Top Banner
Corporate Governance, Shareholder Rights and Firm Diversification: An Empirical Analysis Pornsit Jiraporn* Department of Accounting, Economics and Finance Texas A&M International University Laredo, Texas 78041 Phone: (956) 326-2518 Email: [email protected] Young Sang Kim Department of Economics and Finance Northern Kentucky University Phone: (859) 572-5160 Email: [email protected] Wallace N. Davidson III Department of Finance College of Business and Administration Southern Illinois University, Carbondale Phone: (618) 453-1429 Email: [email protected] Manohar Singh Associate Professor of Finance Atkinson Graduate School of Management Willamette University, Salem Phone: (503) 698-1947 Email: [email protected] Date: June 27, 2005 JEL Classification: G30, G32, G34 Keywords: diversification, corporate governance, shareholder rights * Correspondence author
33

Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

Mar 11, 2023

Download

Documents

Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

Corporate Governance, Shareholder Rights and Firm

Diversification: An Empirical Analysis

Pornsit Jiraporn* Department of Accounting, Economics and Finance

Texas A&M International University Laredo, Texas 78041

Phone: (956) 326-2518 Email: [email protected]

Young Sang Kim

Department of Economics and Finance Northern Kentucky University

Phone: (859) 572-5160 Email: [email protected]

Wallace N. Davidson III Department of Finance

College of Business and Administration Southern Illinois University, Carbondale

Phone: (618) 453-1429 Email: [email protected]

Manohar Singh

Associate Professor of Finance Atkinson Graduate School of Management

Willamette University, Salem Phone: (503) 698-1947

Email: [email protected]

Date: June 27, 2005

JEL Classification: G30, G32, G34

Keywords: diversification, corporate governance, shareholder rights

* Correspondence author

Page 2: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

2

Corporate Governance, Shareholder Rights and Firm

Diversification: An Empirical Analysis

Abstract

Grounded in agency theory, this study investigates how the strength of shareholder rights influences the extent of firm diversification and the excess value attributable to diversification. The empirical evidence reveals that the strength of shareholder rights is inversely related to the probability to diversify. Furthermore, firms where shareholder rights are more suppressed by restrictive corporate governance suffer a deeper diversification discount. Specifically, we document a 1.1-1.4% decline in firm value for each additional governance provision imposed on shareholders. An explicit distinction is made between global and industrial diversification. Our results support agency theory as an explanation for the value reduction in diversified firms. The evidence in favor of agency theory appears to be more pronounced for industrial diversification than for global diversification.

Page 3: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

3

Corporate Governance, Shareholder Rights and Firm

Diversification: An Empirical Analysis

I. Introduction

Considerable research has explored the issue of corporate diversification. One

critical question is whether corporate diversification enhances or destroys value. Early

researchers argued in favor of diversification citing factors such as greater operating

efficiency, the presence of an internal capital market, greater debt capacity, and lower

taxes (for example, Fluck and Lynch, 1999; Bradley, Desai, and Kim, 1988; Kaplan and

Weisbach, 1992; Porter, 1987; Ravenscraft, 1987; among others). During the 1950’s and

1960’s, many corporations took on various diversification programs. Recently, however,

the trend has reversed and many firms have returned to specialization.

Several academic studies in the 1990’s provide evidence on the destructive effect

on firm value of corporate diversification (for example, Comment and Jarrell, 1995;

Liebeskind and Opler, 1995; Lang and Stulz, 1994; Servaes, 1996; Berger and Ofek,

1995; Denis, Denis, and Yost, 2002, among others). More recently, arguments have been

advanced and new evidence presented that diversification may be beneficial or, at the

minimum, not value-destroying (Villalonga, 2004; Whited, 2001; Campa and Kedia,

2002; and Mansi and Reeb, 2002). Others have suggested that it may be the acquisition

of poorly performing units (Graham, Lemmon and Wolf, 2002) or miscalculations of

Tobin’s q (Whited, 2001) that explain the diversification discount. Hence, the debate on

the impact of diversification still continues in the literature.

Motivated by agency theory, we contribute to the literature in this area by

exploring the role of the agency costs in explaining the value discount (or premium?)

Page 4: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

4

caused by diversification. In so doing, we examine the relation between firm value,

corporate governance, shareholder rights and the propensity to diversify. We employ the

Governance Index developed by Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003) to represent the

strength of shareholder rights. Gompers et al (2003) construct a Governance Index on the

basis of how many corporate governance provisions exist that restrict shareholder rights,

with a higher index indicating weaker shareholder rights.

This study examines the influence of shareholder rights both on the extent of

diversification and on the excess value arising from diversification. First, we investigate

the relation between the propensity to diversify and the strength of shareholder rights.

We find evidence that firms where shareholder rights are weak are more likely to be

industrially diversified. This evidence is in favor of the explanation that managers exploit

the weak shareholder rights and diversify the firm unwisely. As a result, industrially

diversified firms exhibit a reduction in value. The evidence on global diversification,

however, is more ambiguous. We find no relation between the strength of shareholder

rights and the propensity to be diversified globally. Hence, global diversification does not

appear to be motivated by managers taking advantage of weak shareholder rights. The

value reduction affiliated with global diversification (Denis, Denis, and Yost, 2002),

therefore, may not be explained by the agency cost perspective.

Second, we investigate the impact of shareholder rights on firm value. To measure

the valuation effects, we use the concept of excess value, first developed by Berger and

Ofek (1995). We document that more restrictive corporate governance is associated with

lower excess value in diversified firms. Apparently, where shareholder rights are weaker,

firms suffer a more severe reduction in value. The detrimental effect on firm value of

Page 5: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

5

weak shareholder rights is found in all of the diversification categories except for global

diversification. This evidence is consistent with an agency cost explanation. Diversified

firms where shareholder rights are weak (and, therefore, management powers are strong)

are expected to suffer from acute agency costs created by the separation of ownership and

control. More specifically, we document that each additional restrictive governance

provision imposed on the shareholders diminishes the excess value by approximately 1.1-

1.4% on average1.

