Top Banner

of 26

Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

Apr 06, 2018

Download

Documents

Jerry Solow
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    1/26

    European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921

    Endogenous institutional change after independence

    Heather Congdon Fors, Ola Olsson

    Department of Economics, School of Business, Economics, and Law, Go teborg University,

    Box 640, 405 30 Goteborg, Sweden

    Received 10 June 2005; accepted 15 January 2007

    Available online 4 May 2007

    Abstract

    Independence from colonial rule was a key event for both political and economic reasons. We

    argue that newly independent countries often inherited sub-optimal institutional arrangements,

    which the new regimes reacted to in very different ways. We present a model of endogenous changes

    in property rights institutions where an autocratic post-colonial elite faces a basic trade-off between

    stronger property rights, which increases the dividends from the modern sector, and weaker property

    rights that increases the elites ability to appropriate resource rents. The model predicts that revenue-maximizing regimes in control of an abundance of resource rents and with insignificant interests in

    the modern sector will rationally install weak institutions of private property, a prediction which we

    argue is well in line with the experience of several developing countries.

    r 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    JEL classification: O17; O57; P14

    Keywords: Institutions; Property rights; Independence; Resource rents; Rent seeking

    1. Introduction

    The rules that societies live by have proven to be crucial for all kinds of economic

    development. A number of recent studies have established links between the general

    quality of countries economic institutions and, for instance, income per capita (Hall and

    Jones, 1999; Acemoglu et al. (AJR), 2001, 2002; Easterly and Levine, 2003; Acemoglu and

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    www.elsevier.com/locate/eer

    0014-2921/$ - see front matterr 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.euroecorev.2007.01.010

    Corresponding author. Tel.: +46 31 7731341; fax: +46 31 773 1326.

    E-mail addresses: [email protected] (H. Congdon Fors), [email protected](O. Olsson).

    http://www.elsevier.com/locate/eerhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2007.01.010mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2007.01.010http://www.elsevier.com/locate/eer
  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    2/26

    Johnson, 2005; Olsson and Hibbs, 2005). Perhaps more difficult to understand is what

    explains the wide international variation in measures of institutional quality. Empirical

    and theoretical efforts in this tradition have typically focused on deep historical

    explanations such as the various effects of colonialism (Acemoglu et al., 2001, 2002;

    Sokoloff and Engerman, 2000) or the role of the sovereign in the legal and economicsystems of medieval Spain, France, and Britain (North, 1990; Glaeser and Shleifer, 2002).

    However, although institutions typically display a high degree of persistence, we argue that

    the institutional configuration of countries is also influenced by more recent circumstances.

    The central issue that we address in this article is why more or less equally autocratic

    regimes installed widely different institutions for private property after independence. In

    countries like Singapore, the government pursued a strengthening of property rights and of

    the protection against government expropriation, whereas development was quite the

    reverse in some initially relatively developed countries like Ghana and Zambia. The major

    hypothesis advanced in this article is that the relative importance of natural resource rents

    played a central role for post-independence institutional development. The development

    literature contains numerous anecdotal accounts of how large inflows of easily

    appropriable rents from oil and valuable minerals provided rulers in developing countries

    with strong incentives towards expropriation of private property (Bates, 1981; Bates and

    Collier, 1993; Ndikumana and Boyce, 1998; Bigsten, 2001, Sala-i-Martin and Subrama-

    nian, 2003). Several econometric studies have also confirmed the negative relationship

    between natural resource abundance and institutional quality (Leite and Weidmann, 1999;

    Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian, 2003); Dalgaard and Olsson, 2007).

    In order to understand this phenomenon, we present a model of endogenous change in

    property rights institutions and executive constraints. We take as given the deeperhistorical effects of for instance the disease environment and the identity of the colonizer,

    and model endogenous institutional choice for a more or less autocratic elite who

    maximize their own utility in a two-period setting. The first period starts at independence

    and is typically characterized by sub-optimal property rights institutions from the

    perspective of the new regime.1 The ruling elite has economic interests in a modern, formal

    sector but can also appropriate rents from a natural resource sector. These circumstances

    imply that the ruling elite faces a basic trade-off between weak and strong institutions of

    private property. Strong property rights will make the modern sector prosper and raise the

    ruling elites incomes from that sector. Weaker property rights, on the other hand, means a

    poorly functioning modern economy but makes the ruling elites expropriation of resourcerents easier.

    Our model predicts that ruling elites are more inclined to weaken property rights if easily

    appropriable natural resource rents abound, whereas the lack of an easy rents-sector

    coupled with substantial interests in a modern sector will motivate even an autocratic

    ruling elite to install stronger private property rights, which in turn results in higher

    growth. The costs of institutional change also play a central role in our model. In addition,

    a higher initial level of property rights protection will diminish, in some instances even

    negate, the negative impact of natural resource abundance on growth, as demonstrated

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    1See Acemoglu et al. (2001, 2002) for possible explanations as to why colonial powers might establish extractive

    institutions in the colonies. Further, Djankov et al. (2003) argue that the institutions put in place by colonial

    powers were likely to be inefficient, even when the colonizers attempted to transplant their own institutional

    arrangements directly.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1897

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    3/26

    empirically by Mehlum et al. (2006).2 Therefore, the initial level of property rights

    protection plays an important role in both the incentive faced by the ruling elites to

    strengthen or weaken property rights as well as the cost constraint faced by the ruling

    elites. In this respect our model maintains a strong aspect of institutional persistence, as

    argued by authors such as Acemoglu et al. (2001, 2002, 2005) and Acemoglu and Robinson(2005), while at the same time allowing for more recent events to play a key role in the

    formation of property rights institutions.

    We argue that the main insight from our model is well in line with observed post-

    colonial experiences in many developing countries.3 Although independence from colonial

    rule is the main type of change that we have in mind, we believe that our model might also

    have relevance for understanding the institutional choices after other discontinuous regime

    shifts such as the transition from communism, or even the onset of colonization. Indeed,

    Beck and Laeven (2006) find evidence that natural resources have been a major

    impediment to institutional development in transition economies.

    Our research extends a long tradition stretching back to Adam Smith that emphasizes

    the central role of property rights in development (Coase, 1960; Demsetz, 1967; Alchian

    and Demsetz, 1973; North, 1981, 1990; Firmin-Sellers, 1995; de Soto, 2000). Our argument

    about the forces behind the choice between weak and strong private property rights is to

    some extent inspired by Acemoglu et al.s (2001, 2002) colonial theory of how European

    settlers installed extractive institutions when the disease environment was hostile for

    permanent settlement and when there were easily exploitable human resources (proxied by

    population density and degree of urbanization). According to the same logic, strong

    institutions were created where permanent European settlement was feasible. The formal

    model in this article shares the basic prediction in Acemoglu et al. (2002, 2005) work that aregimes own interests in a progressive sector as well as the existence of easily appropriated

    rents are crucial for understanding institutional choice.

    Like North (1981), Acemoglu and Johnson (2005), and Djankov et al. (2003), we

    recognize that property rights institutions affect the economy along two dimensions. The

    first dimension is the relationship between common men, for instance whether private

    property is secure against expropriation by a neighbor. The second dimension is the

    interaction between ruling elite and subject and to what extent the government can

    expropriate means from the people. In their empirical efforts to unbundle institutions to

    determine what kind of influence different institutions have, Acemoglu and Johnson (2005)

    show that property rights constraining the ruling elite from expropriation appear to be themore important dimension for development.4 Furthermore, Glaeser et al. (2004) show in

    their empirical analysis that almost all former colonies in 1960 were dictatorships. The

    crucial question that arises from their analysis, and which we examine in this article, is why

    some autocratic ruling elites pursued growth-oriented policies (such as strengthening

    property rights institutions) while others did not.

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    2See Sachs and Warner (2001), Gylfason (2001), and Woolcock et al. (2001) for discussions of the possible

    reasons for the observed curse of natural resources.3See the working paper version of this article (Congdon Fors and Olsson, 2005) for a more lengthy discussion of

    how post-colonial developments in Singapore, DR Congo, Botswana, Zambia, and Ghana are conducive to ourmodel.

