Top Banner

Click here to load reader

70

ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons...

Feb 01, 2018

Download

Documents

truongmien
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

ECON 337901

FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Peter Ireland

Boston College

Spring 2018

These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike4.0 International (CC BY-NC-SA 4.0) License. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/4.0/.

Page 2: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Two Perspectives on Asset Pricing

Where we have been . . .

A Introduction

1 Mathematical and Economic Foundations2 Overview of Asset Pricing Theory

B Decision-Making Under Uncertainty

3 Making Choices in Risky Situations4 Measuring Risk and Risk Aversion

C The Demand for Financial Assets

5 Risk Aversion and Investment Decisions6 Modern Portfolio Theory

Page 3: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Two Perspectives on Asset Pricing

. . . and where we are heading:

D Classic Asset Pricing Models

7 The Capital Asset Pricing Model8 Arbitrage Pricing Theory

E Arrow-Debreu Pricing

9 Arrow-Debreu Pricing: Equilibrium10 Arrow-Debreu Pricing: No-Arbitrage

F Extensions

11 Martingale Pricing12 The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model

Page 4: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

7 The Capital Asset Pricing Model

A MPT and the CAPM

B Deriving the CAPM

C Valuing Risky Cash Flows

D Strengths and Shortcomings of the CAPM

Page 5: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

MPT and the CAPM

The Capital Asset Pricing Model builds directly on ModernPortfolio Theory.

It was developed in the mid-1960s by William Sharpe (US,b.1934, Nobel Prize 1990), John Lintner (US, 1916-1983), andJan Mossin (Norway, 1936-1987).

Page 6: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

MPT and the CAPM

William Sharpe, “Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of MarketEquilibrium Under Conditions of Risk,” Journal of FinanceVol.19 (September 1964): pp.425-442.

John Lintner, “The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selectionof Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets,”Review of Economics and Statistics Vol.47 (February 1965):pp.13-37.

Jan Mossin, “Equilibrium in a Capital Asset Market,”Econometrica Vol.34 (October 1966): pp.768-783.

Page 7: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

MPT and the CAPM

But whereas Modern Portfolio Theory is a theory describingthe demand for financial assets, the Capital Asset PricingModel is a theory describing equilibrium in financial markets.

By making an additional assumption – namely, that supplyequals demand in financial markets – the CAPM yieldsadditional implications about the pricing of financial assets andrisky cash flows.

Page 8: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

MPT and the CAPM

Like MPT, the CAPM assumes that investors havemean-variance utility and hence that either investors havequadratic Bernoulli utility functions or that the random returnson risky assets are normally distributed.

Thus, some of the same caveats that apply to MPT also applyto the CAPM.

For example, one might hesitate before applying the CAPM toprice options.

Page 9: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

MPT and the CAPM

The traditional CAPM also assumes that there is a risk freeasset as well as a potentially large collection of risky assets.

Under these circumstances, as we’ve seen, all investors willhold some combination of the riskless asset and the tangencyportfolio: the efficient portfolio of risky assets with the highestSharpe ratio.

Page 10: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

MPT and the CAPM

But the CAPM goes further than the MPT by imposing anequilibrium condition.

Because there is no demand for risky financial assets except tothe extent that they comprise the tangency portfolio, andbecause, in equilibrium, the supply of financial assets mustequal demand, the market portfolio consisting of all existingfinancial assets must coincide with the tangency portfolio.

In equilibrium, that is, “everyone” must “own the market.”

Page 11: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

In the CAPM, equilibrium in financial markets requires thedemand for risky assets – the tangency portfolio – to coincidewith the supply of financial assets – the market portfolio.

Page 12: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

The CAPM’s first implication is immediate: the marketportfolio is efficient.

Page 13: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

The line originating at (0, rf ) and running through(σM ,E (r̃M)) is called the capital market line (CML).

Page 14: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Hence, it also follows that all individually optimal portfoliosare located along the CML and are formed as combinations ofthe risk free asset and the market portfolio.

Page 15: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Recall that the trade-off between the standard deviation andexpected return of any portfolio combining the riskless assetand the tangency portfolio is described by the linearrelationship

E (r̃P) = rf +

[E (r̃T ) − rf

σT

]σP .

