the state of the art of the ECJ's interpretation of article 267

TFEU, if the arbitral tribunal is denied authority to request preliminary rulings, the

award is on the edge. The arbitral tribunal has two options: (a) can cooperate with a

national court and suspend the procedure requesting the national court to assess

the preliminary ruling issue or (b) it can grant an arbitral award irrespective of a

potential incompatibility with the European “public policy”. Such award can be

voided by any Member State national court in light of the ECJ case-law on article

267 TFEU on the ground either of the national procedural law or of the Article V

paragraph 2, let b) of the New York Convention. In this case the plaintiff will have to

file a second arbitral procedure to obtain an enforceable award in the European

Union.

Our goal is to test each rule in respect to its effect on parties' ex-ante incentives to choose

to exclude competition law disputes from a contractual arbitration clause.

32 See footnote 11, above.

11

Page 12: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

General assumptions

A first assumption is based on the fact that ECJ's preliminary rulings do not concern the

merit of the case but they are only a matter of EU law interpretation. Hence, we can

assume that parties' effort cannot directly influence the outcome of the preliminary ruling, it

is out of parties sphere of control.33 On the contrary, parties' investment in effort can

influence the decision both of the arbitral tribunal, on the merit of the case, and of the

national court, on whether a preliminary ruling is necessary for reaching a decision in light

of Article 267 TFEU.

We can also assume that under the second rule, namely lack of authority to request a

preliminary ruling, there is no overlap of respective jurisdiction between the arbitral tribunal

and the national court. Their decisions making process are completely independent

events. In fact, as mentioned above, on one hand it is a general principle of arbitration that

national courts cannot review an arbitral award on the merit of the case. On the other

hand, also the arbitral tribunal, even when cooperating with a national court, can express

an opinion but does not have jurisdiction to address the need of preliminary ruling for the

case.

In the light of these assumptions, we represent in Figure 1 and Figure 2 the dynamics of

this problem respectively under the first and the second rule:

Figure 1:

33 See footnote number 5 above.

12

Page 13: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

Figure 2:

Definition of the participation constraint

We focus now on the economic analysis of the two legal rules discussed above. Under the

first rule, which we call Ra that provides arbitral tribunals with authority to request

preliminary ruling, parties' ex-ante participation constraint to the arbitration proceeding is

described by the Priest-Klein's model:

Ra : pa W−(1−pa ) L−C−S>0 (1)

With pa representing plaintiff's probability of victory; W is the amount at stake in case

plaintiff wins; (1-pa) is plaintiff's estimation of the probability of defendant's victory; L is

plaintiff's loss in case defendant wins a possible counter-claim. The term C represents the

cost of the procedure and S is the lost opportunity of settlement. Only when this

participation constraint is positive, namely Ra > 0, plaintiff will file a lawsuit.34

This well known process of selection of disputes for litigation needs to be modified if we

34 Priest, G.L., and B. Klein, ‘The selection of disputes for litigation’ (1984) 13 The Journal of Legal Studies, 1. The standard participation constraint indicated in the literature is: pW – C > S and means that plaintiff's expected gain from litigation is bigger than the potential settlement amount. However we are not interested in the settlement, so we prefer a formulation that considers settlement as a cost-opportunity of litigation. Moreover, the formulation we choose here considers also the fact that defendant may have counterclaims, for instance reputation damages.

13

Page 14: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

focus our attention on what happens under the second rule, namely when arbitral tribunals

are denied authority to request a preliminary ruling. As illustrated in Figure 2 above, in this

case, the parties are facing a three-phase procedure and according to our assumptions

the adjudicator of each phase can only address a legal issue that is specific to the phase

in which he/she has jurisdiction. Therefore, under the second rule, the participation

constraint is not equal to Ra any more. Plaintiff is facing a differently structured decision

problem. We call p1, p2 and p3 plaintiff's probability to win the legal argument respectively

in the first, the second or the third phase of the procedure. Given the fact that this three

probabilities are attached to three different and completely independent events (see what

stated in the general assumptions, above, and in part (I) of this paper), to find a party's

total probability of victory we have to multiply among themselves the probabilities of each

independent event that need to jointly occur for reaching a positive outcome and then we

sum them together. Figure 3, below represents all the possible outcomes of the multi-

phase dispute with the relative probabilities and identifies in green those positive for

plaintiff and in red those positive for defendant. We repeat, for the sake of clarity, that the

third phase is a refile of the arbitration, which is needed if the first arbitral award is set

aside by a national court in the second phase.

