Top Banner
Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and Consumption of Nutrients in India by Amlan Das Gupta A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY in The Faculty of Graduate and Postdoctoral Studies (Economics) THE UNIVERSITY OF BRITISH COLUMBIA (Vancouver) October 2014 © Amlan Das Gupta, 2014
141

Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

Dec 10, 2021

Download

Documents

dariahiddleston
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and

Consumption of Nutrients in India

by

Amlan Das Gupta

A THESIS SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF

THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF

DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

in

The Faculty of Graduate and Postdoctoral Studies

(Economics)

THE UNIVERSITY OF BRITISH COLUMBIA

(Vancouver)

October 2014

© Amlan Das Gupta, 2014

Page 2: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

ii

Abstract

This thesis is motivated by the unique experience of India regarding economic growth and

the corresponding impact on nutritional status. Despite sustained periods of growth,

malnutrition levels in India have shown modest improvement. Moreover, average calorie

consumption in the country is going down even as consumption expenditure and incomes go

up. The objective of this thesis is to shed light on some possible causes of this puzzling

phenomenon. The second chapter is a theoretical exploration of the possibility that

preference for conspicuous consumption could be a factor contributing to this decline in

calorie consumption. This chapter starts by incorporating status seeking preferences in a

dual-economy general equilibrium model and then demonstrates that, in such a setting,

economic growth could lead to a fall in calorie consumption across the income distribution

even with incomes rising at the same time. In Chapter 3 the implications of the main

assumption of "keeping up with the Jones" preferences, from the theoretical model of

Chapter 2, is tested in the data. This assumption implies that household calorie consumption

should decline with peer group income. So the effect of peer group income on calorie

consumption is estimated using World Bank data collected from rural India. Using these

estimates it is roughly estimated that Veblen competition can account for more than a third of

the missing calories. A unique source of variation in peer group income, based on caste-wise

domination across villages, is used for identification. The fourth chapter looks at the impact

of the public food distribution system (PDS) in India, on the household per capita

consumption of calories and proteins. This effect is identified using random shocks

introduced into the delivery system of PDS through the impact of rainfall on agricultural

output in the state which is the largest supplier of grains to the system. The results suggest

that a rise in PDS performance has different effect in different regions in the country. Yet, for

those who benefit from this system, the impact on nutrient consumption and malnutrition is

significant and large.

Page 3: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

iii

Preface

The identification and design of this research program and the performance of the various

parts of the research, and analysis of the research data was done by the author.

Page 4: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

iv

Table of Contents

Abstract ................................................................................................................................................. ii

Preface .................................................................................................................................................. iii

Table of Contents ................................................................................................................................ iv

List of Tables ........................................................................................................................................ v

List of Figures ...................................................................................................................................... vi

Acknowledgement .............................................................................................................................. vii

Dedication .......................................................................................................................................... viii

1. Introduction ...................................................................................................................................... 1

2. Dual-economy Model with Veblen Preferences ............................................................................. 7

3. Empirical Estimation of Veblen Induced Peer Income Effect on Calorie Consumption ....... 37

4. Impact of Public Distribution of Food in India on Consumption of Nutrients. ....................... 68

5. Conclusion ..................................................................................................................................... 108

Bibliography ..................................................................................................................................... 112

Appendix to Chapter 2 ..................................................................................................................... 118

Page 5: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

v

List of Tables

Table 2.1: Simulation, Rise in Industrial Productivity ........................................................... 23

Table 3.1: Summary Statistics ...................................................................................................... 41

Table 3.2: Individual Characteristics by Caste ........................................................................ 42

Table 3.3: Village Characteristics by Caste Dominance of Villages .................................... 51

Table 3.4: Individual Characteristics by Village Dominance ............................................... 52

Table 3.5: OLS Estimates of Peer Income on Calorie Consumption .................................. 54

Table 3.6: OLS Estimates on Sample of Low Castes Only .................................................... 55

Table 3.7: IV First Stage, Village Caste Dominance on Peer Income ................................ 56

Table 3.8: IV Second Stage, Peer Income on Calorie Consumption ................................... 58

Table 3.9: Testing for Sanskritization ........................................................................................ 62

Table 3.10: Second Stage IV Using Non-Food Expenditure .................................................. 63

Table 3.11: Comparison of IV Estimates Using Veblen Calories to Total Calories ........ 64

Table 4.1a: Summary Statistics Main Variables ...................................................................... 82

Table 4.1 b: Summary Statistics (control variables and household characteristics) ...... 84

Table 4.2: OLS Estimates, PDS Uptake on Nutrient Consumption .................................... 87

Table 4.3a: Despatches of PDS Grain from Other States by Zone ...................................... 94

Table 4.3b: PDS Grain Despatches from Donor States .......................................................... 95

Table 4.4: Changes in Key Variables Over Time, North-East Zone ................................... 98

Table 4.5: IV Estimates, Quota-Uptake Difference on Nutrient Consumption .............. 103

Table 4.6: Change in Quota-Uptake Gap and Calorie Consumption Over Time .......... 104

Table A.1: Simulation: Effect of Rising Productivity on Food Demand ......................... 128

Page 6: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

vi

List of Figures

Figure 1.1: Percentage of Underweight Children Less Than 5 Years................................... 2

Figure 2.1: Path of Food Demand as Productivity Grows ..................................................... 21

Figure 2.2: Calorie Engel Curves ................................................................................................ 33

Figure 4.1: Local Polynomial Estimates of PDS Grain as Function of Income ................ 75

Figure 4.2: Relationship Between Income and PDS Grain (Schematic) ........................... 76

Figure 4.3: Histogram of Income, Sample of PDS Users........................................................ 77

Figure 4.4: Demand and Supply Curves for PDS Grains ...................................................... 78

Figure 4.5a: PDS Rice Procurement from Major Supplier States ....................................... 89

Figure4.5b: PDS Wheat Procurement from Major Supplier States ................................... 90

Figure 4.6: Rice Procurement by PDS Zones ........................................................................... 96

Figure A.1: Path of Food Demand as Productivity Grows .................................................. 129

Figure A.2: Path of Food Demand as Productivity Grows (labourers) ............................ 130

Figure A.3: Path of Food Demand as Productivity Grows (landowners) ........................ 130

Page 7: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

vii

Acknowledgement

For his essential guidance and help with this thesis I would like to thank my supervisor Dr.

Mukesh Eswaran and also my supervisory committee members Dr. Patrick Francois and Dr.

Kevin Milligan. I am also grateful for useful comments and suggestions from Dr. Siwan

Anderson, Dr. Kaivan Munshi, and the participants of the empirical workshop at the

University of British Columbia, especially Dr. Thomas Lemieux and Dr. Nisha Malhotra. I

have also benefitted greatly from discussions with my fellow graduate students.

Page 8: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

viii

Dedicated to my Grandparents

Page 9: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

1

Chapter 1: Introduction

In its path towards development, India is perhaps one of the most closely followed countries

in the economics literature. In the past two decades the Indian economy has been growing

rapidly. Now it is often classified along with China as one of the emerging economies with

the potential to rival the economic clout of the western developed nations. However, unlike

China, India is still suffering under the heavy burden of extensive poverty and malnutrition.

Food, primary healthcare and basic sanitation are still out of reach for large sections of the

people. This thesis concentrates on one such basic aspect of development in India, namely,

the nutritional status of the Indian population.

In many ways the Indian experience regarding nutrition has been particularly interesting if

not unique. There are some clear patterns to the trends in nutritional intake in India that

seems to challenge conventional economic logic. One such trend is the very slow decline in

malnutrition in the country despite rapid economic growth. As a result of this, the

malnutrition figures in India are still comparable to the poorest regions of the world (See Fig

1.1) although it is far ahead in terms of both income and other development indicators.1 The

state of nutrition, however, has reached a critical stage where it has ceased to be a

humanitarian problem restricted to the very poor and has started to impinge upon the

economic/productive capacity of the whole country. According to a World Bank report

published in 2005 (Gragnolati et al. 2005) micronutrient deficiencies alone may cost India

US$2.5 billion annually.

1 However Panagariya (2013) has questioned the validity of the reference group used by the WHO on the basis

of which the malnutrition figures are calculated. He argues that the reference group is genetically different from

Indians.

Page 10: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

2

The second stylised fact about nutrition in India is that on an average calorie and protein

consumption is declining in the population. This fact becomes even more surprising when

viewed in conjunction with the first. However this is quite established in the literature now

and is sometimes referred to as the calorie puzzle of India (Patnaik 2007, Deaton and Dreze

2009). Studies have also shown that increasing proportions of the population are slipping

below the standard of calorie2 consumption being used by the government to calculate the

poverty line (Mehta et al. 2000).

.

2 These are 2100 Kilocalories for the urban areas and 2400 Kilocalories for the rural areas.

Page 11: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

3

Latest estimates using the National Sample Survey data show that in 2009-10 even the

average calorie consumption for the whole population was more than 15 percent lower than

these standards.

Another characteristic of calorie consumption in India was pointed out by Deaton and Dreze

(2009) when they showed that calorie Engel curves for India are upward sloping and yet

shifting downwards over time. This means that the fall in calorie consumption alluded to

earlier is happening not only at the average but at every point in the income distribution,

which suggests that the reason behind this phenomenon is not just impoverishment.

Something has happened which is turning tastes and preferences away from food. For a

country like India with the current levels of child malnutrition such trends are an alarming

sign. In fact this threatens to stymie and even reverse the modest rates of decline in

malnutrition achieved till now.3

This thesis aims to address all of the above stylised facts on Indian nutrition by looking at

some of the factors which may have caused these general trends to appear. The next two

chapters exclusively concentrates on the last stylised fact by looking at a hitherto unexplored

reason for the fall in calorie consumption throughout the income distribution. This is the

increased desire for conspicuous consumption driven by competition for status within ones'

peer group. In an environment where rapid economic growth is pushing up incomes there is a

possibility that agents constantly feel pressured to keep pace with the consumption of their

neighbours. If this pressure is strong enough we might see a reduction in consumption of

essentials like food. In order to lend support to this theory two important questions need to be

3 According to the NFHS 3 report percentage of children under 5 years deemed to be wasted has actually gone

up in 2004-5 compared to 1998-99. However in terms of stunting and underweight figures, modest gains have

been observed over the same period.

Page 12: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

4

answered. Firstly, it needs to be ascertained whether such preferences for conspicuous

consumption indeed exists in India, even for the poor. And, secondly, we must examine

whether the negative effect on calorie consumption, which this is liable to generate, is strong

enough to overturn any other factors (for example rising incomes) that may be helping

calorie consumption.

Chapter 2 addresses the second question as described above. It starts by looking at the

implications of "Keeping up with the Jones" (KUJ) preferences on the choice between

conspicuous consumption and non-conspicuous consumption goods (food). These

preferences imply that the marginal utility of conspicuous consumption would now be rising

with the average conspicuous consumption in the agent's peer group. In a partial equilibrium

setting KUJ preferences directly translate into a negative relationship between non-

conspicuous consumption and peer group income of the consumer. As the next step, these

KUJ preferences are incorporated into the demand side of a Dual Economy general

equilibrium model where prices, incomes and peer group incomes are endogenously

determined. In this setting it is shown that productivity driven economic growth could lead to

a fall in calorie consumption even as incomes go up. One caveat here is that the income

effect on food consumption needs to bounded. If this is too high it might overturn the

negative effect of rising peer group income generated by the KUJ preferences. However,

whether the income effect is smaller than the KUJ effect in reality is a question that may only

be answered through empirical investigation.

Chapter 3 is primarily an empirical exercise aimed at answering the two questions that

emerge after the theoretical analysis in Chapter 2. Firstly, do KUJ preferences exist, even

amongst the poor rural population in India? Secondly, even if KUJ exists is it strong enough

Page 13: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

5

to explain the falling calorie consumption? In particular, is the negative effect of peer group

income on calorie consumption, as generated by KUJ, larger than the positive own income

effect? As a first step it is argued that in a rural Indian setting, own caste members living in

the same village are a good approximation for the peer group that such an agent would be

exposed to. Next using a World Bank household and village level survey data the effect of

this peer group's income on household calorie consumption is estimated. Unlike most peer

effects estimation self - selection is not an issue here as caste members are born into their

peer groups as per the rules of the Hindu caste system. However, the small sample size of

this dataset introduces significant classical measurement error into the peer group income

measure. To deal with this problem a unique source of variation in peer group income based

on village level land ownership pattern is used for identification. The estimates indicate that

not only is there a negative and significant effect of peer group income on calorie

consumption, it is in fact almost twice as big as the positive own income effect. Using the

estimates it is roughly estimated that about a third of the missing calories may be accounted

for through this channel.

The relevance of status competition in the determination of choice of food amongst

households, as pointed out in Chapters 2 and 3, is not just of theoretical interest. It also

suggests that any policy intervention whereby income supplements are provided to all

households to boosts their nutrient intake would, in all likelihood, not have the desired effect.

This observation is extremely relevant to the current debate regarding the efficacy of the

Public Distribution System (PDS) of food grains in India. The PDS is the biggest and most

extensive food security program of the Indian government. Its function is to collect all grains

offered up for purchase at the government determined minimum price and then store this

Page 14: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

6

stock for distribution at subsidised prices through its vast network of fair price shop.

However the system has often come under criticism for being highly inefficient as well as

ineffective. One area of strong criticism has been the leakage of PDS grain into the black-

market while being transported or from storage. This is touted as the main reason why most

eligible households are unable to buy their full quota of grains. Many are of the view that the

government should relinquish the responsibility of transporting the grain and just pass on the

intended amount of subsidy to eligible households as cash transfers.

Chapter 4 attempts to contribute to this debate by looking at the impact of PDS grain

consumption on nutrient consumption. The identification strategy relies on the unique nature

of PDS grain consumption which is often restricted by lack of supplies rather than by the

amount of the quota or the lack of demand. This implies that any exogenous shock to PDS

supply while keeping demand constant would directly affect amount of PDS grain consumed.

So random weather shocks in the states that supply the bulk of PDS grain is used as

identifying variation. Interestingly, the estimation results do not provide clear cut evidence in

favor of PDS. However results from the strongest specification suggests that there is a

positive impact on calorie consumption. Back of the envelope calculations based on these

estimates indicate that scrapping the PDS and replacing it with a cash transfer equivalent to

the subsidy would negatively impact calorie consumption by 1-9 percent depending on

assumptions.

Page 15: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

7

Chapter 2: Dual-economy Model with Veblen Preferences

2.1 Introduction

Recently there has been a lot of concern and surprise at the finding that per-capita calorie

consumption in India has been falling in spite of rising incomes over the last couple of

decades or so. This chapter attempts to provide an explanation to this phenomenon on the

basis of Veblen preferences. It starts with a simple dual-economy setting with status seeking

preferences. Later on an income distribution is introduced into the model to highlight the

effects of income inequality on status seeking. The chapter demonstrates the theoretical

possibility of the calorie reduction phenomenon.

As mentioned in Chapter 1 the phenomenon of falling calorie consumption across the income

distribution was demonstrated in the most detailed manner by Deaton and Dreze (2009).

Their paper also explore many possible explanations for this puzzle. They show, for

example, that it is not driven by either food prices or fall in incomes. They also rule out the

possibility that it is driven by a budget squeeze on food due to the introduction of new non-

food essentials to the choice set (like education and sanitation). This theory does not seem

persuasive to them since if it were the case then we would expect people to shift towards

cheaper calorie sources. Instead people are shifting to costlier foods. Two possible

explanations that the authors feel might be having some merit are that either people’s tastes

and preferences have changed, or their calorie requirements have fallen due to the

introduction of machines in all walks of life. The latter explanation was tested in Li and Eli

(2010), where the authors constructed measures of calorie requirements based on activity

Page 16: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

8

levels reported by survey respondents. But although this explained a lot of the changes in

food composition it could not explain the fall in calorie consumption over time. The question

that arises is what other explanation could be plausible?

One such explanation is suggested by Banerjee and Duflo in their book The Poor Economics

(2011). Here it is pointed out that the poor may be misinformed about the nutrient values of

different foods. So they may be spending more on fats and less on cereals without the

knowledge that the total nutrition intake is falling due to this switch. It is very plausible that

when people get richer they would switch to tastier foods, but what is strange is that people

often reduce their overall calorie intake while doing this. This would suggest that there may

be some factor that urges people to shift to costlier, tastier calories more often than is healthy

for them.

One interesting observation is that the fall in average calorie consumption is not particular to

India. This phenomenon has been observed previously in England during the industrial

revolution (1770-1850) and also in China more recently (Clark et al. 1995, Du et al. 2002

and Meng et al. 2009). In all these situations, the economy at the time was experiencing high

growth rates and incomes were going up. This leads one to suspect that rising incomes might

have something to do with lowering demand for food over the entire income distribution.

Another paper by Subramanium and Deaton (1996) offers some interesting insights about

this. This paper attempts to verify empirically the notion that poverty leads to low nutrition,

which in turn causes people to have low productivity and receive lower wages. They find,

using National Sample Survey data from the Indian state of Maharashtra that the required

calories for a poor worker to lead a healthy life can be bought with about 5% of their daily

wages. So they conclude that income is not a constraint on nutrition; rather it is the other way

Page 17: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

9

round. The main reason why the elasticity of food remains very low is due to the substitution

of cheaper calories to more expensive ones. One possible way this could happen is through

higher conspicuous consumption by agents with a status-seeking motive.

In 1899 in his book titled The Theory of the Leisure Class Thorsten Veblen introduced the

idea of conspicuous consumption into economics. Although similar ideas had been voiced by

Adam Smith (1759) before, Veblen was perhaps the first to recognize the role of visible

consumption as a signal of one’s status. Status seeking behaviour is very common amongst

the human race and one of the most important determinants of status is wealth. While it is

difficult to communicate one’s true wealth level by one’s appearance, visible consumption

may provide hints that are easily picked up by others. In some cases people might even be

able to make themselves appear wealthier than they really are.

This status-seeking behaviour has potentially significant consequences for the economy (as

shown in Coelho 1985). In particular when all members of society are experiencing growth

in income, status competition might get intensified so much so that agents would be willing

to reduce food consumption in order to supplement the consumption of status goods. A

similar phenomenon has been noted in outcomes in a general equilibrium framework in the

literature already. Kelly (2005) and Cooper et al. (2001) have used this phenomenon to

motivate economic growth in their models. In these models growth is driven by endogenous

investment in newer varieties of either a normal or a Veblen good.4 Higher income leads a

person to buy more status goods, which in turn causes more investment in them. They show

that in equilibrium all new investment goes into the Veblen sector and results in lowering of

utility with economic growth. Hopkins and Korienko (2004) in a game theoretic model,

4 A Veblen good may be defined as one which provides no utility except as a status enhancement.

Page 18: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

10

investigate the consequences of a change in income distribution in the presence of Veblen

preferences. They show that when the society gets richer almost everybody consumes more

of the Veblen good and utility declines at every income level. While investigating the

relevance of Veblen goods for the well known “Happiness Paradox”,5 Eaton and Eswaran

(2009) conclude that not only is the Veblen hypothesis capable of explaining the paradox,

but it should not be restricted to the developed world only.