The study is organized as follows. We discuss our hypotheses in Section II. The

sample selection criteria and data are discussed in Section III. Then, Section IV displays

the empirical evidence and, finally, Section V concludes.

II. Hypothesis Development

A. Propensity to diversify and shareholder rights

Jensen (1986) argues that, when managers have access to free cash flow, they

tend to spend it unwisely reducing shareholder wealth. There are several ways in which

the free cash flow could be “wasted”. One possibility might be for managers to consume

extra perquisites that are unnecessary. Another possibility could be managers attempting

to expand the firm through acquisitions in unrelated business segments that may not

supply adequate returns to the shareholders. We make an explicit distinction between

global and industrial diversification and argue that weak shareholder rights enable

managers to diversify the firm (perhaps, unwisely) either globally or industrially or both.

Hence, we hypothesize an inverse relation between the strength of shareholder rights and

the propensity for diversification, the weaker the shareholder rights, the more diversified

1 As shown later in the paper, the average firm has about 9 governance provisions. Thus, the average discount that can be attributed to restriction on shareholder rights is roughly 9.9-12.6%, which is both statistically and economically significant.

Page 6: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

6

the firm is expected to be. Our first three hypotheses are related to the strength of

shareholder rights and the propensity to diversify globally, industrially or both.

H1: When shareholder rights are more restricted, firms are more likely to be globally diversified.

H2: When shareholder rights are more restricted, firms are more likely to be

industrially diversified. H3: When shareholder rights are more restricted, firms are likely to be both globally

and industrially diversified. B. Shareholder rights and firm value

As discussed earlier, we contend that weaker shareholder rights lead to a larger

extent of corporate diversification either globally, industrially or both. The overall effects

of diversification on firm value continue to be debated in the literature. Several studies

document a diversification discount whereas others offer evidence of a diversification

premium. Motivated by agency theory, we argue that diversification that results from

agency conflicts is likely to be value-destroying. Since agency conflicts are likely more

severe in firms with weaker shareholder rights, we hypothesize a positive association

between the strength of shareholder rights and firm value.

H4: When shareholder rights are more restricted, firms experience a deeper diversification discount.

III. Sample Selection and Data

A. Sample selection

The initial sample is obtained from the Research Insight COMPUSTAT Industrial

Segment file (CIS) and the Geographic Segment file (CGS) over the period 1993-1998.2

2 Since the segment data are available only for active firms in COMPUSTAT, there may be some survivorship bias in our sample. However, as noted by Denis et al (2002), this bias may not be significant

Page 7: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

7

A firm is classified as industrially diversified if it reports more than one segment in the

CIS file. A firm is regarded as geographically diversified if it reports foreign sales in the

CGS file. Under SFAS No.14 (Statement of Financial Accounting Standards, 1976) and

SEC Regulation S-K, firms are required to report information on industry and geographic

segments whose sales, assets, or profits exceed 10% of the consolidated totals.

Firms are excluded that have segments in the financial industry (SIC codes 6000-

6999) and the utility industry (SIC codes 4900-4999) because these industries are subject

to regulations, rendering the characteristics of their financial information incomparable to

those in other industries. Additional constraints are imposed as in Berger and Ofek

(1995). We exclude firms with sales less than $20 million and firms where the difference

between the sum of the segment sales and total sales exceed 1%.

We further reduce the sample by excluding those observations that do not have

data on the Governance Index in the Investor Responsibility Research Center (IRRC).

The IRRC collects data on corporate governance. However, the IRRC collects data only

periodically and our sample is, therefore, restricted to the years in which the IRRC has

data. For our study, we use data from 1993, 1995 and 1998. The IRRC does not have

governance data for 1994, 1996 and 1997.

Each firm in the final sample is, then, classified into one of the four

diversification categories. Figure 1 shows the four diversification regimes classified

along two diversification dimensions, industrial and global. The final sample consists of a

total of 1,862 firm-year observations. Figure 2 presents the year distribution of firms in

the sample.

enough to contaminate the results. In fact, our empirical results are similar to those of Denis et al (2002), implying that survivorship bias does not distort our results.

Page 8: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

8

-----Insert Figure 1 about here----- -----Insert Figure 2 about here-----

B. The Governance Index (GINDEX)

To measure the strength of shareholder rights, we employ the Governance Index

(GINDEX) developed by Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003) - henceforth GIM. They

use data from the Investor Responsibility Research Center (IRRC), which publishes

detailed listings of corporate governance provisions for individual firms in Corporate

Takeover Defenses (Rosenbaum, 1993, 1995, and 1998). The data on governance

provisions are derived from various sources, such as corporate bylaws, charters, proxy

statements, annual reports, as well as 10-K and 10-Q documents filed with the Security

and Exchange Commission (SEC). The individual governance provisions included in the

construction of the Governance Index are displayed in Table 1. The detailed explanation

for each governance provision is available in the appendix of GIM. They classify

provisions into 5 categories: tactics for delaying hostile bidders (Delay); voting rights

(Voting); director/officer protection (Protection); other takeover defenses (Other); and

state laws (State). Table 1 shows the percentage of firms in our sample that have each

provision in each sample year.

-----Insert Table 1 about here----- The Governance Index is constructed as follows; for every firm, GIM add one

point for every provision that restricts shareholder rights (increases managerial power).

While this index does not accurately reflect the relative impacts of the various provisions,

it has the advantage of being transparent and easily reproducible. The index does not

Page 9: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

9

require any judgments about the efficacy or wealth effects of any of these provisions;

GIM only considers the impact on the balance of power.

To clarify the logic behind the construction of the Governance Index, GIM use the

following example; consider classified boards, a provision that staggers the terms and

elections of directors and, thus, can be employed to slow down a hostile takeover. If

management uses this power judiciously, it could possibly lead to an increase in overall

shareholder wealth; if management, however, uses this power to maintain private benefits

of control, then this provision would diminish shareholder wealth. Either way, it is

apparent that classified boards enhance the power of managers and weaken the control

rights of large shareholders. Hence, the Governance Index captures the balance of power

between management and shareholders.

Most provisions other than classified boards can be viewed with the same logic.