Figure 3:

14

Page 15: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

Each ending position represents a possible outcome of the multi-phase dispute that may

be favourable or unfavourable to plaintiff and it is reached through a different combination

of occurring independent events. The expression Rc, below, represent how the

participation constraint changes in this scenario in light of such definition of parties total

probability of victory:

Rc : [ p1 p2+(1−p1) p2 p3 +p1 (1− p2) p3 ] W−[ (1− p1 ) (1−p2 )+p1 (1− p2) (1−p3)+(1− p1 ) p2 (1− p3) ] L+

−C−S>0

After calculating and simplifying the participation constraint, the following result is reached:

Rc : ( p1 p2 +p1 p3 +p2 p3−2p1 p2 p3)W −(1−p1 p2−p1 p3−p2 p3+2p1 p2 p3 ) L−C−S>0 (2)

For the sake of clarity, this multi-phase procedure affects the participation constraint in two

ways: on one hand, the outcome depends on different and independent events that must

occur simultaneously, in fact we multiply the probability for each singular outcome. But, on

the other hand, in this scenario each party has the opportunity to revert an unfavourable

decision, in fact to find the total parties' probability of success we have to sum the

probabilities of each outcome.

Therefore, in our model, the two legal rules under investigation are represented

respectively by expression (1) and (2), above. To show the consistency of our model with

the Priest-Klein's one, in expression number (2) we can see that once we set:

p1p2+p1p3+p2p3-2p1p2p3 = pc the two expressions have the same structure:

Ra : pa W−(1− pa ) L−C−S>0

Rc: pcW −(1− pc ) L−C−S>0∀ pc =p1 p2+p1 p3+p2 p3−2p1 p2 p3

This statement may appear trivial but it confirms the suitability of our problem settings and

it is a building block for the next part of this paper and for further research on this topic.

A possible critique may involve the introduction of a the third phase, since it is substantially

equal to a re-enactment of the first phase in light both of the national court decision and of

the ECJ's one. We believe that such critique is not sound. The third phase is actually

connected only to the ECJ's decision which is independent from the previous two phases

and from the merit of the case. If the third phase is reached, this means that the ECJ's

decision made the first phase award incompatible with public policy and that the national

court set the award aside. The third phase is like a new dispute between the parties in a

15

Page 16: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

new state of the world changed by the ECJ's preliminary ruling. In fact, in the third phase,

the merit of the dispute must still be decided by an arbitral tribunal (not necessary the

same tribunal of the first phase) while complying with the outcome of the ECJ's

interpretation of European competition law rule, which in this case will be a binding legal

rule for that arbitral tribunal. The reasoning above holds true also when exists a national

regulation setting a cooperation procedure between arbitrators and national courts.

Namely when the arbitral tribunal can suspend the first phase procedure and request a

national court to deal with the preliminary ruling. Later on, when the arbitral tribunal

resumes the first stage, it will address the merit of the case exactly as mentioned above. In

fact, such scenario is substantially a three-phase procedure compatible with the structure

of our model.

On this point, further research may be driven by considerations about individuals

perception and estimation of the uncertain probability of winning in a multi-phase

procedure. Priest-Klein showed that “disputes selected for litigation will constitute neither a

random nor a representative sample of the set of all disputes”.35 They will be those

disputes presenting two characteristics: (a) a probability of success estimated by the

parties which is closer to the threshold probability and (b) the difference between the

parties' expectations of the outcome is bigger. Namely, they will be the cases where

parties are more likely to make an error in the assessment of the probability of success. In

future it will be interesting to investigate this problem on the basis of decision theory. Since

people are not good in estimating complex probabilities structure, the question is whether

in a multi-phase procedure the intrinsic uncertainty of convincing more then one

adjudicator will drive towards more or less litigation? However this is outside of the scope

of this paper.

(III) Dissipation of parties' effort analysisOur attention turns now on parties' efforts under the two legal rules described above. Our

purpose is to discover how the parties' level of effort will be affected by a multi-phase

procedure, and whether it causes an higher lost treasure in comparison to the alternative

rule. If it is true, since the multi-phase procedure is the rule currently applied, we could

argue that the current ECJ's case law has the potential to lead parties away from

arbitration on competition law disputes.

