Top Banner
DEVELOPMENT P ARADIGMS & AFRICAN DIGITAL INNOVATION: The Cage of New Institutional Economics Dr. Laura Mann Assistant Professor International Development Department/Firoz Lalji Centre for Africa London School of Economics and Political Science (and co-author, Gianluca Iazzolino, Research Associate, ID/FLCA, LSE) Email: [email protected] Twitter: @balootiful
25

DEVELOPMENT PARADIGMS FRICAN DIGITAL INNOVATIONICT4D research Examples of software/apps Transaction Costs • Olumoye, 2018, ^integrated e-Government implementation in Nigeria; •

Oct 22, 2020

Download

Documents

dariahiddleston
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • DEVELOPMENT PARADIGMS &

    AFRICAN DIGITAL INNOVATION: The Cage of New Institutional Economics

    Dr. Laura Mann

    Assistant Professor

    International Development Department/Firoz Lalji Centre for Africa

    London School of Economics and Political Science

    (and co-author, Gianluca Iazzolino, Research Associate, ID/FLCA, LSE)

    Email: [email protected]

    Twitter: @balootiful

    mailto:[email protected]

  • 3 key arguments:

    1. Development as an intellectual battlefield.

    2. African Digital discussions are stuck in a NIE cage .

    3. A more heterodox perspective: ICTs as platforms for competitive

    commercial R&D.

  • PART 1: DEVELOPMENT AS AN

    INTELLECTUAL BATTLEFIELD

  • Knowledge impacts upon economic

    development and global competition

    in two ways:

    First knowledge can make economies

    more competitive in existing areas of

    production through knowledge

    acquisition and technology transfer.

    Second, knowledge can help move

    countries out of fierce competition

    in commodity production into new

    activities with higher barriers to

    entry. I.e. capturing knowledge

    rents through R&D and

    commercialisation.

    Most importantly, industrial

    policy involves incentivizing and

    assisting firms and farms to build

    their technological capabilities

    through acquiring new

    technologies and investing in

    learning how to use them

    efficiently (Whitfield et al., 2015:

    35).

    (See also Sutton et al., 2016,

    Oqubay, 2015 UNECA, 2016).

    Effective insertion into global export

    markets offers the potential for

    sustainable income growth. … The key to a h ie v i g th e e e fi ia l o u t o e lies in the capacity to identify,

    appropriate and protect rents, and in

    the context of intense global

    competition, to develop the capacity

    to master dynamic capabilities in

    order to generate rents on a

    sustainable basis… [A] major category of rents are those that are created by

    producers, increasingly through the

    systematic application of knowledge

    to production. (Kaplinsky and Morris,

    2016: 626 and 626).

    (see also OECD; Naude, 2010; Sutton,

    2010; Greenwald and Stiglitz, 2013;

    Mazzucato, 2015; Shimada, 2015;

    Newman et al., 2016: 85-154).

  • Some have described this change as bringing about an

    industrialisation of freshness (Cramer, 2015) while

    others such as Carlota Perez have suggested that

    resource-rich economies within Latin America and Africa

    might be able to use their rich natural resources to

    develop their own geographical-cum-technological

    barriers to entry within the global economy (Perez,

    2015; Whitfield et al., 2016).

  • Renewal of the development process

    depends on reinvesting the knowledge

    surplus into broad-based productivity and

    back into further knowledge production…

    The struggle over the technological

    surplus is not just a competitive

    struggle between countries but

    also to a certain extent, a struggle

    between public funders of science

    and innovation and the private

    firms that commercial that science

    (Mazzucato, 2015).

  • Development is an

    intellectual battlefield in a

    second sense;

    that mainstream policy

    paradigms have been

    subject to epistemic

    contestation over time.

  • Independence

    Era

    1980s- 1990s 1990s onwards Mid 2000s

    onwards

    Economic

    Policy

    Productivist/stru

    cturalist: strong

    emphasis on

    Industrialisation

    Neo-liberal:

    Getting the prices

    right

    New

    Institutional

    Economics:

    Getting market

    institutions

    right

    Growing

    heterodoxity:

    Re-emergence

    of industrial

    policy (although

    debate).

    Social

    Policy

    Universal Limited Residual/

    targeted

    Transformative

    agenda re-

    emerging but

    institutionally

    fragmented

    (many NGOs).

    Higher

    Education

    Policy

    Linked to

    economic

    planning.

    WB denunciation of

    HE funding. The case

    for liberalisation for

    both financial and

    social reasons.

    Renewed

    emphasis by

    WB but very

    donor-driven

    and

    institutionally

    fragmented.

    Domestic

    support returns

    but still

    institutionally

    fragmented.

    Mkandawire (2014: 179) asks: do we inhabit an open

    marketplace of ideas in which ideas merely emerge

    from the economic reality of the time or do we inhabit a

    rigged marketplace in which those with influence and

    financial power are able to shape the research agenda

    and developmental paradigm in relation to their own

    ideas and interests?