Insight from these papers suggests that status seeking preferences have the potential to

generate ex-post utility reducing decisions from agents. But, in order to investigate the

possibility of calorie reduction in India we need to look at the consequences of adding

Veblen preferences to a general equilibrium model of a developing economy. For this

purpose I look at the dual economy model. The concept of dual economy, first introduced by

Arthur Lewis in 1954, is frequently used to model developing economies. This classic model

tells the story of development economies where better technologies in the industrial sector

draws out labour from the agricultural sector, eventually raising incomes in both sectors.

This model naturally introduces heterogeneity in the economy which is a setting where

Veblen competition becomes more potent. Here (section 2.2 below), I present a model based

on Eswaran and Kotwal (1993) dual economy setup. I demonstrate that under certain

conditions Veblen preferences do generate falling food consumption with economic growth

in equilibrium. Then in section 2.3 the same model is presented in a small open economy

setting. Section 2.4 has a slightly more complicated version of the model with the addition of

capital as a factor of production. This model serves to highlight the situation when rising

5 This refers to a finding, mostly in developed countries, that happiness measures do not go up as fast as wealth.

Easterlin (1974, 1995)

Page 19: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

11

income inequality becomes essential for the calorie puzzle. The last section concludes and

discusses the implications of the findings.

2.2 The Basic Model

We start with a description of the preference structure. Suppose that the agent has a choice

between two goods X and Z. Here X is a non-Veblen good which we take as food, and Z is

the Veblen good. Next we make two assumptions which will define the preference structure

for the agents.

Firstly it is assumed that the utility function of the agents are quasilinear in food (X) and the

Veblen good (Z). This kind of preference may be written as follows:

Here lower case denotes quantities of these goods. The function may be any standard

increasing and strictly concave function with

; the next term is a linear

function of the Veblen good Z. This form, although not crucial for the results, helps to

highlight the workings of the Veblen preferences.6 A feature of this utility function is that at

lower levels of consumption of X, marginal utility per dollar spent will be higher than that

from the Veblen good (which does not change). So until an agent’s marginal utility per dollar

from X has fallen to a constant (which is equal to divided by the price of the industrial

good) there will be no consumption of Z. After the marginal utilities per dollar have been

equalised, all extra income will go into consumption of Z. This feature is a very apt

description of preferences in poorer areas where initially agents devote most of their income

to subsistence requirements. Luxury goods and other non-necessary goods are consumed

6 See the appendix for an analysis of the model with the quasilinearity assumption relaxed.

Page 20: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

12

only after the basic needs have been fulfilled. This assumption also implies that Engel curves

for food will not be upward sloping after a certain threshold of income.7

The next assumption is that preferences for the Veblen good Z exhibits "Keeping up with the

Jones" (KUJ) a term coined by Gali (1994) and later formalized further by Dupor and Liu

(2003). Unlike the previous assumption this one is crucial and is the main driver of the

results. According to the formalization of this concept presented in Dupor and Liu (2003),

preferences for Z exhibits KUJ8 if the marginal utility of Z consumption is rising in the

average Z consumption of the agent's peer group .

So we have:

In order to maintain quasilinearity the second derivative of the Veblen function with respect

to the Veblen good Z is assumed to be 0.

Partial Equilibrium

Next I present a simple partial equilibrium result that follows from my assumptions on the

preferences. Assume that food X is the numeraire and the price of the Veblen good Z is p.

7 Flat Engel curves can be achieved, as in Eswaran Kotwal (1990), using hierarchical preferences that are

lexicographic. But quasilinear specification is more tractable as it implies that food demand would respond to

price and in the presence of Veblen preferences also to own income. 8 There is another aspect to preferences involving the Veblen consumption or relative consumption. This is the

differentiation between jealousy and admiration (Dupor and Liu (2003)). For example, if the agent feels jealous

that people in the neighbourhood have fancy cars her utility will be falling with a rise in average consumption

of fancy cars. This would imply that . On the other hand if she admires the higher consumption of fancy

cars in the neighbourhood the preference should have . The results in the present model will go through

with either of these assumptions as long as I have quasi-linearity and KUWJ.

Page 21: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

13

Proposition 1: Consumption of the non-Veblen good (X) falls with the average income of

the group once the agent has started consuming Veblen good (Z), ceteris paribus.

Proof: See Appendix.

The proposition implies that if there are two similar individuals with the same incomes and

facing the same prices, the one living in a richer surrounding will consume less food. This is

a direct implication of “Keeping up with the Jones” aspect of the preferences. When an agent

who has already started consuming both goods moves to a richer peer group, she essentially

move to a group with higher average Z consumption. This drives up her own marginal utility

of Z consumption, prompting her to substitute away from food. This is the feature which

drives the results in this model. This is also the point which is taken to data in subsequent

empirical Chapter 3 and used as a test for the existence of KUJ for the agents in the sample.

General Equilibrium

The partial equilibrium result derived in Proposition 1 above holds own income and prices

constant. But during the period when average calorie consumption in India was falling,

average consumption expenditure and incomes were increasing rapidly (Deaton and Dreze

2009). Since the objective here is to explain the actual occurrences of that period, it is

important to allow for the simultaneous movement of own income and peer group income

(relative food prices were roughly constant) and examine whether calorie consumption can

still fall. This, of course, can be theoretically modeled only in a general equilibrium

framework, which is introduced below.

For the general equilibrium analysis a specific quasi-linear utility function with KUJ is

assumed. It is customary in the literature related to Veblen consumption to model the utility

Page 22: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

14

function as increasing functions of or (see Eaton and Eswaran 2009). In general

the Veblen function is assumed to be strictly concave. But, as discussed above, the particular

context of rural/poor households here makes a quasi-linear specification ideal. With the

removal of the quasi-linear assumption the general equilibrium results presented below are

valid under a different set of conditions. More details are provided in the Appendix.

The specific functional form assumed for an individual i for the sake of tractability is as

given below:

Using these preferences9 it is possible to calculate the demand as a function of price, own

income and group income assuming food X to be the numeraire:

Demand for Z is given by:

9 Note that this specification displays jealousy as long as . Beyond this level of Z consumption we

switch to admiration. But this feature is not relevant for the results.

Page 23: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

15

Supply Side

This section outlines the production system and resources. The population, which is also the

labour force, is normalized to 1, proportion of this population is landless and the rest own

an equal share of the total land. All agents supply labour inelastically. The two goods are

produced according to the following production functions:

Food production requires both land and labour inputs with decreasing returns to labour. Z is

assumed to be an industrial good which only uses labour as input and exhibits constant

returns. Here represents land which is a fixed factor, owned equally by the landlords and

fully used in the production of X. and are the labour allocations to and A and B are the

productivity parameters for the agricultural and industrial sector respectively. This completes

the description of the supply side.

Demand functions have already been calculated, so the last thing is to define the peer group

of the agents. To keep things simple I assume that the peer group g is the same for all agents

and comprises of the entire economy. So now is the average peer

group income used in Veblen comparisons where and are the incomes of the landless

labour group and the landowner group respectively.

The equilibrium of this model is defined by the prices and labour allocation where all

markets clear. But due to the unique nature of preferences assumed, demand for grain is

kinked in income (see expression for food demand in equation 2.1 above). This gives us

Page 24: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

16

three different types of equilibria, and which one obtains depends on the magnitudes of the

productivity parameters for the two sectors. In the first equilibrium both landlords and

landless agents are too poor and cannot afford the Veblen good Z, in the second only the

landlords are rich enough to consume Z, and in the third both types of agents have become

satiated with food and have started consuming Z. In our subsequent analysis we will focus on

the third sort of equilibrium since our objective is to characterize the effect of conspicuous

consumption on food consumption it is essential that agents do consume some Z to bring

them into the analysis.

Effect of Productivity Improvements

Next we conduct some comparative statics exercises in the model by raising the agricultural

and industrial productivity parameters (A and B respectively).

Proposition 2: In an equilibrium in which all agents are satiated with food (X), equilibrium

allocation of labour to the agricultural sector ( will fall with any rise in either agricultural

or industrial productivity (A or B respectively).

Proof: See Appendix.

Intuitively, when agricultural productivity (A) receives a positive shock, incomes rise. So

demand for the industrial Veblen good Z goes up (since agents are assumed to be satiated

with food and devote all further income to the consumption of luxury goods). This draws

labour out of the agricultural sector in order to cater to the increased demand for Z. Similarly,

when industrial productivity (B) goes up it makes the value of the marginal product of labour

in the industrial sector higher than that in the agricultural sector (creating an imbalance). This

Page 25: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

17

also leads to movement of labour out of the agricultural sector into the industrial sector. In

either case, labour is drawn out of the agricultural sector raising the land to labour ratio and

increasing wage rate. This result is similar in spirit to Eswaran-Kotwal’s (1993) results but

there is an extra dimension introduced by the presence of status seeking behaviour. The rise

in income raises average consumption of the Veblen good in the economy. This further

pushes up demand for Z (due to KUJ), leading to magnified effects on the wage rate as

compared to a model without Veblen competition. So Veblen preferences can facilitate a

faster reduction in poverty, however it can have a deleterious effect on food/calorie

consumption as we see below.

A Possible Resolution to the Calorie Puzzle:

The next proposition investigates the possibility of a calorie reduction as documented by

Deaton and Dreze (2009), among others, in Indian data. As mentioned earlier, they have

shown that the Engel curves for calorie consumption have been shifting down over time even

when the relative price of the said good is constant; so calorie reduction has occurred across

nearly all income groups. In order to investigate such a possibility in the present model, two

things need to be ensured. Firstly, the relative price of the industrial good has to be kept

constant, and secondly incomes of both groups need to be rising. According to Deaton and

Dreze (2009) these were the circumstances prevailing in the Indian economy at the time the

calorie reduction was observed (1985 – 2005). In this model we can derive the relative price

of food as a function of parameters and the labor allocation to agricultural sector from the

labour market equilibrium condition (equating marginal products in the two production

sectors) and is given by:

Page 26: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

18

In the equilibrium where everybody is consuming the Veblen good Z, a rise in the

productivity parameters B or A will lower labour allocation to agriculture (Proposition 2).

So it is possible to change A and B in such a way that price remains constant. We have no

way to endogenise the changes in productivity so we will assume here that productivity has

changed keeping the relative price constant. The second point about income is also important

because, as mentioned before, the Deaton and Dreze (2009) paper actually show that calorie

Engel curves are shifting down over time. Although it is not guaranteed in this model that

any productivity shock will raise incomes for all, we can however, show the consequences on

food consumption in the event that all incomes rise.

Proposition 3: In an equilibrium where all are satiated with food, if agricultural and

industrial productivity go up simultaneously keeping relative price of the industrial good

constant, and if landlord’s incomes do not fall, food consumption for both groups fall.

In order to see this, observe the food threshold for both groups after they are satiated with

grain, from the demand for food given in equation 1:

Substituting in the value of using the production function of Z (equation 3) we have:

Page 27: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

19

The shock applied to the system is such that price is constant and B (industrial productivity)

is raised. It has already been shown in Proposition 2 that any rise in productivity will

cause (labor allocation to agriculture) to go down. Thus we see that in the expression for

food demand (above) the numerator remains constant and denominator increases, resulting in

the fall of the overall quantity.

If the relative price of the Veblen good is held constant, the only reason for change in the

food demand is the rise in average consumption of Z. Due to the rise in A and B, total

income in the economy goes up. This means that total Z consumption (in effect ) will go up

as well (since now all extra income goes into Z consumption). This will lead to a fall in the

food demand by way of raising the marginal utility of the consumption of Z. So, while the

income of both groups go up, food consumption falls. In effect, we will observe the falling

Engel curves. (see Figure 2.1)

Discussion

A fall in calorie consumption will not be observed always. Assuming the conditions outlined

in Deaton and Dreze (2009) (constant relative price and rising income) we do see a fall in

food consumption. In the appendix it is shown that the reduction in calories will hold even if

the landlords' income falls in this model. The stipulation that landlord’s income does not fall

is a (strong) sufficient condition, not a necessary condition, for the result in Proposition 3 to

hold.

Amongst the two main assumptions imposed on the preference structure the role of quasi-

linearity is not crucial (the other being KUJ). This assumption implies that income effect is

totally absent in the demand for food, and is essentially an extreme representation of the fact

Page 28: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

20

that food elasticity is found to be quite low for people with sufficient income (see Behrman

and Deolalikar 1987). If on the other hand, a positive (but modest) income elasticity of food

is introduced in the model it would work against the Veblen effect and push up food

consumption when incomes rise. In this case, whether calorie reduction obtains would come

down to which of the two effects are stronger. In the appendix a model with positive income

effect and KUJ has been used to demonstrate that calorie reduction can still obtain.

Whether KUJ preferences actually exist in the Indian populace and whether or not it can

dominate the income effect is an empirical question. This will be the focus of the next

chapter.

Page 29: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

21

Page 30: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

22

2.3 Small Open Economy

In this section I assume that the economy is free to import goods from the world market. I

also assume that the domestic agents take the world price of food as given, in other words it

behaves like a small open economy. A small open economy takes the relative price of

food/industrial good as a constant ( say). Here profit maximisation by producers in the

industrial sector means that they still equate their marginal cost of production i.e. the wage to

the value of the marginal output from 1 unit of labour ( ). This means that wages are now

pegged at . In this setting we have the following result.

Proposition 4: In the small open economy setting, a rise in industrial/agricultural

productivity leads to calorie reduction for both groups when both groups are consuming the

Veblen good.

Proof: Increase in A leads to a rise in to re-equate agricultural wage to . This change

keeps wage constant but raises land rental income for the landlords. As a result landlords

demand more Z. Since domestic production of Z cannot be increased (as workers are drawn

into agriculture) the increased demand for Z is met by importing Z. As a result, average Z

consumption of the economy goes up and food consumption for everybody falls. This creates

some excess of grain which is then exported to pay for the import of Z.

Since determines the wage an increase in B leads to a rise in income of both groups along

with a fall in labour allocation adjusts to equate agricultural wages to the industrial

wages. This should lead to a fall in land income, but for the sake of comparison we assume

that total income rises for the landowners as well. This will in turn lead to a rise in Z

consumption of both groups since they have already been satiated with food. Then, from the

Page 31: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

23

expressions of the food thresholds we know that we will have a fall in the food thresholds.

Below is the expression for the food threshold/demand at constant relative price of food.

One other way to see this is that since productivity has gone up total income of all agents in

the economy will have to go up, this means that average level of Z consumption will also go

up (since all agents are assumed to be satiated with grain already). So now we can read from

the expression for the food threshold above that food consumption will fall. Below is a

simulation result using parameter values . Here

and are food consumption and incomes for the two income groups respectively.

Productivities Incomes Food Consumption Agri. Lab

A B

1 1 1 2.578 0.789 0.789 0.622

1 1.5 1.5 2.861 0.680 0.680 0.463

We can see the calorie reduction result here. A rise in B leads to rise in income of both

groups (although landlords enjoy less proportionate increase due to fall in ).

Table 2.1: Simulation Showing Fall in Food Consumption with Rise in Industrial Productivity.

Notes: Table shows a simulation result of raising Industrial Productivity B from 1 to 1.5 keeping other

parameters constant. Parameter values used are . Here and

are food consumption and incomes for the two income groups respectively.

Page 32: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

24

The small open economy setting is a good approximation for a less-developed economy like

India. India is typically self sufficient in food grain production but imports a lot of industrial

goods. Although the volume of trade is large, India is definitely unable to affect world prices.

So this assumption is quite close to reality.

One distinct advantage here is that we don’t need to worry about keeping the relative price

constant while we change the productivities. The calorie reduction result is strengthened in

this setting. It is particularly interesting that the result holds for growth in agricultural

productivity, which is quite analogous to what we observe from India.

2.4 Capital as a Third Factor of Production

Model with Capital

In this section I am going to present a version of the above model which is more general in

various ways. To begin with I will not be assuming any specific functional form for the

Veblen preference term in the utility function. This form will be analogous to the way

Veblen preferences are modeled in general in the literature (see Eaton and Eswaran 2009).

There are, however, certain restrictions which are discussed below. The other difference is

that I introduce a third factor of production (capital) which is unequally distributed

throughout the population (unlike the other factors) and is used exclusively in industrial good

production. As we shall see the rate of return for capital will be growing more than all the

other factors. As a result of this, rising income inequality with economic growth gets

introduced into the model.

Page 33: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

25

This features of rising inequality with growth in this model is interesting for two reasons.

Firstly, it is generally accepted that income inequality has been on the rise in India (see

Deaton and Dreze 2002). So the prediction of the previous model that income inequality is

going down was not representing reality. Also, since Veblen competition is driven by the

desire to catch-up with the rich, one would expect rising income differences to have

significant effects. Here the new model makes a significant contribution by pointing out that

even if marginal utility from consumption is falling for both goods, in the presence of rising

income inequality and status competition, an income driven rise in own consumption of the

status good could lead to a rise in marginal utility of the status good. This is due to a higher

average consumption of the status good in the peer group where average income has gone up

by more than the individual's. This is the key insight of the capital model.

Also worth pointing out is the fact that in the previous model we could never have observed

rising income inequality with economic growth with certainty. The reason is that land rental

rates may be falling even if we make our regular assumption that all agents have higher

incomes after the productivity growth. So we may still have a lowering of income inequality,

leading to a rise in food consumption. This problem persists even if we assume unequal

distribution of land. Although an unequal distribution of land also introduces a continuous

distribution of income, it still does not ensure rising income inequality.

Lastly, in this section I work with the assumption that an agent’s comparison group consists

of all the agent’s who can be observed to be consuming more of the Veblen good than her.

This is a much more realistic assumption than what I had earlier. In the previous model we

had just two income groups and it was impossible to make even the simplest assumption that

Page 34: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

26

the agent’s compare themselves with their richer peers. The comparison group assumption

turns out to be quite important as it determines the movement of the average Z consumption.

An even better assumption would be that people only compare with a subset of agents

consuming more of the Veblen good (not with agents who are much richer), but in the

context of this model it will only add complications rather than extra insight.

Formally the three new assumptions are as follows:

Assumption 1: An agent’s peer/comparison group consists of all agents earning a higher

income than her.

A disadvantage with this, and in fact with any peer group assumption I make, is that it

presumes that people’s peer groups are essentially determined by their incomes. Although in

reality income is definitely an important determinant of one’s social circle it is never the only

criterion. Occupation, religion, race, caste etc are also important determinants. But in this

model I will abstract from this. Perhaps this abstraction is the reason why I observe certain

aberrations from reality when I look at the Calorie Engel curves predicted by this model.

This feature is discussed in more detail below.

For the next assumption I introduce an index for each agent as i which is continuous between

0 and 1.