35 Ibid.

16

Page 17: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

We intend to use the standard formulation of a rent-seeking game in litigation:

p=αA r

αAr +βBr

The probability p of winning the case, is a function of A, namely plaintiff's level of effort in

litigation, and B, defendant's level of effort in litigation; with α and β representing

coefficients of parties respective position in the merit of the dispute. While the term r is a

factor determining the productivity of rent-seeking expenditures. For the sake of simplicity,

we shall assume that parties' stakes in the dispute are symmetric (W = L), in fact this is

often the truth in contractual relationships. The model we are using to solve this problem is

an adaptation of the one used by Dari-Mattiacci and Parisi to describe the rise of rent

dissipation. We also choose to follow part of their notation and the useful simplification

provided by the normalization of the value at stake W.36

In Dari Mattiacci-Parisi's model each party's share of the rent seeking competition (R A for

plaintiff and RB for defendant) will be equal to:37

RA =pA−A and RB =pB−B

With pA and pB representing parties' respective probabilities to win the case in function of

their respective efforts. As mentioned above, the parties value at stake W is not present in

the formula because of the normalization.38 Regarding the first rule Ra, assuming for

simplicity that the parties have also symmetric merits in the dispute, namely α = β = 1, the

dissipation of effort analysis is perfectly identical to the one described by Dari Mattiacci

and Parisi in their model of rent-seeking dissipation. Ex-ante, Parties' can expect that their

net share of the rent (RaA for plaintiff and RaB for defendant) is going to be:39

36 Dari-Mattiacci, G., and F. Parisi, ‘Rents, dissipation and lost treasures: Rethinking Tullock’s paradox’ (2005) 124 Public Choice, 411. “In order to keep notation simple, we model the parties’ investment in rent-seeking as fractions of the rent. The literature has usually used capital letters like X and Y to denote the absolute values of the parties' expenditures in rent-seeking and X/(X+Y)V and Y/(X+Y)V to denote the parties’ shares in the rent. Party X’s payoff thus is generally represented as X/(X+Y)V-X (the portion of the rent he or she earns minus the rent-seeking expenditure). In our model we use the labels A and B to denote the fractions of the rent that are spent on rent-seeking, rather than the absolute values of the expenditures. In our model, therefore A=X/V. This merely represents a different way to measure effort, and it does not impinge upon the generality or the validity of the model. In our model, party A’s payoff is A/(A+B)V- AV=[A/(A+B)-A]V. The absolute value of the rent, V [in our model this term V is called W], can thus be simplified (or simply normalized to 1), allowing us to concentrate on the parties’ expenditures and the magnitude of the dissipation as fractions of the rent.”

37 Please note that this is an upper case A to differentiate it from the term Ra representing the first legal rule, and the term RaA, below, representing plaintiff's share of the rent seeking competition under the first rule.

38 See footnote 23.39 Dari-Mattiacci, G., and F. Parisi, ‘Rents, dissipation and lost treasures: Rethinking Tullock’s paradox’ (2005) 124

Public Choice, 411.

17

Page 18: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

RaA =pA−A=Ar

A r +Br−A

RaB =pB−B=Br

Ar +B r−B

And the parties will maximize their own share of the rent by choosing A* and B* that satisfy

the following first order conditions:

δRaA

δA:

rAr−1 Br

( Ar +Br )2−1=0

δRaB

δB:

rBr−1 Ar

( Ar +Br )2−1=0

(3)

As proved by Dari-Mattiacci and Parisi, the levels of investment that satisfy (3) are A* = B* =

r/4.40 This means that under the rule Ra, namely when arbitral tribunal has authority to

request preliminary ruling, if r = 2 each party will spend exactly 1/2 of the value of the

dispute in rent-seeking and the two parties together will dissipate the whole value of the

dispute.

Things get slightly more complicated in our adaptation of this model, describing parties'

effort under the rule denying arbitral tribunals' authority to request a preliminary ruling. In

our model's description of the problem, pA and pB are a function of p1, p2 and p3 which are

the probabilities that a party will win a respective phase of the three-phase procedure.

They are functions of parties' respective effort in each phase, namely p1(A1, B1), p2 (A2, B2)

and p3 (A3, B3). Thus, parties respective probability of winning the case is pA(p1A, p2A, p3A),

and pB(p1B, p2B, p3B) with the following extended formulation:

p1A=α1 A1

r

α1 A1r +β1B1

r; p2A=

α2 A2r

α 2 A2r +β2 B2

r; p3A=

α3 A3r

α 3 A3r +β3 B3

r

p1B=β1B1

r

α 1 A1r +β1 B1

r; p2B=

β2 B2r

α2 A2r +β2 B2

r; p3B=

β3B3r

α3 A3r +β3 B3

r

In the light of this, we can accordingly change the formulation of Dari-Mattiacci and Parisi's

model and make it compatible with the second rule, namely Rc. In our model, parties’ net

shares of rent are derived from expression number (2), in part (II) of this paper (see