    4Throughout the article, we will use property rights institutions and constraints against the executive as

    synonymous terms, reflecting the elites respect for private or state ownership. Respect for state ownership means

    that the elite does not regard state-owned property as their own.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211898

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    4/26

    This issue is also treated in a recent work by Rajan and Zingales (2006). Their basic

    argument is that it is the particular configuration of constituencies rather than political

    institutions that is the key for understanding why bad policies often prevail despite their

    social inefficiency. In their model, comprehensive reforms (expansion of education and

    removal of barriers to entry in the modern sector) are often blocked because oligopolistsand an educated class create a kind of unholy alliance that keep the masses out of

    education and everyone but the oligopolists out of business ownership. In a voting game

    between the three constituencies, it is shown that comprehensive reforms will only be

    carried out when the educated class is relatively large and when the oligopolists are very

    efficient. Rajan and Zingales model is different from ours in at least two crucial respects:

    Firstly, there is no state or government in the Rajan and Zingales framework, only three

    constituencies. In our model, a potentially predatory government plays a key role, as in

    many developing countries. Secondly, Rajan and Zingales type of pro-market reforms is

    essentially about removing barriers to entry in an initially oligopolistic market whereas the

    type of reform that we consider is a strengthening of protection against government

    expropriation for all.

    Finally, like us, Svensson (1998) analyzes the potential reasons why a government does

    not invest in stronger property rights. The basic reason in Svenssons model is that ruling

    elites are uncertain about staying in power due to political instability and hence do not

    internalize the full benefit of institutional investment, a scenario which differs from ours

    where the potential for capturing rents is the key feature. Other models of property rights

    and growth include Tornell (1997) and Sonin (2003).

    The paper is organized as follows. Section two outlines the ruling elites basic trade-off

    in terms of investment in property rights institutions and proceeds by presenting a solutionto the full model. Section three then makes labor supply endogenous and introduces

    variations such as trade liberalization. Section four concludes the paper.

    2. The model

    In this section, we present and discuss the main assumptions in a two-period model of an

    autocratic ruling elites endogenous choice of costly property rights reforms. For

    simplicity, we assume that the ruling elite does not have to worry about being overthrown

    as long as they provide a minimum of public goods.5 The country has just emerged from

    independence and the ruling elite has inherited property rights institutions from a formercolonial regime. While it is possible that these institutions are optimal, it is more likely that

    they are not. As will be shown, the model serves to explain how it even might be optimal

    for a ruling elite to weaken property rights institutions.

    2.1. Basics

    A central element of our model is that property rights institutions and constraints

    against the executive should be weak in former colonies where the relative importance of

    natural resource rents is strong. The empirical case for this assumption is illustrated in

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    5There is a growing literature studying the mechanisms through which non-benevolent rulers might stay in

    power for decades in developing countries despite the presence of potential rebels (Olsson and Congdon Fors,

    2004; Acemoglu et al., 2003).

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1899

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    5/26

    Figs. 1a and b. Fig. 1a shows the conditional correlation between a measure of rule of law

    and strength of property rights in 2004 on the vertical axis and the share of energy and

    mineral rents to GNI in 1999 on the horizontal axis for 67 former colonies (see A1 for a

    presentation of the variables and estimations involved). The underlying equation includes

    a number of geographical control variables plus Acemoglu et al.s (2001) variable LogSettler Mortality, which is widely interpreted as a proxy for the quality of property rights

    institutions during colonial times. In line with previous findings mentioned in the

    introduction, both settler mortality and our natural resource measure have a strong and

    statistically significant negative association with the rule of law.

    In Fig. 1b, we replace the previous resource variable with the log of country area. This

    variable is often seen as a proxy for natural resource wealth (Sachs and Warner, 1997) as

    well as a (negative) determinant of openness to trade (Frankel and Romer, 1999). In this

    specification, the negative estimate for our natural resource variable is even more

    significant (t-value 5:27). Thus, even after controlling for a proxy for colonial history,natural resource rents appear to have a strong negative impact on property rights

    institutions.6

    For the individual country, our theory builds on the notion that countries that had a

    large flow of resource rents at independence should experience a weakening of institutional

    strength. This should at least be true until the end of the Cold War around 1990, an event

    which gave rise to a trend break with a steadily increasing political freedom in most

    developing countries. Statistical assessments of our institutional assumptions are

    complicated by the fact that extensive time series for institutional variables are rare. In

    Fig. 2, we use a variable called Executive constraints from the Polity IV dataset where a

    high score (max +7) indicates that the executive is effectively constrained by law and isregularly held accountable by a legislature or in elections (Marshall and Jaggers, 2003),

    whereas a low score (1) implies unlimited authority, or that the state, for some reason, is

    not functioning 1.7

    We focus here on development from independence until 1991 in three countries that are

    all heavily endowed with natural resource rentsNigeria, Republic of Congo, and

    Zambia. The first two countries are indeed the two most resource-rich countries in Fig. 1a.

    Furthermore, Nigeria is maybe the most important case in Africa given its size and huge oil

    rents.8 As Fig. 2 shows, Nigerias score fell from 7 to 1 or 1 after independence with a

    short period of good years in the early 1980s. Republic of Congo and Zambia both

    experienced a steady decline throughout the period. Although these trends do not establishany proof of the validity of our assumption, they are well in line with anecdotal evidence

    cited in the Introduction. In a more extensive working paper, we provide further

    qualitative evidence in favor of our hypothesis from Singapore, DR Congo, Botswana,

    Zambia, and Ghana (Congdon Fors and Olsson, 2006).

    Let us now proceed with the model. Let us assume a scenario with an autocratic ruling

    elite who is primarily motivated by the possibility of making personal revenue with the

    least possible effort. The ruling elite has two potential sources of personal gain: Their

    private (non-state) interests in a modern sector that operates on the world market and a

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    6For a more complete discussion of this type of results in the literature, see Dalgaard and Olsson (2007).7We have given a score of 1 to what the dataset refers to as interregnum, transitional, or interruption

    episodes.8See Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian (2003) for an account of how oil rents have affected the Nigerian society.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211900

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    6/26

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    MLIGM B

    CIV

    TG O

    SLE

    UG A

    PAN

    RW A

    GH A

    CA F

    MDG

    KEN

    NER

    LK ABFA

    CR I

    ZAR

    TCD

    HTI

    TZA

    SLV

    BRB

    HN D

    DOM

    SEN

    BHS

    PRY

    SGP

    GT MBGD

    JA M

    SDN

    GIN

    URY

    PER

    BRAMA RSUR

    BOL

    US A

    ARG

    IND

    HKG

    MU S

    AUSNZLEG Y

    VNM

    PAK

    CM R

    TUN

    CO L

    ME X

    IDN

    CH L

    ZAFCAN

    MYS

    GU Y

    TTO

    ECU

    VEN

    MRT

    DZ AAG O

    NG A

    COG

    Ruleoflaw

    0

    BRB

    HK G

    MUS

    SGP

    GM B

    TTO

    JAM

    BHS

    NZLRW A

    HTI

    SLVTGO

    SLEDOM

    CR I

    PAN

    LK ATUN

    UR YSEN

    BGD

    GH A

    GIN

    GTM

    HN D

    NIC

    BFA

    CIV

    UGA

    MD G

    CA N

    COG

    MA R

    VNMCMR

    MLI

    SURNG A

    PRY

    CAF

    GUY

    MR TUS A

    ECU

    CH L

    KEN

    NE R

    TCD

    PAK

    AUS

    AGO

    MM R

    TZAEG YZAF

    MYS

    BOL

    VEN

    SDN

    ARGDZA

    ME X

    PERCOL

    ZAR

    IDN

    INDBRA

    Ruleoflaw

    -6 -4 -2 0 2 4

    2

    1

    0

    -1

    -2

    -0.1

    Energy and mineral rents/GNI

    0.1 0.2 0.3

    2

    1

    0

    -1

    -2

    Log of country area

    a

    b

    Fig. 1. (a) Partial scatter plot, Rule of law in 2004 vs energy and mineral depletion as a share of GNI in 1999

    among former colonies. Note: The figure shows the conditional correlation between the two variables in a

    multivariate regression. The estimated underlying equation in the figure is: Rule of law in 2004 0:9135(constant) t 1:53 1:66 Nrg_Min1999/GNI t 2:34 0:283 Log Settler Mortality t 2:33 0:010 Latitude t 1:10 0:129 Sub-Saharan Africa dummy t 0:58 1:164 Neo-Europe dummyt 3:77. R2 0:54, N 67. OLS-estimator with robust standard errors was used. See Appendix A1 forvariable descriptions. (b) Partial scatter plot, Rule of law in 2004 vs Log of country area among former colonies.