Assumption 2: All agents are endowed with a single unit of labour; total land is equally

distributed, but total capital is distributed according to a function

Page 35: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

27

I will not be imposing any further restriction on the distribution of capital. I believe an

unequal distribution of capital assets is quite a reasonable assumption. Typically capital

would be accumulated through savings but here I will abstract from that and assume the total

stock of capital is fixed at . The shape of the distribution function of capital, although

irrelevant for the main results, has important implications for the predicted food Engel

curves. I will elaborate further on this after I characterize the equilibrium. Also the

assumption about equal distribution of land is essentially a simplifying assumption. Having

the landowner class as before introduces many other issue like how much capital land-

owners should have etc. This unduly complicates the model without adding to the basic

insight.

Assumption 3: The utility function is now given as follows:

v

Note that with the new Assumption 1 average Z consumption relevant to an agent is

dependent on the agent. It is now given as follows for person i with i not equal to 1:

With the assumed utility function the demand for food is given as follows:

Page 36: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

28

Observe that the income at which agent starts consuming Z is not the same for all. More is

said about this in the section below about food Engel curves.

This specific preference structure is assumed for the purpose of highlighting the scenario

where rising income inequality becomes essential for the calorie reduction phenomenon. The

main model presented above used quasilinear preferences which assumed away income

effect on food. Hence, income did not play any significant part in those results. Here it is

assumed that the Veblen component of the preferences is concave. Moreover, the influence

of own consumption of Z and peer group's consumption of Z is assumed to be opposite but

equal in magnitude. This feature makes it essential that if demand for X has to fall in any

equilibrium with constant prices, the peer group's consumption of Z has to increase more

than own consumption. In the general equilibrium this condition translates into rising income

inequality. An even more general model is presented in the appendix where the magnitude of

influence of own and peer group's consumption of Z is allowed to be different. In this model

the results simply depends on the relative strengths of own and peer income effects.

Supply Side

There are certain modifications to the supply side as well, but these are standard. The

production functions are now given as:

Next let the factor prices for labour, land and capital be w, v and r respectively. Then we can

write the incomes of each agent as follows:

Page 37: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

29

These expressions can be expressed in terms of the labour allocations alone once we have

worked out the factor prices. So we look at the conditions for profit maximisation in the two

sectors. From the industrial goods sector we have the following:

..... ( 5)

..... ( 6)

Also from the grain producer’s profit maximisation condition we have:

..... ( 7)

..... ( 8)

Since there is perfect mobility of labour between the two sectors only a single wage may

exist. So using the two first order conditions with respect to labour we can obtain an

expression for the price of the industrial good in terms of resource allocations only.

... ( 9)

Demand for grain and the industrial good are as before. Using the expressions for the

incomes of the different classes from above and equations 5) - ( 9) we can express the

demands for grain and industrial goods only in terms of factor allocations. Next we impose

the market clearing conditions for land, labour and capital.

Page 38: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

30

The market clearing conditions that are yet to be taken care of are the grain market and the

market for industrial goods. We can drop one of these by Walras’ Law. The other equation

can be expressed fully in terms of either the labour allocation to grain or industrial goods

sector. Once we solve this equation for the labour allocation we can go back to our equations

5) - ( 9) to calculate all the relevant variables.

Now we can write down the final grain market clearing condition in terms of labour

allocation to the grain sector using the demand for food calculated earlier:

.... ( 10)

Here the food demand is a function of incomes and price of Z which are given by equations

( 5), ( 6), ( 8), and ( 9). Equation 10) can be expressed only in terms of the labour

allocation to agriculture and other parameters. Assuming that equilibrium exists, we can

solve for this key variable which allows us then to compute all other parameters for this

general equilibrium.

Now various equilibria may exist for this model depending on the proportion of population

that has enough income to consume Z. For our purposes the most interesting equilibrium is

the one where all have graduated to become Z consumers. Henceforth I will restrict my

attention to this equilibrium only. The next proposition looks at the comparative statics when

I vary the productivity parameters for this equilibrium.

Page 39: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

31

Proposition 5: In the equilibrium where all are satiated with food, any increase in industrial

or agricultural productivity (represented by the parameters B and A respectively) leads to a

fall in the equilibrium labour allocation to agricultural sector.

Intuition: The intuition for this proposition is completely analogous to that of the

corresponding proposition from the model without capital. Any increase in productivity

raises income. A rise in the incomes of the Z consumers raises the demand for Z and this

draws labour out of the agricultural sector. The effect is enhanced due to the presence of the

Veblen parameter. What is noteworthy is that this result holds exactly as it did in the

previous model even with positive income effect on food. The reason why this follows so

simply is because of the assumptions on the peer group and income distribution. The

construction of the model dictates that any productivity driven economic growth leads to an

increase in the gap between own and peer group's consumption of the Veblen good. This

feature increases marginal utility of Veblen consumption and helps to counter the income

effect on food which might have turned the result by increasing food demand. Proof is in the

appendix.

Construction of the Food Engel Curves

Since the objective of this chapter was to provide an alternative explanation of the findings in

Deaton and Dreze (2009), I will try to compare the slope of the Engel curves that this model

predicts to the one that we find in their paper. They found, quite reasonably, that the Engel

curves for food are positively sloped. This of course includes the effect of Veblen

preferences. It turns out that the slope of the Engel curve in the equilibrium where all agents

have started consuming Z depends on the distribution of capital.

Page 40: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

32

In this variant of the model the food consumption is given by:

When we look at the Engel curves we keep the relative price of industrial good constant. So

the only thing determining the food consumption is the term . Individual agent i's

Engel curve for food rises with income until income hits the mark, given by the above

expression at zero consumption of Z.

This is a positive quantity since we assume that first derivative of the Veblen function is

always positive and finite. After this, food consumption goes up but slower than income

(assuming that is constant). So as shown in figure 2.4 below, an individual’s food Engel

curve begins with a straight stretch coinciding with the 450

line, shown by the black line.

After reaching the curve rises but with slope less than one (shown by the red lines). The

exact shape of this section depends on the function V in Assumption 3.

Also note that since in this model varies by the individual, the food threshold is also

different for different people as shown in the figure by the other red lines. The richest agent

in this model is the agent indexed by i=1. When she graduates to become a Z consumer her

income is given by:

Page 41: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

33

When the agent who is just behind agent 1 graduates, then agent 1 has already done so. So

for this next agent income at which she graduates is lesser than x1d:

This is evident from the fact that V' is falling in its argument. So each agent along the index

line 0 – 1, graduates to a different income level.

Page 42: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

34

If we look at the Engel curve for the population, of course we are going to see a different

picture compared to an individual.10

Different individuals are on different points on their

individualized Engel curves indexed by i. The population Engel curve will be an aggregation

of these in the general equilibrium. This is essentially what the empirical Engel curves in

Deaton and Dreze (2009) represent.

Calorie Puzzle Revisited

Also, in this setting we are again interested in investigating the possibility of a calorie puzzle

occurrence. Now the expression for relative price of food is a bit more complicated (given by

equation (2.9)), yet it is still possible to raise A and B simultaneously in such a way that

relative price remains constant. Although the following proposition mirrors an earlier one,

the demonstration here is under more general conditions.

Proposition 6: In an equilibrium where all are satiated with food, if productivity parameters

both rise keeping the relative price constant, is large enough to ensure that the poorest

person's income is going up, then food consumption falls for all agents

Proof: See Appendix.

10

To obtain this relationship we take the average food consumption of all agents with a particular income and

then plot this against income. Now due to our assumption on the capital distribution income is unique for all

agents with the same index. Here we again consider the situation where everybody has started consuming Z. So

food consumption for agent i is given by the expression for food demand given by:

Clearly, the shape of the Engel curve will be totally determined by how varies with income. Now

because the distribution of capital is assumed to have a positive slope, income is rising with the index of the

agent. So in order to have rising Engel curves, we need to rise with i (because v is concave).

Note that at i = 1 this quantity is equal to 0. But at i = 0 it is:

The above inequality holds as the integral is always higher than . Hence, if the functions are smooth, will be rising over some part of the income distribution. This implies that the Engel curves will be rising for

those ranges.

Page 43: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

35

Intuition: Two of the assumptions we make are important for this proposition. The fact that

agents only compare with those richer than themselves, and the rise of income with the index

of the agents, (induced by the distribution of capital) ensure that the difference between own

and peer group average consumption of Z goes higher (becomes more negative) for all

agents. This is the implication of rising income inequality. Next as the prices are constant,

this raises marginal utility per dollar of consuming Z. As a result food consumption falls.

The predictions of this model with capital are in some ways fundamentally different from

that of the former model. The most significant difference is the importance of rising income

inequality in the capital model. The food demand functions for the two models are given by:

Whereas in the previous model food consumption fell with the average Z consumption, in the

latter model it falls with the difference between own consumption and the average. As a

result of this, we observe reduction in food consumption in the capital model only if

productivity growth leads to a rise in income inequality within the comparison group. So

according to this model if we are observing a downward shift of the calorie Engel curves, we

must be associated with rising income inequality all through the income distribution. We can

achieve this condition theoretically by making a natural assumption that capital assets are

unequally distributed.

2.5 Conclusion

The basic model has a quite few interesting insights to offer on the role of status seeking

behaviour in a simple dual economy. The first is that the effects of rise in productivity are

Page 44: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

36

enhanced in the presence of conspicuous consumption. With everybody having higher

income, Veblen competition is intensified according to our preferences. This leads to higher

incomes and faster growth of the industrial sector. It is this trait of status seeking that others

like Cooper et al. (2001) have used to generate growth. This is also reflected in the finding

that labour allocation to agricultural sector would be much higher in the absence of Veblen

preferences.

The second interesting contribution is to demonstrate the possibility that the calorie–

reduction puzzle documented by Deaton and Dreze (2009) and others may be attributed to

status seeking behaviour. This reduction in calories has been shown to possibly obtain both

in the closed as well as the small open economy version of a model incorporating Veblen

preferences. In fact as we change the assumptions to either include capital or extend it to the

small open economy case the results arise more naturally with fewer and more realistic

assumptions.

Page 45: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

37

Chapter 3: Empirical Estimation of Veblen Induced Peer Income

Effect on Calorie Consumption

In this chapter the partial equilibrium result from Chapter 1 (Proposition 1), which predicts a

negative relationship between peer group income and food consumption in the presence of

KUJ is taken to the data using the Living Standard Measurement Survey collected by the

World Bank. The goal here is to provide evidence for the existence of preferences for

keeping up with the Joneses among rural agricultural communities in India. This exercise is

similar to those in other papers which attempt to measure the effect of peer group income on

economic outcomes e.g. Luttmer (2005) on happiness measures and Charles et al. (2009) on

conspicuous consumption. Of these, the approach followed in this paper is closest to that of

Charles et al. (2009).11

They use the fact that in USA, being non-white is a negative signal

for wealth and the so-called poorer races have to spend more on conspicuous consumption to

make up for this handicap. The authors find that the differences in spending on visible

consumption by race can be explained by the average incomes of the particular race. But,

while the Charles et al. (2009) paper addresses interracial differences in income driving

Veblen consumption, here within caste income distributions and its effect on conspicuous

consumption are examined. Also, rather than highlight the signalling aspect of the Veblen

goods, the setting here is closer to the “keeping up with the Joneses” motivation as regards

the consumption of status goods (see Galli 1994).

11

Khamis et al. (2010) use the same methodology as Charles et al.(2009) with Indian data and find mixed

results.

Page 46: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

38

One paper which measures the impact of peer group income on consumption expenditure for

rural Indian households is Munshi and Rosenzweig (2009). Although in a different context

which pertains to a test of the hypothesis that households enjoy full insurance from caste

based insurance networks, the paper finds a positive relationship between own sub-caste

(jati) consumption and own consumption. In this exercise we are going to concentrate on the

peer income effect on calorie consumption. However, we are going to be using the same peer

group for the individual households as used by the Munshi and Rosenzweig paper, which is

castes and village based.

One important contribution in this empirical exercise is the unique instrument used to tackle

measurement issues with the peer group income variable (also encountered in Munshi

Rosenzweig 2009). In this sample, low caste individuals living in low caste dominated

villages earn higher agricultural income than low castes living in high caste dominated

villages (Anderson 2011). This creates an exogenous variation in own caste income among

the low castes across the two types of villages. On using this instrument, estimates for peer

income effect turn out to be negative and significant. Moreover they are twice the magnitude

of the estimated own income effect (which are positive as expected), which is exactly in line

with the theoretical model.

At this juncture I should point out that due to the limitations of the theoretical model

presented in the previous chapter it is not possible to calculate the exact magnitude of peer

income effect and own income effect that would lead to the calorie reduction phenomenon.

In fact different assumptions on the nature of the Veblen/KUJ part of the preferences could

lead to different conditions being required for calorie reduction. For example, in the model

with capital presented in the previous chapter it is implicitly assumed that own and peer

Page 47: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

39

income effects on food consumption are equal in magnitude but opposite in sign. This

assumption leads to the requirement of rising income inequality for calorie reduction to go

through.12

However in this chapter the attempt will be to estimate the elasticities of own and

peer group income without much reference to income inequality. The results suggest that

own income effect is about half the size of peer income effect. This implies that rising

income inequality may not be required for the possibility of calorie reduction with income

growth. However if income inequality is going up within the peer group it will only magnify

the negative impact on calorie consumption.

3.1 The Data

The data used here is from the World Bank series of Living Standards Measurement Survey

(LSMS) conducted in several countries. This particular data is from the Survey of Living

Conditions conducted for the two Indian states of Uttar Pradesh (U.P) and Bihar. Here

between December 1997 and March 1998, 1035 households were surveyed in Bihar from 57

villages in 13 different districts, and another 1215 households were surveyed in U.P from 63

villages in 12 districts. The survey is restricted to rural households and most households

derive livelihood from agriculture. It provides fairly detailed information about

demographics, member’s characteristics, consumption, access to facilities, means of

livelihood and also information about the environment in which the household is situated

(village level characteristics). Although similar datasets like Indian Human Development

Survey or the Rural Economic Development Survey also contain village level information,

12

In fact rising income inequality would be a requirement for calorie reduction whenever own income effect is

assumed to be equal or greater than peer income effect.

Page 48: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

40

LSMS is the only dataset where the variation in village level land-ownership patterns may be

used to identify my main coefficient of interest.

The main variables of interest for this exercise are income, caste, price of food and total

calorie consumption. The caste of each household is known. The income of the household is

generated (following Anderson 2011) by adding total wage income of all household

members, income from enterprise, total proceeds from crop sales, transfers and the total

value of home production of in-kind receipts of crops and foods. The calorie consumption

variable is constructed by using the household consumption of different food items and

multiplying them with estimates of calorie content from Gopalan et al. (1974).13

Food items

used are rice, wheat, barley, maize, bajra (course millet), pulses, sugar, gur (jaggery), eggs,

meat/fish, milk, milk-products, potatoes, edible oil and vanaspati (a form of oil). It should be

mentioned that certain assumptions had to be made while constructing variables. Firstly, the

quantities of rice, pulses etc are multiplied by average amount of calorie content for all types

of rice and pulses. This is because the data does not provide information about the exact type

of these foods. Also, these calorie estimates are constructed from data about food

purchased/produced by the households and it does not imply that it coincides with calorie

consumption. In particular, household members could have taken meals outside their house

or other guests could have had meals in the household, but there is no information about this

13

There have been updated versions of Gopalan (1974). I preferred to use the version closest to Deaton and

Dreze (2009) so as to make my variables as consistent with theirs as possible. However there does not seem to

be much difference in the two versions particularly in the context of this dataset which only lists broad

categories of food items like rice or pulses. In contrast NSS datasets list much more detailed classification of

food items consumed.

Page 49: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

41

in the data.14

The price of food is calculated by averaging the prices of all food items used for

the calorie consumption, with weights proportional to their share in the food expenditure.

Table 3.1 below provides summary statistics for some of the primary variables of interest.

14

Although I can see the monetary value of meals consumed outside from the data, there is no reliable method

of calculating the nutritive value of these meals. In the main specification I control for expenditure on outside

meals, but they do not appear to have any significant effect on calorie consumption.

Page 50: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

42

The large standard deviation in the average per-capita calorie consumption of the household

perhaps reflects the difference in household member’s characteristics.

Patterns of occupations, degree of mechanisation in one’s job, availability of public goods

are other factors that may contribute to differences in calorie consumption (using the

arguments of Deaton and Dreze (2009) and Li and Eli (2010) about calorie requirements).

Page 51: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

43

So controls for occupation, crop type choices, factors determining strenuousness of everyday

life (like distance to water source) etc will be used in the main regressions.

Table 3.2 above, is the breakup of the sample according to occupation (proportions). Note

that this is just the primary means of livelihood as reported by agents. Most of the agents

have their own farms. The next biggest chunk are the casual labourers who work for daily

wages in other people's farms. Some are also permanent (having long term contracts with

employers) agricultural workers. Salaried workers and traders (shop owners) are other

sizeable proportions. This information along with that on hours worked will be important as

we attempt to control for calorie requirement of the agents. The break down in Table 3.2

suggests that the sample is essentially rural and agricultural.

Apart from income generating activity, people may also be engaged in other, strenuous day

to day activities. For example, fetching drinking water from far away is one such activity.

Also the type of crop being cultivated, fertility of the land owned, amount of irrigation

available and degree of mechanization of the different farm processes may also be important

determinants of calorie requirement. Table 3.2 gives an idea of the information available

about these factors. From the statistics it seems that we should not be too concerned about

these factors. Most people fetch water from relatively close quarters. Also, the average

quality of land is the dominant reported soil type. Nevertheless, I will be controlling for them

in my regressions.

Page 52: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

44

3.2 Empirical Strategy

The primary objective of this study is to investigate the relationship between calorie

consumption and the average income of the agent’s social group after controlling for own

income, price of food and other factors affecting calorie requirement. The first step of this

analysis is the identification of an appropriate peer group for the agents. Here, the relevant

reference group for an agent is assumed to consists of her own caste people living in her own

village. This assumption also implies that economic outcomes of other castes are either

unobservable or do not matter to agents while they make their own consumption decisions.

In terms of the model presented before we are essentially assuming that the entire population

for an agent is her own caste members living in her own village. While choosing the

reference group we need to ensure that the agents interact sufficiently within this group and

have the opportunity to observe each other’s consumption patterns. For our purposes the

assumption of own caste people seems to be the best way to proceed. Firstly, it is a

documented fact that in rural India caste based social interaction is very important. For

example, the information passed through these social interactions is good enough to sustain

informal credit networks within castes (Munshi and Rosenzweig 2005, 2006). The

arrangement provides added insurance to rural agents against unforeseen shocks like illness

or marriages. As such they are highly valued by the members. Information networks within

castes and sub-castes (jatis) are strengthened by strict rules forbidding members to marry

outside the caste. These strong caste networks have also been cited as the main reason why

spatial migration is extremely low in India (Munshi Rosenzwieg 2005). Anderson (2011)

conjectures that inter-village migration is rarely seen in India probably because the caste

based networks are not known to extend beyond the village boundaries.

Page 53: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

45

Another piece of evidence on the importance of caste networks is manifested in politics.

Especially in the states of UP and Bihar (on which this analysis is based) caste based political

parties are very strong. There is evidence that people will tolerate a lower quality politician

in office as long as she belongs to the party that represents one’s caste (Banerjee and Pande

2007).