40 Ibid. As clarified in Dari-Mattiacci and Parisi: the second order conditions for this problem are ∂2RaA/∂A2 = [-(Ar+Br)+r(Br-Ar)] [rAr-2Br / (Ar+Br)3] and ∂2RaB/∂B2 = [-(Ar+Br)+r(Ar-Br)] [rArBr-2 / (Ar+Br)3]. The reader may easily verify that the necessary values ∂2RaA/∂A2<0 and ∂2RaB/∂B2<0 are always guaranteed by A=B for any value of r.

18

Page 19: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

above), and they are set as equal to:41

RcA : ( p1A p2A +p1A p3A +p2A p3A−2p1A p2A p3A )−( A1 +A2 +A3)RcB : ( p1B p2B+p1B p3B+p2B p3B−2p1B p2B p3B)−(B1+B2 +B3 )

(4)

To make things simpler, without losing in precision, we can assume that since parties are

not aware ex-ante of what will be the merit of the disputes they may assume to have

symmetric cases in respect to the merits in all the phases of the procedure, namely that in

all p1, p2 and p3 the values α = β = 1. Moreover, under such circumstance, the strategy for

a party willing to maximize its chance to win the game is to divide its total effort in three

equal amounts. The total amount that she is willing to invest in the litigation, namely the

total effort will be compound of this three parts A tot= A1 + A2 + A3 and they will be all set

equal to a value Ac = A1 = A2 = A3. The same will be true for the counterpart Btot= B1 + B2 +

B3 and with Bc = B1 = B2 = B3. The obvious result of the above assumptions is that parties'

probabilities of success in each phase of the dispute will be equal, i.e. p1 = p2 = p3. These

assumptions are not too restrictive. In fact we can expect that in line with the predictions of

Priest-Klein's model on the selection of disputes for litigation, ex-post “when either plaintiff

or defendant has a 'powerful' case, settlement is more likely because the parties are less

likely to disagree about the outcome” of the trial. The contrary is true when a case is

problematic, namely when the merit or the law applicable is uncertain.42 Therefore, ex-ante

parties expect that ex-post they will settle cases in which one party has better merits and

select for litigation those cases that will actually be characterized by both the most

challenging merits and the most challenging interpretation of competition law. In other

words, ex-ante parties will expect to litigate cases where the probability of winning is close

to 50% in all the phases of the procedure.43

After the simplification introduced by the above assumptions we can rewrite expression

number (4) defining parties' net share of the rent in our model as equal to:

41 Dari-Mattiacci, G., and F. Parisi, ‘Rents, dissipation and lost treasures: Rethinking Tullock’s paradox’ (2005) 124 Public Choice, 411.

42 Priest, G.L., and B. Klein, ‘The selection of disputes for litigation’ (1984) 13 The Journal of Legal Studies, 1.43 In further writings, it will be interesting to examine, this issue from the ECJ viewpoint which has an institutional

mission to make the EU Law application clearer through it's case-law and therefore has an interest to hear such highly problematic chases.

19

Page 20: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

RcA=3p A2 −2p A

3 −3A c , ∀ pA=Ac

r

Acr +Bc

r→ RcA=

3Ac2r

( Acr +Bc

r )2−

2Ac3r

( Acr +Bc

r )3−3A c

RcB=3pB2−2pB

3 −3Bc , ∀ pB=Bc

r

Acr +Bc

r→RcB=

3Bc2r

( Acr +Bc

r )2−

2Bc3r

( Acr +B c

r )3−3Bc

In order to maximize their net share of the rent, for plaintiff in respect to A and for

defendant in respect to B, the parties will choose Ac* and Bc

* that satisfy the following first

order conditions:

δRcA

δAc

:2rAc

2r−1 Bc2r

( Acr +Bc

r )4

−1=0

δRcB

δBc

:2rBc

2r−1 Ac2r

( Acr +Bc

r )4

−1=0

(5)

This result complies with the requirements set by the Dari Mattiacci-Parisi's model.44 In

fact, when we compare expression number (5) with expression number (3), it is clear that

they are qualitatively the same functions and they are diverging only quantitatively.45 In

fact, when Ac* = Bc

* it is straight forward that in Rc, namely under the rule denying authority

to arbitrators, the levels of investment that satisfy (5) are Ac* = Bc

* = r/8, while on the

contrary in Ra above, the solution of (3), was: A* = B* = r/4.46

However, in our model the rents Ac* and Bc

* are dissipated in each of the three phases of

the litigation procedure and the total party's expenditure, namely Atot*, is equal to 3 times

