Top Banner
Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium theory Eric Smith Duncan K. Foley SFI New School for Social Research SFI Complex Systems Summer School SF 2007
39

Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Jan 17, 2022

Download

Documents

dariahiddleston
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Classical thermodynamics and

economic general equilibrium theory

Eric SmithDuncan K. Foley

SFINew School for Social Research

SFI Complex Systems Summer School SF 2007

Page 2: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Outline

• History and some conventions

• Modern neoclassical economics

• Structure of thermodynamics

• The right connection

• An example

Page 3: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

A (very) little history

Page 4: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Parallel goals of “natural” and “social”

physics circa 1900

• Define and characterize equilibria

• Describe transformations

Points of restEquations of state

Work, heat flow

“Best” resource allocationsDiscovery of price systems

Trade, allocation processes

Page 5: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

The Walrasian Analogy

• Equilibrium as force balance in mechanics

• Equilibrium as balance of “marginal utility” in exchange

“demands”

Leon Walras (1909)

Page 6: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Analogies from mechanicsPosition (x)

Potential Energy (V)

Force (F)

Holdings (x)

Utility (U)

Prices (p)

F = −∇V p = ∇U

“Ball settles in the bottom of the bowl to minimize energy”

(Utility is implicitly measurable)

Page 7: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Gibbs and thermodynamics

• Entropy is maximized in a closed system at equilibrium

• For “open” subsystem, excess entropy is maximized

• Helmholtz Free Energy is equivalently minimized

Ball settles in the bottom of the bowl to maximize excess entropy

(by losing energy)

A = U − TS

S(U)

S(U)− βU

β =∂Senv

∂Uenv≡ 1

T

Distinction between particle and system

Page 8: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

And yet Fisher...

• Particles and individuals are unpredictable

• State variables are only properties of thermodynamic systems at equilibrium

• Fisher mixes metaphors from thermodynamics and statistical mechanics

A particle

Space (x? V?)

Energy (U?, E?, V?)

Force (F)

An individual

Commodities (x)

Utility (U)

Marginal utility (p)

Irving Fisher (1926)

Page 9: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Analogy and confusion

• J. H. C. Lisman (1949)

• J. Bryant (1982)

A quasi-eq. systemEntropypV (ideal gas)

pV = NT

An individualUtility (“analogon”)px (value)

px = NT (productive content)

Page 10: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

DisgustThe formal mathematical analogy between classical thermodynamics and mathematic economic systems has now been explored. This does not warrant the commonly met attempt to find more exact analogies of physical magnitudes -- such as entropy or energy -- in the economic realm. Why should there be laws like the first or second laws of thermodynamics holding in the economic realm? Why should ``utility'' be literally identified with entropy, energy, or anything else? Why should a failure to make such a successful identification lead anyone to overlook or deny the mathematical isomorphism that does exist between minimum systems that arise in different disciplines?

Samuelson 1960

Page 11: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

But duality survived

• Extensive quantities

• Intensive quantities

Energy, volume

Temperature, pressure

Goods

Prices

Page 12: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

The marginalist revolution and modern

“Neoclassical” mathematical

economic theory

Page 13: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Indifference and utility

• Suppose more than one good

• Only try to capture the notion of indifference

• Relative prices = marginal rates of substitution of goods

• “Absolute” price undefined∂u/∂xi

∂u/∂xi= pi/pj

x = (x0, x1, . . . , xn)

u(x) = Ux1

x2

1 U

Utility is now explicitly only ordinal

Page 14: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

The separating hyperplane

• “Edgeworth-Bowley” box: Conserve “endowments”: (allocation of resources under conditions of scarcity)

• Prices separate agent decisions from each other (trade and production)

• “Pareto Optimum” defines equilibrium as no-trade

• Trade to equilibrium must be irreversible

P.S.

x1

x2

1

No trade any agent can propose from an equilibrium will be voluntarily accepted by any other agent

(Tj. Koopmans, 1957)

Page 15: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Duality: prices and demandsx = (x0, x1, . . . , xn)

∂u

∂xi∝ pi

δe = δp · x + p · ∂x

∂U

∣∣∣∣p

δU

e (p,U) ≡ minx

[p · x | u [x] ≥ U ]

x1

x2

1 U

u(x) = U

“Offer prices”

Expenditure function

∂e

∂pi

∣∣∣∣U

= xi

Page 16: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Exchange economies and the Walrasian equilibrium

P.S.