Almost every provision enables management to resist different types of shareholder

activism, such as calling special meetings, changing the firm’s charter or bylaws, suing

the directors, or replacing them all at once. GIM note, however, that there are two

exceptions, secret ballots (confidential voting) and cumulative voting. A secret ballot or

confidential voting designates a third party to count proxy votes and, therefore, prevents

management from observing how specific shareholders vote. Cumulative voting enables

shareholders to concentrate their directors’ votes so that a large minority shareholder can

ensure some board representation. These two provisions are usually proposed by

shareholders and opposed by management because they enhance shareholder rights and

diminish the power of management. Thus, for each one, GIM add one point to the

Governance Index when firms do not have it. For all other provisions, GIM add one point

Page 10: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

10

when firms do have each of the provisions. In summary, the Governance Index is simply

the sum of one point for the presence (or absence) of each provision.

C. Excess Value

To measure the value of globally and industrially diversified firms, we use the

excess value measure following the modified version of Berger and Ofek (1995). We use

the single-segment domestic firm as the benchmark to compute excess value. We argue

that the excess value measure is superior to Tobin’s q (Lang and Stulz (1994)) because

Tobin’s q requires replacement cost in the denominator and neither foreign inflation rates

nor the exchange rate effect are taken into account. The excess value measure is

computed following Berger and Ofek (1995) with the modification in Bodnar, Tang, and

Weintrop (1999), and is defined as follows.

EVi,t= log (MVi,t / Imputed Value i,t)

Imputed Value i,t = ∑ (SSale i,t× Multiplier)

Where: EVi,t is the excess value for firm i in year t; MVi,t is the firm’s market

capitalization (market value of common equity plus book value of debt) for firm i in year

t; and Imputed Value is the sum of segment sales multiplied by the sales multiplier. The

Multiplier is measured as the median total market capitalization to sales for the single-

segment domestic firms in the same industry in the same year. A positive excess value

indicates that the entire firm is worth as a whole more than the sum of its segments

whereas a negative excess value shows that the firm as a whole is worth less than the sum

of its segments. Thus, a positive excess value implies a diversification premium while a

negative excess value indicates a diversification discount.

IV. Empirical Evidence

Page 11: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

11

A. Summary statistics

Descriptive statistics for selected firm characteristics for our sample appear in

Table 2 Panel A. The multi-segment domestic firm is not significantly larger than its

single-segment counterpart in terms of sales but significantly larger in terms of total

assets (2,605.62 vs. 2,846.33 in sales and 2,021.95 vs. 2,575.76 in total assets). Multi-

segment global firms, however, are considerably larger than single-segment firms both in

terms of sales and total assets (2,910.84 vs. 6,093.77 in sales and 2,725.20 vs. 6, 524.77

in total assets). Multi-segment firms have larger debt ratios, smaller capital expenditures,

and smaller R&D expenditures. Likewise, global firms have larger debt ratios, lower

capital expenditures and smaller R&D expenditures. In terms of managerial (executives

and board members) ownership, there is no significant difference between single-segment

domestic (SD) firms and multi-segment domestic (MD) firms (14.13% vs. 12.69%).

However, the difference is significant between single-segment global (SG) firms and

multi-segment global (MG) firms (10.74% vs. 8.46%).

-----Insert Table 2 about here----- Panel B of Table 2 displays the excess value3 by diversification type. It should be

noted that the excess value for single-segment domestic firms is the highest, suggesting

that focused firms are more valuable. As mentioned earlier, we do not concentrate on

ascertaining whether the excess value is, on average, positive or negative. Rather, our

3 The excess value is constructed as described in Berger and Ofek (1995). The benchmark firm is the single-segment domestic firm. In computing the excess value, we use the entire universe of firms with available data on COMPUSTAT. Then, we retain only the observations where the Governance Index is available. The summary statistics shown here are only for the observations that remain in the final sample. Firms that are followed by the IRRC tend to be large and well-established. Hence, firms with low excess value are, perhaps, less likely to be included. This may explain why both the mean and the median are positive although diversification is found to be value-destroying.

Page 12: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

12

focus is on determining the association between the excess value and the strength of

shareholder rights.

B. Propensity to diversify and shareholder rights

Table 3 presents the univariate analysis for the Governance Index and the extent

of firm diversification. In the last column, we test domestic firms against global firms

regardless of whether they are industrially diversified or not. The average number of

governance provision for the domestic firm is 9.01 (median 9.00) and that for the global

firm is 9.47 (median 10.00). The different is statistically significant at the 1% level both

in the t-test and in the distribution-free non-parametric test (Z-score). The evidence

reveals that weaker shareholder rights (more restrictive governance) are associated with

global diversification.

------Insert Table 3 about here-----

In the last row of Table 3, we compare single-segment firms with multi-segment

firms, regardless of whether they operate globally or just domestically. The average

number of governance provisions of the single-segment firm is 8.73 (median 9.00) while

that for the multi-segment firm is 9.83 (median 10.00). The difference is statistically

significant at the 1% level. Firms where shareholder rights are weak seem to be

industrially diversified.

We also divide the sample further into single-segment domestic (SD), single-

segment global (SG), multi-segment domestic (MG) and multi-segment global (MD)

firms. The multi-segment global firm (MG) has 9.87 governance provisions on average

(median 10.00). This is higher than the numbers of governance provisions in the other

Page 13: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

13

three groups. The results imply that weaker shareholder rights are associated with a

combination of both global and industrial diversification.