Given the strong interaction within the community for people born into the same caste, it

seems natural to assume that own caste members will be a good representation of an agent’s

reference group.15

Here I will restrict attention to own caste members from the same village

because presumably these people will be most visible to the agent and the people they meet

and socialize with. Also, it is often seen that when people compare themselves they tend to

do so with people they think are similar to themselves. For example a poor farmer would be

less affected with the information that a millionaire has bought a private jet than if told that

her fellow farmer in the village has just bought a new television set.

So now we can write out the basic regression as follows:

..... (3.1)

Here is log per-capita calorie consumption of the household i in a typical month, is log

of household income per-capita, is the log average income per-capita of the people of the

same caste as household i living in the same village excluding household i, is log of food

price facing the agent, X is a set of individual or village level controls and e is a random error

term which will be clustered at the village level.

15

The assumption is contrary in spirit to the widely documented phenomenon of Sanskritization (Srinivasan

1952) where the lower castes emulate behaviour of the upper castes. But this is an effect which should be

particular to castes and hence should be taken into account by including caste fixed effects. Also I show later

that most other caste incomes do not affect an agent’s consumption decision.

Page 54: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

46

3.3 Measurement Error and Instrument

A possible problem with the specification presented above is that average caste income and

calorie consumption may be endogenously determined.16

We have very little idea about what

determines the incomes of the agents in our dataset. There could be many unobserved

characteristics of either the household or the village that systematically affects both calorie

consumption and caste income. These things will have to be varying by caste and village. For

example, if people belonging to a certain caste enjoy both higher incomes as well as a less

labour intensive life due to their being physically better suited to live in a particular area. Or

certain caste members who are rich might own facilities (for example water or cattle) in their

villages that help them survive on lesser calorie intake. Although I try to control for as many

village characteristics as possible, one can never be sure that all possible sources of

endogeneity have been accounted for.

Another more important problem is the presence of classical measurement error in the main

variable of interest; average income of own caste in the village. This variable is not measured

precisely since sometimes there are very few observations of each caste from each village (2-

3 or even less). Amongst the three lower caste groups in the sample, the Backward

Agricultural castes have 3 or less households sampled in 18 villages, Backward Other Castes

has 3 or less sampled in 31 villages and the SC/ST caste group has 3 or less sampled in 22

villages out of a total sample of 72.17

Also in reality caste networks are organised at the sub-

caste level (also known as jatis see Munshi Rosenzwieg 2005), however there is no

information about sub-castes in this data. So the average caste income that is calculated may

16

A Durban Wu Hausmann test of exogeneity of average caste income with the basic specification yields a p

value of 0.0002 indicating that OLS is not consistent. 17

The villages where just 1 household of a particular caste is sample, are dropped since the caste income cannot

be calculated for such cases.

Page 55: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

47

be deviating from its true value quite significantly. However, there is no reason to expect any

correlation between the measurement error and the observed value.18

As such we may take

this to be a case of classical measurement error. This error will likely produce attenuation

bias in the coefficients making them lower in magnitude. The best strategy here would be to

instrument the average caste income variable. It turns out that there exists a candidate

instrumental variable which serves my purpose.

In a recent paper Anderson (2011) uses the same dataset to show that low caste people living

in high caste dominated villages have significantly less income than similar low caste people

living in low caste dominated villages, where dominance is determined by which caste owns

the majority of the land in the village. She goes on to show that this difference is largely

attributable to the fact that, in high caste dominated villages, high caste villagers own the

water sources and do not sell water to the low caste people. This breakdown in water trading

networks reduces the agricultural income of the low castes.

One implication of the finding of Anderson (2011) is that for a low caste agent living in a

low caste dominated village her entire peer/social group will have higher income than a

similar counterpart living in a high caste dominated village. The strategy in this chapter will

be to use this variation in the peer group’s income to identify the Veblen effect on calorie

consumption. As an instrument for average caste income in the village a dummy for village

dominated by the low castes is used. This instrument solves the measurement error problem

in two ways. First, it introduces an exogenous variation to the true value of peer group

income which is uncorrelated with the measurement error and secondly this variation affects

all low caste agents so sub-caste level average incomes are also affected. Using this IV a two

18

The measurement error is not due to any systematic sampling anomaly, rather it is a result of lower sample

size which simply increases the noise in the observed variable.

Page 56: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

48

stage least squares estimation procedure is carried out, where in the first stage the following

equation is run on a sample restricted to low caste people:

The equation contains which takes the value one if the responder belongs to a low caste

dominated village. In the second stage the estimated values of from this equation is used

in the original equation (equation 3.1) to estimate the parameter of interest. Here also the

sample is restricted to low castes only.

In order for to be a good instrument it is important that this dummy indicating the

agent’s village dominance does not affect calorie consumption on its own except through its

effect on peer group income.19

The first concern is that the breakdown in water trade in the high caste dominated villages

(the main reason of the variation according to Anderson 2011), by itself may be affecting

calorie consumption. The results could be biased if people with lower access to water (as

should be the case in high caste dominated villages) have to expend a lot of energy trying to

irrigate their crops by digging or carrying water. To control for this, variables indicating

nearness to water sources like rivers and canals, availability of groundwater and public

groundwater projects are included in all the specifications.

A second issue is the presence of unobservables that may vary by caste dominance across

villages (for example public goods, resources etc.). As a response to this concern, this paper

follows Anderson (2011) in arguing that the variation in caste dominance across villages is

19

Of course the dummy will also have an effect on own income but that will be controlled for.

Page 57: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

49

largely exogenous to any present economic outcomes. The first step in this is to argue that

caste dominance is exogenously determined. The pattern of settlement in this area is

determined by migration patterns from over a thousand years ago. Later, just before

independence in 1947 land ownership tended to be concentrated in the hands of the upper

caste. So there was prevalence of absentee landlordism, that is, the landlord might be living

in some other village altogether (Metcalf 1979). After independence the government

undertook a land reform drive to redistribute land to the landless tenants. This resulted in

ownership of land passing on to some low caste tenants (Neale 1962). From then on land

ownership rights have been passed down by older generations by way of inheritance. Formal

selling of land is very rare. It has been observed that only 1% of land is sold each year (Dreze

et al. 1999). So land ownership in a particular village is exogenously determined by the

settlement patterns and the land reform drive.

The second step in the argument is to show that the two kinds of villages are very similar on

most observable characteristics. This is an extremely important observation in this context

since village fixed effects are not being used; it is thus quite comforting to know that the

villages are similar at least on the caste dominance line (see Table 3.3 below).20

Table 3.3

compares some village level variables and Table 3.4 looks at household characteristics across

the two types of villages. As far as village characteristics are concerned the equivalence of

means cannot be rejected for any of the variables. This suggests that the villages of the two

types are similar in most ways. Regarding the household level characteristics there are some

that are significantly different like literacy, but these variables can be controlled for in my

20 Table 3.3 and 3.4 are replications of Tables 1 and 2 in Anderson (2011), but they are equally relevant here. I

have of course added and subtracted some variables according to the requirements in the present context.

Page 58: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

50

regressions. Also the comparison of calorie consumption and mean caste income gives us

some indication about the result we might expect later.

The last concern regarding the IV is the possibility of caste based migration across villages

or inter-caste mobility. But the latter concern can be dismissed altogether because of the

strict rules of the Hindu caste system in India. Though sociologists have documented a

phenomenon “Sanskritization” where lower castes try to graduate into a higher caste by

trying to emulate the ways and practices of the upper caste, this process is not the same thing

as caste mobility. See Srinivas (1952). Also to be noted is that if Sanskritization has been

going on it will only make my results weaker. Since there is a complete absence of high caste

people from the low caste dominated villages the residents of low caste dominated villages

have less opportunity to emulate high castes and so should be consuming more calories.

Permanent inter-village migration is also very minimal in India (Munshi and Rosenzweig

2005, 2006). The main reason for this is believed to be the caste based consumption

smoothing/insurance networks that are not known to extend beyond the village.

Also to test the validity of the instrument intuitively I follow Murray's (2006) suggestion and

include the low caste dominated dummy in a reduced form regression of the second stage.

The coefficient of the dummy is negative and significant in all the specifications (not

reported here).

Page 59: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

51

Page 60: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

52

Page 61: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

53

3.4 Results

This section begins with the basic OLS results of equation 5 as presented in Table 3.5 and

Table 3.6 (below). The coefficient on the average income of the household's caste from that

village is very small, mostly insignificant and always negative (except for one specification).

The basic regression includes controls for state, caste fixed effects, total number of hours

worked by the members of the household, number of women and children in the household

and average age in the household. Technically it is also possible to include village fixed

effects in this regression but since there are about 120 villages and about 2000 households

there is not enough data to precisely estimate all these parameters. Subsequent specifications

introduce dummies for each of the 25 districts21

(in column 2), occupation controls (column

3), and dummies to indicate whether the household is engaged in the cultivation of cereals,

cash crops, oilseeds or bulbous roots (column 4). The rationale for inclusion of these controls

is to either take care of any spatial characteristics of the location of the agent (for example

people in hilly areas may have less calories than others living in plains) and remove the

effects of some special occupation or crop cultivation that requires more effort than others

(for example paddy cultivation is supposed to be a back breaking work). The fifth and sixth

specifications (column 5 and 6) includes controls for distance to nearest water source,

quality of land owned, percentage of land owned irrigated, and also distance to basic

facilities like public distribution shops, hospitals/medical centers and schools. Also, some

parts of calorie consumption may also be motivated by Veblen competition. For e.g. more

expensive foods like meat and milk products may carry a status value in itself. Introducing

21

Each state in India is divided into a number of districts. 13 districts from the state of Bihar and 12 from Uttar

Pradesh are included in this survey. Public good distribution is largely administered by the district level

bureaucracy in India.

Page 62: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

54

controls for demographics and occupations of households helps control for different

perceptions among households about what constitutes Veblen goods and Veblen bads.

Amongst the controls added own income has a positive and significant coefficient, as

expected. Some other controls not reported are also interesting. For example, average age in

Page 63: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

55

the household and average age squared are both significant. Coefficient of average age is

positive and age-squared is negative indicating a concave relationship between calorie

consumption and average age in the household. Caste dummies for the two lowest castes are

also significant and both have a positive sign. Amongst the controls for occupation and crop

cultivation the only significant ones are interest income (negative effect) and pulses

cultivation (negative effect).

Page 64: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

56

In Table 3.6 the same regressions using log calorie consumption and log incomes are

reported using a sample of low castes only (castes included are backward agricultural,

schedule castes and schedule tribes). This is done in order that we may be able to compare

the OLS and the IV results which is also run on a sample of just the low-castes. Here the

coefficient of interest (average own caste income) is negative and the base specification (one

without any controls except age and hours worked) is also significant. But all coefficients are

small in magnitude and much lower than those of own income which are always significant.

Next, the main IV results are presented, the first stage (Table 3.7) followed by the second

stage (Table 3.8). The basic specification (column 1) has own income, literacy, state and

Page 65: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

57

caste controls, and also controls for availability of water and average age of household

member. In the next 5 regressions I add the controls analogous to those added in the OLS

specifications earlier. The last one is a regression on a restricted sample of people working

on their own farms and uses controls for degrees of mechanization like use of tractors etc.

The purpose of this is again to address the calorie requirement issue. This is a two stage least

square estimation. Recall from equation (3.2) that the first stage equation is as follows:

is again log average caste income of the village where agent i lives.

Significance of the coefficient of the dominance dummy ( ) indicates the validity of the

instrument in terms of being a determinant of the variable average caste income. As we can

see that the F statistic for most of the columns are very high. The F values are way higher

than the rule of thumb value of 10 indicating the joint significance of the first stage equation.

Next in the second stage the estimated values of log average caste income according to

the above specification are used to instrument for it in our main equation. Here the dependent

variable is per-capita calorie consumption. Equation (3.1) is given below for reminder.

The calorie measurements are per-capita calorie intake per month measured in kilocalories.

As can be seen from Table 3.8 below, the main coefficient of interest (that of own caste

average income) is negative in all specification and significant for all except the basic one

(without any controls). The result without controls is somewhat expected as the uncontrolled

regression cannot account for idiosyncratic variations in calorie requirement, tastes and

preferences or availability of helpful public resources.

Page 66: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

58

The results (refer to Table 3.8 Column 7, specification with all controls) indicate that a 1 %

change in average income of the agent’s caste results in a 0.22 % fall in the per-capita

monthly calorie consumption. In order to get some idea about meaning/significance of this

magnitude we first note that mean low caste income per-capita in high caste dominated

villages is Rs. 665.53 on average. The same statistic for low caste dominated villages is Rs.

1141.17. So we can say that living in a low caste dominated village implies that the person

has a comparison group which on an average is richer by Rs. 475 per-capita annually. This

sort of a differential in income of the comparison group leads to a fall in daily calorie

consumption per-capita of about 15.7%. These magnitudes are much higher than the

Page 67: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

59

magnitudes we obtain through the OLS estimation. This disparity may be due to the

attenuation bias from the measurement error in peer group income.

The next question is how effective are these numbers in explaining the calorie reduction

documented in Deaton and Dreze (2009). In order to get an idea about this a couple of rough

calculations will be useful. Now according to Deaton et al. (2009) rural per-capita household

expenditure went up from 251.3 in 1983 (38th

round of NSS) to 318.3 in 2004-5 (61st round

of NSS) in real terms. Assume that the average income of the comparison group goes up by

exactly the same amount as per-capita household expenditure. Then, using the estimates in

this chapter, the fall in mean per-capita calorie consumption due to rise in peer income alone

is about 5.8 %. Actual findings from the Deaton et al. (2009) paper puts the fall in calorie

consumption during this period to about 9%. Next if we take into account the effect of own

income (which increases calorie consumption) the figure above has to be revised down to

3.2%. But, even this is more than a third of the actual fall as calculated by Deaton and Dreze

(2009). So the estimates explain a significant portion of the calorie puzzle.

More importantly, in the context of the theoretical model presented in the previous chapter,

these results demonstrate that own income has about half the influence that peer group

income has on calorie consumption. Although we cannot conclude from this evidence that

the observed calorie reduction is necessarily through the Veblen channel, it seems very

probable.

Page 68: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

60

3.5 Robustness

1.Influence of High Castes: Sanskritization?

The first robustness check is designed to test the assumption made earlier about the

irrelevance of other group incomes to the calorie consumption decision. The most relevant

test for this would be to include the other castes’ incomes in the basic regression. The main

argument against the assumption made earlier is the concept of "Sankritization" as first

pointed out in Srinivas (1952). This is the notion that lower castes are continuously trying to

emulate the behaviour of the upper castes with the view to climbing up the social status

ladder. Since higher castes are richer and they consume fewer calories on an average, the

existence of Sanskritzation would imply that agents living in high caste dominated areas will

be consuming lower calories, thus reducing their calorie consumption differential with their

companions in low caste dominated regions. (Note that there are no high castes in the low

caste dominated villages, so no such mechanism could be working there.) In other words, if

this mechanism is working the previous analysis underestimates the Veblen effect.

In order to test this, high caste average income is included as a regressor into the basic

regressions presented in Table 3.6. Of course the specification suffers from the whole gamut

of problems that were initially present (mainly the measurement error issue). Another

problem with this is the very few numbers of observations due to the complete absence of the

high caste agents from low caste dominated villages. Also, for the very same reason, it is not

possible to include high caste average income in the IV regressions since all the low caste

dominated agents will have a missing value totally eliminating the variation.

Page 69: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

61

The results are reported in Table 3.9. Inclusion of the high caste’s average income does not

change the result much. In fact the coefficient on the high caste income variable is

insignificant lending further credence to the assumption made earlier.

2. Non-food Expenditure

Although we have seen that food consumption falls with rise in peer group income we still

have no idea where the saving from this lower consumption goes. The next set of regressions

is designed to investigate where the money generated from lowering calorie consumption is

being used. Data is available for some durables and some non-food items (although many of

the non-food items may be classified as essentials). The IV estimation done in tables 3.7 and

3.8 is repeated here with a series of expenditures on non-food items as the dependent

variable. In each regression all the controls used in table 3.8 are also included.

The results are reported in Table 3.10. All coefficients except the one on children’s clothing

turn out to be insignificant. Thus not much can be deduced about where the money is going

from the lower food consumption. Yet the coefficient on children’s clothing is perfectly

consistent with our story.

Page 70: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

62

Page 71: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

63

Page 72: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

64

3. Calories from Veblen Foods

Agents derive calories from all kinds of food items. Some of these might be Veblen goods

themselves. For example for many societies meat or dairy products are considered to be elite

foods associated with a higher status or wealth. This sub-section focuses on certain food

items which may be viewed by agents as high status items. Here, the IV regression is run

with the same specification as before but calories derived from more elite/fashionable foods

such as milk, meat, eggs, sugar etc as dependent variable.

Page 73: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

65

The coefficient for own caste income (reported in Table 3.11 column 2) are significant and

positive except in column 7 where all controls are included. This suggests that for foods

which may be perceived as status goods by the agents the effect goes the other way round.

One of course, would have expected all the coefficients here to be positive and significant,

but there is some confounding in this data since our choice of food items as Veblen or non-

Veblen is likely to be quite arbitrary. A proper analysis of what is considered richer food can

only be done with more fine data like for example what Charles et al. (2009) have done with

a survey specially designed for the purpose of identifying Veblen goods from non-Veblen

ones. Another interesting feature here is that the coefficient for Veblen food prices is positive

and significant in all specifications whereas the coefficient for own income is negative

(although insignificant in some specifications). Since positive price effect is usually

associated with conspicuous consumption goods, this evidence suggests that the choice of

food items is perhaps not grossly incorrect.

3.6 Conclusion and Discussion of Alternate Explanations

The objective of the paper was to demonstrate that the decrease in calorie consumption in

India during the period 1985-2005 may have been due to (to some extent at least) the

manifestations of status competition. The paper contributes towards this in two parts. First in

the theoretical part (Chapter 2) it was shown that in the general equilibrium of a standard

dual-economy model with Veblen preferences (as represented by "Keeping up with the

Jones" specification), it is possible for food consumption to decrease with economic growth

under certain conditions. It turns out that the elasticity of food demand with respect to own

Page 74: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

66

income is required to be modest in comparison to the Veblen effect in order for us to see

calorie reduction with income growth.

In the empirical part, the main contribution of this paper is to demonstrate a robust negative

relationship between peer group’s income and own calorie consumption. What is more, the

magnitude of the coefficients of peer group income are much larger than those of own

income. The take away message is that peer group’s behaviour does have some effect on the

behaviour of an individual. This is consistent with the conditions generated in the Chapter 2,

although it is not totally conclusive.

An alternate interpretation of this result is that people derive information about how to spend

their money by observing the behaviour of their peer group. Although this explanation

cannot be ruled out, it is possible to claim that this is also consistent with the Veblen theory

as long as agents only look at richer neighbours while deciding what to consume. The strong

relationship with higher income may perhaps be indicative of this.