Ac* as well as Btot

* is equal to 3 times Bc*. The following graphic clarifies our results

comparing the two rules from a different perspective and representing the total lost

treasure that occurs in the dispute resolution under the two analysed rules in function of

the variable r:

44 Second order conditions are always negative for any value of r given that Ac=Bc.45 In order to test this formulation we can set r = 1 and maximize each share function first in respect to A and then to B

obtaining that the model provides results for Ac* = Bc

* and the values of A and B are positively correlated to r, namely when r increases A and B are going to increase as well.

46 Dari-Mattiacci, G., and F. Parisi, ‘Rents, dissipation and lost treasures: Rethinking Tullock’s paradox’ (2005) 124 Public Choice, 411.

20

Page 21: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

Commenting the graph above, we can say that for all value of r the second rule causes

parties higher effort in litigation. In fact, under the rule granting arbitrators authority to use

Article 267 TFEU (Ra) for r = 1 each party will spend 1/4 of the value of the dispute in

litigation with a total lost treasure will be equal to 1/2 of the total value of the dispute. While

under the rule denying arbitrators authority to use Article 267 TFEU (Rc), for r = 1 each

party will dissipate 1/8 of the dispute value, in each of the three-phases of the procedure.

Namely, throughout the entire procedure each party will dissipate 3/8 of the value of the

case with a total dissipation, for the two parties together, equal to 6/8 (simplified in 3/4) of

the value of the dispute instead of 1/2 as under the first rule. Therefore, for r = 1 ECJ's

denied authority on arbitral tribunals will cost to parties and to the society a 25% higher

rent-seeking dissipation value than what results when arbitral tribunals are granted such

authority. The graph shows also that, under the two different rules, full dissipation of the

value of the dispute will occur at different values of r. When the arbitral tribunal has

authority to request preliminary ruling (the blue line, Ra) each party will spend exactly half

of the value of the dispute in rent-seeking and the two parties together will dissipate the

whole value of the dispute when r=2. On the contrary when the tribunal is denied such

authority (the red line, Rc) the total dissipation is reached at a lower condition, namely

r=4/3.47

Although it is out of the scope of this paper we shall specify that Dari-Mattiacci and Parisi 47 We should remember that, given our assumptions, to obtain the total party's effort Atot

* and Btot* the values Ac

* and Bc*

have to be multiplied by three, once for each phase of the procedure. Therefore Atot* = 3Ac

* and Btot* = 3Bc

* = 3r/8, from which we derive that Atot

* = Btot* = 1/2 if when r=4/3.

21

Page 22: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

found that when such point is reached if parties have an exit-option, namely do not file a

lawsuit, parties will start to use the exit option together with mixed participation strategies.

“When parties randomize their participation in the game there is a positive probability that

no party plays and the rent remains unexploited” creating a lost treasure loss.48 As we can

see from the graph the point at which the lost treasure loss starts sooner under Rc then

under Ra.

Proposition 1: Everything else constant, under a rule denying arbitral tribunals'

authority to refer for preliminary ruling, parties expenditure in rent-seeking and the

total lost treasure in competition law disputes will be higher in comparison to those

under a rule granting arbitral tribunals authority to apply Article 267 TFEU. When

parties become aware of such principle, they may ex-ante exclude competition law

from their contractual arbitration clauses preferring national litigation forums.

The policy implication is quite clear, this is an analytical argument for a reversal in the

ECJ's case-law. We could reformulate Proposition 1 in a more general form saying that

multiple and independent jurisdictions in the decision of a dispute produce an increase in

parties expenditure in a rent-seeking competition and lost treasure in comparison to a

decision reached in front of a single adjudicator.

ConclusionWe applied two of the most fortunate law and economics models on litigation to analyse

the effects of the European Court of Justice's interpretation of Article 267 of the Treaty on

the Functioning of the European Union. When the European Court of Justice denies

arbitral tribunals authority to request a preliminary ruling it also causes adverse effects on

parties incentives to use arbitration proceedings for resolving their competition law

disputes. Consequently it impairs the effectiveness and efficiency of arbitration as a

mechanism of private enforcement of EU competition law. The Priest and Klein's model on

the selection of disputes for litigation helped us to define the participation constraint for

entering into litigation under the described ECJ's case law. However the core of our

analysis calls up the Dari Mattiacci and Parisi's model on the dissipation of value through

rent-seeking to show how parties level of effort is affected by the possible interpretations of

Article 267 TFEU. As expected, the result of this exercise provides a strong argument for

reverting the current interpretation of Article 267 TFEU. In fact holding every other variable

48 Dari-Mattiacci, G., and F. Parisi, ‘Rents, dissipation and lost treasures: Rethinking Tullock’s paradox’ (2005) 124 Public Choice, 411.