  • PART 2: THE NEW INSTITUTIONAL

    ECONOMICS PARADIGM AND AFRICAN

    DIGITAL ECONOMIES.

  • ICT4D research Examples of software/apps

    Transaction Costs

    • Olumoye, 2018, integrated e-Government implementation in Nigeria;

    • Wenner et al., 2017, Organizational models of mobile payment systems in low-resource environments

    • Alam and Wagner, 2016, The Relative Importance of Monetary and Non-Monetary Drivers for Information and Communication Technology Acceptance in Rural Agribusiness

    • Boateng, 2014, Resources, Electronic-Commerce Capabilities and Electronic-Commerce Benefits: Conceptualizing the Links

    • Baro and Endouware, 2013, The Effects of Mobile Phone on the Socio-economic Life of the Rural Dwellers in the Niger Delta Region of Nigeria

    • G2P payments: Bourse Familiale (Senegal), SAGE (Uganda);

    • P2B payment services: Kopo Kopo (Kenya); BambaPos (Kenya).

    • B2B payment service: Cellulant, ConnectAfrica (Kenya) • P2P payments: Nomanini (Kenya), designed to facilitate

    transfers in the informal economy; Forex, Eastpesa, to perform cross-border payments in East Africa; Bitpesa (Kenya), Blockchain-based money transfer service

    • Aggregators for bulk payments: InTouch (Senegal), Yo Uganda (Uganda)

    • Early arguments about possibilities of Business Process Outsourcing ( flat earth and global opportunities

    Information Asymmetries

    • Furuholt, 2018, The role telecentres play in providing e-government services in rural area ;

    • Qureishi, 2017, The forgotten awaken: ICT s evolving role in the roots of mass discontent

    • Riggins and Weber, 2017, Information asymmetries and identification bias in P2P social microlending;

    • Kampenhout, 2017, There is an app for that? The impact of community knowledge workers in Uganda;

    • Islam and Gronlund, 2011, Bangladesh calling: farmers' technology use practices as a driver for development;

    • Aker and Mbiti, 2010, Mobile Phones and Economic Development in Africa;

    • M-Cow (Kenya) provides relevant information (on market prices, weather, livestock and crop health) to farmers;

    • Abacus (Kenya) helps local and international investors get information about business opportunities in Kenya;

    • Jumo (Kenya) allows several SMEs to share behavioral data from mobile usage to create financial identities;

    • Tala (Kenya) provides customer credit scores to financial institutions.

    • Arguments made about digitizing auction (as in tea, flower and coffee) and marketing boards.

    Property rights

    • Mulalu and Veenendal, 2015, PGIS Based Land Information Mapping and Map Updating to Support Rural Community Knowledge Building

    • Tamowke, 2012,

    • Duvail et al., 2006, Participatory Mapping for Local Management of Natural Resources in Villages of the Rufiji District (Tanzania)

    • GhanaPostGPS - Ghana's official digital property system • Bitland (Ghana) Blockchain-based registration system; • MAST (Mobile Application to Secure Tenure), USAID-

    initiative currently deployed in Tanzania and Zambia; • Kadaster (Jordan), an initiative to digitize land records; • Aadhard (India), a large scale biometric identification

    system to provide all Indian citizens with an ID number linked to biometric indicators and incorporated into formal land transactions to avoid fraud.

  • There is much less attention to the potential roles that ICTs might

    play in reducing production costs. In fact, ICTs have often been

    positioned as technologies that can leapfrog other infrastructural

    deficits like transportation and electricity infrastructure.

    Yet African countries will absolutely need to build strong transport

    and electricity infrastructures if they want to reduce production

    costs and seriously compete within the global economy. Increasing

    market efficiency and assuring property rights will only get you so

    far (See Murphy and Carmody, 2015; Foster et al., 2018).

    Further, the NIE perspective does not help us think

    strategically about the role of ICTs within the knowledge

    economy.

  • WHY THE NARROW FOCUS ON NIE?

  • 1. Much research funding is driven by commercial interests of tech firms like Facebook, IBM, Mastercard, and Visa who have an interest in focusing attention on NIE issues (see Mann, 2018).

    1. The donor community remains an

    important consumer of digital innovation and their approach to economic growth and social policy remains less heterodox and more residual.

    1. Popular appeal of the Silicon Valley

    culture among tech developers and perhaps a limited understanding of the context in which many digital innovations within the US emerged (i.e. from federally funded labs). See Block, 2011; Weiss, 2014; Mazzucato, 2015).

    IBM Research - Africa Scientists

    at Riara School, Nairobi.

  • PART 3: THE ROLE OF DIGITAL

    TECHNOLOGIES IN A COMPETITIVE

    KNOWLEDGE ECONOMY

  • But also data gatherers.

    And platforms for

    research and

    development.