    Note: The figure shows the conditional correlation between the two variables in a multivariate regression. The

    estimated underlying equation in the figure is: Rule of law in 2004 2:71 (constant) t 4:61 0:183 Logareat 5:27 0:237 Log Settler Mortality t 2:47 0:016 Latitude t 2:27 0:012 Sub-SaharanAfrica dummy t 0:94 1:74 Neo-Europe dummy t 5:47. R2 0:65, N 69. OLS-estimator withrobust standard errors was used. See Appendix A1 for variable descriptions.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1901

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    7/26

    more or less easily appropriable flow of rents from a state-controlled natural resource

    sector. These incomes are available in a current as well as in a future period. The ruling

    elite also controls (but cannot make personal gain of) the government budget with

    revenues from the natural resource sector and income taxes on labor. In order to avoid

    being overthrown, the ruling elite has to supply a fixed (minimum) amount of public goods

    like infrastructure, defense, and police to uphold the most fundamental functions of thestate. What remains in the public budget can be spent on costly reforms of the prevailing

    property rights institutions. It is assumed that all changes in property rights, regardless

    of whether they involve a weakening or a strengthening or rights, give rise to direct costs.

    The ruling elite gains utility only from personal enrichment.

    These basic assumptions are summarized in Eq. (1), showing the ruling elites utility

    function in general form:

    Ur R0 M0 ejZ1 Z0j dR1Z1 M1Z1. (1)

    The utility of the ruling elite is a simple linear function of wealth in the form of current and

    future expropriated rents R0 and R1Z1 and of current and future profits from the rulingelites private interests in the modern sector M0 and M1Z1. Utility is also a negative

    function of the effort of changing property rights ejZ1 Z0j. dp1 is a time discount

    factor. Z1 is the quality of property rights institutions and constraints against the executive

    in the future period and is the ruling elites key choice variable. They have inherited a

    property rights regime of strength Z0 and consider increasing or decreasing this level. The

    personal costs of these changes are a function of the absolute level of Z1 Z0 DZ such

    that e0jDZj40 and e0 0. In other words, investments over the prevailing level

    DZ40 give rise to an equally large disutility as disinvestments DZo0 and the least

    disutility is gained from status quo DZ 0 when no effort at all is exerted in either

    direction.A central assumption of the paper is that R01Z1o0 since weak constraints against the

    executive makes expropriation of natural resource rents for personal gain easier. With

    strong constraints against the executive, the ruling elite will be unable to use the state

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    -2

    -1

    0

    1

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    8

    1960 1964 1968 1988

    Executiveconstrain

    ts

    Nigeria

    Congo, Rep.

    Zambia

    1972 1976 1980 1984

    Year

    Fig. 2. Development of Executive constraints since independence in three resource-rich countries. Note: The

    variable in question is referred to as XCONST in Marshall and Jaggers (2003).

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211902

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    8/26

    companies as a source of personal revenue. Equivalently, M01Z140 because stronger

    property rights has a positive effect on total output in the modern sector as well as a

    positive net effect on ruler rents. We assume that the specific mechanism through which

    stronger property rights translates into greater modern sector rents for the ruling elite is

    private firm ownership. If firms have a safe legal environment, transaction costs arereduced, firms produce more and even the elites profits increase. Direct expropriation of

    modern sector profits is assumed to be impossible since firms operate on the world market

    and could relatively easily shut down production and move elsewhere.9 The natural

    resource sector, on the other hand, is highly immobile and therefore an ideal object of

    expropriations. The price of expropriating resource rents is of course that modern sector

    output shrinks.

    The assumption that the same type of property rights institutions affect the natural

    resource sector and the modern sector is a cornerstone of our model. A potential objection

    might be that the institutions constraining the ruling elite from expropriating natural

    resource rents are different from the institutions affecting modern sector output. If that

    was the case, there would be no trade-off of the kind modelled here and a kleptocratic

    ruling elite should simply minimize the constraints against expropriation in the natural

    resource sector and maximize the strength of private property rights in the modern

    sector.10

    However, as will be specified below, it will be assumed here that the ruling elites revenue

    from the modern sector comes from private minority share-holding. Since the ruling elite

    thus is directly involved both in the resource sector (through state-ownership) and in the

    modern sector (through private ownership), firm-owners in the modern sector who are not

    part of the elite will judge the quality of property rights by the standards of behavior thatthe ruling elite employs in the resource sector. If the ruling elite steals natural resource

    rents from the state-owned companies for their own enrichment, rational firm-owners will

    expect that the ruling elite sooner or later will do the same in the modern sector. Firm

    owners will therefore cancel some of their more risk-exposed activities and try to keep a

    low profile in general. If all firms undertake such extra precautions, transaction costs

    increase and efficiency is hampered. Hence, both sectors will be affected by the same set of

    institutions, measured by Zt.

    If we disregard the government budget and all constraining factors for a moment, the

    optimal level of Z1 from the ruling elites point of view is the solution to the first-order

    condition:

    e0jDZj qjDZj

    qZ1 dR01Z

    1 M

    01Z

    1 0. (2)

    This condition relates the basic intuition behind the paper; investment in property rights

    institutions entails a trade-off for the ruling elite between the direct cost of effort ejDZj

    and the indirect cost of lower expropriated rents R1Z1 on the one hand, and the benefits

    of greater dividends from the modern sector on the other.

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    9One might of course imagine that some large firms in the modern sector are immobile in the short run and

    therefore suitable objects of predation.10Deliberate institutional differences between a formal and an informal sector are modelled in Olsson and

    Congdon Fors (2004).

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1903

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    9/26

    2.2. Functional form

    With the general form above, however, we cannot derive an explicit solution for Z1 or

    indeed say much else of interest. We will therefore specify a functional form of the utility

    function and of the government budget constraint that we believe capture the centralaspects of the ruling elites investment decision.

    Starting with the appropriable rents Rt, we mentioned earlier that these can most easily

    be thought of as proceeds from a more or less state-controlled natural resource sector.11

    Let us assume that there is a total flow of rents rt during period t 0; 1. For simplicity,we choose to model them as exogenous incomes that are generated without using any

    inputs and that rents are expected to be stable over time; r0 E0r1 r. Since the

    companies are state-owned, all rents are supposed to flow into the government budget.

    However, the predatory ruling elite will attempt to confiscate rents for their personal

    enrichment. The amount that the ruling elite can lay their hands on Rt depends on the

    existing level of government constraints. We assume that

    Rt max Z Ztr

    Z; 0

    , (3)

    where Z is a critical level of institutions beyond which rent appropriation is impossible.

    The max sign above means that if Zt4 Z, then Rt 0.12 We will assume throughout that

    Zto Z which arguably is the normal case for the developing countries that we have in

    mind. The amount of rents that are not expropriated by the ruling elite Ztr= Z flow into thegovernment budget, as will be shown below.

    The ruling elites second source of personal revenue comes from share-holding in theprivate sector. To explain how such an ownership has been obtained is beyond the scope of

    this article.13 As a share-holder, the ruling elite gets their part of total dividends; Mt ZPtwhere Zo0:5. The assumption ofZo0:5 means that the ruling elites holdings are relativelysmall, at least smaller than to give them a majority ownership in the private sector.14

    We further assume that Z is uncorrelated with Zt.

    Profits in the modern sector are given by

    Pt ptQt wLm;t ptZtLbm;t wtLm;t. (4)

    For simplicity, the quality of property rights institutions Zt increases modern sector output

    Qt linearly like a (Hicks neutral) total factor productivity variable. The channel throughwhich a higher Zt affects output is a general increase in efficiency and a reduction of

    transaction costs. Analogously, a weakening of property rights would induce firm owners

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    11See Acemoglu et al. (2003) for a similar assumption. Real world examples of more or less state-controlled

    mining companies are Gecamines (copper) and MIBA (diamonds) in former Zaire, Debswana (diamonds, joint

    venture with De Beers) in Botswana, Endiama (diamonds) in Angola, and ZIMCO in Zambia. We also believe

    that marketing boards such as that for cocoa in Ghana might also serve as a source of easily appropriable rents

    (Bates, 1981).12This reflects the idea that diversion of natural resource rents in developed countries like Canada, Australia, or

    the United States do not seem to enter the rulers objective function.13

    Evidence from Kenya and an analysis of the ruling elites private ownership patterns are discussed at length infor instance Bigsten and Moene (1996) where the phenomenon is referred to as straddling.

    14One could imagine that the ruling elite gains utility not through dividends, but through the general increase in

    the standard of living brought about by a thriving modern sector. In this case, Z would represent the utility derived

    from the modern sector.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211904

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    10/26

    to take extra precautions and force them to spend more time on improductive

    activities such as contract enforcement.15 Lm;t is labor supply to the modern sector at

    period t, and bo1 gives the (diminishing) returns to labor. Labor supply is

    treated as exogenous and fixed in this section so that Lm;t Lm but will be made

    endogenous below. Workers are paid a wage rate wt which is equivalent to the valuemarginal product; wt ptZtbL

    b1m;t . In other words, modern sector labor will be more

    productive on the margin (and will be better compensated) if property rights institutions

    are strong. The price of modern sector output is pt. Below we will specify the price level to

    be p0 p1 1.