We enhance the univariate analysis with a logistic regression analysis presented in

Table 4. A number of control variables are included4. First, several prior studies show

that firm size impacts the extent of corporate diversification. For instance, Dennis et al

(1997) provide evidence that the number of business segments in which a firm operates is

positively related to firm size. Similarly, Singh et al (2004) provide evidence that firm

size is a positive predictor of firm diversification in that larger firms have greater

propensity to be diversified. As a result, we employ the logarithm of total assets to

control for firm size. Furthermore, Denis, Denis, and Sarin (1997) suggest that certain

firms are characterized by the need for large amounts of firm-specific knowledge that is

not easily transferable to other lines of business. Thus, we control for firm-specific

knowledge by including a measure of R&D intensity (R&D/Sales). Finally, within

Jensen’s agency framework (1986), firms where managerial ownership is high tend to

have shareholders’ and managers’ interests better aligned and, therefore, suffer less

agency costs. Morck et al (1988) and McConnell et al (1990) provide evidence of a

predominantly positive relation between corporate value and managerial ownership. With

respect to the relation between diversification and agency costs, managerial ownership is

found to be an important determinant of corporate diversification (Denis, Denis, and

Sarin, 1997). Thus, we include managerial ownership as a control variable as well. Our

managerial ownership variable measures the direct stock ownership by managers and

4 Alternative control variables are used and produce qualitatively similar results. To capture the potential industry effects, we industry-adjust the control variables by subtracting the industry median from the value of each variable for a given firm. The first two digits of the SIC codes are employed to identify the industry.

Page 14: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

14

board of directors and is computed as the number of shares of stock held by the

executives and board members as a percentage of total shares outstanding.

In Model 1, the dependent variable is a dichotomous variable that is equal to 1 if

the firm is globally diversified and 0 otherwise. The coefficient of the Governance Index

in Model 1 is not statistically significant, suggesting no relation between the strength of

shareholder rights and the propensity to be globally diversified. Thus, hypothesis 1 (H1)

does not seem to be supported here.

------Insert Table 4 about here-----

In Model 2, the dependent variable is a dichotomous variable that takes the value

of 1 if the firm is industrially diversified and 0 otherwise. The Governance Index has a

positive and highly significant coefficient. Hence, a higher number of governance

provisions that limit shareholder rights are associated with a higher probability to be

industrially diversified. This evidence is consistent with hypothesis 2 (H2). In Model 3

and Model 4, we include managerial ownership as a control variable5 and obtain

qualitatively similar results on the Governance Index.

To test hypothesis 3 (H3), we estimate a multinomial logistic regression where the

dependent variable is a discrete variable that takes on four possible values (1 if single-

segment domestic (SD), 2 if multi-segment domestic (MD), 3 if single-segment global

(SG) and 4 if multi-segment global (MG)). These four diversification regimes represent

the four possible combinations of global and industrial diversification. The results of the

multinomial logistic regression are displayed in Table 5. The last column of the table

shows the results for the multi-segment global (MG) firm. This group represents firms

5 The data on managerial ownership are available for only 971 firms in the sample. Hence, we include managerial ownership in a separate set of regressions.

Page 15: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

15

that are both globally and industrially diversified. The Governance Index has a positive

and significant estimated coefficient.6 The evidence indicates that a higher number of

governance provisions (weaker shareholder rights) contributes to a greater likelihood that

the firm is both globally and industrially diversified. The evidence lends support to

hypothesis 3 (H3).

------Insert Table 5 about here-----

It can be argued that governance structure and diversification are endogenously

determined. If this is the case, then, the simultaneous equations framework may be more

suitable for testing H1, H2, and H3. As a robustness check, we run Hausman’s

specification test to check for the presence of simultaneity. The Hausman tests are all

statistically insignificant. There is no evidence of simultaneity. We conclude that

endogeneity does not seem to impact the results.

In conclusion, we find support for H2 and H3 but not for H1. More restrictive

governance, which suppresses shareholder rights, is associated with a higher degree of

industrial diversification and the combination of both global and industrial diversification

(but not global diversification alone).

C. Shareholder rights and firm value

We test H4 in a multiple regression framework to control for firm specific

characteristics other than governance and diversification attributes. In Table 6, the results

of a regression analysis are shown. The dependent variable is the excess value (calculated

as in Berger and Ofek, 1994). The test variable is the Governance Index. A number of

control variables are included; global and industrial diversification, firm size (Log of total

6 An alternative regression is run where managerial ownership is included (results omitted). The results remain similar.

Page 16: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

16

assets), profitability (EBIT/sales), debt ratio, growth opportunities (CAPX/sales),

informational asymmetry (R&D/ sales), advertising expenses, and percentage of

managerial ownership. These control variables are employed in a number of prior studies

on diversification (Dennis, Dennis, and Yost, 2002; Berger and Ofek, 1995; among

others).

------Insert Table 6 about here----- We run two sets of regressions. First, we attempt to replicate the results of other

previous studies by regressing the excess value on the diversification dummies and the

control variables. Then, in the second set of regressions, we add the Governance Index in

the regressions to ascertain the impact of the strength of shareholder rights on firm value.

In the first three models in Table 6 (where the Governance Index is not included), all of

the diversification dummies (except the global dummy7) exhibit negative and significant

coefficients, suggesting that diversification reduces firm value.

Then, to determine the impact of the strength of shareholder rights on firm value,

we add the Governance Index in Models 4, 5, and 6. In Model 4, we include the

Governance Index, the global diversification dummy, and the control variables. The

estimated coefficient of the Governance Index is negative and statistically significant.

The evidence is consistent with the hypothesis that firms where shareholder rights are

restricted (high GINDEX) experience low excess value. In Model 5, we replace the

global dummy with the multi-segment dummy. The estimated coefficient for the

Governance Index remains negative and significant. In model 6, we use various

diversification dummies to capture the influence of dual-global and industrial-

diversification strategies and obtain similar results. The results suggest that firms with 7 The coefficient of the global dummy is significant at the 15% level, however.

Page 17: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

17

weak shareholder rights (restrictive governance) suffer a deeper diversification discount8.

The predictions of H4 are, therefore, supported. Notably, consistent with prior empirical

evidence, a higher degree of managerial ownership seems to alleviate agency conflict as

we find that the excess value positively associates with managerial ownership.

The estimated coefficient of the Governance Index varies from -0.011 to -0.014,

indicating that for each additional governance provision imposed on shareholder rights,

the excess value declines by approximately 1.1-1.4%. Because the average firm in the

sample has about 9 governance provisions, the average discount on firm value is about

9.9-12.6% that can be attributed to the suppression of shareholder rights through strict

corporate governance. A discount of this magnitude is both statistically and economically

significant.