It is also worth mentioning that people can be getting status signals from various overlapping

peer groups. For example people may be moving in two different groups and they may be

rising in the income hierarchy in one and falling in the other at the same time. This makes

measurement and quantification of the Veblen effect very complicated. Here the attempt has

been to isolate and identify the Veblen effect from one particular peer group while

controlling as best as we can the influence of other groups. The objective was to establish the

existence of the effect and also to have some idea about its magnitude.

As far as the calorie puzzle in India is concerned, findings of this paper suggests that status

competition can be a significant factor contributing to it. Incomes have been rising across

Page 75: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

67

almost all levels of the income distribution in the last couple of decades. This fact, when

coupled with my finding that a rise in income of the peer group leads to a fall in the calorie

consumption of agents, leads to predictions very similar to the falling Engel curves as

described in Deaton and Dreze (2009). Using the estimated rise in consumption over 1984 to

2004 by Deaton et al. (2009) we see that these estimates can explain a significant part of the

missing calories (roughly one third). However, evidence presented here is from a small

sample of rural Hindu low caste households from just two states in India. The chapter does

not claim to have identified the peer income effect for the whole of India. Also, the relevance

of this evidence for the calorie puzzle is largely suggestive in nature. However, in the limited

scope of this study I find no evidence that might suggest anything that runs contrary to the

theory presented in Chapter 2.

If the evidence presented here is to be believed, these findings also have some policy

implications. Firstly, it suggests that policy makers should account for the fact that just

aiming to increase incomes (like paying out cash transfers) for all may not help to achieve

goals like improving nutritional intake. In my estimates, the coefficient on own income is

positive but almost half of that of the peer group income. So calorie intake would not rise as

long as the agent does not perceive own income to be going up much more than her peer

group’s income. On the other hand, information dissemination drives that try to sell food

consumption as an important household goal (and may be fashionable goal) might help

temper the perception that nutrition comes second to taste or status.

Page 76: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

68

Chapter 4: Impact of Public Distribution of Food in India on

Consumption of Nutrients.

4.1.Introduction

In the last two decades the Indian economy has experienced a sustained period of high

growth.22

Yet, this economic success has had very limited impact on the incidence of

malnutrition in the country. India's child malnutrition levels have been and are still

comparable to those in the poorest regions of the world (Gragnolati et al. 2005). Even more

alarming is the fact that increasing fractions of the population are slipping below the

recommended calorie consumption standards23

of the government even as their incomes and

consumption expenditures are going up (Deaton and Dreze 2009). In the light of this

situation, food security has to be one of the biggest concerns for policy-makers.

One recent step taken by the government in this direction is the Food Security Bill 2013.

This bill enhances the coverage of the public distribution of subsidised food (PDS) from

about 30% of the population to 70%. The move is the latest in a series of government efforts

designed to either streamline, re-focus or improve the efficiency of this gigantic public

program. From its humble origin as a largely urban based food rationing scheme under

British rule, the PDS has now grown into the biggest food security program of the Indian

Government, both in terms of its scale,24

and in terms of the investments involved.25

The

22

Indian GDP has been growing on an average at more than 5% per annum since the late 1980s. 23

These standards are 2100 Kilocalories for the urban areas and 2400 Kilocalories for rural areas per person per

day. 24

With more than four hundred and fifty thousand fair price grain outlets spread all over the country.

Page 77: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

69

important question that is yet to be answered is whether the impact of this program on food

security and malnutrition in the country is significant and in proportion to its size and

expense. Also, is it possible to achieve the same impact using some other smaller, less

complicated mechanism? Some of these questions relevant to the PDS debate will be the

focus of the present paper.

By most accounts the PDS program is quite popular amongst its beneficiaries.26

Yet it has

been severely criticised for its inefficiency and ineffectiveness by both internal evaluations as

well as external agencies like the World Bank and the FAO. For example, it has been pointed

out that for every rupee of subsidy passing on to the targeted beneficiary the central

government has to spend Rs 4.27. Also it was estimated that in the absence of PDS poverty

in the whole country would have gone up by just 2 percent points, highlighting the

ineffectiveness of the PDS in impacting either poverty or food security in proportion to its

cost. (Radhakrishna et al. 1997).

Besides ineffectiveness the PDS also suffers from gross inefficiencies mainly due to

corruption leading to the leakage of grains into the black market (Jha and Ramaswami 2010).

Khera (2011a) estimates that in 2007-08 37.2 percent of the rice and 57.7 percent of the

wheat issued to the states for distribution from the central pool, were lost due to diversion.

These diversions are generally believed to be the reason why eligible households only

consume about 50 percent of their allotted quota (Svedberg 2012, Khera 2011 a, b). Due to

such alarming losses many are of the view that the distribution mechanism should be

replaced by cash transfers by the amount of the subsidy (Kapur et al. 2008, Kotwal et al.

25

The subsidy cost to the Central Government was 5.2% of its total expenditure in the 10th Plan period 2002-

07. (Source Planning Commission of India) 26

People usually travel the long distances to the PDS shops repeatedly in the hope of getting their share of

allocated grain although they are frustrated very often. Khera (2011a)

Page 78: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

70

2011, Svedberg 2012). Others argue that the elasticity of income transfers and the effect

of PDS quotas are not equivalent due to the possibility of transferred cash being spent

on non-food items (Dreze 2010, Khera 2011b, Himanshu 2011, Cherian 2013). Besides, the

whole system of procurement and distribution also achieves other state goals like price

stability and famine prevention. Nevertheless, everyone would agree that the PDS needs to

improve its delivery mechanism27

and improve its targeting to better serve the needs of the

poor.

This chapter will attempt to contribute to this debate by answering the fundamental question

regarding the relevance of the PDS in terms of raising calorie and protein consumption in the

population. In simple terms: What would be the impact of an improvement in the supply of

PDS grain on nutritional intake? This efficiency of supply of the PDS could be a measure of

the ability of the system to make the allotted amount of food available for the people to buy.

The exercise is challenging mainly because of the peculiarities of the PDS system. The

government subsidises the grain but also imposes a quota which varies by state of residence,

income and over time. Besides, on many occasions, agents are unable to buy their full quotas

because of supply-side deficiencies on the part of the government suppliers. This implies that

an agent's observed PDS grain consumption is not always her quantity demanded or her full

quota (as simple demand theory would tell us), but it may be something rationed by supply

failures. This feature may be used to identify the relationship between PDS efficiency and

the consumption of nutrients. Factors that may affect the grain delivery mechanism of the

PDS would directly influence the amount of grain available for dispensation in the PDS

shops. One such factor is rainfall, especially in those areas that are large contributors to

27

According to Himanshu and Sen (2011) improving delivery is a higher priority than expanding entitlement

regarding improving the impact of the PDS.

Page 79: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

71

the PDS stock. Also stock availability would impact different regions differently. In grain

surplus areas locally procured grain may be used in PDS, but in grain scarce areas

supplies have to be brought in from outside. A combination of these two is used in

this chapter to identify the effect, after controlling for preferences and demand

determinants as best as possible.

There are advantages gained by looking at nutrient (calorie/protein) consumption rather

than amount of grains delivered or bought. Firstly, nutrient consumption of the people has to

be the ultimate aim of any food-security measure. Secondly, there remains a concern that

agents may be buying from PDS shops and then selling them again at higher prices

(Bhagwati and Panagariya 2013). Looking directly at calorie consumption should help

circumvent this problem. Like all other subsidies, the PDS is also a market intervention and

is bound to affect nutrient consumption through various channels including local socio-

economic institutions. The first step here would be to properly identify econometrically the

net effect of PDS on nutrient intake and then to unravel the mechanisms if possible.

4..1 Institutional Background: Evolution of the Public Distribution System in India

The origins of the PDS go back to the early 1940s during the Second World War. The British

regime had introduced rationing of food items due to war time necessities. After

independence in 1947 the Government of India decided to continue with the system.

According to Dantwala (1993) about 54 million people in the urban areas were covered at

this time. The rationale behind urban rationing was that unrestricted markets would draw out

food grains from the rural hinterland in times of scarcity. At this stage the main focus was on

achieving price stability and preventing famines. Although this approach would soon change,

nevertheless it introduced an urban bias in the PDS that would persist for some time.

Page 80: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

72

By 1956, the end of the first five year plan period, it was becoming clear that PDS had to be

transformed into a food security program and this transformation took place through the

second five year plan period (1957-1961). The total number of PDS outlets or fair price

shops went up from 18,000 to 51,000 (Nawani 1994). Soon the PDS organisation took its

present shape with the formation of the Food Corporation of India (FCI) in 1965. Every year

the government would announce a minimum support price for food-grains. Any unsold

stocks at the declared minimum price would be bought by the FCI and stored. These stocks

would then be issued out to state governments for distribution through the PDS and also for

maintaining a buffer stock for times of scarcity. The whole country was divided into 5 zones

with most of the grain surplus areas located in the North. Today the FCI maintains a huge

stock of over 54 million tonnes of food grain and distributes throughout the country via

492,000 fair price shops (11th plan, Planning Commission of India).

After the liberalisation of the Indian economy in 1991, the PDS came back into policy

debates mainly because of the huge subsidy burden it was imposing on the government. The

total subsidy for running the program had gone up from 0.04% of GDP in 1970-71 to 0.5%

of GDP in 1991-92. At this time there were a number of reviews of the PDS and its working.

These studies highlighted the large expense being incurred for very small gains. Various

recommendations were made for targeting subsidies to the poor in order to curtail the subsidy

burden (Ahluwalia 1993, Parikh 1994, Radhakrishna et al. 1997, Dutta and Ramaswami

2000, 2001, Indrakant 2000). Responding to the criticism, the government decided to go in

for targeting by income. In 1997 the Targeted Public Distribution System (TPDS) was

introduced. This scheme offered 10 Kgs of grains per month to households below poverty

line (BPL) at half the cost of procurement to the FCI. At the same time subsidies for

Page 81: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

73

households above poverty line (APL) were totally eliminated. The quota for BPL households

was eventually raised to 35 kgs per month in 2002. Also many state governments have

tinkered with PDS entitlements on their own. For example Tamil Nadu persisted with the

universal PDS system while states like Andra Pradesh and Kerala have reduced their quotas.

A good summary of these changes can be found in Khera (2011b), Planning Commission

(2005).28

In spite of these changes the problems with the PDS still persist. According to the Planning

Commission's report for the 11th plan, subsidy cost for maintaining the PDS has gone up

from Rs. 51.7 billion in 1996-97 to Rs. 238.3 billion in 2006-07 which is more than an

increase of 3.5 times. Also identification of the poor has not been done well by the

state governments. According to the Planning Commission's survey report, although uptake

by poor households were much higher than previously, only about 57% of the BPL families

were being covered by the targeted PDS. Errors in identification exist both in inclusion as

well as exclusion with many "ghost" BPL cards going around.

As a remedy to the targeting problems the Government came up with the latest legislation in

2013, increasing the coverage of TPDS to 70% of the income distribution in the rural areas

and 50% in the urban areas. Each household will be entitled to 5 Kgs of grains per month at

very subsidised prices for the next three years. These changes might bring about a more

significant improvement in food security in the future but it is unlikely to be simply due to a

rise in entitlement. One major issue is the delivery mechanism and the leakage of grains to

28

See also the article "Simplifying the food security bill" published in the Hindu Newspaper on 12 March 2012.

http://www.thehindu.com/multimedia/archive/00948/Simplifying_the_NFS_948744a.pdf

Page 82: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

74

the black market. This problem needs to be addressed and some suggested methods are cash

transfers or cash cards that take the distribution mechanism out of the equation entirely.

The main focus of this chapter, however, is not to suggest wholesale changes or

improvements in supply mechanism but to exploit exogenous changes in supply to estimate

the effect of current PDS consumption on nutrition.

4.2. Motivating the Empirical Setup

As mentioned before the objective of this chapter is to estimate the effect of PDS grain on

the consumption of nutrients by utilising exogenous shocks to PDS supply while controlling

for demand related factors as best as possible. This section attempts to explain the economic

logic behind this approach and the assumptions required for the purpose. Also, the

composition of the sample to be used for analysis is discussed.

The PDS grain consumption that we observe is the outcome of optimization by the

households. One of the key determinants of this optimum quantity would be the household's

income. Figure 4.1 plots a kernel estimation of PDS grain consumption as a function of

annual mean per capita consumption expenditure (MPCE) separately for 2004 and 2009.

Both curves are consistently downward sloping apart from a small section at the beginning.

This shows that for most of the sample PDS grain is an inferior good. PDS consumption is

increasing in MPCE only for the poorest.29

However when we consider an impact of supply

29

It might come as a surprise that most of this sample of PDS users are above the poverty line as indicated by

the vertical lines in Figure 4.1. However, it should be borne in mind that below poverty line status in India is

determined not just by income but by a host of different criterion via a BPL census conducted by the

government every 10 years. Scores are awarded to each surveyed household for each criterion and the final

decision is made according to a cut-off on these scores. For example, owning a motorised vehicle or a

refrigerator would debar you from BPL status, but being shelter-less or belonging to a primitive tribal group

would lead to automatic qualification into the group. Also, the different states have some independence in

determining the cut-off criteria used in their jurisdiction for BPL status determination. This diversity in

Page 83: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

75

shocks to the optimum PDS grain consumption we need to take into account the response of

both these groups of households.

Figure 4.2 is a stylized representation of Figure 4.1 for purposes of illustration. Suppose the

household with income is the income for which PDS grain consumption peaks.

Any household with income less than for example , would be treating PDS grain as a

determining criterion for BPL status is the likely cause of the surprisingly low number of PDS users lying

below the Planning Commission's poverty line in this sample.

Notes: These lines depict the relationship between PDS grain consumption (wheat and rice)

and Monthly Per Capita Consumption Expenditure×12. The relationship is estimated by

local polynomial smoothing. The kernel function used is Epanechnikov and the degree of

polynomial used is 1. This estimation was done only on households with MPCE less than or

equal to a hundred thousand rupees. Two vertical lines are at the ten thousand and thirty

thousand rupees mark indicate the official poverty line for India according to the Planning

Commission and the poverty line used by the World Bank.

Source: NSS rounds 61st and 66th

Page 84: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

76

normal good. Similarly households to the right of like will consider PDS grain as an

inferior good. However it should be pointed out that households like those with income like

are very few in the sample (refer to Figure 4.3 to see the distribution of MPCE in the

sample).

Next let us analyse how these different households might react to an exogenous supply shock

to PDS grain. While we expect the demand for PDS grain to be some sort of downward

sloping curve in price, the supply curve is dictated by the amount of the quota and the price

at which this quota may be bought. The supply curve facing any particular household is

contingent upon its income status (APL/BPL) and the state in which it is situated. However,

in general the supply function would look something like the curve labelled SS in

Figure 4.4. This figure represents demand and supply of PDS grain for a representative

Page 85: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

77

consumer who is allotted a quota of Q kilograms of grain at price P. The quantity supplied is

.

anything between 0 and Q at price P, however at all other prices quantity supplied is 0. This

is the supply curve in an ideal situation. But, as described earlier, PDS is seldom able to

deliver the promised amount of grains to its consumers due to large scale illegal leakage into

black markets. Also buying from the PDS is also associated with travelling long distances to

reach the Fair Price Shop (FPS) and standing in long queues and then often returning empty

handed. In other words, the effective price paid by the consumer is higher than the

official subsidised price. Also, the quantity available for collection is below the quota

46

283

901

1963

3377

4251

4745

50944985

4643

4117

3673

3179

2720

2447

2133

17181587

13201197

0

10

00

20

00

30

00

40

00

50

00

Fre

qu

en

cy

0 20000 40000 60000 80000 100000income

Figure 4.3: Histogram of Income (MPCE), Sample of PDS users with MPCE less than

from NSS 61st and 66th rounds.

Notes: This figure shows the distribution of income/ monthly percapita consumption

expenditure (MPCE) for the sample of PDS users with MPCE less than Rs 1,00,000. Sample

includes all agents from 2004 and 2009 NSS surveys. Amounts are deflated to 2004 prices.

Page 86: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

78

amount Q. In Figure 4.4 this is represented as a shift of the supply curve from SS to SE. Now

is the maximum amount available to the consumer and this at an effectively higher price

of .

Next we would like to investigate the implications of a positive supply shock to the PDS. In

such a case we may imagine that the effective price falls to and quantity available for

collection goes up to say . This means that the supply curve now shifts down (as

indicated by the arrow) to SE1. Now consider two different households represented by their

demand curves DD and D1.

Page 87: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

79

If these consumers are from the region to the left of from Figure 4.2 then DD represents

the household with higher income amongst the two. If on the other hand the they are from the

range of income to the right of then D1 is the household with higher income. In either

case, however, it is clear that the supply shock leads to higher consumption of PDS grain.

Such a supply shock therefore, will lead to an upward shift in PDS grain consumption, as

shown in Fig. 4.2. This observation motivates the empirical specification used in this paper.

The supply shock introduced into the PDS system by random rainfall shock in PDS grain

supplier states is used to identify the effect of a rise in PDS grain consumption on nutrient

consumption in households. Of course, this approach relies on being able to control for the

factors affecting the demand curve. Also, if we look at Figure 4.1 the estimated relationship

between MPCE and PDS grain in 2004 and 2009 seem to be parallel shifts of each other. It is

unlikely that this change is due to people substituting into PDS grains (due to shift in

preferences). Such a response would have ensued if perhaps there had been a large negative

shock to incomes throughout the distribution (since PDS grain is considered inferior).

However the period between 2004 and 2009 was a period of rapid economic growth in

India. A more plausible explanation lies in the improvement of PDS delivery of food

grains which reduced the gap between the quota and the actual uptake. This is exactly what I

plan to use in the identification strategy.

In this exercise the sample restricts attention to households who have reported a positive

quantity purchased from PDS. This excludes agents who do not own a ration-card and are

ineligible to buy from the PDS, as well as those who chose not to buy from it. The latter

category can again be sub-divided, based on the possible reason for their choice. The richer

households may choose not to consume PDS grain considering it to be of inferior quality. On

Page 88: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

80

the other hand, the very poor might be unable to buy from the PDS due to income

constraints. However given the drastically subsidised prices of PDS grain (ranging from Re

1/KG to Rs 5.5/KG for households below poverty line (BPL)), it is unlikely that a household

will be income constrained to buy at least a portion of its allotted quota. To put this in

perspective, consider that the highest possible expenditure on PDS grain for a BPL

household is Rs 210 per month (if the highest quota is purchased at the highest price). The

official poverty line income per day according to the Planning Commission is Rs. 26-33

per capita per-day, which is a monthly household income of about Rs 2400 assuming a

family of three. Therefore, the proportion of households dropping out because of income

constraints is likely to be small.

4.3. Data

National Sample Survey Data

The first exercise is to estimate the impact of PDS grain consumption on calorie/protein

intake. For this I use the NSS consumption data from rounds 66th and 61st (2009, 2004

respectively). These are the large rounds making the combined sample of more than

two hundred thousand households. This is a very detailed consumption survey at the

household level whose sampling method makes it representative at the district, state and

national levels. Both quantity and value of consumption are reported in most cases making it

possible to calculate nutrient consumption on the one hand and also the price paid by the

agent by dividing the value by the quantity. The nutrient consumption tables used in this

exercise are the same that are used by the NSS and the original source is Gopalan et al.