    In summary, the ruling elites personal revenue from the modern sector will be

    Mt ZPt ZZtLbm1 b. (5)

    The ruling elites disutility of effort is an increasing function of the deviation from status

    quo:

    ejDZj yZ1 Z0

    2

    2

    yDZ

    2

    2

    ,

    where y40 indicates the degree of effort required to carry out changes in property rights

    institutions. The assumption of a quadratic function ensures that investment and

    disinvestment are equally costly in terms of disutility and implies that the ruling elite

    has a kind of status quo bias. Whereas the first derivative with respect to Z1 can have any

    sign, the second derivative is unambiguously positive at y40. This means that there is an

    increasing marginal disutility of institutional change. What this is intended to show is that

    institutional changes will require more and more effort on the margin as jDZj increases and

    hence give rise to a greater and greater utility loss.

    All in all, these assumptions give us a more detailed functional form of the ruling elites

    objective function in (1):

    Ur 1 Z0

    Z

    r ZZ0L

    bm1 b

    yZ1 Z02

    2

    d 1 Z1

    Z

    r ZZ1L

    bm1 b

    !. 6

    In maximizing personal revenue, the ruling elite has to take into consideration not only

    the legal constraints but also the fiscal constraints as given by the government budget. We

    will assume that in order to stay in power for more than one period, the ruling elite has to

    supply a fixed quantity of public goods G. This quantity includes the costs of police,

    defense, physical infrastructure, and basic government administration.

    The level of G might also be regarded as an indicator of the strength of one-man-rule.

    With a given revenue flow, a low G means that the ruling elite has a relatively great degree

    of freedom in deciding themselves what institutions to create and how much to spend on

    public goods. Conversely, a high G means that the ruling elite is highly constrained in the

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    15We could also think of an increase in Zt as causing an entry of new firms, as in Rajan and Zingales (2006). In

    their model, however, entry makes profits shrink for the oligopolists already active in the sector, which causes

    them to vote against such a reform. A similar scenario is sketched in Do (2004) where entrepreneurs bribe a

    regulator to restrict entry. In our model, firm owners have no such power.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1905

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    11/26

    process of institutional reform and that they are obliged to satisfy rather ambitious goals in

    terms of public goods provision in order to avoid being thrown out of office. 16

    A more long-term type of government expenditure is institutional reform. As in

    much of the literature on adjustment costs in investment, the costs of institutional

    investment or disinvestment are a convex function ofDZ: cZ1 Z02=2 where c40 is aparameter. The second derivative is simply c40, implying an increasing marginal cost. In

    order to reap the benefits of property rights investment, the ruling elite must be able to

    credibly enforce these rights. That entails investment in a number of supporting

    institutions, e.g. court systems, property registration offices, etc. If the ruling elite chooses

    to disinvest, on the other hand, they will be faced with the costs of dismantling the existing

    structures and probably also with the cost of compensating the losers from such a reform

    in some way.

    It might be argued that disinvestment in property rights institutions is less

    costly than investment. A way to formalize this notion would be to include a c0oc for

    disinvestment costs. In the extreme case, one could have a c0 0 which would imply

    that a worsening of institutions is costless. As will be shown below, such an assumption

    would mean that only positive investments were constrained by the government

    budget. This could easily be incorporated in the model.17 However, we do believe that it

    is reasonable to assume that rulers are always somewhat constrained from destroying

    property rights completely. Further, some positive level of second period property

    rights institutions is required in order to fulfill the second period budget constraint

    (see below).

    Government revenue has two sources; the non-expropriated rents from the natural

    resource sector Ztr=

    Z and a proportional income tax on workers in the modern sectortwLm tZtbLbm. The marginal tax rate t might be thought of as the (exogenously given)

    revenue-maximizing tax rate as in a Laffer-curve. The governmental budget restriction in

    the initial period states that fixed government outlay plus the costs of property rights

    investment or disinvestment must not exceed revenue, i.e.:

    GcZ1 Z0

    2

    2

    ptZ0bLbm

    Z0r

    Z. (7)

    We assume for the remainder of the article that GotZ0bLbm Z0r= Z so that the ruling

    elite always has some scope for institutional reform. Further, the level of Z1 must be such

    that second period revenue is sufficient to cover the second period fixed governmentoutlay, i.e.:

    GptZ1bLbm

    Z1r

    Z. (8)

    These budget restrictions imply that the optimal level of property rights institutions is

    defined in the interval Z1 2 max~Z

    1 ; Z

    1 ; Z

    1 where

    ~Z

    1 G

    tbLb

    m

    r= Z40 (9)

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    16See Aghion et al. (2004) for a model of an endogenously determined political insulation from the people.17A demonstration of the effects of asymmetric costs is provided upon request. The only effect would be that it

    could change a lower boundary solution if this turned out to be the equilibrium.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211906

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    12/26

    and

    Z

    1 Z0

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi2tZ0bL

    bm Z0r= Z G

    c

    sv0, (10)

    while the upper boundary of property rights in period 1 is

    Z

    1 Z0

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi2tZ0bL

    bm Z0r= Z G

    c

    s40. (11)

    Therefore, even if property rights disinvestment was costless, the ruling elite would still

    face the second period budget constraint, ~Z

    1 . Thus, costless disinvestment will only make

    the weakening of property rights more likely in the case where (10) 4 (9). Note that the

    scope for reform in either direction increases with r; t and Lbm and decreases with G. In

    addition, the scope for reform in either direction increases with Z0 and decreases with cwith respect to the first period budget constraint. The max-term defining the lower bound

    of Z1 reflects the constraint that the actual Z1 is necessarily non-negative whereas a

    negative institutional level might be financially viable in terms of the first period budget

    constraint (i.e. if Z

    1o0.

    2.3. Optimal institutional change

    The utility function and the governmental budget constraint form a maximization

    problem for the ruling elite

    maxZ1

    Ur subject to cZ1 Z02=2ptZ0bL

    bm

    Z0r

    Z G

    and tZ1bLbm

    Z1r

    ZXG. 12

    By setting up a Lagrangian function G with multipliers l1 and l2, we can derive the

    following KuhnTucker first-order conditions:

    qG

    qZ1 yZn1 Z0

    dr

    Z dZLbm1 b l1cZ

    1 Z0 l2 tbL

    bm

    r

    Z p0,

    qG

    ql1 tZ0bL

    bm

    Z0r

    Z G cZ1 Z0

    2=2X0, (13)

    qG

    ql2 tZ1bL

    bm

    Z1r

    Z GX0, (14)

    qG

    ql1 l1 0;

    qG

    ql2 l2 0;

    qG

    qZ1 Z1 0.

    The third line shows the complementary slackness conditions. The second-order condition

    for maximum is fulfilled since the Lagrangian function is strictly concave in the relevantrange Z140.

    The problem above implies that we can characterize the set of solutions in the following

    Lemma:

    ARTICLE IN PRESSH. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1907

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    13/26

    Lemma 1. The maximization problem in (12) has four potential unique solutions:

    Z1 :

    ~Z

    1 if Zopt1 p

    ~Z

    1

    and l1 0;

    l240;i

    Z

    1 4~Z

    1 if Zopt1 pZ

    1

    and l1 l40;

    l2 0ii

    Zopt1 if Z

    1oZopt1 oZ

    1

    and l1 0;

    l2 0;iii

    Z

    1 if Zopt1 XZ

    1

    and l1 l40;

    l2 0;iv

    8>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>:where ~Z1 , Z1 and Z1 are given by (9), (10) and (11), respectively,

    Zopt1 Z0

    d

    yZLbm1 b

    r

    Z

    (15)

    and

    l

    Zopt Z1

    Z

    1 Z0

    y

    c; l

    Zopt Z1

    Z

    1 Z0

    y

    c; l2

    y ~Z

    1 Zopt

    tbLbm rZ

    . (16)

    Proof. The results follow from straightforward manipulations of the first-order condi-

    tions. &

    The first two solutions (i)(ii) represent lower boundary extrema where the ruling elite

    disinvests in property rights institutions as much as they can afford, (iii) is an interior

    maximum with positive or negative investment, and (iv) is an upper boundary solution

    where the ruling elite uses all available government means for positive investment.

    The term Zopt1 is given by the unconstrained maximum qUr=qZ1jZ1Zopt 0. This valuemight or might not be attainable depending on the level of affordable reforms. The

    Lagrangian multipliers l

    , l

    and l2 reflect the shadow value of net government revenue

    in case of constrained boundary solutions.