Finally, a recently study by Bebchuk, Cohen, and Ferrell (2004) constructs an

“Entrenchment Index” based on 6 of the 24 governance provisions9 in Gompers et al

(2003). They contend that this index can better explain firm value (represented by

Tobin’s q) and stock returns than the Governance Index- specifically, the higher the

Entrenchment Index, the lower the firm value. Following Bebchuk et al (2004), we create

the Entrenchment Index and include it in the regression in Model 7. The coefficient of the

Entrenchment Index is negative and significant, suggesting that managerial entrenchment

is associated with a value reduction. Therefore, our results agree with those in Bebchuk,

Cohen, and Ferrell (2004). 8 As a robustness check, we replace the global dummy with foreign sales as a continuous alternative measure of global diversification and re-run the regression (results omitted). The results are similar. Likewise, we replace the multi-segment dummy with the Herfindahl index as a continuous alternative measure of industrial diversification and re-run the regression (results not shown). The results are, again, consistent with the results arrived at using dummy variable specification. 9 The six provisions included in the Entrenchment Index are staggered boards, limits to shareholder bylaw amendments, supermajority requirements for mergers, supermajority requirements for charter amendments, poison pills, and golden parachutes.

Page 18: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

18

We now examine whether the detrimental effect is uniform across different

diversification categories. We accomplish this by constructing a number of interaction

terms between the Governance Index and the various diversification dummies. The

results of the regressions with the interaction terms appear in Table 7. Model 1 includes

two interaction terms, one that combines the Governance Index with the global dummy

variable and another that combines the Governance Index with the multi-segment dummy

variable. Both of these interaction terms produce negative and significant estimated

coefficients. The results reveal that restrictive governance reduces firm value both in the

presence of global diversification and industrial diversification.

------Insert Table 7 about here-----

In Model 2, we include three interaction terms in the regression, each term

corresponding to the Governance Index interacting with each diversification dummy. All

of the interaction terms in Model 2 display negative and statistically significant estimated

coefficients, implying that restrictive governance provisions destroy value in all of these

diversification categories.

We repeat the previous regressions in Model 3 and Model 4 but add managerial

ownership as a control variable. Interestingly, in Model 3, when managerial ownership is

included, the estimated coefficient of the interaction term between the Governance Index

and global diversification becomes insignificant. The results for the rest of the interaction

terms are qualitatively similar to those in Model 1 and Model 2. The results in Model 3

indicate that, after controlling for managerial ownership, restrictive governance (weak

shareholder rights) does not reduce the excess value in firms that are globally diversified.

It does so, however, in the other diversification regimes.

Page 19: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

19

Finally, in Model 5, we control for the interaction effects between managerial

ownership and diversification. The three variables that interact ownership with the

diversification dummies are added as controls in Model 5. The results in Model 5 are

similar to those in Model 4 except for the interaction term between the Governance Index

and the single-segment global dummy, which loses its significance. This is hardly

surprising, however, given that the Governance Index does not explain global

diversification as much as industrial diversification in the previous analyses.

In summary, there is a positive (negative) relationship between the strength of

shareholder rights (corporate governance) and firm value. The diversification discount is

more severe when the firm has more governance provisions that restrict shareholder

rights. This relation does hold in all of the diversification categories except for global

diversification even after controlling for ownership structure.

V. Concluding Remarks

Corporate diversification has been a topic of interest for researchers in the past

couple of decades. The main thrust of the research in this area is to identify whether

diversification is beneficial or detrimental to firm value. Having enjoyed support in the

1960’s and 1970’s, the benefits of diversification have been viewed with skepticism in

the 1990’s. A number of studies have uncovered the “diversification discount”. The

discount has been corroborated in several recent studies (Comment and Jarrell (1995),

Lang and Stulz (1994), Servaes (1996), Berger and Ofek (1995)). Nevertheless, several

studies published after 2000 have cast doubt on the diversification discount and offer new

perspectives based on more sophisticated methods (Villalonga, 2004; Whited, 2001,

among others).

Page 20: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

20

Because of the on-going debate on the costs and benefits of diversification, we

contribute to the literature by empirically examining the potential connections between

corporate governance, shareholder rights, firm value, and the propensity for a firm to be

diversified. The Governance Index developed by Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003) is

employed as the measure of the strength of shareholder rights. There is evidence that

when shareholder rights are more restricted, the firm is more likely to be diversified. We

argue that weak shareholder rights allow management to diversify the firm unwisely,

resulting in a decline in value.

The excess value developed by Berger and Ofek (1995) is used as a proxy for

firm value. The evidence in our study reveals that firms where shareholder rights are

more suppressed by restrictive governance provisions suffer a deeper diversification

discount. This is true for all diversification categories except for global diversification.

When shareholder rights are weak, agency costs created by the separation of ownership

and control are likely to be more acute. As a result, the diversification discount is more

severe.

Our study contributes to the literature both in corporate diversification and agency

theory. In corporate diversification, our results complement findings of those studies that

identify agency costs as responsible for the value reduction (Denis, Denis, and Sarin,

1997; Hyland and Diltz, 2002; among others). Consistent with the agency theory

perspective, we demonstrate that restrictive corporate governance provisions may enable

management to pursue strategies that are not necessarily consistent with shareholders’

wealth maximization (in this particular instance, suboptimal diversification that destroys

firm value). Our study also contributes by considering the relative effects of global and

Page 21: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

21

industrial diversification separately whereas most other studies take into account only

industrial diversification (with a notable exception of Denis, Denis, and Yost, 2002).

In conclusion, our results complement those of Denis, Denis, and Sarin (1997).

Both studies find empirical support for agency theory. Unlike Denis, Denis, and Sarin

(1997), however, our focus is on the strength of shareholder rights and corporate

governance whereas theirs is on managerial ownership. The results of both studies,

nevertheless, are remarkably similar in the sense that they provide support for agency

conflict as responsible for the diversification discount.

