Top Banner
Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options
51

Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Jan 05, 2016

Download

Documents

Hope Caldwell
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Chap 4

Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and

Real Options

Page 2: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

We reviewed the finer points of net present value methodology.

It will always be the starting point for real options analysis ( ROA ) because we need the present value of a project without flexibility as a because.

Page 3: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

A simple deferral option

Consider a decision that you must make today either to invest in a $1,600 project right now, or to defer until the end of a year.

Once made, the investment is irreversible.

Page 4: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

600200,2600,1)1.1(

200600,1

0

tt

NPV

To have perpetual level cash flows, the depreciation of the project each year is compensated by replacement investment of equal magnitude.The price level of output is $200 now, and there is a 50-50 chance that it will go up to $300 at the end of a year or down to $100. In either case, the price change is assumed to be permanent.Therefore the long-term expected price level is also $200.The first unit is sold at the beginning of the first year of operation.The cost of capital is 10 percent.

Page 5: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

1 1

1,600 300 1,600 1000.5 [ ,0] 0.5 [ ,0]

1.1 (1.1) 1.1 (1.1)t tt t

NPV

MAX MAX

1,600 3,300 1,600 1,1000.5 [ ,0] 0.5 [ ,0]

1.1 1.1MAX MAX

1,700 8500.5[ ] 0.5[0] 773

1.1 1.1

Page 6: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Thus, we are better off by deciding today to defer, rather than to invest.

The value of the deferral option is the difference between the two alternatives, namely $773 - $600 = $173.

Suppose that the volatility of the price increase but its expected value stays the same.

For example, there may be a 50-50 chance that it goes either to $400 or $0.

Page 7: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

1 1

1,600 400 1,600 00.5 [ ,0] 0.5 [ ,0]

1.1 (1.1) 1.1 (1.1)t tt t

NPV

MAX MAX

1,600 4,400 1,600 00.5 [ ,0] 0.5 [ ,0]

1.1 1.1MAX MAX

0.5 [2,545.45,0] 0.5 [ 1,454.55,0]MAX MAX

= 0.5[2,545.45] = 1,272.73

Page 8: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

The value of the deferral option has increased from $173 to $673.

When uncertainty increases in the economy, due perhaps to political unrest, then one would predict that investment would decline in response because it becomes worth more to “ wait to see what happens. ”

Page 9: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 10: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

A simplified comparison of net present value, decision tree analysis, and real options analysis

You have to decide right now whether to precommit to a project that will cost $115 million next year with absolute certainty, but will produce uncertain cash flows – a 50-50 probability of either $170 million or $65 million.

The alternative to pre-commitment is to wait the end of the year to decide, and this right costs $C0.

Page 11: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Estimating the net present value

Capital Asset Pricing Model, and search for company-level betas that are presumed to have the same risk as the project that is being valued.

The payoffs of our project and of the twin security.

Note that the twin security has cash payoffs that are exactly one fifth of the payoffs of our project,

Page 12: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 13: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

%5.171

)13($5.0)34($5.020

1

))(1()(0

kk

k

VqVqV du

100$175.1

)65($5.0)170($5.0

PV

Page 14: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Its present value is $115/1.1 = $104.55. The NPV of the project is $100 - $104.55 = - $4.55 Let’s use a portfolio of m shares of the twin security and B

bonds to replicate the payouts of our project. Replicating portfolio payoff in the up state : m($34) +

B( 1 + rf ) = $170

Replicating portfolio payoff in the down state : m($13) + B( 1 + rf ) = $65

Present value of the replicating portfolio : m($20) + B = 5 ($20) + 0 = $100.

The replicating portfolio approach discounts expected cash flows at a risk-adjusted rate, while the risk neutral approach discounts certainty-equivalent cash flows at the risk-free rate.

Page 15: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 16: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Decision tree analysis This is a long-standing method for attempting to

capture the value of flexibility.

The NPV of the project has increased from - $4.55 million given the inflexible pre-commitment

alternative to $23.40 million with the ability to defer.

Consequently, the value of the deferral option, using the DTA approach is

40.23$175.1

5.27$

175.01

)0($5.0)55($5.0

NPV

Page 17: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

$23.4 – ( - $4.55 ) = $27.95 million. At first glance, this seems to be a good

approach, but on close reflection the DTA method is wrong. Why? Because the DTA approach violates the law of one price.