    The solutions derived in Lemma 1 might be used to express the following intuitive

    results:

    Proposition 1. (a) The ruling elite is more likely to strengthen (weaken) property rights

    institutions if Z and Lm are high (low) and if r andy are low (high). (b) In the case of positive

    boundary solutions, the change in the strength of property rights institutions in either

    direction increases with t, r, Lm and Z0 and decreases with G and c.

    Proof. (a) Whether institutions are strengthened or weakened is determined by the sign of

    Zopt1 Z0 d ZL

    bm1 b r= Z

    =y. A high Z and Lm and a low r imply that a positive

    sign is likely, and vice versa.

    (b) From (9)(11), we know that the greatest feasible institutional change in either

    direction is Z

    1 Z0 Z0 Z

    1

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi2tZ0bL

    bm Z0r= Z G=c

    q40, while the minimum

    feasible level ofZ1 is ~Z

    1 G=tbLbm r= Z40. From these expressions, it is easily seen that

    the result in (b ) applies. &

    ARTICLE IN PRESSH. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211908

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    14/26

    In the case of Z1 ~Z

    1 or Z

    1 as in (i) and (ii) of Lemma 1, the ruling elite is totally

    committed to destroying existing institutions. The proposition shows that this scenario

    might arise when the modern sector is small (low Lbm), when the ruling elites interests in the

    modern Z sector are small, or when the rent flow r is large. The greater are r, t, Lm and Z0at this equilibrium, the stronger is the government budget and the ruling elite can afford aneven greater weakening of institutions. This income effect might however be balanced by

    the fact that a weakening of property rights is less likely if Lm increases according to (a).

    A greater Gi.e. a smaller autonomy for the ruling elitewill in this equilibrium mean

    a smaller deterioration in institutions.

    When we have an interior solution such that Z1 Zopt1 , then the optimal level of

    institutions in period 1 will depend positively on the inherited level of institutions in

    period 0 and negatively on resource rents r. Indeed, Figs. 1a and b provide an empirical

    counterpart of this theoretical result with settler mortality as a proxy for Z0. However, if

    we look at institutional change as in Proposition 1, it is easily seen that a weakening of

    property rights is more likely if the rent flow r is large.18 In other words, the model predicts

    that countries with a relatively substantial rent flow at independence should face a

    worsening of property rights institutions. The logic is of course that high rents imply that a

    kleptocratic ruling elites opportunity costs of installing stronger property rights are high

    since a strong protection against expropriation will mean lower rents for themselves.

    However, apart from this substitution effect of an increase in r, rents also have an income

    effect via the budget constraint, as discussed above.

    In the interior solution, Z1 further increases with Z and Lm. The greater the ruling elites

    interests in the modern sector and the greater the size of this sector, the greater is the

    likelihood of a positive change in second-period property rights institutions, as one mightexpect.

    In the upper boundary solution where Z1 Z

    1 , the ruling elite spends every available

    penny in the government budget on improving property rights. The reason is simply that

    their marginal utility of Z1 is positive in the whole feasible range. This good outcome is

    therefore more likely when the modern sector is relatively important for the ruling elites

    personal enrichment, i.e. when Z and Lm are high and r is low.

    From (11), we see that Z1 increases with r in the upper boundary solution due to the

    income effect since an increase in r shifts the budget constraint further out. However, an

    increase in r also decreases the marginal utility of property rights investments, which is the

    force behind the substitution effect ofr. At a certain level ofr, an interior solution will arisein which case an increase in r will lower the optimal level of property rights.19 Thus, all else

    equal, the income effect of increases in r will dominate in the upper boundary solution if

    such increases start at very low levels of r, whereas beyond a certain level, the substitution

    effect of a higher r will dominate. It is also interesting to note that in this good equilibrium,

    a smaller fiscal autonomy for the ruling elite (a higher G) will imply a lower level of

    property rights institutions since the discretionary part of the budget shrinks. Similarly,

    high costs of institutional changereflected by high levels of y and cwill inevitably

    result in small deviations from Z0.20

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    18More precisely, there will be a disinvestment in institutions if r4ZLbm1 bZ.

    19This level of r is reached when l 0 which happens when Zopt1 r; Z

    1 r; .20The equations above show that both Z

    opt1 Z0 and Z

    1 Z0 Z0Z

    1 will approach zero as y and c

    approach infinity.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1909

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    15/26

    If total output in the country is measured as modern production plus the official or non-

    diverted flow of rents from the natural resource sector, then we can write Yt Qt

    Ztrt= Z. The growth rate of the economy in the case of an interior solution will therefore be

    Y1 Y0Y0

    Zopt

    Z0Z0

    dZ0y

    ZLbm1 b rZ

    v0. (17)

    The growth rate is thus negatively related to the flow of rents r. The negative marginal

    effect on growth of an increase in r decreases in absolute terms with Z0, implying that

    countries with relatively good initial institutions should experience smaller adverse effects

    of a high r.

    The corresponding growth rate for a country that optimally fully utilizes the government

    budget for positive investment is

    Y1 Y0Y0

    ^

    Z

    1 Z0Z0

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi2tZ0bLbm Z0r= Z G=cq

    Z040. (18)

    As mentioned above, for this category of countries in the good equilibrium, natural

    resources do not constitute a curse. On the contrary, growth will increase with an increase

    in r. These findings perhaps contribute to explaining the results from the empirical growth

    literature that countries with good institutions seem to be able to escape the curse of

    natural resources (Mehlum et al., 2006). However, as shown above, beyond a certain level

    of r, an interior solution will arise and the (institutions-weakening) substitution effect will

    start to dominate.

    3. Extensions

    In this section, we will extend our basic model to account for the effects of endogenous

    labor supply, natural resource booms and declines, foreign aid, trade liberalization, and

    impediments to institutional efficacy.

    3.1. Endogenous labor supply

    In the derivations above, labor supply Lm was assumed to be exogenously given and

    fixed throughout the two periods. This is not a totally satisfactory assumption since it canbe easily imagined that labor supply should depend on for instance the tax rate and,

    perhaps more interestingly, on the quality of institutions in the modern sector. In this

    section, we will therefore derive labor supply endogenously and analyze how this alters the

    results from the previous section. We will assume that the decisions about institutional

    choice and labor supply are made as in a sequential game with the ruling elite acting as a

    leader whose supply of property rights institutions is taken as given by the workers.

    Let us assume that the ruling elites objective function is as in (6). Let us also postulate

    that there is only one group of workers with the linear utility function

    UlLm;t 1 tZtbL

    b

    m;t gL Lm;t G for t 0; 1.In each of the two periods, the working part of the population receives utility from after-

    tax labor income 1 tZtbLbm;t, from leisure or informal household production

    gL Lm;t, and from the public goods G provided by the ruling elite. The only new

    ARTICLE IN PRESSH. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211910

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    16/26

    parameters here are L which is the fixed total endowment of labor resources, and g40 that

    reflects the marginal utility (or productivity) of household production. Note that property

    rights do not affect the output of informal household production.21

    The workers maximize Ul with labor supply Lm;t as the control variable, taking Zt as

    given. From the usual first-order conditions, we find that the equilibrium level will be

    Lm;t 1 tZtb

    2

    g

    1=1b. (19)

    Thus, labor supply in period t will be positively associated with the strength of property

    rights institutions in period t. This should make sense; the greater the levels of Zt, the

    greater the workers marginal product and the greater his or her labor supply to the

    modern sector. Conversely, the greater the utility from household production g, the lower

    the supply of modern sector labor.

    The ruling elite realizes by backward induction what labor effort that will be supplied tothe modern sector and takes this level as given in their own optimization. This means that

    the ruling elites utility function becomes

    Ur X1t0

    dt 1 ZtZ

    r Z1 bb2b=1bZ

    1=1bt

    1 t

    g

    b=1b

    yZt Z02

    2.

    The first period government budget constraint is still that

    GcZ1 Z0

    2

    2

    ptZ1=1b0 b

    1b=1b 1 t

    g

    b=1b

    Z0r

    Z

    , (20)

    which in turn implies that the highest attainable level of institutional change is

    Z

    1 Z0 Z0 Z

    1

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi2tZ

    1=1b0 b

    1b=1b1 t=gb=1b Z0r= Z G

    c

    s40,

    (21)

    while the second period budget constraint remains as

    GptZ1=1b1 b

    1b=1b 1 t

    g b=1b

    Z1r= Z. (22)

    When the optimization problem is changed in this way, the KuhnTucker first-order

    conditions become more complicated. As visual inspection should make clear, the solution

    to this optimization problem will depend to a great extent on the levels of the labor

    elasticity parameter b as well as on the other parameters of the model. In order to simplify

    the analysis without losing focus on the essentials, we will make the following assumptions

    for the remainder of the analysis:

    b 23; d y c g 1. (23)

    The assumption that b 23

    is standard, i.e. that the share of labor in production is 23.22 The

    assumption that the remaining parameters are equal to one is a simplification, which in

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    21This could be the case if informal production does not require significant investment (see, e.g., Besley, 1995).