(1974). Data set also provides demographic and household characteristics of the surveyed

households.

Page 89: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

81

In the entire sample, about 60,000 households bought rice from the PDS and about 30,000

bought wheat. The total number of households who bought anything at all is about 80,000.

This number is expected to be far less than the number who are eligible to buy. There is no

data about possession of ration cards (cards that show eligibility for PDS) in the 66th round

about 76% have ration cards amongst the households sampled in the 61st round. As such it is

difficult to identify the households below poverty line (BPL). The best that can be done is to

infer the type of household by checking the price paid since it is known that BPL household

receive a subsidised price. This information is used to build the main variable of interest

which is the gap between allotted quota and uptake of grains. Quotas vary by state, income

and type of grain. The source for information about PDS quotas used for this exercise is

Khera (2011b), Planning Commission (2005) and the article "Simplifying the food security

bill" published in the Hindu Newspaper on 12 March 2012. Although the best efforts were

made to ensure accuracy, it has to be admitted that the available information leaves some

room for confusion in some cases.

Another issue is the problem of identifying all households who have access to PDS. As

described earlier there is no information about ration cards holding in the 66th round data. So

most of the analysis here is conducted on a restricted sample of households who have

reported some quantity purchased from the PDS. The potential selection problem here arises

from people who are eligible yet choose not to consume. But the identification strategy (as

hinted at in the introduction) would rely on supply shocks to the PDS and these people would

be unlikely to be affected by these shocks anyway. Besides, by restricting the sample it is

made certain that the household has access to a fair price shop and has a ration card.

Page 90: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

82

The summary statistics for some of the key variables for this restricted sample is reported in

Table 4.1a and Table 4.1b. The change from 2004 sample and 2009 sample is also reported.

Page 91: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

83

There are two interesting aspects in Table 4.1a. Firstly, it shows that calorie consumption per

capita has fallen from 2004 to 2009. Although this is the general trend for the whole

population as reported by Deaton and Dreze (2009), it is a bit surprising to find the same

trend in a restricted sample of PDS users who would be in general poorer than the

population. Protein consumption however seems to have gone up in the sample which is

contrary to what is going on in the whole population. The second interesting aspect is that

over time PDS does seem to have expanded both in terms of coverage and grain

delivery. Both number of PDS users (number of observations) and quantity consumed of

PDS rice and wheat have gone up, this in spite of the 2004 NSS full sample being bigger

than the 2009 sample. Yet, the gap between quota and uptake has gone up, perhaps reflecting

the expansion in quotas and entitlements that have taken place in between these two years. In

all other respects the 2009 sample seems to be doing better.

Page 92: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

84

Page 93: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

85

4.4. Empirical Strategy and Results

4.4.1 OLS

We begin the analysis with a pooled OLS estimate where the main variables of interest are

household intake of rice/wheat from the PDS and the difference between quota allotted to the

household and total uptake.

The equation to be estimated is as follows:

Here represents the Monthly Per Capita household consumption of calories or

proteins in logarithm for household i in district d in time t in state s. is the main

variable of interest. It is either PDS uptake of rice or wheat or the difference between the

quota of food grains and the uptake of grains for household i in district d in time t in state s.

and are district and year controls, are state-time controls, are household level

economic and demographic characteristics and is the error.

The results are reported in Table 4.2. The OLS results are exactly as we would expect. Both

PDS consumption of rice and wheat have positive significant coefficients indicating that it

does contribute to nutrient consumption positively. The signs of the variable of interest also

change when we switch to quota-uptake differences. Negative significant coefficients here

indicate that PDS inefficiency impacts both protein and calorie consumption negatively and

significantly. Controls used are of three types. Firstly we use a set of demographic

controls like caste and religion of the household, next are household characteristics like size,

number of females and adults, method of cooking, land-ownership, whether they consume

out of their own produce and electrification and lastly there are a set of incomes (proxied by

Page 94: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

86

Monthly Per Capita consumption expenditure MPCE30

) and prices of PDS and open market

purchases of wheat, rice and sugar (the three main items obtained via the PDS).

Occupation dummies following National Classification of Occupation codes 2004, and

seasonal dummies (using NSS sub-rounds31

) have also been included.

The size of the coefficients imply that a one kilogram increase in the quota - uptake gap leads

to a fall of 0.8 percent in daily calorie intake and 0.69 percent fall in daily protein intake.

Using the mean figures for the sample these numbers may be translated to a 15.2 kilocalorie

fall in average calorie consumption per person every day.

30

Following Hnatkovska et al. (2012), MPCE figures have been converted to 2004 prices using state-level

deflators calculated using state level poverty lines as reported by the Planning Commission. Planning

Commission (2004-05, 2009-10) 31

NSS collects data in four sub-rounds which are July-September, October December, January - March and

April - June. Controlling for these sub-rounds allows to take out seasonal variation in prices and grain demand.

Page 95: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

87

Page 96: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

88

4.4.2 Omitted Variable Bias and the Instrument

One major concern regarding identification is the presence of omitted variables that might

have prompted agents to self-select into the sample. Firstly, there are many government

sponsored welfare programs running at the same time (for example NREGA and IRDP32

).

Suppose a politically well connected household has better access to all these programs. Then

the political connection variable may explain both higher access to PDS and higher calorie

consumption giving us a spurious correlation. The other side of the story is that a politically

marginalised households may have very low access to resources and be forced to consume

from the PDS which may be looked upon as an inferior good. In either case calorie

consumption and PDS efficiency will be found to be spuriously correlated. These factors

essentially cause a selection bias where a particular kind of households (e.g. politically aware

or well connected) get self selected into the sample. In order to circumvent this potential

problem I need an exogenous variation in the quota-uptake difference which will not be

correlated with these unobservable factors. Now I will describe the instrument I use for this

purpose.

The PDS in India works by procuring grains directly from the farmers and then redistributing

them at subsidized prices through fair price shops. As mentioned, for procurement the

government declares a minimum price each year and buys up all the grains offered up at that

price. This operation of buying, storing, and supplying the grains is done by the

Food Corporation of India (FCI). Among the states, Punjab and Andhra Pradesh have been

the biggest

32

National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (NREGA) promises 100 days of employment at minimum wages.

Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP) provides loans to poor households at subsidised rates.

Page 97: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

89

suppliers of rice to the FCI, whereas the supply of wheat is heavily dominated by Punjab (see

Fig. 4.5). The salience of Punjab as a supplier of the FCI leads one to expect that any

variation in the agricultural production of Punjab would affect the stocks of food grains with

the FCI and in turn the supply of grains at the fair price shops.

The variation in agricultural production is determined by various factors. Of these some are

totally random like rainfall. Although Punjab is a state with large tracts of irrigated land (one

of the reasons why it produces large surpluses to be sold to the FCI), its agriculture is still

rain dependent. One of the reasons for this is that irrigation itself is rain dependent. Drought

years may adversely affect agricultural output. Hence we should observe a link between the

rainfall in Punjab and the availability of PDS grain in all states in that year. This variation in

rainfall in Punjab is what I will be using to instrument for PDS leakage.

0

10

020

030

040

0

Ric

e p

rocure

men

t in

hu

nd

red

tho

usa

nd

ton

nes

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Total Punjab

Andhra Pradesh

Figure 4.5a: Rice Procurement from Major Supplier States.

Source: Food Corporation of India website

Page 98: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

90

For this purpose I construct a variable using rainfall data from the state of Punjab over the

time period 1990-2009. The data is available at the website of Indian Institute of Tropical

Meteorology.33

For each of the years I construct a metric for above average rainfall by

subtracting the average rainfall over two decades i.e. 1990-2009, from the current year’s

rainfall.

Two assumptions are made in this argument. First, I am assuming that rain has some effect

on the agricultural output in Punjab. This may be safely assumed for most areas in India

since Indian agriculture is notoriously susceptible to the vagaries of the monsoon. Yet,

33

The rainfall data may be downloaded free from the website of Indian Institute of Tropical Meteorology at:

http://www.tropmet.res.in/

050

10

015

020

025

0

Wh

ea

t pro

cure

men

t in

hu

nd

red

tho

usa

nd

tonn

es

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Total Punjab

Haryana

Figure 4.5b: Wheat Procurement from Major Supplier States.

Source: Food Corporation of India website

Page 99: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

91

Punjab is one of the states where irrigation through canals and pumps is used a lot, hence

there might be some suspicion that the rain dependence of Punjabi agriculture may have

lessened somewhat in recent years. To test this I looked at the total value of rice and wheat

production in Punjab from 2004 to 2010. The correlation coefficient between these figures

and my rainfall metric is 0.16 and 0.17 respectively. So although it is true that agriculture is

not as rain-dependent as it used to be earlier, there is still positive relation between the two.34

Another link to be examined is whether an increase in agricultural production in Punjab also

causes larger uptake of grains from Punjab by the FCI. Here as well there may be some

subtle reasons to question this very innocuous looking assumption. For example: in a year

when rains are good in the entire country Punjab would have high output, but there would be

extra grains to be brought up from other states as well. In such a scenario it is possible that in

good years less grain may be picked up from Punjab and more from other states which are

more dependent on rain. In years of low rainfall the bulk of FCI purchases are brought from

Punjab which is less rain dependent and more mechanized in its farming techniques. But

once again I find that the correlation between the uptake from Punjab by the FCI and value

of total production is 0.43 and 0.28 for rice and wheat respectively for the years between

2004 and 2010 (Source Ministry of Agriculture and Cooperation website, Government of

India). So the assumptions involved in the argument for the instrument seem to be valid.

The Punjab rainfall instrument has a major disadvantage, however, which is that it varies

only by year. This means that, with this instrument, year fixed effects and state-year fixed

effects cannot be used. Also, in India rainfall is often determined by the quality of the

34

Due to the rampant use of pumps for irrigation, some of the areas in Punjab are facing salinity and water table

depletion.

Page 100: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

92

monsoon,35

which is liable to affect rainfall all over the country. Thus rain in Punjab may be

correlated with rain in other states, which in turn may have a bearing on consumption of

nutrients in those other areas. So it is essential that state-year fixed effects be used.

One solution to this problem would be to interact the basic rainfall metric with some other

variable which varies at the region, district, or household level which could enhance the

effect of the original variable. A similar strategy was used by Nunn and Qian (2012), where

they try to estimate the impact of U.S. food aid on conflict in Africa. Here they instrumented

for US food aid by an interaction between US agricultural production and the propensity for

a country to partake of US aid as represented by their average receipts of aid. In the current

setting, a similar strategy would be to use the differential impact of Punjab's rainfall on the

different zones that the PDS apparatus is divided into.

Zonal variation in PDS grain supply

One of the main functions of the Food Corporation of India is to move food-grains from the

surplus areas to the deficit areas. It is perhaps due to the good work of the FCI that the threat

of famine has largely disappeared from the country. For this purpose, FCI divides the country

into five zones which are North, South, East, West and the North-East. The North zone

includes the states of Punjab, Haryana, Uttar Pradesh which happen to be the major grain

surplus states both for wheat and rice. The South has states like Andhra Pradesh which is a

big surplus state for rice, but the others like Tamil Nadu, Karnataka and Kerala are more or

less neutral. In the East, West Bengal and Orissa do have surpluses from time to time but

would be best described as self sufficient. Most of the grain deficit areas fall in the West and

35

The seasonal winds from the sea which bring rain after the summer are known as the monsoons.

Page 101: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

93

North-East zones. As such there has to be a lot of movement of grains out of the North zone

into the West and the North-East.36

This structure and the distribution of the surplus and deficit areas leads us to expect that any

rain shock to the Punjab would lead to differential impact on PDS supplies in different zones.

We would expect the biggest improvements to happen in the grain deficit areas and only

marginal or no improvements for the East or South.

The patterns in inter-zone grain transfers by the FCI become more apparent when we look at

the figures representing planned and actual despatches of grain into and from various zones.

These figures for the year 2012-13 are presented in Tables 4.3a and 4.3b. Table 4.3a shows

amounts of inter-state grain transfers by the FCI into states belonging to the five zones. In

terms of total volume of transfers the North-East definitely receives less than the other

zones, but this is not surprising considering that only about 3 percent of the total population

of the country lives in this zone. The size of the population in the other zones is clearly

reflected in the amounts of the grain transfers they get. However it should be noted that for

all zones except the North-East, these figures are liable to include intra-zone transfers as

well, that is transfers from other states belonging to the same zone. Also the fact that most of

the states belonging to the North are surplus grain producers is reflected in the relatively low

inter-state transfers into these states.

33

North East zone has Assam, Manipur, Meghalaya, Arunachal Pradesh, Mizoram and Nagaland.

Page 102: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

94

Table 4.3b on the other hand, shows where the grain dispatches are coming from. While

there exists at least one state in each of the four big zones which contributes a non-zero

amount to the PDS stock in other states, there is no contribution of this kind from any state in

the North-East. This is hardly surprising if one takes into account the very low amounts that

are procured by the FCI from the North-East. Procurement of rice by zones is shown in

Figure 4.6 for the years 2000 to 2010.37

The procurement of rice from North-East is almost

negligible when compared to the other zones. So it is perhaps safe to assume that the North-

East would be totally dependent on other states for its PDS supplies. In particular it should be

dependent on the North which is not only the biggest supplier of grains but also sends out a

lot of grains to other states (Table 4.3b). At the same time the North receives very few inter-

state grain transfers (as evident from Table 4.3a) indicating that most of the grains sent out

from the northern states (like Punjab) end up in states outside the North zone.

37

The corresponding figure for wheat is not shown since the North and the states of Punjab and Haryana always

make up more than the 90% of the procurement while the South and North-East do not contribute at all.

Page 103: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

95

The North-East zone is of special interest to this exercise for a number of reasons. First, it

happens to be a low producer of food grains and hence is largely dependent on the surplus

zones for its supplies. On top of that the North-Eastern states are quite remotely located and

as such provide ample opportunities for illegal diversion of food grains into the black market

while grains are being transported. This conjecture is consistent with the findings of Khera

(2011a) who reports that over 80% of the grains allocated to the state of Assam never reach

the people. Table 4.4 reports some descriptive statistics of key variables in the NE zone

along with the change from 2004 to 2009. The interesting thing in this table is that the PDS

seems to have made good progress during this time. Both the consumption of PDS rice and

Page 104: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

96

wheat have improved and with no change in quotas during this time the gap between

quota and uptake has also reduced significantly. Along with this there has also been a rise

in the number of PDS users. But calorie consumption has still gone down on average and

protein consumption has shown no change.

4.4.3 Exclusion Restriction

This interaction between zones and the Punjab rain metric is to be used in a two stage least

square estimation as an instrument for quota-uptake difference. The main identifying

assumption here is that the differential impact of Punjab rainfall on the PDS supply in the

different zones is the only way it can affect calorie consumption in households. In order that

050

10

015

0

Zo

na

l R

ice P

rocu

rem

en

t, in 1

000

00

Ton

ne

s

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

North South

East West

North-East

Figure 4.6: Zonal Rice Procurement by Zones

Source: Food Corporation of India website

Page 105: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

97

this assumption is not violated a number of precautions have been taken. Here the main

concerns about the validity of the instrument are discussed.

The first concern is that rainfall in Punjab could affect calorie consumption independent of

its effect on PDS efficiency. It is possible that higher rainfall in Punjab causes a nationwide

shock to the markets which affects agricultural output, agricultural prices and economic

activity all over the country. This might be another channel affecting calorie/protein

consumption in other states apart from its effect on the efficiency of the PDS. However these

concerns are taken care of through the state-year fixed effects which control for state specific

shocks for each year. Also prices of PDS and open market food grains (rice and wheat) and

sugar are controlled for to ameliorate the effect of unobservables on the grain market.

Also, rain in Punjab may be correlated with rain in other states which may cause a boom in

these states as well. From Figure 4.1 we know that a negative relationship exists between

income and PDS consumption, hence we may expect a boom year to drive down PDS uptake

in that year. This may lead to confounded results from the 2SLS estimation. In order to

address this concern the first step is to exclude Punjab and some other states which are close

to it (like Haryana and Himachal Pradesh etc.) from the sample since in these states we

would most likely be picking up the effects of rainfall on local conditions rather than PDS

efficiency. For the rest of the states it is unlikely that rain in Punjab would directly affect

local conditions. However, rainfall in Punjab may be correlated with rain in these other states

through the quality of the monsoons in that year. This year specific effect would be taken

care of using the year fixed effect and the state-year fixed effects.

Page 106: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

98

There is still another possible scenario where the identifying assumption may be violated,

which is when rainfall in Punjab causes supply spillover effects which are zone specific

(apart from the PDS generated effects). However, this is unlikely since the zonal partitioning

is, to the best of my knowledge, particular to the PDS only. No other government programme

Page 107: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

99

uses this partitioning system to either distribute resources or to fix target groups. As such it is

difficult to imagine reasons why any spillover effect would be zone-specific. If there are

spillovers dependent on geographical features or nearness to Punjab then the year state

effects should absorb that as well. A zone specific spillover effect, if any, would most likely

be caused by the resultant surge in PDS supply itself. Although with the current approach

this effect cannot be disentangled from the main effect, it may be argued that any attempt to

measure the effect of rise in PDS supply on calorie consumption should include any spillover

effects of a rise in PDS supply to that region anyway.

4.4.4 Two Stage Least Squares

So now, the first stage of the 2SLS is given as follows:

Here is Punjab's rainfall, measured as described above, in the current year. Variables

are now also indexed with the PDS zones which is represented by j. is a set of

dummies that indicate which zone the household belongs to (j takes five values indicating the

five PDS zones). Two separate specifications are run, differentiated by the set of dummies

used for the instrument. In the first specification only the NE dummy is used, which makes it

a comparison between households in the NE zone to the rest of India. In the second

specification all dummies except North are used, which implies a comparison of the different

zones with North as the reference group. Also, the dummy for the respective PDS zones

Page 108: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

100

is also controlled for directly in each of the regressions. Standard errors are clustered at

the year-zone level.

The first stage results are reported in the first two columns of Table 4.5. While interpreting

these coefficients one needs to keep track of the comparison group. For example, the

negative significant coefficient for NE zone in column one indicates that rain in Punjab has a

negative impact on quota-uptake gap in the NE zone when compared to the rest of India, as

expected. On the other hand the coefficients in column two uses North zone as the

comparison group. Since Punjab itself is situated in the North zone it is expected that

negative impact on quota-uptake gap would be quite high for this region. Hence it is not

surprising that the South and East have statistically significant coefficients that are positive.

This indicates that the impact of Punjab's rain on the gap/inefficiency is smaller in these

areas when compared to the North zone. However, the West has an insignificant coefficient

indicating that the impact of rain is statistically equivalent to that in the North. The only

negative significant negative coefficient is for North-East which is exactly what one would

expect given this region's overdependence on outside suppliers38

.