To value the cash flows provided by the deferral option, we need to use the replicating portfolio approach.

Page 18: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Real options analysis

To confirm with the law of one price when we evaluate the deferral option, we can form a complicating portfolio that is composed of m shares of the twin security,

Replicating portfolio in the up state : m($34) + B( 1 + rf ) = $55

Replicating portfolio in the down state : m($13) + B( 1 + rf ) = $0

Default-free bonds pay 8 percent interest.

Page 19: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Replicating portfolio in the up state : 2.62($34) - $31.53( 1.08 ) = $89.08 - $34.05 =$55.00 Replicating portfolio in the down state : 2.62($13) - $31.53( 1.08 ) = $34.06 - $34.05 =$0 Present value of the replicating portfolio : m($20/share) + B($1.00) = 2.62($20) - $31.53 = $20.87 The value of deferral is therefore $25.42 million.

Page 20: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

The DTA approach

The DTA approach will give the wrong answer because it assumes a constant discount rate throughout a decision tree, when the risk-less of the cash flow outcomes changes based on where we actually are located in the tree.

Replicating portfolio in the up state : m($34) + ( 1 + rf ) B = $0

Replicating portfolio in the down state : m($13) + ( 1 + rf ) B = $50

Present value of the replicating portfolio : m($20) + B = - 2.38 ($20) + $74.93 = $27.34

%9.311

)0($5.0)55($5.087.20$

kk

PV

Page 21: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 22: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Intuition of the replicating portfolio approach

m Vu + B (1 + rf) = Cu

-[ m Vd + B (1 + rf) = Cd]

m V0 + B0 = C0

securityu d

u d

C C Incremental option payoffm

V V Change in the value of the twin

Page 23: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

The marketed asset disclaimer

The frustrating part of the twin security approach is that it is practically impossible to find a priced security whose cash payouts in every state of nature over the life of the project are perfectly correlated with those of the project.

Therefore, it is nearly impossible to find market-priced underlying risky assets.

Page 24: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Early applications of real options analysis used the prices of world commodities as the underlying risky asset, but made the somewhat arbitrary assumption that the volatility of the underlying project without flexibility was the same as the observed volatility of the world commodity.

We are willing to make the assumption that the present value of the cash flows of the project without flexibility is the best unbiased estimate of the market value of the project were it a traded asset.

We call this assumption the Market Asset Disclaimer ( MAD ).

Page 25: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

If we use the MAD assumption, the payouts of the twin security are the same as those of the project itself, $170 in the up state and $65 in the down state, and the present value of the project is $100.

Replicating portfolio in the up state : m($170) + B( 1 + rf ) = $55

Replicating portfolio in the down state : m($65) + B( 1 + rf ) = $0

m = 0.524 and B = - $31.54

Page 26: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Present value of the project with flexibility : m($100) +B = 0.524($100) - $31.54 = $52.40 -

$31.54 = $20.86 MAD assumption as the basis for valuing real

options on any real asset where we are able to estimate the traditional net present value without flexibility.

And if it’s okay for NPV analysis, then we can reasonably assume that the PV of a project without flexibility is the value it would fetch were it a marketed asset.

Page 27: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

The risk-neutral probability approach

It starts out with a hedge portfolio that is composed of one share of the underlying risky asset and a short position in “m” shares of the option that is being priced; in our example this is a call position, the right to defer.

uV0 – mCu = dV0 – mCd

170 – m(55) = 65 – 0

Page 28: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

909091.1055

100)65.07.1()( 0

du CC

Vdum

Where :u = Up movement = 1.7 d = Down movement = 0.65 V0= Starting value = 100 Cu = call value in up state = 55 Cd = call value in down state = 0

Page 29: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Given that we are long one unit of the underlying and short 1.909091 units of the call option :

0 0 0

0 0 0

: 170 - 1.909091(55) 65.00

: 65 - 1.91(0) 65.00

V - 100 - 1.909091

(V - ) (1 ) V -

(100u

Hedge portfolio payoff in the up state

Hedge portfolio payoff in the down state

mC C

mC rf u m C

0 - 1.909091 ) (1.08) 1.7(100) - 1.909091(55)C

Page 30: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 31: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

86.20)909091.1(

]10008.1

)100170([

0

C

)1()])1(

())1(

([0 ff

df

u rdu

ruC

du

drCC

)1(

)1(0

f

du

r

CppCC

1)(])1(

[])1(

[

du

du

du

ru

du

dr ff

Page 32: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

More on the risk-adjusted and risk-neutral approaches

Exhibit 4.6 shows a two-period example of a project that has a current value of $100 with objective probabilities, q = 0.6, and ( 1 – q ) = 0.4, of moving up by 20 percent or down by 16.67 percent each time period.