    A similar assumption is made in Olsson and Congdon Fors (2004).22See for instance Krueger and Lindahl (2001) for a discussion of the most plausible world level.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1911

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    17/26

    many cases will be relaxed in the subsections below. The greatest attainable change in

    property rights is thus

    Z

    1 Z0 Z0 Z

    1 ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

    2 tZ30c1 t2 Z0r

    Z G s

    , (24)

    where c 32243

    , while ~Z

    1 is the value of Z1 that satisfies

    t ~Z

    1 3c1 t2

    ~Z

    1 r

    Z G 0. (25)

    Further, setting b 23

    means that the ruling elites utility function above becomes a cubic

    function ofZ1. Unlike in the exogenous labor supply case, the second-order condition for

    maximum is not necessarily fulfilled in the endogenous labor supply case since theLagrangian function is not strictly concave in the relevant range Z140. Rather, as shown

    in Congdon Fors and Olsson (2006, Appendix 1), there are two extreme points, given by

    the expression

    Zl;opti

    Zl;max1 1

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi1 4Zd1 t2Z0 r= Z

    q2Zd1 t2

    ;

    Zl;min1 1

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi1 4Zd1 t2Z0 r= Z

    q

    2Zd1 t

    2;

    8>>>>>>>>>>>:(26)

    where d 1681

    . Obviously, we can disregard Zl;min1 as a potential solution to the ruling elites

    optimization problem. Upon inspection of (26), it is clear that we will have different types

    of solutions for Zl;max1 depending on the size of the expression under the square root sign.

    Congdon Fors and Olsson (2006, Appendix 2) characterize in detail the solutions for Zl;max1and for Z1. The analytically most interesting scenario arises when Z0 r= Z40 and theexpression under the square root sign ranges between zero and one, which ensures that

    Zl;max1 40. Figs. 3a and b show two types of solutions with this feature. In these cases, it is

    also evident that Zl;max1 oZl;min1 . The local minimum also provides us with important

    information: At levels higher than Zl;min1 , investment in property rights once again starts to

    yield utility gains for the ruling elite.

    Now that we have established the local maximum and the three constrained cases, it

    remains to determine what the optimal solution to the ruling elites maximization problem

    will actually be. The optimal solution depends on the relationship between the constrained

    solutions and the unconstrained local maximum, and the utility derived by the ruling elite

    from each. In Congdon Fors and Olsson (2006, Appendix 2), all possible equilibria and the

    conditions associated with them are characterized formally.

    On a more intuitive level, there are as before four potential solutions: (i) Z1 ~Z

    1 , (ii)

    Z1 Z

    1 ; (iii) Z1 Z

    l;max1 ; or (iv) Z

    1 Z

    1 . In (i) and (ii), the ruling elite weakens property

    rights as much as they can afford, whereas an interior maximum is optimally chosen in (iii).Whether the latter involves a strengthening or a weakening of institutions is not clear but

    depends on the parameters. This kind of equilibrium (with a worsening of property rights)

    is illustrated in Fig. 3a. (iv) shows the upper boundary solution, which might arise in four

    ARTICLE IN PRESSH. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211912

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    18/26

    different cases, for instance when Zl;max1 4Z

    1 . A noteworthy feature is further that Zl;max1

    might not be the optimal choice even when it is affordable. As Fig. 3b shows, Z

    1 might

    give a higher utility than Zl;max1 since the utility function starts increasing again beyond the

    minimum.

    If we are to make a general characterization, the results in the endogenous labor supply

    case will be similar to those above:

    Proposition 2. (a) With endogenous labor supply, the ruling elite is more likely to

    strengthen (weaken) property rights institutions if Z and Z0 are high (low) and if r and t are

    low (high). (b) In the case of positive boundary solutions, the change of propertyrights institutions in either direction increases with r and Z0 and with t if to13, and decreases

    with G.

    Proof. See Appendix A2.

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Z1

    Z0

    Zt-institutional strength

    Ur- utility of ruling elite

    *Z1

    Z1

    +- Z1

    Z0+*

    Z1 = Z1

    Ur- utility of ruling elite

    Zt- institutional strength

    - Z1

    +

    Fig. 3. (a) Optimal weakening of institutions with endogenous labor supply. Note: Interior maximum is optimal

    since Zn1 Zl;max1 oZ0. (b) Optimal strengthening of institutions with endogenous labor supply. Note: Upper

    boundary is optimal since Zn1 Z

    1 4Z04Zl;max1 ; UrZ

    1 4UrZl;max1 .

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1913

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    19/26

    As before, positive (negative) changes are more likely if Z is large (small) and r is small

    (large). If the imbalance between the incentives for strengthening property rights Zd1

    t2Z20 and the incentives for weakening them r= Z is large in either direction, a boundarysolution is more likely where the results in (b) will apply. A difference from the previous

    section is that a strengthening of property rights is more likely if the level of inheritedinstitutions Z0 is high. This implies a kind of path dependence: Countries with strong

    property rights at independence will invest in even stronger rights whereas the reverse will

    be true for more weakly institutionalized colonies. The logic is that better initial

    institutions means that the modern sector is relatively more productive, so that the losses

    from weakening institutions will be greater, and there will be a greater incentive to

    strengthen property rights. Further, since r and Z0 affect both the unconstrained and the

    constrained solutions, they might have both income and substitution effects, as discussed

    above.

    The proposition shows that a rise in Z only has an impact on the maximum whereas G

    only affects the constrained solutions. An interesting case might occur if two otherwise

    identical countries have slightly different levels of required public goods, G. Let us assume

    that for some reason, one of the countries (country 1) gives a larger discretionary power to

    the ruling elite than in country 2 so that G1oG2. Then, if the situation is as in Fig. 4, this

    means that country 1 will optimally be at the upper boundary solution whereas country 2

    will be stuck at the lower boundary. This illustrates the notion that even small differences

    between countries might give drastically different outcomes regarding the optimal

    structure of institutions.

    3.2. Natural resource booms and declines

    We have assumed that r0 E0r1 r, i.e. the rents from natural resources in the second

    period are expected to equal the rents in the first period. In this section, we analyze the

    effects of r0ar1 on ruling elites optimal choice of Z1. Note that the first period budget

    constraint will be identical to that in (24) with r r0, while the ruling elite will maximize

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    Z0

    Z

    1

    +Z

    1

    Zt

    Ur

    Country 1

    Country 2

    Fig. 4. A high and a low equilibrium level of property rights resulting from different country levels of minimum

    public spending G24G1. Note: The figure illustrates how two countries with slightly different levels of mimimum

    public goods can have two widely different equilibrium levels of institutional strength with Country 2 disinvesting

    to its lower boundary and Country 1 (with a lower G) investing to its upper boundary.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211914

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    20/26

    second period utility taking E0r1 r1 into account, i.e.

    Zr;max1 1

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi1 4Zd1 t2Z0 r1= Z

    q2Zd1 t2

    (27)

    and the second period budget constraint will now be

    t ~Z

    1 3c1 t2

    ~Z

    1 r1Z

    G 0. (28)

    If a natural resource boom is anticipated, we have r14r0. The result is that Zr;max1 and

    ~Z

    1 will occur at a lower level of property rights institutions while at the same time Zr;min1

    will occur at a higher level. The main result that Zr;max1 will fall with an anticipated resource

    boom is intuitively straightforward. Because r0 does not change, there is no first period

    income effect from the natural resource boom, while there is a second period income

    effect.23

    3.3. Foreign aid

    So far we have assumed that the ruling elite can only finance changes in property rights

    institutions through domestic means. There is, however, a possibility that the ruling elite

    receives development aid from foreign donors. Ideally, this aid would be ear-marked for

    institutional development, yielding the following upper budget constraint :

    ^Z

    1 Z0 ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

    2 tZ3

    0c1 t2

    Z0r

    Z A G s

    , (29)

    where A is foreign aid. Given that Z1 Z

    1 , the effect of aid would therefore be to increase

    the optimal level of property rights institutions. If Z1 ZA;max1 , on the other hand, the

    budget constraint is not binding and the ruling elite may choose to forgo the foreign aid in

    favor of a lower level of institutions.

