Top Banner
Economics 387 Lecture 6 Demand for Health Capital Tianxu Chen
38

Economics 387

Jan 20, 2016

Download

Documents

MickeyF MickeyF

Economics 387. Lecture 6 Demand for Health Capital Tianxu Chen. Outline. The Demand for Health Labor–Leisure Trade-Offs The Investment/Consumption Aspects of Health Investment over Time The Demand for Health Capital Changes in Equilibrium: Age, Wage, and Education - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Economics 387

Economics 387

Lecture 6

Demand for Health CapitalTianxu Chen

Page 2: Economics 387

Outline

• The Demand for Health• Labor–Leisure Trade-Offs• The Investment/Consumption Aspects of Health• Investment over Time• The Demand for Health Capital• Changes in Equilibrium: Age, Wage, and Education• Empirical Analyses Using Grossman’s Model• Obesity—The Deterioration of Health Capital• Conclusions

Page 3: Economics 387

THE DEMAND FOR HEALTHConsumer as Health Producer

• Grossman used the theory of human capital to explain the demand for health and health care.

• According to human capital theory, individuals invest in themselves through education, training, and health to increase their earnings.

• Four important aspects of health demand:

Page 4: Economics 387

Consumer as Health Producer

1. It is not medical care as such that consumers want, but rather health. People want health; they demand medical care inputs to produce it.

2. Consumers do not merely purchase health passively from the market. Instead, they produce health, combining time devoted to health-improving efforts with purchased medical inputs.

Page 5: Economics 387

Consumer as Health Producer

3. Health lasts for more than one period. It does not depreciate instantly, and it can be analyzed like a capital good.

4. Perhaps, most importantly, health can be treated both as a consumption good and an investment good. As a consumption good, health is desired because it makes people feel better. As an investment good, health is desired because it increases the number of healthy days available to work and to earn income.

Page 6: Economics 387

Health Capital

• Your body is like a “car.”

• Huh ???Huh ???

• How do we think of the body as a capital good, and medical care as a health investment ???

Page 7: Economics 387

A Schematic

Figure 7-1 Investing in Health Care

Page 8: Economics 387

A Model for Time Spent Producing Health

• I = I(M,TH), where I is investment in health, M is market health inputs and TH is time used in the production of health

• B = B(X,TB), where B is other goods produced, X is market purchased goods and TB is time used producing other goods

• The ultimate resource is time:

T = TH (improving health) + TB (producing other goods) + TL ( lost to illness) + TW (working)

Page 9: Economics 387

LABOR–LEISURE TRADE-OFFS

• Suppose now the time spent creating health investment to be “health-improvement time” TH and call TB the leisure time.

• Assume TH and TL are fixed (we will relax this assumption later)

• Time available for work or leisure=365- TH – TL= TB + TW

• TB is measured toward to the right while TW

is measured toward the left.

Page 10: Economics 387

LABOR–LEISURE TRADE-OFFSLabor-Leisure Model

• VS represents the labor-leisure trade-off faced which reflects the wage rate.

• Given labor-leisure preferences represented with indifference curves, utility is maximized at income of Y2 and leisure time A.

Figure 7-2 Labor-Leisure Trade-Off

Page 11: Economics 387

Impact of Investments in Health• Over time investments in

health reduce time lost to illness, TL’, and thereby increase leisure time 365 –TH’ – TL’.

• The labor-leisure tradeoff line shifts to the right allowing for a choice with more income and more leisure time at E’.

Figure 7-3 Increased Amount of Healthy Time Due to Investment

Page 12: Economics 387

THE INVESTMENT/CONSUMPTION ASPECTS OF HEALTH

Production of Healthy Days

• This illustrates the production of healthy days using a single input, health stock.

• If health stock falls below Hmin, it indicates death.

• The shape of the function indicates diminishing marginal returns.

Figure 7-4 Relationship of Healthy Days to Health Stock

Page 13: Economics 387

Production of Home and Health Goods

• AECD represents production possibilities.