x1

x2

1

x = (x0, x1, . . . , xn)

p = (p0, p1, . . . , pn)

L = u(x)− βp ·(x− x0

) 0

eq

“Wealth preservation” hoped to extract a single equilibrium from the Pareto set

Maximize:

Page 17: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Trading paths to equilibrium really aren’t determined

• The equilibrium price is a terminal property of real trade

• Need not restrict prior paths of trading

• The equilibrium price can be quite unrelated to the Walrasian price

P.S.

x1

x2

F. Hahn and T. Negishi (1962)

“and you may ask yourself ‘how did I get here?’ ”

Page 18: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

The mathematical structure of

thermodynamics

Page 19: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

State relations• General statistical systems

have E, S, not predictable

• Only for equilibrium systems is E also a constraint U

• S(V,U) = max(S)|V,U defines the “surface of state”

• Equation of state is not dependent on the path by which a point is reached

Open-system, reversible

Closed-system, irreversible

S = S(V,E)

S

V

E

U

U

Reversible and irreversible transformations result in the same final state relation

Page 20: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Duality and Gibbs potentialS(U, V )

dS ≡ 1T

dU +p

TdV

δ

(1T

U +p

TV − S

)= U δ

(1T

)+ V δ

( p

T

)

∂S

∂V

∣∣∣∣U

=p

T

∂ (G/T )∂ (p/T )

∣∣∣∣1/T

=∂G

∂p

∣∣∣∣T

= VG

T=

U + pV − TS

T

S

V

U

State:

Page 21: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Connecting thermodynamics to mechanics

V F = p*area

S(U, V )

dS ≡ 1T

dU +p

TdV dA = −pdV − SdT

∂S

∂V

∣∣∣∣U

=p

T−∂A

∂V

∣∣∣∣T

= p

A(T, V ) = U − TS

Page 22: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Reversible transformations and work

V1

p1 p2

V2

Load

reservoir (T)

piston

∆W =∫ (

p1 − p2)dV 1

=∫−

(dA1 + dA2

)

= −∆A

−∂A

∂V

∣∣∣∣T

= p

A

Helmholtz “free energy”

Page 23: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Analogies suggested by dualitySurface of state

Increase of entropy

Intensive state variables

Gibbs potential

Indifference surface

Increase of utility

Offer prices

Expenditure function

u(x) = US(V,U) = max(S)|V,U

G = U + pV − TSe (p,U) ≡ min

x[p · x | u [x] ≥ U ]

δS ≥ 0 δU ≥ 0

∂u

∂xi∝ pi

∂S

∂V

∣∣∣∣U

=p

T

Page 24: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Problems (1): counting

x = (x0, x1, . . . , xn)

p ≡ (p0, p1, . . . , pn) /p0

(U, V )(

1T

,p

T

)

• Different numbers of intensive and extensive state variables (incomplete duality)

• Entropy is measurable, utility is not

• Total entropy increases; individual utility does

G(p, T ) e(p,U)

δS ≥ 0 δU ≥ 0

Page 25: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Problems (II): meaningT

−pdV = dW = dU − TdSp

A

P.S.

x1

x2

Page 26: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Essence of the mismatch

• In physics, duality of state constrains transformations

• In economics, conservation of endowments forces irreversible transformations

The “price” of this power is that we must limit ourselves to reversible transformations, and cannot conserve all extensive state variable quantities

The result is that dual properties of state become irrelevant to analysis of transformations

Page 27: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Finding the right correspondence

Page 28: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Three laws in both systems• Encapsulation

The state of a thermodynamic system at equilibrium is completely determined by a set of pairs of dual state variables

Economic agents are characterized by their holdings of commodity bundles and dual offer price systems to each bundle

Energy is conserved under arbitrary transformations of a closed system

Commodities are neither created nor destroyed by the process of exchange

A partial order on states is defined by the entropy; transformations that decrease the entropy of a closed system do not occur

A partial order on commodity bundles is defined by utility; agents never voluntarily accept utility-decreasing trades

• Constraint

• Preference

Page 29: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

The construction

• Relate the surface of state to indifference surfaces correctly

• Study economics of reversible transformations

• Associate quantities by homology, not by analogy

Page 30: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Quasilinear economies: introduce an irrelevant good • Indifference surfaces are

translations of a single surface in x0 (hence so are all equilibria of an economy)

• All prices on the Pareto Set are equal

• Differences among equilibria have no consequences for future trading behavior

u(x) = x0 + u(x)

x ≡ (x0, x)

Page 31: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Duality on equivalence classes

∀i > 0

SQL = u(x) dSQL = dx · p

p0

Independent of distribution of x0 among agents

Equivalence class of expenditures corresponds to Gibbs

eQL(p,U) = p0 [U − u (x)] + p · x p0 ↔ T

eQL − p0U ↔ G = −TS + (U + pV )

Resulting economic entropy gradient is normalized prices

∂u

∂xi=

pi

p0

Page 32: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Reversible trading in a closed economy

x

P.S.