    If it is the case that the ruling elite instead treats the aid as an additional source of rents

    in both periods, then the effect on the maximum will be the same as in the case of a natural

    resource boom as in (27), where r A enters in the place of r1. This means that aid

    decreases the strength of property rights institutions in the case of an interior solution.

    Hence, foreign aid that is not used for investment in property rights institutions couldresult in worsening institutions and have a negative impact on economic development. This

    potential negative effect of aid appears in the theoretical model of Acemoglu et al. (2003),

    and seems to be somewhat supported by empirical evidence (Knack, 2000). Note that

    foreign aid also here increases fiscal revenue (by the amount Z0A= Z and thus Z1 in an

    upper boundary solution, but to a smaller extent than in (29).

    3.4. Trade liberalization

    International trade is another factor that may influence the ruling elites maximization

    problem. We assume that trade will influence the price of the modern sector output and

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    23If the shock to natural resource rents is unanticipated it will have not affect Zr;max1 or~Z

    1 . As a result, neither

    the local maximum nor the budget constraints change.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1915

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    21/26

    that a liberalization is usually associated with a fall in modern sector prices. This will be the

    case if the domestic price of manufactures before trade liberalization is higher than the

    world price. The effect of this price change depends on the timing of the liberalization.

    Start with the scenario where trade liberalization occurs in the second period, so that

    p0 1; p1o1. Here, the first period budget constraints will remain the same as in (24),while the second period budget constraint becomes

    t ~Z

    1 3p31c1 t

    2 ~Z

    1 r

    Z G 0 (30)

    and the equation for the interior maximum becomes

    Zp;max1

    1

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi1 2p31Zd1 t

    2Z0 r= Zq

    p

    3

    1Zd1 t

    2. (31)

    We can easily confirm that Zp;max1 increases with p1. The intuition is that a lower price level

    decreases labor supply and makes modern sector production less attractive in relative

    terms than rent seeking.

    If trade liberalization occurs in the first period, and p0 Ep1 po1, then the first

    period budget constraint becomes

    Z

    1 Z0 Z0 Z

    1

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi2 tZ30p

    3c1 t2 Z0r

    Z G

    s. (32)

    Clearly, a fall in p lowers the maximum feasible change in property rights institutions.However, Z

    p;max1 will also increase with p in the same way as in (31). In other words, trade

    liberalization that is accompanied by a permanently lower price for modern sector goods

    will weaken property rights institutions if we initially have an interior or an upper

    boundary solution. The results are of course reversed if a trade liberalization causes an

    increase in modern sector prices.

    Another potential impact of trade liberalization is to increase the volume of natural

    resource extraction, hence increasing the rents from natural resources.24 In this case,

    the effect of trade liberalization will be the same as in the case of a natural resource boom

    as in (27).

    3.5. Impediments to institutional efficacy

    Former colonies typically face many obstacles to institutional change, such as

    low population density, a complex geography, and great ethnic diversity (see

    for instance Herbst, 2000). These factors can influence the ruling elites optimal

    choice of property rights institutions in two ways. First, it may be that y41 (rather

    than y 1 as assumed previously). This corresponds to a greater amount of effort

    being required on the ruling elites part to bring about institutional change, with the local

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    24For example, Chichilnisky (1994) presents a model of international trade that demonstrates that countries

    with poorly defined property rights will appear to have a comparative advantage in resource-intensive production,

    even when technology, endowments and preferences are the same in all countries. This can, in turn, lead to

    overextraction of natural resources in the countries with low levels of property rights.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211916

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    22/26

    maximum defined by

    Zy;max1 y

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiy2 2Zd1 t2yZ0 r= Z

    qZd1 t

    2. (33)

    The effect of an increase in y is to make any change, be it investment or disinvestment, less

    attractive.25 Another possibility is that these obstacles cause c41. This corresponds to an

    increase in the cost of institutional change via the first period government budget. In this

    case, the budget constraint is as given in (21). It is directly evident that an increase in c will

    lower the amount of institutional change that is attainable.26 In the worst case, high costs

    of institutional change may compel a ruling elite to choose a low property rights

    equilibrium over a high property rights equilibrium.

    We have assumed that Z increases modern sector output at a 1:1 ratio. It is possible,

    however, that the effect of Z on modern sector output is less than unity. There is sometheoretical support for the notion that the effectiveness of property rights on modern

    sector output is positively related to the state of technology (Demsetz, 1967; Alchian and

    Demsetz, 1973), so that low technology may decrease the effectiveness of property rights

    on modern sector output. Other potential factors include low levels of human capital

    accumulation, missing markets, limited access to credit, a high degree of ethnic

    fractionalization and geographical impediments. In this case, output in the modern sector

    would be e3Z30d1 t2, where eo1. The effect on the second period budget constraint and

    the optimum solution would then be identical to (30) and (31), while the first period budget

    constraints become

    Z

    1 Z0 Z0 Z

    1

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi2 tZ30e

    3c1 t2 Z0r

    Z G

    :

    s(34)

    The effect of eo1 is to lower the maximum feasible investment in property rights

    institutions, while at the same time lowering the level of property rights institutions at

    which the maximum occurs. Finally, an increase in g, the marginal productivity of

    household production, will have the opposite general effect of e on the budget constraints

    and the unconstrained optima.27

    The above impediments to institutional efficacy all have in common that they restrict the

    scope of attainable institutional change compared to what would otherwise be the case.Further, in the case when output is adversely affected, the ruling elite may be more inclined

    to choose a low level of property rights institutions.

    4. Conclusion

    In this article, we have attempted to model the decision process of property rights

    (dis)investment by an autocratic ruling elite. We have been motivated by the previous

    literature that has emphasized the crucial role institutions play in economic development,

    as well as by institutional changes that have taken place in former European colonies since

    ARTICLE IN PRESS

    25However, the sign of the partial derivative of (33) with respect to y can be either positive or negative.26Whether this results in higher or lower level of Z1 depends on whether the ruler optimally strengthens or

    weakens property rights institutions.27The only difference being that g will occur in quadratic form rather than cubic, as is the case with e.

    H. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1917

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    23/26

    independence. Further, the model has been motivated by the literature on the natural

    resource curse and the observation that many resource-poor countries in Asia have shown

    a considerably stronger economic performance than resource-rich African countries

    despite similar initial levels of institutional quality.

    The main insight of our model is the existence of a potential trade-off for an autocraticelite between strong institutions of private propertywhich increase revenue from the

    modern sectorand weaker property rights that facilitate the personal appropriation of

    rents from a natural resource sector. We show that even a completely self-interested ruling

    elite may have incentives to strengthen property rights if the modern sector is relatively

    profitable. Additionally, the model retains a component of institutional persistence, which

    is present in much of the literature on the origins of institutions in former colonies.

    Although we have assumed that the ruling elite is only interested in personal enrichment,

    one could easily alter the model to fit an altruistic ruling elite. In this case, the rent

    appropriation part of the utility function would disappear, and Z would measure the ruling

    elites willingness to expanding the modern sector. The cost of an investment would then

    set the limit to how much the elite could invest; variations in institutional investment

    would thus depend on initial levels of institutions.

    Although the article discusses a number of extensions to the basic model such as the

    impact of foreign aid and trade liberalization, we believe that several other aspects might

    be fruitfully analyzed within the framework outlined above. For instance, we have only

    briefly touched upon the issue of why larger former colonies seem to have been

    disadvantaged in terms of institutional development. An econometric analysis is clearly

    needed in order to understand the exact channels of causation.

    A further line of inquiry might be the impact of stronger property rights on humancapital accumulation, an issue that we have not dealt with at all here. Neither have we

    explicitly considered the possibility that the ruling elite initiates other types of institutional

    changes in the modern sector that are detrimental to the economy, such as the pursuit of

    import substitution strategies or entry restrictions into the modern sector. However, we

    conjecture that the opposing forces of a modern and a natural resource sector as modelled

    in this article may shed some light also on this issue. All else equal, it seems likely that a

    newly independent regime with a strong flow of mineral rents and a sense of self-sufficiency

    is more inclined to adopt inward-oriented policies than a resource-poor country. Clearly,

    the curse of natural resources is a multi-faceted phenomenon that deserves further

    attention.

    Acknowledgment

    We are grateful for comments from Arne Bigsten, Anne Boschini, EER editor

    Thorvaldur Gylfason, Anke Hoeffler, Olof Johansson-Stenman, Johanna Jussila Hammes,

    Kalle Moene, Violeta Piculescu, two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at the

    Go teborg University, the Stockholm University, the EEA Meeting in Amsterdam, DET

    Workshop at the University of Copenhagen, the Malmsten Research Group, the Nordic

    Workshop in Development Economics, and the CSAE Conference at the OxfordUniversity. Congdon Fors and Olsson both gratefully acknowledge financial support

    from Vetenskapsra det and from the Wallander-Hedelius and Malmsten Foundations,

    respectively.