Page 22: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

22

References

Bebchuk, Lucian, Alma Cohen, and Allen Ferrell, 2004, “What matters in corporate governance?” Harvard University and National Bureau of Economic Research, Working paper. Berger, Philip G., and Eli Ofek, 1995, “Diversification’s effect on firm value”, Journal of Financial Economics 37, 39-65. Bradley, M., A. Desai, and E. Kim, 1998, “Synergistic gains from corporate acquisitions and their division between the stockholders of target and acquiring firms”, Journal of Financial Economics 21, 3-40. Billett, M., and D. Mauer, 2000, “Diversification and the value of internal capital markets: The case of tracking stock”, Journal of Banking and Finance 24, 1457-1490. Billett, M., and D. Mauer, 2003, “Cross subsidies, external financing constraints, and the contribution of the internal capital market to firm value”, Review of Financial Studies 16 (4), 1167-1201 Bodnar, Gordon M., Charles Tang, and Joseph Weintrop, 1999, “both sides of corporate diversification”: The value impacts of geographic and industrial diversification, Working paper, Johns Hopkins University. Campa, J.M., and S. Kedia, 2002, “Explaining the diversification discount,” Journal of Finance 57, 1731-1762. Comment, R., and G. Jarrell, 1995, “Corporate focus and stock returns”, Journal of Financial Economics 37, 67-88. Denis, D. J., D. K. Denis, and A. Sarin, 1997, “Agency problems, equity ownership, and corporate diversification”, Journal of Finance 52, 135-160. Denis, D. J., D.K. Denis, and K. Yost, 2002, “Global diversification, industrial diversification, and firm value”, Journal of Finance 57, 1951-1979 Fluck, Z., and A. Lynch, 1999, “Why do firms merge and then divest?: A theory of financial synergy”, Journal of Business 72, 319-346. Gompers, Paul, Joy Ishii, and Andrew Matrick, 2003, “Corporate governance and equity prices”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 107-155. Graham, J.R., M. Lemmon, and J. Wolf, 2002, “Does corporate diversification destroy value?” Journal of Finance 59, 695-720.

Page 23: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

23

Hadlock, C., M. Ryngaert, and S. Thomas, 2001, “Corporate structure and equity offerings: Are there benefits to diversification?” Journal of Business 74 (4), 613-635. Hyland, David, and David Diltz, “Why firms diversify? : An empirical examination”, Financial Management 31, 51-82. Jensen, M., 1986, “Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers”, American Economic Review 76, 323-329. Kaplan, S., and M. Weisbach, 1992, “The success of acquisitions: Evidence from divestitures”, Journal of Finance 48, 107-138. Lang, Larry H. P., and Rene Stulz, 1994, “Tobin’s q, corporate diversification and firm performance”, Journal of Political Economy 102, 1248-1280. Liebeskind, J., and T. Opler, 1995, “The causes of corporate refocusing: Evidence from the 1980’s”, University of Southern California, Working paper. Mansi, Sattar, and David M. Reeb, 2002, “Corporate diversification: What gets discounted?” Journal of Finance 57, 2167-2184. McConnell, J. and H. Servaes (1990). “Additional Evidence on Equity Ownership and Corporate Value.” Journal of Financial Economics 27: 595-612. Morck, R., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny (1988). “Management Ownership and Market Valuation: An Empirical Analysis.” Journal of Financial Economics 20: 293-316. Porter, M., 1987, “From competitive advantage to corporate strategy”, Harvard Business Review 65, 43-59. Ravenscraft, D., 1987, “The 1980s mergers wave: An industrial organization perspective”, in The Merger Boom: An Overview, edited by L. Browne and E. Rosengren, Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 17-37. Singh, Manohar, I. Mathur, K. C. Gleason, 2004 “An Analysis of Interrelationship among Corporate Governance, Ownership Structure and Diversification Strategies,” Financial Review 39, 489-526 Servaes, Henri, 1996, “The value of diversification during the conglomerate merger wave”, Journal of Finance 51, 1201-1225. Villalonga, Belen, 2004, “Does diversification cause the “diversification discount” Financial Management 33, 5-28 Whited Toni, 2001, “Is it efficient investment that causes the diversification discount?” Journal of Finance 56, 1667-1692

Page 24: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

24

Figure 1: Global and industrial diversification classification. Single-segment firms operate in only one industrial segment whereas multi-segment firms operate in more than one industrial segment. Domestic firms operate only in the U.S. while global firms operate in, at least, one country outside the U.S. Single-segment Domestic firms operate in only one segment and only in the U.S. Multi-segment Domestic firms operate in more than one industrial segment but only in the U.S. Single-segment Global firms operate in only one industrial segment but have a presence aboard. Multi-segment Global firms operate in more than one segment and also outside the U.S.

Industrial Diversification

Single-segment Multi-segment

Domestic

Single-segment Domestic

(SD)

Focused

Multi-segment Domestic

(MD)

Only industrially diversified

Global

Diversification

Global

Single-segment Global

(SG)

Only globally diversified

Multi-segment Global

(MG)

Both industrially and globally

diversified

Page 25: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

25

Figure 2: Year Distribution of the sample firms

SD stands for single-segment domestic, SG for single-segment global, MD for multi-segment domestic, and MG for multi-segment global.

SDMD

SGMG

Total

1993

1995

1998

Total

423

279

507653

1862

176

108 180312

776

14196 187

185

609

10675 140

156

477

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

1800

2000

199319951998Total

Page 26: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

26

Table 1: Individual governance provisions employed in the construction of the Governance Index

The detailed explanation for each governance provision is available in the Appendix of Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003) Percentage of firms with governance provisions in