Since the CAPM implies that the tangency and marketportfolios coincide, the formula for the Capital Market Line islikewise

E (r̃P) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]σP .

Page 16: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

And since all individually optimal portfolios are located alongthe CML, the equation

E (r̃P) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]σP .

implies that the market portfolio’s Sharpe ratio

E (r̃M) − rfσM

measures the equilibrium price of risk: the expected returnthat each investor gives up when he or she adjusts his or hertotal portfolio to reduce risk.

Page 17: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Next, let’s consider an arbitrary asset – “asset j” – withrandom return r̃j , expected return E (r̃j), and standarddeviation σj .

MPT would take E (r̃j) and σj as “data” – that is, as given.

The CAPM again goes further and asks: if asset j is to bedemanded by investors with mean-variance utility, whatrestrictions must E (r̃j) and σj satisfy?

Page 18: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

To answer this question, consider an investor who takes theportion of his or her initial wealth that he or she allocates torisky assets and divides it further: using the fraction w topurchase asset j and the remaining fraction 1 − w to buy themarket portfolio.

Note that since the market portfolio already includes some ofasset j , choosing w > 0 really means that the investor“overweights” asset j in his or her own portfolio. Conversely,choosing w < 0 means that the investor “underweights” assetj in his or her own portfolio.

Page 19: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Based on our previous analysis, we know that this investor’sportfolio of risky assets now has random return

r̃P = wr̃j + (1 − w)r̃M ,

expected return

E (r̃P) = wE (r̃j) + (1 − w)E (r̃M),

and variance

σ2P = w 2σ2

j + (1 − w)2σ2M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ,

where σjM is the covariance between r̃j and r̃M .

Page 20: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃P) = wE (r̃j) + (1 − w)E (r̃M),

σ2P = w 2σ2

j + (1 − w)2σ2M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ,

We can use these formulas to trace out how σP and E (r̃P)vary as w changes.

Page 21: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

The red curve these traces out how σP and E (r̃P) vary as wchanges, that is, as asset j gets underweighted oroverweighted relative to the market portfolio.

Page 22: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

The red curve passes through M, since when w = 0 the newportfolio coincides with the market portfolio.

Page 23: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

For all other values of w , however, the red curve must liebelow the CML.

Page 24: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Otherwise, a portfolio along the CML would be dominated inmean-variance by the new portfolio. Financial markets wouldno longer be in equilibrium, since some investors would nolonger be willing to hold the market portfolio.

Page 25: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Together, these observations imply that the red curve must betangent to the CML at M.

Page 26: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Tangent means equal in slope.

We already know that the slope of the Capital Market Line is

E (r̃M) − rfσM

But what is the slope of the red curve?

Page 27: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Let f (σP) be the function defined by E (r̃P) = f (σP) andtherefore describing the red curve.

Page 28: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Next, define the functions g(w) and h(w) by

g(w) = wE (r̃j) + (1 − w)E (r̃M),

h(w) = [w 2σ2j + (1 − w)2σ2

M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2,

so thatE (r̃P) = g(w)

andσP = h(w).

Page 29: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

SubstituteE (r̃P) = g(w)

andσP = h(w).

intoE (r̃P) = f (σP)

to obtaing(w) = f (h(w))

and use the chain rule to compute

g ′(w) = f ′(h(w))h′(w) = f ′(σP)h′(w)

Page 30: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Let f (σP) be the function defined by E (r̃P) = f (σP) andtherefore describing the red curve. Then f ′(σP) is the slope ofthe curve.

Page 31: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Hence, to compute f ′(σP), we can rearrange

g ′(w) = f ′(σP)h′(w)

to obtain

f ′(σP) =g ′(w)

h′(w)

and compute g ′(w) and h′(w) from the formulas we know.