    ARTICLE IN PRESSH. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211918

  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    24/26

    Appendix A

    A.1. Description of variables used in Figs. 1a, b, and 2

    Variable N Max Min Mean StDev

    Rule of law in 2004 127 1.93 2.31 0.22 0.89

    Nrg_Min1999/GNI 112 0.36 0 0.033 0.075

    Logarea 127 16.12 3.04 10.99 3.08

    Log Settler Mortality 69 7.99 2.15 4.69 1.22

    Latitude 127 60 0 15.28 10.0

    Sub-Saharan Africa dummy 127 1 0 0.36 0.48

    Neo-Europe dummy 127 1 0 0.03 0.17

    Executive constraints 7 1

    Description:

    Sample: 127 former colonies.

    Rule of law in 2004: Source: Kaufmann et al. (2005).

    Nrg_Min1999/GNI : Energy and mineral rents as a share of GNI in 1999. Source: World

    Bank (2004).

    Logarea: Log of total country area. Source: World Bank (2004).

    Log Settler Mortality: Log of annual mortality among soldiers and bishops per 1000

    individuals during colonial times. Source: Acemoglu et al. (2001).Latitude: Distance from equator in absolute latitude degrees. Source: World Bank (2004).

    Sub-Saharan Africa dummy: Source: World Bank (2004).

    Neo-Europe dummy: Dummy for Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and the United States.

    Source: Acemoglu et al. (2001).

    Executive constraints: Degree of effective constraints (in terms of rule of law, constitutional

    sharing of power, etc.) on the executive.

    Note: All data are available from http://www.hgu.gu.se/item.aspx?id=2465 or upon

    request.

    A.2. Proof of Proposition 2

    Proof. (a) Whether institutions are strengthened or weakened is determined by the sign of

    Zl;max1 Z0 1=2Zd1 t21

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi1 4Zd1 t2Z0 r= Z

    q Z0. A straightforward

    manipulation of this expression shows that Zl;max1 Z040 if 1 2Zd1 t2Z04ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi

    1 4Zd1 t2Z0 r= Zq

    . By squaring both sides, we receive 1 4Zd1 t2Z0

    2Zd1 t2Z0

    241 4Zd1 t2Z0

    r= Z, which in turn implies that

    Zd1 t2Z204r= Z. Thus Zl;max1 Z040 if Zd1 t

    2Z204r= Z, which is the essence of (a).(b) From (25) and (24), we know that the greatest feasible institutional change in either

    direction is Z

    1 Z0 Z0 Z

    1

    ffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi2tZ30c1 t

    2 Z0r= Z Gq

    40, while the minimum

    ARTICLE IN PRESSH. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 18961921 1919

    http://www.hgu.gu.se/item.aspx?id=2465http://www.hgu.gu.se/item.aspx?id=2465
  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    25/26

    feasible level of Z1 is defined by t ~Z

    1 3c1 t2 ~Z

    1 r= Z G 0. From theseexpressions, it is easily seen that the results in (b) regarding r; Z0; and G apply. Since

    to1, the multiplicative term t1 t2 achieves its maximum at t 13. &

    References

    Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., 2005. Unbundling institutions. Journal of Political Economy 113 (5), 949995.

    Acemoglu, D., Robinson, J., 2005. Persistence of Power, Elites, and Institutions. MIT, Cambridge, MA, Mimeo.

    Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J.A., 2001. The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical

    investigation. American Economic Review 91 (5), 13691401.

    Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J.A., 2002. Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making

    of the modern world income distribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4), 12311294.

    Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J.A., 2005. Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-run Growth.

    In: Aghion, P., Durlauf, S. (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth. Amsterdam, North-Holland.Acemoglu, D., Robinson, J., Verdier, T., 2003. Kleptocracy and divide-and-rule: A model of personal rule. NBER

    Working Papers No. 10136.

    Aghion, P., Alesina, A., Trebbi, F., 2004. Endogenous political institutions. Quarterly Journal of Economics 119

    (2), 565611.

    Alchian, A.A., Demsetz, H., 1973. The property right paradigm. Journal of Economic History 33 (1), 1627.

    Bates, R.H., 1981. Markets and states in tropical Africa: The political basis of agricultural policies. University of

    California Press, Berkeley.

    Bates, R.H., Collier, P., 1993. The politics and economics of policy reform in Zambia. In: Bates, R.H., Krueger,

    A. (Eds.), Political and Economic Interactions in Economic Policy Reform. Blackwell, Oxford (Chapter 9).

    Beck, T., Laeven, L., 2006. Institution building and growth in transition economies. Journal of Economic Growth

    11 (2), 157186.

    Besley, T., 1995. Property rights and investment incentives: Theory and evidence from Ghana. Journal of Political

    Economy 103 (5), 903937.

    Bigsten, A., 2001. Policy-making in resource rich countries: Lessons from Zambia. World Economics 2 (3),

    139153.

    Bigsten, A., Moene, K., 1996. Growth and rent dissipation: The case of Kenya. Journal of African Economies 5

    (2), 177198.

    Chichilnisky, G., 1994. North-South trade and the global environment. American Economic Review 84 (4),

    851874.

    Coase, R.M., 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3, 144.

    Congdon Fors, H., Olsson, O., 2006. Endogenous Institutional Change After Independence. Extended working

    paper version, available on personal website: hhttp://www.hgu.gu.se/item.aspx?id=2465 i.

    Dalgaard, C.-J., Olsson, O., 2007. Windfall Gains, Political Economy, and Economic Development. Journal ofAfrican Economies, forthcoming.

    Demsetz, H., 1967. Toward a theory of property rights. American Economic Review 57 (2), 347359.

    de Soto, H., 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else.

    Black Swan Books, London.

    Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., 2003. The new comparative economics.

    Journal of Comparative Economics 31, 596619.

    Do, Q.-T., 2004. Institutional Trap. Policy Research Working Paper 3291, World Bank.

    Easterly, W., Levine, R., 2003. Tropics, germs, and crops: How endowments influence economic development.

    Journal of Monetary Economics 50, 339.

    Firmin-Sellers, K., 1995. The politics of property rights. American Political Science Review 89 (4), 867881.

    Frankel, J., Romer, D., 1999. Does trade cause growth? American Economic Review 89 (3), 379399.

    Glaeser, E., la Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., 2004. Do institutions cause growth? Journal ofEconomic Growth 9, 271303.

    Glaeser, E.L., Shleifer, A., 2002. Legal origins. Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (November), 11931230.

    Gylfason, T., 2001. Natural resources, education and economic development. European Economic Review 45,

    847859.

    ARTICLE IN PRESSH. Congdon Fors, O. Olsson / European Economic Review 51 (2007) 189619211920

    http://www.hgu.gu.se/item.aspx?id=2465http://www.hgu.gu.se/item.aspx?id=2465
  • 8/3/2019 Endogenous Institutional Change After Independenc

    26/26

    Hall, R., Jones, C., 1999. Why do some countries produce so much more output than others? Quarterly Journal of

    Economics 114 (1), 83116.

    Herbst, J., 2000. States and Power in Africa. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

    Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., Mastruzzi, M., 2005. Governance matters IV: Governance indicators for 19962004.

    World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3630.

    Knack, S., 2000. Aid dependence and the quality of governance. World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper

    #2396, Washington, DC.

    Krueger, A.B., Lindahl, M., 2001. Education for growth: Why and for whom? Journal of Economic Literature 36

    (December), 11011136.

    Leite, C., Weidmann, J., 1999. Does mother nature corrupt? Natural resources, corruption and economic growth.

    IMF Working Papers 99/85.

    Marshall, M.G., Jaggers, K., 2003. Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 18002003

    hhttp://www.cidcm.umd.edu/inscr/polity/ i.

    Mehlum, H., Moene, K., Torvik, R., 2006. Institutions and the resource curse. Economic Journal 116 (508), 120.

    Ndikumana, L., Boyce, J.K., 1998. Congos odious debt: External borrowing and capital flight in Zaire.

    Development and Change. 29, 195217.

    North, D., 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. WW Norton and Company, New York.North, D., 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press,

    Cambridge.

    Olsson, O., Congdon Fors, H., 2004. Congo: The prize of predation. Journal of Peace Research 41 (3), 321336.

    Olsson, O., Hibbs, D.A., 2005. Biogeography and long-run economic development. European Economic Review