The second stage results are reported in the last three columns of Table 4.5. The coefficients

of quota-uptake are negative and significant in the first specification (column 3, with only the

North-East interaction as IV) providing evidence to support the claim that PDS supplies or

efficiency is positively related to calorie consumption at the household. These results imply

that a fall of one kilogram in the quota-uptake gap leads to a 0.55 percent point rise in calorie

consumption (about 8.5 to 9 Kcal at the average). The magnitude of the coefficient is smaller

38

Although both specifications are jointly significant, the F-statistic for the specification with all four zonal

interactions is just higher than 8, slightly below the accepted norm of 10.

Page 109: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

101

than those obtained by OLS in Table 4.2 which is perhaps because the OLS results were

upward biased due to the self selection of households with better access to PDS and other

public resources. As discussed earlier, this may have been due to their better knowledge

about these availability facilities or their better connectivity in the circles of political power .

However, when we look at the specification with all the zonal interactions as IV we find in

column 4 of Table 4.5 that the coefficients in the second stage are positive and significant.

This is true for both calorie consumption (rise of 0.28 percent for a rise of 1 KG in the gap)

and protein consumption (a rise of 0.7 percent). This result is surprising and goes contrary to

both the first IV specification as well as the OLS results of Table 4.2. Before attempting to

interpret this I would like to point out that the first stage of this particular specification is not

as strong as the first one. F-statistics for the first stage is just over 8 which would lead one to

suspect that the first stage is slightly weak. This could be due to the fact that for regions that

do not depend so much on grain from outside (like south and west) the Punjab rainfall may

not be such a good predictor of the quota-uptake gap. Hence, using all the zonal interactions

somewhat dilutes the effectiveness of the instrument.

If we assume that the coefficients are correct these results (columns 4 and 5) provide

evidence in favor of the critics of PDS. However, the usual argument involving the

inefficiency of the PDS cannot be invoked to explain this. These results imply that

households who are less exposed to PDS inefficiency also consume less protein and calories.

One explanation could be that PDS grains are of much lower quality and switching from

open market grains to PDS grains reduces the quality of nutrition intake. For this to be true

the household in question has to be rich enough to afford the same amount of grain at open

market prices as it could under PDS prices. From the evidence of Figure 4.1 and 4.3 the

Page 110: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

102

sample of PDS users do seem to be enjoying quite high consumption expenditures. However,

this explanation is not too persuasive since calorie content of both PDS and open market

grains have been taken to be the same in this exercise.

A second explanation for this result with all zonal interactions may be suggested on the basis

of the trends in calorie consumption and PDS efficiency. As pointed out in detail in the

previous chapters average calorie and protein consumption in India is following a declining

trend. If this trend coincides with a rise in PDS delivery efficiency and coverage (evidence

provided in Table 4.6 below) then we could be spuriously observing the results in the last

two columns of Table 4.5. However time fixed effects were included in the regression

essentially to take care of this eventuality.

The third and most plausible explanation is that the benefits of PDS efficiency is manifested

only on certain sections of the wealth distribution and calorie-consumption spectrum. It

could also differ by regions. When we make a country-wide analysis using the entire income

distribution much of the effect is confounded. In order to unravel the causes of these results it

may be useful to carry out the analysis at various quantiles of the income distribution.

Finally, to provide more insight about the relationship between income (MPCE) and the main

variables of interest (i.e. quota-uptake difference and calorie consumption), Table 4.6

provides a breakup of the sample in terms of MPCE and then displays how different income

groups have evolved from 2004 to 2009 in terms of quota-uptake difference and calorie

consumption. From this we can see that quota-uptake difference has gone down for all

income groups but the fall is much lower for high income groups. Regarding calorie

consumption it seems that low income groups have seen an increase whereas high income

groups show a decline.

Page 111: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

103

Page 112: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

104

Page 113: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

105

4.6. Conclusion

The chapter looks at the impact of the PDS on nutrient consumption in some detail.

However, on the basis of the evidence presented here it is still difficult make an

unambiguous statement on the effectiveness of the PDS. The strongest and most robust

specification estimated here is the one with North-east zone interacted with Punjab Rainfall

and this tells us that PDS efficiency does have a positive impact on calorie consumption.

Using these estimates it is possible to make rough evaluations of the impact of the PDS on

the current sample of PDS users. For example, in the event that the PDS is scrapped the grain

consumption derived from the PDS in this sample would go down from 16.85 Kilograms per

month to 0 and the quota-uptake gap would go up by the same amount. This would lead to a

fall in calorie consumption by more than 9 percent or by an absolute amount of 176

kilocalories per day. The average calorie consumption which was just more than 1900

Kcal/day would now go down to just over 1724 Kcal/day.

However this figure is liable to be a gross overestimate because funds that were used to buy

from the PDS would now be used to buy its substitutes from the open market. One crude way

to take this into account would be to calculate the average amount of money freed by the

absence of the PDS and calculate the impact of this amount on calorie consumption using our

coefficient on consumption expenditure. We can also compute the actual subsidy provided

by the government to BPL households by subtracting the central issue prices of the BPL

from the APL. So we can add to the income effect from above the impact of giving the

households a cash transfer equal to the amount of the subsidy. Even after controlling for all

this the loss in per day calorie consumption using the estimates and averages from this

Page 114: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

106

sample is still about 150 Kcals, which is 8 percent of the average calorie consumption in the

sample.

However the rough estimates reported above use the sample averages of PDS consumption

and MPCE. We are more interested in the effect that PDS has on households below the

poverty line. BPL households are of course difficult to identify. In fact if we go by the

current poverty line of Rs 28-32 per day of the Planning Commission then the sample of PDS

users contain less than 50 of such households (refer to Figure 4.3). However the

identification of BPL households involve various other criteria that often differ by state. To

be realistic I choose for evaluation the threshold of Rs 40,000 MPCE which is just above the

international poverty line of $ 1.25 PPP per capita per day. At this level of income PDS

consumption is much higher, at about 20 Kgs/month39

and the impact of PDS as calculated

for the full sample above comes to about 170 Kilocalories per person per day. However, it

has to be noted that the coefficients used to generate this figure are estimated at the mean and

are liable to be different if estimated at other points of the income distribution. In the absence

of the relevant coefficients the calculations can be re-done under the assumption that the

money freed by the absence of the PDS grain is spent to buy grains in the open market at the

APL prices (proxy for the market price). In this scenario the negative impact on calorie

consumption is only due to the loss of income of the amount of the subsidy which translates

into just 1 percent drop in calorie consumption. However, given that most studies find a

income elasticity of food to be less than 1 (see Subramanian and Deaton 1996 and Behrman

and Deolalikar 1987), this scenario seems implausible. The real effect would lie somewhere

in between these two figures.

39

Using local polynomial smoothing estimates of the relationship between MPCE and PDS grain consumption

for the sample of PDS users with MPCE less or equal to a Rs 100,000.

Page 115: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

107

The other thing that this chapter sheds light on is the nature of inter-regional relationship in

the PDS. While the North zone is the biggest supplier of excess grains, NE and West are the

most significant beneficiaries. While the South and East are quite self-sufficient and also

efficient in terms of their PDS, they are not major users of excess bounty from the North. As

such, outcomes in certain regions respond more than others if PDS is changed or modified.

Since NE and West are more food insecure than the rest, it would be useful for policy makers

to keep this in mind.

From this evidence it does seem that the PDS is having significant impact against

malnutrition . However it is yet to be seen whether the price the government is paying for

this benefit is worth it or not. Counterfactuals where the PDS is replaced by direct cash

transfers may also be estimated in future research by actually estimating demand functions

for PDS grain.

Page 116: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

108

5. Conclusion

Amongst all nations of the world, India today suffers from the dubious distinction of housing

the largest number of poor and malnourished people. It is undoubtedly a significant challenge

to the discipline of Development Economics. The present thesis is an attempt to contribute to

the understanding of the factors and mechanisms that help determine food-security and

nutrition in this country. In this attempt the thesis concentrates on two different aspects

where one is related to the demand of food whereas the other pertains to the supply side.

Chapters 2 and 3 are an investigation of the role of status competition and conspicuous

consumption in determining choice of food and in turn calorie consumption. Chapter 2

begins by examining the consequences of having preferences that reflect status competition

(Keeping up with the Jones) in the simplest setting. Then as more factors like prices and

incomes are allowed to be determined endogenously in the model a clearer picture of the

potential of Veblen consumption for influencing calorie consumption emerges. The main

takeaways from this chapter is that status competition generates a negative relationship

between peer group income and food consumption holding everything else constant.

However, in a general equilibrium setting with productivity driven economic growth these

same preferences could generate falling calorie consumption provided that the effect of rising

own income was small, or there was rising income inequality within the agent's peer group.

The findings in this chapter give us a few implications which could be either used to test for

Veblen preferences with the appropriate data or at least allow for comparison with the actual

scenario using stylised facts that we know. For example, it is shown that if own income

effect is modest, any economic growth that leads to a rise in incomes keeping relative price

Page 117: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

109

of food constant is liable to reduce food consumption for all groups. This is exactly the

situation in India as described by Deaton and Dreze (2009) during 1985-2004.

Chapter 3 is the empirical investigation that seeks to test the assumptions made in Chapter 1

and also provide some evidence to vindicate the role of status competition in generating the

fall in calorie consumption in India. Using data from rural India and exploiting a unique

source of variation in caste income, estimates of the effect of peer group income on calorie

consumption are obtained. As predicted by the theory, these estimates are negative and

significant. Moreover the magnitude of own income effect is far lower than the negative

effect of peer income. Since this was one of the conditions for calorie reduction outlined in

Chapter 2, this finding reinforces the possibility that status competition has been significantly

contributing to it. Back of the envelope calculations indicate that this factor could be

responsible for a third of the missing calories.

The third chapter also gives us some idea about the mechanism through which status

competition could be influencing calorie consumption. The data does not support the

hypothesis that resources hitherto being used for food purchases are now being used for non-

food items. However, there is some evidence indicating that peer group income increases

calories derived from non-cereal foods, dairy and meat products. This indicates that rather

than considering food in general as a non-conspicuous consumption good, agents only

consider certain food items to be as such. In fact they are shifting away from some of the

traditional foods like cereals towards tastier foods like milk and meat. This finding is

consistent with evidence presented by others (Deaton and Dreze 2009) which shows that

while calorie consumption is falling on an average fat consumption is on the rise. It may also

explain why there is no significant decline in food expenditure.

Page 118: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

110

While Chapters 2 and 3 shed light on one of the determinants of food demand in rural India it

may be argued that for the poor food supply is usually the bigger concern. Adequate food

supplies, made available at affordable prices, is the essence of food security. Fortunately,

unlike food demand, this is an area which can be targeted through government policy. In the

fourth chapter the focus is shifted to the supply side. This chapter aims to evaluate the

efficiency and effectiveness of the biggest food security scheme of the Indian government,

namely, the public food distribution system. The effect of a rise in PDS grain supply on

nutrient consumption is estimated using the differential effect of rain induced PDS supply on

the different PDS regions across the country. Using these estimates it is possible to calculate

the impact of the PDS system on calorie consumption under different assumptions.

The fourth chapter also throws some light on the nature of regional distribution of grains by

the PDS. Due to the lack of domestic production in the Northeast and West zones these

regions are heavily dependent on supplies from other areas. These supplies generally come

from the North zone where most of the surplus grain areas like Punjab and Haryana are

located. This feature builds in a natural variation in the PDS mechanism used to deliver

grain to the different regions. The chapter uses this variation for identification.

The results also contribute to the debate about whether subsidised food (as is the PDS) or

cash transfers to the amount of the intended subsidy should be the preferred method to

achieve food security. However in order to answer this question properly, cross price

elasticities and other income elasticities of demand need to be estimated as well. With the

present level of understanding it is only safe to say that there is a possibility that the

replacement of PDS by cash transfer could negatively impact calorie consumption by as

Page 119: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

111

much as 9 percent of the present level. In the present scenario, where calorie consumption on

an average is low and falling, this sort of impact could prove to be disastrous.

Page 120: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

112

Bibliography

1. Ahluwalia, D. (1993) " Public distribution of food in India : Coverage, targeting and

leakages". Food Policy Volume 18, Issue 1, February 1993, Pages 33–54

2. Alesina, Alberto, Reza Baqir and William Easterly (1999) ‘Public Goods and Ethnic

Divisions’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 1243–84.

3. Anderson, S., (January 2011) “Caste as an Impediment to Trade”, American Economic

Journal: Applied Economics 3: 239–263

4. Banerjee, A.V. and Pande, R. (2007) “Parochial Politics: Ethnic Preferences and Politician

Corruption” BREAD working paper No. 152

5. Banerjee, A., and Duflo, E. (2011) “Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to

Fight Global Poverty”, Public Affairs, New York

6. Banerjee, A., and S. Mullainathan, (May 2010 ) “The Shape of Temptation: Implications for

the Economic Lives of the Poor” NBER Working Paper No. 15973,

7. Behrman, Jere R., and Anil B. Deolalikar. (1987) "Will developing country nutrition improve

with income? A case study for rural South India." The Journal of Political Economy 95.3:

492-507.

8. Bhagwati J. and A. Panagariya, (2014) 'Why growth matters : how economic growth in India

reduced poverty and the lessons for other developing countries'. Chapter 15 "Adult Nutrition

and Food Security". Public Affairs.

9. Card, D. (2001). 'Estimating the return to schooling: Progress on some persistent econometric

problems'. Econometrica, 69(5), 1127-1160.

10. Charles, K. K., Hurst, E., and Roussanov, N., (2009) “Conspicuous Consumption and Race”,

The Quarterly Journal of Economics, May

11. Cherian M. (2013): “Cash transfers are bad for food security”, The Hindu, 11 May

12. Clark, Andrew E. Paul Frijters and Michael A. Shields. “Relative Income, Happiness, and

Utility: An Explanation for the Easterlin Paradox and Other Puzzles (Mar., 2008) "Journal of

Economic Literature , Vol. 46, No. 1, pp. 95-144

13. Clark, Andrew E, and Andrew J. Oswald. (1996) “Satisfaction and comparison income”.

Journal of Public Economics 61 359-381

14. Coelho, P. (1985). “An examination into the causes of economic growth: status as an

economic good”, Research in Law and Economics, vol. 7, pp. 89–116.

15. Cooper, B., Garcia-Penalosa, C. and Funk, P. (2001). “Status effects and negative utility

growth”, Economic Journal, vol. 111, pp. 642–65.

Page 121: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

113

16. Dantwala, M.L., (1993), 'Agricultural Policy: Prices and Public Distribution System',

Indian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol 48, No.2, April - June

17. Deaton, A., & Dreze, J. (2002). Poverty and inequality in India: a re-examination. Economic

and Political Weekly, 3729-3748.

18. Deaton, A., and Dreze J., (2009) “Food and Nutrition in India: Facts and Interpretations,”

Economic and Political Weekly, 44(7), 42–65.

19. Drèze, J., P. Lanjouw, and N. Sharma. (1999). “Economic Development in Palanpur,

1957–93.” In Economic Development in Palanpur Over Five Decades, ed. Peter Lanjouw and

Nicholas Stern, 114–242. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

20. Drèze, J. (2010): “Unique Facility, or Recipe for Trouble”, The Hindu, 25 November.

21. Duesenberry, J. S. (1949). Income, saving, and the theory of consumer behavior (Vol. 87).

Harvard Univ Pr.

22. Du, S, B Lu, F Zhai and B M Popkin (2002): “A New Stage of the Nutrition Transition in

China”, Public Health Nutrition, 5(1A), pp 169-74. Eaton, B. C., and Eswaran, M., “ Well-

being and Affluence in the Presence of a Veblen Good”, The Economic Journal, 119 (July),

1088–1104.

23. Dupor, B. and Wen-Fang Liu (Mar., 2003) “Jealousy and Equilibrium Overconsumption”,

The American Economic Review, Vol. 93, No. 1, pp. 423-428

24. Dutta, B. and B. Ramaswami (2001) " Targeting and Efficiency in the Public Distribution

System: Case of Andhra Pradesh and Maharashtra". Economic and Political Weekly, vol.36,

No. 18 (May 5-11, 2001), pp. 1524-1532

25. Dutta, B. and B. Ramaswami (2000) 'Reforming Food Subsidy Schemes in India:

Estimating the Gains from Self-Selection', mimeo, Indian Statistical Institute

26. Easterlin, Richard A. (1974). "Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some

Empirical Evidence." In Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of

Moses Abramovitz, ed. R. David and M. Reder. New York: Academic Press, 89-125.

27. Easterlin, Richard A. (1995). "Will Raising the Incomes of All Increase the Happiness of

All?" Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 27(1): 35-47.

28. Easterly, W. and R. Levine (1997) ‘Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions’,

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4): 1203–50.

29. Eaton, B. C., and Eswaran, M., (2009) “ Well-being and Affluence in the Presence of a

Veblen Good”, The Economic Journal, 119 (July), 1088–1104.

30. Eswaran, M. and Kotwal. A., (1993) “A Theory of Real Wage Growth in LDCs”, Journal of

Development Economics 42 243-269.

Page 122: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

114

31. Fred Arnold, Sulabha Parasuraman, P. Arokiasamy, and Monica Kothari. (2009). Nutrition in

India. National Family Health Survey (NFHS-3), India, 2005-06. Mumbai: International

Institute for Population Sciences; Calverton, Maryland, USA: ICF Macro

32. Galli, Jordi. (1994) "Keeping Up with the Joneses: Consumption Externalities, Portfolio

Choice and Asset Prices", Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, February, 26(1), pp. 1-8.

33. Gopalan, C, Rama Sastri, B.V & S. C Balasubramanian. (1974) “Nutritive Value of Indian

Foods” National Institute of Nutrition Indian Concil of Medical Research Hyderabad.

34. Gragnolati M., M. Shekar, M. Das Gupta, C. Bredenkamp and Yi-Kyoung Lee. (2005), HNP

Discussion paper: “India’s Undernourished Children: A Call for Reform and Action”

35. Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. (1991) "Quality ladders in the theory of growth."

The Review of Economic Studies 58.1: 43-61.

36. Himanshu and A. Sen (2011): “Why Not a Universal Food Security Legislation?”, Economic

& Political Weekly, 46(12): 38-47.

37. Himanshu (2011): “Food or Cash: The Subsidy Conundrum”, Mint,

http://www.livemint.com/2011/03/01211232/Food-or-Cash-the-subsidy-conu.html?h=B

38. Hnatkovska, V., Lahiri, A., & Paul, S. (2012). Castes and labor mobility. American

Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 4(2), 274-307.

39. Hopkins, E. and Kornienko, T. (2004). “Running to keep in the same place: consumer choice

as a game of Status”, American Economic Review, vol. 94, pp. 1085–107.

40. Indrakant S (2000): "Food Security and Public Support: A Study of Andhra Pradesh" in N

Krishnaji and T N Krishnan (ed), Public Support for Food Security, Sage, New Delhi

41. Jayachandran, S., & Pande, R. (2013). Why Are Indian Children Shorter Than African

Children?. Working paper.