Page 32: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

g(w) = wE (r̃j) + (1 − w)E (r̃M),

impliesg ′(w) = E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)

Page 33: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

h(w) = [w 2σ2j + (1 − w)2σ2

M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2,

implies

h′(w) =1

2

{2wσ2

j − 2(1 − w)σ2M + 2(1 − 2w)σjM

[w 2σ2j + (1 − w)2σ2

M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2

}

or, a bit more simply,

h′(w) =wσ2

j − (1 − w)σ2M + (1 − 2w)σjM

[w 2σ2j + (1 − w)2σ2

M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2

Page 34: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

f ′(σP) = g ′(w)/h′(w)

g ′(w) = E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)

h′(w) =wσ2

j − (1 − w)σ2M + (1 − 2w)σjM

[w 2σ2j + (1 − w)2σ2

M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2

imply

f ′(σP) = [E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)]

×[w 2σ2

j + (1 − w)2σ2M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2

wσ2j − (1 − w)σ2

M + (1 − 2w)σjM

Page 35: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

The red curve is tangent to the CML at M. Hence, f ′(σP)equals the slope of the CML when w=0.

Page 36: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

When w = 0,

f ′(σP) = [E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)]

×[w 2σ2

j + (1 − w)2σ2M + 2w(1 − w)σjM ]1/2

wσ2j − (1 − w)σ2

M + (1 − 2w)σjM

implies

f ′(σP) =[E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)]σM

σjM − σ2M

Meanwhile, we know that the slope of the CML is

E (r̃M) − rfσM

Page 37: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

The tangency of the red curve with the CML at M thereforerequires

[E (r̃j) − E (r̃M)]σMσjM − σ2

M

=E (r̃M) − rf

σM

E (r̃j) − E (r̃M) =[E (r̃M) − rf ][σjM − σ2

M ]

σ2M

E (r̃j) − E (r̃M) =

(σjMσ2M

)[E (r̃M) − rf ] − [E (r̃M) − rf ]

E (r̃j) = rf +

(σjMσ2M

)[E (r̃M) − rf ]

Page 38: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃j) = rf +

(σjMσ2M

)[E (r̃M) − rf ]

Letβj =

σjMσ2M

so that this key equation of the CAPM can be written as

E (r̃j) = rf + βj [E (r̃M) − rf ]

where βj , the “beta” for asset j , depends on the covariancebetween the returns on asset j and the market portfolio.

Page 39: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃j) = rf + βj [E (r̃M) − rf ]

This equation summarizes a very strong restriction.

It implies that if we rank individual stocks or portfolios ofstocks according to their betas, their expected returns shouldall lie along a single security market line with slope E (r̃M) − rf .

Page 40: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

According to the CAPM, all assets and portfolios of assets liealong a single security market line. Those with higher betashave higher expected returns.

Page 41: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

There are several complementary ways of interpreting thisresult.

All bring us back to the theme of diversification emphasized byMPT.

Both take us a step further, by emphasizing as well the idea ofaggregate risk, which cannot be “diversified away,” andidiosyncratic risk, which can be diversified away.

Page 42: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

The first interpretation goes directly back to the MPT: a stockwith low and especially negative σjM will be most useful fordiversification.

But then all investors will want to hold that stock. Inequilibrium, therefore, the stock’s price will be high and, givenfuture cash flows, its expected return will be low.

Therefore, stocks with low or negative betas will have lowexpected returns. Investors hold these stocks, despite their lowexpected returns, because of they are useful for diversification.

Page 43: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Conversely, a stock with high, positive σjM will not be veryuseful for diversification.

In equilibrium, therefore, the stock will sell for a low price.

Therefore, stocks with high betas will have high expectedreturns. The high expected return is needed to compensateinvestors, because the stock is not very useful fordiversification.

Page 44: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPMThe second interpretation uses the CAPM equation in itsoriginal form

E (r̃j) = rf +

(σjMσ2M

)[E (r̃M) − rf ]

together with the definition of correlation, which implies

ρjM =σjMσjσM

to re-express the CAPM relationship as

E (r̃j) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]ρjMσj

Page 45: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃j) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]ρjMσj

The term inside brackets is the equilibrium price of risk.

And since the correlation lies between −1 and 1, the termρjMσj , satisfying

ρjMσj ≤ σj ,

represents the “portion” of the total risk σj in asset j that iscorrelated with the market return.

Page 46: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃j) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]ρjMσj

The idiosyncratic risk in asset j , that is, the portion that isuncorrelated with the market return, can be diversified away byholding the market portfolio.

Since this risk can be freely shed through diversification, it isnot “priced.”

Page 47: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃j) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]ρjMσj

Hence, according to the CAPM, risk in asset j is priced only tothe extent that it takes the form of aggregate risk that,because it is correlated with the market portfolio, cannot bediversified away.