1993

1995

1998

Full Sample Delay Blank Check 82.60 86.70 87.37 85.93 Classified Board 63.52 64.04 58.89 61.76 Special Meeting 31.66 35.47 33.12 33.51 Written Consent 34.59 36.45 33.51 34.75 Protection Compensation Plans 67.92 73.89 61.73 67.29 Contracts 16.98 14.45 12.11 14.12 Golden Parachutes 53.03 51.89 51.42 51.99 Indemnification 40.04 38.42 25.39 33.44 Liability 72.12 67.98 48.32 60.85 Severance 4.61 87.03 12.50 9.24 Voting Bylaws 15.93 15.11 16.75 16.00 Charter 2.52 2.63 2.96 2.74 Cumulative Voting 14.05 13.46 10.70 12.46 Secret Ballot (Confidential Voting) 14.47 14.29 9.41 12.30 Supermajority 21.80 20.03 15.21 18.47 Unequal Voting 2.94 2.46 1.93 2.36 Other Anti-greenmail 8.18 7.88 5.67 7.04 Directors' duties 8.18 7.39 6.19 7.09 Fair Price 38.57 34.98 2.60 3.22 Pension Parachutes 7.55 5.25 2.96 4.89 Poison Pill 63.30 60.92 56.44 59.67 Silver Parachutes 17.34 4.60 2.96 4.62 State Anti-greenmail Law 16.56 15.44 13.27 14.82 Business Combination Law 91.20 90.80 92.27 91.51 Cash-out Law 3.56 3.12 2.45 2.95 Directors' Duties Law 4.82 3.95 3.74 4.08 Fair Price Law 32.49 31.52 29.38 30.88 Control Share Acquisition Law 2.47 24.96 22.68 23.95 Governance Index 9.63 9.59 8.87 9.30

Page 27: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

Table 2: Summary Statistics Panel A: Descriptive statistics. SD stands for single-segment domestic, SG for single-segment global, MD for multi-segment domestic, and MG for multi-segment global.

Domestic Global

SD MD t-statistics SG MG t-statistics

Full Sample

Sales 2605.62 2846.33 -0.60 2910.84 6093.02 -5.51*** 3947.82

Total Assets 2021.95 2575.76 -1.66* 2725.20 6524.77 -5.13*** 3875.55

Debt Ratio10 21.85% 26.02% -2.87*** 19.43% 26.24% -7.35*** 23.36%

EBIT/Sales 7.73% 9.50% -1.55 10.52% 10.03% 0.67 9.56%

CAPX/ Sales 10.72% 6.90% 3.81*** 9.93% 7.51% 2.64*** 8.80%

R&D/Sales 3.89% 0.63% 3.39*** 6.06% 3.01% 6.98*** 3.69%

Advertising/Sales 10.85% 8.26% 1.35 13.10% 14.20% -0.52 12.25%

% Managerial Ownership 14.13% 12.69% 0.92 10.74% 8.46% 2.39** 11.03%

* statistically significant at the 10% level ** statistically significant at the 5% level *** statistically significant at the 1% level

10 The debt ratio is calculated as total debt divided by total assets

Page 28: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

28

Panel B: Excess value by type of diversification Mean Median N S.D.

Multi-segment Domestic (MD) 5.47% 0.34% 279 49.24

Single-segment Global (SG) 9.17% 10.18% 507 62.34

Multi-segment Global (MG) 9.57% 7.66% 653 53.89

Single-segment Domestic (SD) 24.66% 24.65% 423 50.74

Total 12.28% 11.39% 1, 862 55.38

Page 29: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

29

Table 3: Univariate tests for the Governance Index

Single-Segment

Mean

(Median)

Multi-Segment

Mean

(Median)

t-test

Z-score

Domestic

vs.

Global

Domestic 8.53 9.74 -5.51*** 9.01

8.00 10.00 -5.31*** 9.00

N (423) (279) (702)

Global 8.96 9.87 -5.53*** 9.47

9.00 10.00 -5.65*** 10.00

N (507) (653) (1160)

t-test -2.24** -0.65 -3.37***

Z-score -2.14** -0.93 -3.55***

8.73 9.83 -8.23*** Single-segment vs.

Multi-segment 9.00 10.00 -8.21*** N (930) (932)

* statistically significant at the 10% level ** statistically significant at the 5% level, *** statistically significant at the 1% level

Page 30: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

30

Table 4: Logistic regressions predicting global and industrial diversification with the Governance Index and controls.

The Governance Index is as defined in Gomper et al (2003). Excess value is calculated based on Berger and Ofek (1994).

Model 1

(Wald statistics)

Model 2

(Wald statistics)

Model 3

(Wald statistics)

Model 4

(Wald statistics)

Dependent dichotomous variable Global Industrial Global Industrial

Intercept -1.100*** -2.111*** -0.967*** -2.113*** (34.20) (126.17) (15.20) (73.25) Governance Index -0.100 0.099*** -0.015 0.112*** (0.26) (30.82) (0.34) (20.70) Relative Log (Total Assets) 0.693*** 0.457*** 0.711*** 0.449*** (236.99) (149.27) (125.88) (72.97) Relative R&D to Sales -2.137** -0.756 -3.136 -0.689 (5.81) (1.19) (6.92) (0.66) Managerial Ownership (%) - - 0.000 0.000 (0.89) (0.48) No. of Observations 1,862 1,862 1,006 1,006

Pseudo R2 22.4% 16.2% 22.5% 16.2%

* statistically significant at the 10% level ** statistically significant at the 5% level *** statistically significant at the 1% level

Page 31: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

31

Table 5: Multinomial logistic regression predicting firm diversification with the Governance Index and controls.

The Governance Index is as defined in Gomper et al (2003). Excess value is calculated based on Berger and Ofek (1994).

MD

(Wald statistics)

SG

(Wald statistics)

MG

(Wald statistics)

Intercept -2.361*** -1.252*** -3.108*** (66.75) (26.81) (131.51) Governance Index 0.115*** -0.002 0.088*** (16.37) (0.00) (11.64) Relative Log (Total Assets) 0.466*** 0.700*** 1.121*** (45.52) (127.23) (298.16) Relative R&D to Sales -1.397 -2.650** -2.664 (1.56) (6.07) (5.14) Pseudo R2 26.7%

* statistically significant at the 10% level ** statistically significant at the 5% level *** statistically significant at the 1% level

Page 32: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

32

Table 6: Regressions of the Excess Value on the Governance Index, global and industrial diversification dummies and controls.