42. Jha, S., & Ramaswami, B. (2010). “How can food subsidies work better? Answers from India

and the Philippines.” (September 1, 2010). Asian Development Bank Economics Working

Paper Series, (221).

43. Jorgenson, Dale W. (1961) "The development of a dual economy." The Economic Journal

71.282: 309-334.

44. Kapur, D., P. Mukhopadhyay and A. Subramanian (2008): “The Case for Direct Cash

Transfers to the Poor”, Economic & Political Weekly, 43(15): 37-43.

45. Keely, Louise C. (2005) “Why isn’t growth making us happier? Utility on the hedonic

treadmill”, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization Vol. 57 333–355

46. Khera, R. (2011a). "Trends In Diversion Of PDS Grain". Economic and Political Weekly,

Vol - XLVI No. 21, May 21.

Page 123: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

115

47. Khera, R. (2011b). 'Revival of the Public Distribution System: Evidence and

Explanations'. Economic and Political Weekly, Vol - XLVI No. 44-45, November 05.

48. Khera, R. (2011c). "India’s Public Distribution System: Utilization and Impact." Journal of

Development Studies, March 07.

49. Kochar, A. (2005). "Can Targeted Programs Improve Nutrition? An Empirical Analysis

Of India’s Public Distribution System." Economic development and cultural change, 54 (1),

20335.

50. Kotwal, A., M. Murugkar and B. Ramaswami (2011): “PDS Forever?”, Economic &

Political Weekly, 46(21): 72-76

51. Kotwal, A. B. Ramaswami, W Wadhwa. (2011) “Economic Liberalization and Indian

Economic Growth: What's the evidence?” Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 49, issue 4,

pages 1152-99

52. Lewis, W.A., (1954), Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour,

Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies 22, 139-191.

53. Li, N., and Eli, S., (2010) “In Search of India’s Missing Calories: Energy Requirements and

Calorie Consumption”, November

54. Linssen. R., L. van Kempen, and G. Kraaykamp. (2010) “Subjective Well-being in Rural

India: The Curse of Conspicuous Consumption”, Published online: 12 May 2010

55. Luttmer, P. (2005). “Neighbours as negatives: relative earnings and well-being”, Quarterly

Journal of Economics, vol. 120, pp. 963–1002.

56. Metcalf, Thomas R. (1979). Land, Landlords, and the British Raj: northern India in the

nineteenth Century. Berkeley: University of California Press.

57. Mehta, J. and Shanta Venkatraman. (Jul. 1-7, 2000) “Poverty Statistics: Bermicide's Feast”

Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 35, No. 27, pp. 2377-2379+2381-2382

58. Meng, X, X Gong and Y Wang (2009): “Impact of Income Growth and Economic Reform on

Nutrition Availability in Urban China: 1986-2000”, Economic Development and Cultural

Change, 57(2), 261-95.

59. Munshi, K. and M. Rosenzweig (2006), “Traditional Institutions Meet the Modern World:

Caste, Gender, and Schooling Choice in a Globalizing Economy” The American Economic

Review, Vol. 96, No. 4 pp. 1225-1252

60. Munshi, K. and M. Rosenzweig. (2005). “Why is Mobility in India so Low? Social

Insurance, Inequality, and Growth.” Bureau for Research and Economic Analysis of

Development (BREAD) Working Paper 097.

Page 124: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

116

61. Munshi, K. and M. Rosenzweig, (2009) Why is mobility in India so low? Social insurance,

inequality, and growth. No. w14850. National Bureau of Economic Research.

62. Nawani, N.P. (1994) " Indian experience on household food and nutrition security" Food and

Agricultural Organisation of United Nations. Chapter 6

63. Neale, Walter C. (1962). Economic Change in Rural India; Land Tenure and Reform in

Uttar Pradesh, 1800–1955. New Haven: Yale University Press.

64. Nunn, N., and N. Qian. (2012). “ Aiding Conflict: The Impact of U.S. Food Aid on Civil

War”. Working Paper 17794. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

65. Palmer-jones, R., & Sen, K. (2001). "On Indian Poverty Puzzles and Statistics of Poverty" .

Economic and Political Weekly , 201-17.

66. Panagariya, A. (2013). Does India Really Suffer from Worse Child Malnutrition Than Sub-

Saharan Africa?. Economic & Political Weekly, 48(18), 98-111.

67. Parikh, K (1994): 'Who Gets How Much from PDS - How Effectively Does It Reach the

Poor?', Sarvekshana, January-March

68. Patnaik, U. (2004). "The Republic of Hunger". Social Scientist , 9-35.- (2007) “Neoliberalism

and Rural Poverty in India”. Economic and Political Weekly 3132-50

69. Planning Commission (2005). 'Performance Evaluation of Targeted Public Distribution

System (TPDS).' Programme Evaluation Organisation. Government of India.

70. Planning Commission (2007, 20012), 'Press Notes on Poverty Estimates'

71. Radhakrishna, R. (2005). “Food and Nutrition Security of the Poor: Emerging Perspectives

and Policy Issues”. Economic and Political Weekly 1817-21

72. Radhakrishna, R. K. Subbarao with S. Indrakant and C.Ravi. (1997). " India's public

distribution system: a national and international perspective" World Bank discussion papers ;

no. 380

73. Ramaswami, B. and P. Balakrishnan (2002) "Food prices and the efficiency of public

intervention: the case of the public distribution system in India" Food Policy 27 (2002)

419–436

74. Ray, R & Lancaster, G (2005) “On Setting the Poverty Line Based on Estimated Nutrient

Prices: Condition of Socially Disadvantaged Groups during the Reform Period”,Economic &

Political Weekly, 40(1), 1 January, 46-56.

75. Smith, A. (1759) “The Theory of Moral Sentiments” London, A Milar

76. Srinivas, M.N. (1952). “ Religion and Society Among the Coorgs of South India”

(Oxford, 1952), p. 30:

Page 125: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

117

77. Subramanian, S. and Angus Deaton, (1996) “The Demand for Food and Calories”, Journal of

Political Economy, Vol. 104, No. 1, pp. 133-162

78. Svedberg, P. (2012) 'Reforming or Replacing the Public Distribution System with Cash

Transfers?' Economic & Political Weekly Vol XLVII no 7

79. Veblen, T. (1899). “The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study of Institutions”,

New York: Macmillan Company.

Page 126: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

118

Appendix to Chapter 2

Proposition 1: Consumption of the non-Veblen good falls with the average income of the

group once the agent has started consuming Veblen good.

Proof: This can be shown for any general utility function of the form assumed in the text.

The agent’s problem is as follows:

Taking the Lagrange multiplier to be λ we have the first order conditions as follows:

This of course assumes that the poor have enough money to consume some Z. Then totally

differentiating with respect to we have:

The RHS is less than 0 since , , and average Z is sure to go up with

average income as long as any single person has been satiated with food in the group.

Page 127: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

119

Solving the General Equilibrium

Using the production functions and resources specified in the main body of the paper we may

calculate incomes of the two types of agents (landlords and landless labourers). Agents

receive wages for their labour which is equal to the marginal product of labour and the

landlords get rent from land which is also the marginal product of land. So if w and v are the

wage and rental rates respectively we can write the incomes of the two groups as follows

Also profit maximization for the industrial good implies that marginal cost of producing one

more unit of industrial good is equal to the wage. So we have:

p = w/B ... (A.3)

Also assume that

... (A.4)

and

... (A.5),

which are the market clearing conditions for land and labour. Next we use Walras’ law to

drop the market clearing condition for the industrial good, and hence we can concentrate on

the food market clearing condition using the demand functions given in equation 2.1 in the

main body of the chapter.

Page 128: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

120

The food market clearing equation can be of three kinds depending on which equilibrium we

are in. The first is the case where neither group is rich enough to consume Z. So all income is

spent on food. The supply of grain is given by the production function. So in equilibrium we

must have:

Next if the landlords have been satiated with food but the workers have not we have:

Here I have used equations (A.1) and (A.3) to substitute the values of p and w in the food

threshold expression. Lastly we come to the last equilibrium where both income groups are

satiated with food and have started consuming Z:

Since the relative price of the industrial good and the incomes can be expressed in terms of

we can write all three above equations in terms of the labour allocation to agriculture.

From here we calculate which solves the general equilibrium because the incomes and the

relative price of the Veblen good p, can be easily calculated using equations (A.1), (A.2) and

(A.3).

Proof of Proposition 2

Proposition 2: In an equilibrium where all agents are satiated with the necessary good X,

allocation of labour to the agricultural sector will fall with any rise in either industrial or

agricultural productivity.

Page 129: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

121

Proof: The market clearing condition for X determines the allocation of labour to the

agricultural sector . This is the key variable in this model which can be used to then

calculate all the remaining incomes prices and consumptions. This key equation is given by

equation (A.6.3) as:

Here

as given by equation (A.3) and

.

Substituting in the values of we can write the relevant grain market equilibrium

condition (equation (A.6.3)) as follows:

It can be easily verified that increases in both A and B would cause the LHS to increase

leaving the system in disequilibrium. In order to re-equalise the two sides will have to

adjust. So it remains to be seen how the LHS responds to a rise in . If LHS rises with

then a rise in productivity parameters A and B would cause a fall in the equilibrium value

for in this model. Differentiating the LHS with respect to we have the following:

Page 130: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

122

If the expression (A.8) above turns out to be positive then we may conclude that allocation of

labour to agriculture falls with a rise in productivity. The expression A1 has two parts. The

first of these, which is always positive, goes to infinity as (as long as ). The

second part is negative and its magnitude is highest at . This is a finite quantity given

by

So since the positive part can be very large and the negative part is finite for any parameter

value we may conclude that there always exists some for which (A.8) is positive and

falls with a rise in productivity. It remains to be seen whether expression (A.8) is positive or

not at the equilibrium value of . In order to check this I substitute into (A.8) the equation

(A.7) which gives us the equilibrium value of .

Equation (A.7) may be rewritten as follows:

Substituting in the value of the LHS from above into expression (A.8.1) we have:

Page 131: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

123

This above expression is always positive as lies in between 0 and 1. Thus (A.8.1) is

always positive at the equilibrium . Hence allocation of labour to the agricultural sector

always falls when either of the productivity parameters is raised.

Model with Positive Income Effect

The fact that we observe this falling calorie consumption is due to the two important

assumptions. First is the assumption of “Keeping up with the Joneses” (KUJ) which pushes

up the marginal utility of Z with rising average income. The second important assumption is

that of quasi-linearity which means that there is no income effect to the consumption of X.

For a necessary good like X having no income effect at high levels of income is resonable.

But one may want to see what happens in the model if there is some income effect. In order

to do that I need to remove the quasi-linearity from the preferences. Here I apply the simplest

modification conserving KUWJ and jealousy but replacing the linear term with Z by a

concave one:

Page 132: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

124

Here measures the strength of KUJ feature in the utility function. Higher is greater is

the rise in marginal product of Z with peer group income/ Z consumption. With this utility

we can calculate the implicit demand functions as follows:

As expected this demand also goes down with group income, but in this case food demand is

also positively related to own income. So whether food demand falls or not depends on how

own incomes and the peer group income change in the general equilibrium.

Proposition 4: A sufficient condition for the equilibrium labour allocation to agriculture to

fall with a rise in industrial or agricultural productivity is:

Proof: The equilibrium condition for the market for X is as follows:

Substituting in the values in terms of , and with some simplification this can be reduced to

the following:

Clearly, the LHS goes up with any increase of A. But a rise in B causes LHS to rise only

if . Let us suppose for the time being that . Now, in order to prove the

proposition we need to see if the LHS rises with . Differentiating we get:

Page 133: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

125

The expression (A.10) above is clearly positive for all . But this is not necessary. Even

for higher values of the expression (A.10) may turn out to be positive for some values

of . To see this I look at the value of expression (A.10) in equilibrium by substituting

equation (A.9) into expression (A.10):

Again this expression cannot be negative if . But even for higher this may be positive

for low values of .

The intuition for this result is slightly involved. First note that if food demand will

increase with a rise in B. To see this, note that a rise in B impacts food demand through two

different channels. Firstly, through “Keeping up with the Jones”, via a rise in

average/aggregate production of Z at the same labour allocation. This effect reduces food

demand. It is in turn countered by the fall in price of Z (which increases demand for food).

Page 134: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

126

If the impact of a falling price dominates and demand for food goes up. This would

result in an inflow of labour to the agricultural sector and not out.40

But very high is also a problem in this model. The reason is the dependence of food

demand on the aggregate Z production. After the initial productivity shock the system tries to

restore equilibrium by adjusting (proportion of labour working in agriculture). When

falls aggregate Z production goes up. If the impact of this on food demand is too big it may

never reach equilibrium (food demand falls faster than food supply), or it may reach an

equilibrium by increasing .

When , is not so low as to increase food demand with B and neither so high as to

make food demand fall faster than supply. Hence we would observe falling with rising A

or B. But it should also be pointed out that is a sufficient condition. As above, even

for some food demand may be falling slower than supply with decreasing . The

speed of adjustment of these quantities also depends on the initial equilibrium , before the

productivity shock occurs. So if the initial was low enough we may have falling with

productivity even for some .

Calorie Reduction

Note that no calorie reduction will be observed if does not fall with rise in productivity

parameters in this model. If were to rise, aggregate food production would rise even with

no rise in agricultural productivity, implying that some if not all would have to be consuming

more food. So we expect calorie reduction only when falls. But, this is not enough to

40 Also note, due to the way the industrial sector is set up, any rise in B leaves the expenditure on Z ( unchanged. Hence any change in equilibrium labour allocation will have to be due to changes in the food

market induced by changes in price or average Z consumption

Page 135: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

127

ensure calorie reduction as it was in the earlier model. Here we have the income effect to

contend with. While a falling and rising B reduces food demand a rise in income pulls it

in the opposite direction. Of course higher is , greater is the negative impact of the falling

. In the end it boils down to whether the income effect would dominate or the KUJ effect.

Any further conclusions about calorie reduction is difficult to make as I do not have a closed

form solution for . But simulations may give us some further insight into the possibility. In

particular I can display the influence of the KUJ parameter by simulating the food demand

through the model for different values of . In the following table I start with the following

initial parameter values: A=1, B=1, , and . For this combination of

parameters, equilibrium values of the key variables of the model are given below for

comparison:

A B Price ( Z)

1 1 0.44 1.0612 1.06 2.95 0.65 1.81

Here represent food demands and represents incomes of the landless and

landowners respectively

Next I raise A to 2, increase B keeping price constant about 1.0612 and not the changes in

incomes and food demand for the two groups. Then I repeated the process for subsequently

higher values of .

Page 136: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

128

A B Price(Z)

1.7 1 1 0.44 1.06 1.06 2.95 0.65 1.81

2 3.18 0.18 1.06 3.37 5.74 1.01 1.72

1.9 1 1 0.47 1.02 1.02 2.97 0.66 1.97

2 3.66 0.14 1.02 3.73 5.87 0.93 1.47

2 1 1 0.49 1 1 2.99 0.66 1.99

2 4 .125 1 4 6 0.88 1.33

2.2 1 1 0.99 0.7 0.71 3.53 0.71 3.53

2 8.3 0.06 0.7 5.87 7.23 0.64 0.77

In each case, (characterized by different values of ), I find that incomes of both groups rise

after the rise in productivity parameters. The relative price of Z has been kept constant at the

original level. Food demand for landowners always falls after the process of productivity

increase. For lower food demand for the landless agent are rising, but note that as we go to

higher levels of (stronger KUWJ) this increase gets smaller and smaller till when

we see a fall in food demand for both groups. The simulations give us an indication that even

without quasilinear specification it is possible to observe calorie reduction if the KUWJ

aspect in the preferences are strong enough. The graphs below simulate the model for an

increase in A from 1 to 3, with B increasing correspondingly to hold relative price constant.

This exercise is carried out for 4 different values of , 1.9, 2.0, 2.1 and 2.15.

Table A.1: Simulation Showing the effect of Rising Productivity on Food Demand for Increasing

Values of

Notes: There are four sets of simulations reported for increasing values of as indicated in Column 1. For each

simulation there are two sets of productivity parameters (second set having higher values) across whom relative

price of the industrial good is held constant (fifth column). The values of other parameters are held constant for

these simulations are given on page 100.

Page 137: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

129

The Figure A.1 above, displays how total food consumption evolves as we increase

productivity parameters keeping relative price of Z constant. As expected this is increasing

for lower s but eventually turns negatively sloped for higher . Figures A.2 and A.3 are

similar to the first one, except that they show the food consumption of the landless and the

landowners separately. Food consumption of the landless is a concave function which

becomes more and more concave with higher . Eventually for we observe

falling food consumption at higher values of productivity. On the other hand the

landowner’s consumption of food is always falling. The persistent fall in the landlord’s food

consumption may be attributed to the fact that with falling land rental rates are falling and

hence landlord’s total income does not rise as fast as the landless labourer’s income.

Page 138: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

130

Page 139: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

131

Proof of Proposition 5:

Proposition 5: In the equilibrium where all are satiated with food, any increase in industrial

or agricultural productivity (represented by the parameters B and A respectively) leads to a

fall in the equilibrium labour allocation to agricultural sector.

Proof: The grain market equilibrium condition (equation (2.10)) in this case is given as

follows (after substituting in the value of p from equation (2.9). The LHS is the combined

food demand for all agents indexed 0 to 1 and the RHS is the food supply:

First note that whenever A or B increases, ceteris paribus, the LHS goes up by less than the

RHS.

The only way to re –equate the two sides of the equation is to decrease (leading to a fall

in the RHS and a rise in the LHS). The other source of variation in the LHS is the term

. But as is shown in the proof of the next proposition below, this term falls when incomes

go up in this model. As a result this would cause the LHS to fall further leading to a further

lowering of . This is the enhancing effect of the Veblen term that was talked about in the

main text.

Proof of Proposition 6:

Proposition 6: In an equilibrium where all are satiated with food, if productivity parameters

both rise keeping the relative price constant, (capital allocation of the agent with index

Page 140: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

132

i=0) is large enough to ensure that the poorest person's income is going up, then food

consumption falls for all agents

Proof: The demand for food in this case is given by the following:

Where is the average Z consumption of all agents with income greater than i.

Since p is held constant the only thing driving the food demand is the difference

between own and peer group’s consumption of Z

In this equilibrium all extra income accrued due to the rise in the productivity

parameters goes into consumption of Z

All changes in income from land and labor are common for all hence any change in

the difference between own and peer group’s consumption of Z has to be driven by

changes in capital income. (Note that incomes will rise for all given our assumption

about k0)

In other words, if the difference in capital income of a particular agent and that of his peer

group rises then food consumption will fall.

Assuming that the change in the rental rate of capital due to the change in productivity

parameters is , we can write that food consumption falls for agent j if:

Or

Page 141: Essays on Some Determinants of Food-Security and ...

133

The expression within the curly brackets is always negative owing to the fact that .

So this condition is satisfied for all j . Hence food consumption goes down for all

agents.