Page 48: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃j) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]ρjMσj

Thus, according to the CAPM:

1. Only assets with random returns that are positivelycorrelated with the market return earn expected returnsabove the risk free rate. They must, in order to induceinvestors to take on more aggregate risk.

Page 49: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃j) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]ρjMσj

Thus, according to the CAPM:

2. Assets with returns that are uncorrelated with the marketreturn have expected returns equal to the risk free rate,since their risk can be completely diversified away.

Page 50: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

E (r̃j) = rf +

[E (r̃M) − rf

σM

]ρjMσj

Thus, according to the CAPM:

3. Assets with negative betas – that is, with random returnsthat are negatively correlated with the market return –have expected returns below the risk free rate! For theseassets, E (r̃j) − rf < 0 is like an “insurance premium” thatinvestors will pay in order to insulate themselves fromaggregate risk.

Page 51: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

The third interpretation is based on a statistical regression ofthe random return r̃j on asset j on a constant and the marketreturn r̃M :

r̃j = α + βj r̃M + εj

This regression breaks the variance of r̃j down into two“orthogonal” (uncorrelated) components:

1. The component βj r̃M that is systematically related tovariation in the market return.

2. The component εj that is not.

Do you remember the formula for βj , the slope coefficient in alinear regression?

Page 52: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Consider a statistical regression of the random return r̃j onasset j on a constant and the market return r̃M :

r̃j = α + βj r̃M + εj

Do you remember the formula for βj , the slope coefficient in alinear regression? It is

βj =σjMσ2M

the same “beta” as in the CAPM!

Page 53: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Deriving the CAPM

Consider a statistical regression:

r̃j = α + βj r̃M + εj with βj = σjM/σ2M

the same “beta” as in the CAPM!

But this is not an accident: to the contrary, it restates theconclusion that, according to the CAPM, risk in an individualasset is priced – and thereby reflected in a higher expectedreturn – only to the extent that it is correlated with themarket return.

Page 54: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Valuing Risky Cash Flows

We can also use the CAPM to value risky cash flows.

Let C̃t+1 denote a random payoff to be received at time t + 1(“one period from now”) and let PC

t denote its price at time t(“today.”)

If C̃t+1 was known in advance, that is, if the payoff wereriskless, we could find its value by discounting it at the riskfree rate:

PCt =

C̃t+1

1 + rf

Page 55: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Valuing Risky Cash Flows

But when C̃t+1 is truly random, we need to find its expectedvalue E (C̃t+1) and then “penalize” it for its riskiness either bydiscounting at a higher rate

PCt =

E (C̃t+1)

1 + rf + ψ

or by reducing its value more directly

PCt =

E (C̃t+1) − Ψ

1 + rf

Page 56: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Valuing Risky Cash Flows

PCt =

E (C̃t+1)

1 + rf + ψ

PCt =

E (C̃t+1) − Ψ

1 + rf

The CAPM can help us identify the appropriate risk premiumψ or Ψ.

Our previous analysis suggests that, broadly speaking, the riskpremium implied by the CAPM will somehow depend on theextent to which the random payoff C̃t+1 is correlated with thereturn on the market portfolio.

Page 57: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Valuing Risky Cash Flows

To apply the CAPM to this valuation problem, we can start byobserving that with price PC

t today and random payoff C̃t+1

one period from now, the return on this asset or investmentproject is defined by

1 + r̃C =C̃t+1

PCt

or

r̃C =C̃t+1 − PC

t

PCt

where the notation r̃C emphasizes that this return, like thefuture cash flow itself, is risky.

Page 58: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Valuing Risky Cash Flows

Now the CAPM implies that the expected return E (r̃C ) mustsatisfy

E (r̃C ) = rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

where the project’s beta depends on the covariance of itsreturn with the market return:

βC =σCMσ2M

This is what takes skill: with an existing asset, one can usedata on the past correlation between its return and the marketreturn to estimate beta. With a totally new project that is justbeing planned, a combination of experience, creativity, andhard work is often needed to choose the right value for βC .