Excess Value is computed as described in Berger and Ofek (1995). The Governance Index is constructed based on Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003). GLOBAL is equal to one if the firm is globally diversified regardless of whether it is industrially diversified or not, zero otherwise. MULTSEG is equal to one if the firm is industrially diversified regardless of whether it is globally diversified or not, zero otherwise. MD (Multi-segment Domestic) is equal to one if the firm is diversified industrially but not globally, zero otherwise. SG (Single-segment Global) is equal to one if the firm is diversified globally but not industrially, zero otherwise. MG (Multi-segment Global) is equal to one if the firm diversified both industrially and globally, zero otherwise.

Model 1

(t-statistics)Model 2

(t-statistics)Model 3

(t-statistics)Model 4

(t-statistics)Model 5

(t-statistics) Model 6

(t-statistics) Model 7

(t-statistics)

Intercept 0.022 0.036 0.079** 0.135** 0.123** 0.168*** 0.117***

(0.662) (1.11) (2.10) (2.38) (2.22) (2.87) (2.73)

Governance Index - - - -0.014** -0.011* -0.011** -

(-2.45) (-1.94) (-1.98)

Global -0.051 - - -0.052 - - -

(-1.42) (-1.45)

Multi-segment - -0.120*** - - -0.110*** - -

(-3.58) (-3.26)

Multi-segment Domestic - - -0.199*** - - -0.189*** -0.193***

(-3.74) (-3.55) (-3.62)

Single-segment Global - - -0.101** - - -0.103** -0.102**

(-2.17) (-2.22) (-2.18)

Multi-segment Global - - -0.168*** - - -0.160*** -0.162***

(-3.54) (-3.36) (-3.41)

Entrenchment Index - - - - - - -0.022*

(Bebchuk et al, 2004) (-1.82)

Relative Log (Total Assets) 0.048*** 0.055*** 0.060*** 0.055*** 0.060*** 0.065*** 0.062***

(3.83) (4.51) (4.67) (4.31) (4.81) (4.96) (4.80)

Relative EBIT to Sales 1.098*** 1.060*** 1.065*** 1.074*** 1.043*** 1.047*** 1.050***

(8.43) (8.18) (8.21) (8.24) (8.04) (8.07) (8.10)

Relative Debt Ratio -0.326*** -0.335*** -0.334*** -0.329***-0.339*** -0.337*** -0.330***

(-3.64) (-3.79) (-3.75) (-3.68) (-3.83) (-3.79) (-3.71)

Relative Capital Expenditures to Sales 1.054*** 1.028*** 1.018*** 1.035*** 1.017*** 1.006*** 1.021***

(7.23) (7.09) (7.01) (7.10) (7.02) (6.93) (7.04)

Relative R&D to Sales 1.490*** 1.471*** 1.447*** 1.479*** 1.464*** 1.440*** 1.431***

(6.19) (6.15) (6.05) (6.16) (6.13) (6.03) (5.99)

Relative Advertising Expense to Sales 1.458*** 1.403** 1.450*** 1.389** 1.349** 1.400** 1.403**

(2.64) (2.55) (2.64) (2.51) (2.46) (2.54) (2.56)

% Managerial Ownership 0.000* 0.000** 0.000** 0.000* 0.000* 0.000* 0.000*

(1.82) (1.97) (2.02) (1.67) (1.85) (1.90) (1.90)

No. of Observations 971 971 971 971 971 971 971

F-statistics 21.55*** 23.14*** 19.10*** 19.92*** 21.04*** 17.77*** 17.71***

Adjusted R2 14.5% 15.4% 15.7% 15.7% 16.5% 16.9% 16.9%

* statistically significant at the 10% level ** statistically significant at the 5% level *** statistically significant at the 1% level

Page 33: Corporate governance, shareholder rights and firm diversification: An empirical analysis

33

Table 7: Regressions of the Excess Value on the interaction terms and controls 11 Excess Value is computed as described in Berger and Ofek (1995). The Governance Index is constructed based on Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003). GLOBAL is equal to one if the firm is globally diversified regardless of whether it is industrially diversified or not, zero otherwise. MULTSEG is equal to one if the firm is industrially diversified regardless of whether it is globally diversified or not, zero otherwise. MD (Multi-segment Domestic) is equal to one if the firm is diversified industrially but not globally, zero otherwise. SG (Single-segment Global) is equal to one if the firm is diversified globally but not industrially, zero otherwise. MG (Multi-segment Global) is equal to one if the firm diversified both industrially and globally, zero otherwise.

Model 1

(t-statistics)Model 2

(t-statistics)Model 3

(t-statistics) Model 4

(t-statistics) Model 5

(t-statistics)

Intercept 0.111*** 0.104** 0.074 0.070 0.058

(2.45) (2.32) (1.27) (1.21) (0.93)

Governance Index × Global -0.009*** - -0.003 - -

(-3.41) (-0.12)

Governance Index × Multi-segment -0.005* - -0.010*** - -

(-1.94) (-3.00)

Governance Index × Multi-segment Domestic - -0.018*** - -0.019*** -0.016**

(-4.33) (-3.90) (-2.51)

Governance Index × Single-segment Global - -0.020*** - -0.011* -0.007

(-5.22) (-1.88) (-1.15)

Governance Index × Multi-segment Global - -0.018*** - -0.014*** -0.011*

(-4.61) (-2.71) (-1.82)

Governance Index -0.008* -0.002 -0.005 -0.001 -0.003

(-1.69) (-0.33) (-1.13) (-0.33) (-0.44)

% Managerial Ownership × Multi-segment Domestic - - - - -0.002

(-1.11)

% Managerial Ownership × Single-segment Global - - - - -0.003

(-1.19)

% Managerial Ownership× Multi-segment Global - - - - -0.003

(-0.97)

Managerial Ownership (%) - - 0.000* 0.00* 0.002

(1.61) (1.69) (1.13)

Control variables included Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

No. of Observations 1,862 1,862 971 971 971

F-statistics 32.70*** 31.24*** 18.60*** 17.41*** 13.81***

Adjusted R2 13.3% 14.0% 15.4% 15.7% 16.8%

* statistically significant at the 10% level ** statistically significant at the 5% level *** statistically significant at the 1% level 11 We also run additional regressions by diversification type and obtain qualitatively similar results except for the multi-segment global firm.