δS

1

2

x0

Ext. speculator’s profit = −∫

p0

(dx1

0 + dx20

)

=∫ (

p1 − p2)

· dx1

= p0∆(S1

QL + S2QL

)

But SQL is a state variable!Same for rev. and irrev. trade

Money-metric value of trade is the amount agents could keep an external speculator from extracting

Page 33: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Profit extraction potentials in partially open systems

P.S.

−δA

1

2

x1+(p0/p1)x0

x~

x ≡ (x0, x1, x)

Economic “Helmholtz” potential

AQL = x1 −p0

p1u(x1, x)

dAQL = − p

p1· dx

−∂A

∂V

∣∣∣∣T

= p

V1

p1 p2

V2

Load

reservoir (T)

piston

e− p0Up1

= x1 +p · xp1

− p0

p1u(x1, x)

Page 34: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Aggregatability and “social welfare” functions• QL economies are the most general

aggregatable economies independent of composition or endowments

• For these, a “social welfare” function is the sum of economic entropies

• Such economies are mathematically identical to classical thermodynamic systems

(Obvious reason: dual offer prices are now meaningful constraints on trading behavior)

Page 35: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

A small worked example

Page 36: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

The dividend-discount model of finance

δM = −pNδN +1

rδtδD

Contract Energy Conservation

δU = −p δV + δQ

Constant Absolute Risk Aversion (CARA) utility model

(x0, x1, x2) ≡ (−D,M,N)(p0, p1, p2) ≡ (1/rδt, 1, pN ) (T, 1, p)think

U ≡ Nd

(1− Nd

2νσ2

)−D + φ(M)

Page 37: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

The state-variable descriptionEconomic entropy and basis for the social welfare function

G = M + pNN − 1rδt

S

Economic “Gibbs” part of the expenditure function

A = M − 1rδt

S

Economic “Helmholtz” potential for trade at fixed interest

S ≡ U + D = Nd

(1− Nd

2νσ2

)+ φ (M) rδt =

dM=

∂S

∂M

∣∣∣∣N

∂G∂pN

∣∣∣∣rδt

= N

∂A∂N

∣∣∣∣rδt

= −pN

Page 38: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Summary comments

• Irreversible transformations are not generally predictable in either physics or economics by theories of equilibrium

• They require a theory of dynamics

• The domain in which equilibrium theory has consequences is the domain of reversible transformations

• In this domain the natural interpretation of neoclassical prices may be different

Page 39: Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium ...

Further reading• P. Mirowski, More Heat than Light, (Cambridge U. Press, Cambridge, 1989)

• L. Walras, Economique et Mecanique, Bulletin de la Societe Vaudoise de Science Naturelle 45:313-325 (1909)

• I. Fisher, Mathematical Investigations in the Theory of Value and Prices (doctoral thesis) Transactions of the Connecticut Academy Vol.IX, July 1892

• F. Hahn and T. Negishi, A Theorem on Nontatonnement Stability, Econometrica 30:463-469 (1962)

• P. A. Samuelson, Structure of a Minimum Equilibrium System, (R.W. Pfouts ed. Essays in Economics and Econometrics: A Volume in Honor of Harold Hotelling. U. North Carolina Press, 1960), reprinted in J. E. Stiglitz ed. The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, (MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass, 1966)

• J. H. C. Lisman, Econometrics, Statistics and Thermodynamics, The Netherlands Postal and Telecommunications Services, The Hague, Holland, 1949, Ch.IV.

• J. A. Bryant, A thermodynamic approach to economics, 36-50, Butterworth and Co. (1982)

• Tj. Koopmans, Three Essays on the State of Economic Science (McGraw Hill, New York, 1957)

• G. Debrue, Theory of Value (Yale U. Press, New Haven, CT, 1987)

• H. R. Varian, Microeconomic Analysis (Norton, New York, 1992) 3rd ed., ch.7 and ch.10