Page 59: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Valuing Risky Cash Flows

But once a value for βC is determined, we can use

E (r̃C ) = rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

together with the definition of the return itself

r̃C =C̃t+1

PCt

− 1

to write

E

(C̃t+1

PCt

− 1

)= rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

Page 60: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Valuing Risky Cash Flows

E

(C̃t+1

PCt

− 1

)= rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

implies (1

PCt

)E (C̃t+1) = 1 + rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

PCt =

E (C̃t+1)

1 + rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

Page 61: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Valuing Risky Cash Flows

Hence, through

PCt =

E (C̃t+1)

1 + rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

the CAPM implies a risk premium of

ψ = βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

which, as expected, depends critically on the covariancebetween the return on the risky project and the return on themarket portfolio.

Page 62: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Valuing Risky Cash FlowsAlternatively,

E (r̃C ) = rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

and

r̃C =C̃t+1

PCt

− 1

imply

E

(C̃t+1

PCt

− 1

)= rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

and hence(1

PCt

)E (C̃t+1) = 1 + rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

Page 63: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Valuing Risky Cash Flows

(1

PCt

)E (C̃t+1) = 1 + rf + βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

can be rewritten as

PCt =

E (C̃t+1) − PCt βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

1 + rf

indicating that the CAPM also implies

Ψ = PCt βC [E (r̃M) − rf ]

which, again as expected, depends critically on the covariancebetween the return on the risky project and the return on themarket portfolio.

Page 64: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Strengths and Shortcomings of the CAPM

An enormous literature is devoted to empirically testing theCAPM’s implications.

Although results are mixed, studies have shown that whenindividual portfolios are ranked according to their betas,expected returns tend to line up as suggested by the theory.

Page 65: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Strengths and Shortcomings of the CAPM

A famous article that presents results along these lines is byEugene Fama (Nobel Prize 2013) and James MacBeth, “Risk,Return, and Equilibrium,” Journal of Political Economy Vol.81(May-June 1973), pp.607-636.

Early work on the MPT, the CAPM, and econometric tests ofthe efficient markets hypothesis and the CAPM is discussedextensively in Eugene Fama’s 1976 textbook, Foundations ofFinance.

Page 66: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Strengths and Shortcomings of the CAPM

More recent evidence against the CAPM’s implications ispresented by Eugene Fama and Kenneth French, “CommonRisk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds,” Journal ofFinancial Economics Vol.33 (February 1993): pp.3-56.

This paper shows that equity shares in small firms and in firmswith high book (accounting) to market value have expectedreturns that differ strongly from what is predicted by theCAPM alone.

Quite a bit of recent research has been directed towardsunderstanding the source of these “anomalies.”

Page 67: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Strengths and Shortcomings of the CAPM

Despite some empirical shortcomings, however, the CAPMquite usefully deepens our understanding of the gains fromdiversification.

Related, the CAPM alerts us to the important distinctionbetween idiosyncratic risk, which can be diversified away, andaggregate risk, which cannot.

Page 68: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Strengths and Shortcomings of the CAPM

Like MPT, the CAPM must rely on one of the two strongassumptions – either quadratic utility or normally-distributedreturns – that justify mean-variance utility.

And while the CAPM is an equilibrium theory of asset pricing,it stops short of linking asset returns to underlying economicfundamentals.

These last two points motivate our interest in other assetpricing theories, which are less restrictive in their assumptionsand/or draw closer connections between asset prices and theeconomy as a whole.

Page 69: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Strengths and Shortcomings of the CAPM

These last two points motivate our interest in otherasset-pricing theories, which are less restrictive in theirassumptions and/or draw closer connections between assetprices and the economy as a whole.

Arbitrage Pricing Theory, to which we will turn our attentionnext, yields many of the same implications as the CAPM, butrequires less restrictive assumptions about preferences and thedistribution of asset returns.

Page 70: ECON 337901 FINANCIAL ECONOMICS - irelandp.comirelandp.com/econ3379/notes/ch07slides.pdf · These lecture notes by Peter Ireland are licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommerical-ShareAlike

Strengths and Shortcomings of the CAPM

These last two points motivate our interest in otherasset-pricing theories, which are less restrictive in theirassumptions and/or draw closer connections between assetprices and the economy as a whole.

The equilibrium version of Arrow-Debreu theory draws linksbetween asset prices and the economy that are only implicit inthe CAPM.