• If health is an investment good only, indifference curves look like U1. will not trade any B to get additional health.

• If health is a consumption good then indifference curves look like U2.

Figure 7-5 Allocation of Production Between Heath and Bread

Page 14: Economics 387

INVESTMENT OVER TIMEThe Cost of Capital

• We demand health capital because it helps us earn more and feel better. What does it cost? By analogy, a health clinic purchases thousands of dollars of X-ray equipment. The return to the X-ray equipment is in the future earnings that ownership of the equipment can provide.

Page 15: Economics 387

The Cost of Capital

• Suppose that an X-ray machine costs $200,000, and that its price does not change over time. Suppose that the annual income attributable to the use of the X-ray machine is $40,000 for 5 years. Is purchasing the machine a good investment?

Page 16: Economics 387

The Cost of Capital

• Consider the alternative: Instead of purchasing the X-ray machine, the clinic could have put the $200,000 in a savings account, at 5 percent interest, yielding the following:

200,000 x 1.05 = 210,000 at the end of Year 1

210,000 x 1.05 = 220,500 at the end of Year 2

220,500 x 1.05 = 231,525 at the end of Year 3

231,525 x 1.05 = 243,101 at the end of Year 4

243,101 x 1.05 = 255,256 at the end of Year 5

Page 17: Economics 387

The Cost of Capital

• For the investment in an X-ray machine to be desirable by these criteria, it should provide at least $55,256 in incremental revenue over the five years.

• The problem is more complicated, however, because capital goods depreciate over time.

• For an investment in an X-ray machine to be worthwhile, then, it must not only earn the competitive 5 percent return each year, but it also must provide enough return to cover depreciation.

Page 18: Economics 387

Cost of Capital

• The problem is more complicated, however, because most capital goods depreciate over time.

• The clinic must earn enough not only to cover the opportunity cost from the bank, but also to maintain the value of the machine. For the investment to be worthwhile, then, it must not only earn the competitive 5 percent return each year, but it must also provide enough return to cover depreciation of the machine.

Page 19: Economics 387

Cost of capital

This suggests that the cost of holding this capital good for any one year, as well as over time, will equal the opportunity cost of the capital (interest foregone) plus the depreciation (deterioration of value).

Page 20: Economics 387

The Demand for Health Capital

• Conventional economic analysis provides a powerful conceptual apparatus by which to analyze the demand for a capital good.

• The cost of capital, in terms of foregone resources (for health capital, both time and money) is a supply concept.

• The other needed tool is the concept of the marginal efficiency of investment, the MEI, a demand concept which relates the return to investment to the amount of resources invested.

Page 21: Economics 387

Marginal Efficiency of Investment and Rate of Return

• MEI is the marginal efficiency of investment. As investment in the stock of health increases, the rate of return on additional investment declines.

• If the foregone interest rate plus depreciation is r + δ0, then optimal investment is H0,

which represents the amount of capital at which the marginal efficiency of investment just equals the cost of capital.

Figure 7-6 Optimal Health Stock

Page 22: Economics 387

Marginal Efficiency of Investment• If they considered owning two X-ray machines, they would discover

that the rate of return to the second X-ray machine was probably less than the first.

• To understand this, consider that a clinic buying only one X-ray machine would assign it to the highest priority uses, those with the highest rate of return. If they were to add a second X-ray machine, then logically it could only be assigned to lesser priority uses (and might be idle on occasion). Thus it would have a lower rate of return than the first.

• The clinic would then purchase the second X-ray machine as well, only if its rate of return was still higher than interest plus depreciation.

Page 23: Economics 387

CHANGES IN EQUILIBRIUM: AGE, WAGE, AND EDUCATION

Impact of Age on Investment in Health

• As we age, our health stock depreciates faster, that is, the depreciation rate rises from δ0 to δ1 to δD.

• The result of aging in this model is a continuously falling optimal level of health stock.