22

Page 23: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

constant, under the current ECJ's interpretation of this rule, parties dissipation of value

through rent-seeking will be higher. In conclusion the investigated ECJ's case-law needs

an amendment if we are willing to exploit the full potential that arbitration can offer to the

private enforcement of EU competition law.

References

Artwood, J.R., ' The Arbitration of International Antitrust Disputes: A Status Report and

Suggestions' (1994) 21 Fordham Corporate Law Institute.

Bebchuk, L.A., ‘Litigation and settlement under imperfect information’ (1984) 15 The RAND Journal of Economics, 404.

Bebr, G. ‘Arbitration Tribunals and Article 177 of the EEC Treaty’ (1985) Common Market Law

Review, 489-504;

Benson, B.L., ‘Arbitration’ (1999) Encyclopedia of Law and Econoimcs, 159.

Biavati, P., ‘Pregiudizale comunitaria e arbitrato’ (1995) Rivista dell’arbitrato, 421.

Blanke, G., 'The role of EC competition law in international arbitration: a “plaidoyer”' (2005) 16(1)

European Business Law Review.

Caplan, B., and E.P. Stringham, ‘Privatizing the Adjudication of Disputes’ (2008) 9(2) Theoretical Inquiries in Law, 1.

Dari-Mattiacci, G., and Francesco Parisi, ‘Rents, dissipation and lost treasures: Rethinking Tullock’s paradox’ (2005) 124 Public Choice, 411.

Dempegiotis, S., 'EC Competition Law and International Arbitration in the Light of EC Regulation 1/2003' (2003) 25(3) Journal of International Arbitration.

Derains, Y., 'Public Policy and the Law Applicable to the Dispute in International Arbitration' (1987) ICCA Series No. 3.

Drahozal, C. and Wittrock, Q., 'Is There a flight from Arbitration?' (2008) Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1147697.

Eisenberg, T. and Miller, G., 'The Flight from Arbitration: An Empirical Study of Ex Ante Arbitration Clauses in the Contracts of Publicly Held Companies' (2007) 56 DePaul Law Review, 335.

Fon, Vincy, and Francesco Parisi, ‘Litigation and the evolution of legal remedies: a dynamic model’ (2003) 116 Public Choice, 419.

Gospodinov, Penio Penev, ‘Applicazione in arbitrato del diritto antitrust dell’Unione Europea’

unpublished (Università Commerciale ‘Luigi Bocconi’ Milano 2010).

Kornhauser, Lewis A, ‘Appeal and Supreme Courts’ (1999) Encyclopedia of Law and Econoimcs,

45.

Landes, M, and Richard A Posner, ‘Adjudication as a Private Good’ (1979) 8 Journal of Legal

Studies, 235.

23

Page 24: European Court of Justice vs. Arbitral Tribunals: The Role of …lawandeconomics.pl/wp-content/uploads/2011/05/3PLE… ·  · 2012-04-16Preliminary Ruling When European “Public

Parisi, Francesco, ‘Rent-seeking through litigation: adversarial and inquisitorial systems compared’

(2002) 22 International Review of Law and Economics, 193.

Parisi, Francesco, ‘Seeking Rents in the Shadow of Coase’ (2008) American Law &amp;

Economics Association Annual.

Posner, Richard A, ‘What Do Judges and Justices Maximize? (The Same Thing Everybody Else

Does)’ (1993) 3 Supreme Court Economic Review, 1.

Priest, G.L., and B. Klein, ‘The selection of disputes for litigation’ (1984) 13 The Journal of Legal

Studies, 1.

Radicati di Brozolo, L.G., 'Antitrust: a Paradigm of the Relation Between Mandatory Rules and

Arbitration – A Fresh Look at the “Second Look”' (2004) International Arbitration Law Review.

Shavell, S., ‘Alternative dispute resolution: An economic analysis’ (1995) Journal of Legal Studies, 1.

Tizzano, A., ‘Arbitrato privato e competenza pregiudiziale della Corte comunitaria’ (1983) Rassegna dell’arbitrato, 153.

24