    ICTs as market enablers (in

    the New Institutional

    Economic) frame…

  • Important Notes on African R&D

    1. Adjustment era has had a profound impact on African institutions of higher education and research: massive brain drain, switch of curriculum away from research towards professional courses, dependence on foreign funding, a context in which African researchers are often forced into the role of data gatherers for foreign research projects (Mamdani, 2007).

    1. Due to the dependence on foreign sources of finance, research in

    African countries is heavily dominated by donor paradigms. 1. Particularly, as research becomes increasingly commoditized and

    audited within advanced economies, there is a strong emphasis on commercial applications of publicly funded research and humanitarian aid. Thus in both the private and public sector, we see an increasing overlap between the developmental paradigms of donor countries, their research agendas and the commercial interests of their firms and scientists (McGoey, 2014).

  • The growing importance of the

    private sector and value chains

    compelling the incorporation of

    a business school optique into

    research and training (Moock,

    2011: 16)

  • Platform Extension

    Worker User Digital Disintermediation

    or Re-intermediation?

    ICTS IN RESEARCH ACTION

    Photo from interview with m-health firm in

    Rwanda, 2013

  • If we think back to the idea of development as

    being about generating a sustainable technological

    surplus, we see how ICTs can become platforms

    for extracting technological surplus from existing

    value chains. Therefore while ICTs increase

    efficiency for their users (through the NIE

    paradigm), they also generate a new kind of value

    from the data itself.

  • Struggles over

    Data-Driven Agro-Innovation in

    California’s Central Valley and

    Kenya’s Rift Valley

    http://www.lse.ac.uk/africa/research/twov

    ys

    http://www.lse.ac.uk/africa/research/twovalleyshttp://www.lse.ac.uk/africa/research/twovalleyshttp://www.lse.ac.uk/africa/research/twovalleys

  • • Farmers in both regions are deploying

    digital technology to

    increase productivity

    and reduce transaction

    costs. Some are also

    using tech to move

    into new areas with

    technological

    premiums (single

    origin, fairtrade,

    organic, etc.)

    • As compliance hardens or as farmers integrate

    within larger input and

    supply chains, these

    digital systems may

    become requirements.

    • Informational chains have value beyond

    farmer and compliance

    agency, providing the

    platform operator with

    valuable market

    intelligence and

    framework for R&D.

    • Thus while digital platforms promise to

    increase production,

    reduce waste and

    ensure compliance, they

    also generate a new

    economic value (or

    technological premium)

    for the controllers of

    the platform….

  • Research Question:

    Will this datafication of the agricultural value chain

    boost the competitiveness of agriclusters in emerging

    countries like Kenya? Or will it instead widen the

    knowledge gap, with actors from more advanced

    economies monopolising control over the technological

    surplus generated by digital data on farms in both North

    and South?

  • EMBRAPA (Empresa

    Brasiliera de Pesquisa

    Agropecuaria)

    California’s Central Valley

    Kenya’s Rift Valley Potentially Brazil

  • 1. To encourage African tech developers to look beyond the NIE

    frame and see both the limits of NIE, and the potential

    opportunities of a wider paradigmatic horizon.

    2. To draw attention to the research context, both in terms of the

    funding of ICT related research within African countries, but also

    the ways in which ICTs are being embedded within research

    partnerships in other areas such as agriculture and social policy.

    3. To see these research partnerships as being marked by commercial

    imperatives, and thus to a certain degree, competitiveness over

    the knowledge or technological surplus generated through digital

    intermediation and data.

    4. To push back against a technologically deterministic account of

    digital economic change by demonstrating how the economic

    impacts of digital technologies critically depend on the nature of

    the dominant developmental paradigm or ideas being pursued by

    its firms, policy-makers and funding agencies.

    Conclusions

  • Questions?

    Some relevant publications (happy to share any of them): Kleibert, J. and L. Mann (Unpublished but Draft Available) Capturing Value Amidst Global Restructuring? Economic Development and Information and Technology-Enabled Services in India, the Philippines and Kenya Mann, L. (2018) Left to Other Peoples Devices: A Political Economy Perspective on the Big Data Revolution in Development Development and Change 49(1): 3-36. Foster, Christopher, Graham, Mark, Mann, Laura, Waema, Timothy and Nicholas Friederici (2018) Digital Control in Value Chains: Challenges of Connectivity for East African Firms Economic Geography 94(1) Connectivity at the OP Forum (2017) Connectivity at the Bottom of the Pyramid: ICT4D and Informal Economic Inclusion in Africa Bellagio Centre White Paper, December 2017. Mann, L. and M. Graham (2016) The Domestic Turn: Business Processing Outsourcing and the Growing Automation of Kenyan Organisations Journal of Development Studies 52(4): 530-548. Mann, L. and E. Nzayisenga (2015) Sellers on the Street: the Human Infrastructure of the Mobile Phone Network in Kigali, Rwanda Critical African Studies 7(1): 26-46

    My email: [email protected]

    My twitter: @balootiful (personal) and @TwoGreenValleys (new project- content coming

    very soon!)

    mailto:[email protected]