Figure 7-6 Optimal Health Stock

Page 24: Economics 387

CHANGES IN EQUILIBRIUM: AGE, WAGE, AND EDUCATIONImpact of Age on Investment in Health

• Age may also shift the MEI curve to the left, because the returns from an investment will last for a shorter period of time.

• This will reinforce the decrease in investment that occurs due to increased depreciation.

Page 25: Economics 387

Wage Rate

• As the wage rate rises, so does the return from healthy days and therefore the MEI curve shifts to the right.

• It is now optimal to increase health stock from H0 to H2.

Figure 7-6 Optimal Health Stock

Page 26: Economics 387

Education• Education is seen as

improving the efficiency of producing health which shifts the MEI curve to the right.

• The optimal investment in health stock increases from H0 to H2.

Figure 7-6 Optimal Health Stock

Page 27: Economics 387

EMPIRICAL ANALYSES USING GROSSMAN’S MODEL

Results

• Sickles and Yazbeck (1998) developed and estimated a structural model of health production that looks at the demand for leisure and the demand for consumption for elderly males. They find that both health care and leisure consumption tend to improve health.

Page 28: Economics 387

Results

• Demand for health is estimated by Gerdtham and Johannesson (1999) and their results are consistent with the theoretical predictions and show that the demand for health increases with income and education and decreases with age, urbanization, being overweight, and being single.

Page 29: Economics 387

OBESITY—THE DETERIORATION OF HEALTH CAPITAL

Table 7-1 Weight Status Classified by Body Mass Index

Page 30: Economics 387

Table 7-2 2009 US State Obesity Rates

Page 31: Economics 387

An Economic Treatment of Obesity

• Yaniv, Rosin, and Tobol (2009) note that the human body needs energy to function, with food being the fuel that creates this energy. Their theory of obesity views weight gain as the outcome of a rational choice that reflects willingness to tradeoff future health for present pleasures of eating and lower physical activity.

Page 32: Economics 387

An Economic Treatment of ObesityOverweight individuals can consume junk-food meals, F, and healthy meals, H. They may choose their level of exercise, x. The model defines obesity, S, as:

where δ and ɛ represent calorie per meal F and H, respectively, and μ represents calories expended per instant of physical activity. BMR is the Basal Metabolic Rate, the largest source of energy expenditure.

Page 33: Economics 387

An Economic Treatment of ObesityPeople may eat snacks when they are not hungry, so FS and M denote snacks and hunger-induced meals, respectively:

When the two equations are combined, we see the following result:

When junk food is substituted for a healthy option, S increases by (δ – ɛ).

Page 34: Economics 387

Economic Effects of Obesity• Obesity is a bad health investment, leading to higher

medical expenditures and lower earnings. Finkelstein and colleagues (2009) report that medical spending for the obese was about 42 percent higher per year when compared to someone of normal weight.

• Cawley (2004) finds that heavier white females, black females, Hispanic females, and Hispanic males tend to earn less, and heavier black males tend to earn more, than their less heavy counterparts.

Page 35: Economics 387

Why Has Obesity Increased?• Cutler, Glaser, and Shapiro (2003) show that there was

increased caloric intake for men and women from the late 1970s to the late 1990s.

Table 7-3 Changes in Food Consumption, 1977-1978 to 1994-1996

Page 36: Economics 387

Why Has Obesity Increased?• The reductions in the time required to prepare food

reduced the per-calorie cost of food by 29 percent from 1965 to 1995.

Table 7-4 Time Costs by Demographic Group (minutes)

Page 37: Economics 387

CONCLUSIONS

• People benefit from health in four important ways:­ They feel better when well.

­ They lose less time to illness, and hence can work more.

­ They are more productive when they work and can earn more for each hour they work.

­ They may live longer.

Page 38: Economics 387

CONCLUSIONS

• By analyzing the demand for health in this way, we recognize that the demands for health care inputs— from physicians’ services, to drugs, to therapy—are demands that are derived from the demand for health itself.