Given a weighted average cost of capital of 5.33 percent, we have a mutually consistent set of assumption.

The present value, the objective probabilities multiplied by the payoffs, and the risk-adjusted discount rate are a triad of assumptions that must be mutually consistent with each other.

Page 33: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 34: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

$1001095.1

95.110$1095.1

11.114884.51

0533.1

)44.69()4.0(100)4.0)(6.0(2)144()6.0(2

22

PV

PV

V0 = $100, V1 = 0.6 (120) + 0.4 (83.33) = $105.33, and V2 = 0.36 (144) + 2 (0.6)(0.4)(100) + 0.16 (69.44) = $110.95

(1 ) (1.03) 0.8330.53722

1.2 0.833fr d

pu d

1 (1 0.53722) 0.46278p

Page 35: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 36: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

$1000609.1

106.16$1.0609

14.8749.7341.56

30.1

)44.69()634.0()100()634.0)(537.0(2)144()537.0(2

22

PV

PV

Page 37: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

20

0

0

(1 ) 49, 95

(1 ) 5

1 92.23

120 92.23 27.77

f

f

mu V r B K

mudV r B

m and B

Cu muV B

Page 38: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

This is greater than the $25 payoff if we exercise the option at node D.

Therefore, we hold (i.e., we keep our option alive to exercise later).

At node E : m = 0.1636,B=-10.88,Cd= 2.75

At node F : m = 0.6823,B=-52.53,C0= 15.70

Page 39: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

(1 )

1uu ud

u

qC q CC

RAR

RAR

1

)5(4.0)49(6.077.27

13.07%RAR

Page 40: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

The risk-adjusted return changes from node to node reflecting the changing risk of the payoffs .

53722.0833.02.1

833.003.11,

1

)1(

du

drp

r

CppCC f

f

uduuu

80.2703.1

)5(46278.0)49(53722.0

uC

Page 41: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 42: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

The advantage of the risk-neutral probability approach is that the risk-neutral probabilities remain constant from node to node.

100$168.1

)67($4.0)150($6.00

V

)1(

)1( 000

fr

dVppuVV

0 0 0 0(1 )fV r puV dV pdV

du

drp f

)1(

Page 43: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 44: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 45: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

20

0

(1 ) 75

[ (1 ) 0 ]

f uu

f ud

mu V B r C at node A

mudV B r C at node B

0 ( ) uu udmuV u d C C

)(0 duuV

CCm uduu

0 (1 )f udmudV B r C

)1(0

f

ud

r

mudVCB

Page 46: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

00 0

0

=( ) (1 )

uu ud udD

f

C C C mudVC muV B uV

uV u d r

00

0 0( ) 1 ( ) 1uu ud ud uu ud

f f

C C C C C udVuV

uV u d r uV u d r

[1 ]1 1

uu ud ud

f f

C C Cd

u d r r

1

1 1fuu ud ud

f f

r dC C C

u d r r

1 1

1 1 1f fuu ud ud

f f f

r d r dC C C

u d r u d r r

Page 47: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

1 1(1 )f f

uu ud f

r d u rC C r

u d u d

[ (1 ) ]

(1 )uu ud

f

pC p C

r

Page 48: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.
Page 49: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Comparison of financial and real options

The underlying for a financial option is a security such as a share of common stock or a bond (or interest rates), while the underlying for a real option is a tangible asset, for example, a business unit or a project.

Both types of option are the right, but not the obligation, to take an action.

The fact that financial options are written on traded securities makes it much easier to estimate their parameters.

Page 50: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

With real options, the underlying risky asset is usually not a traded security; therefore, we make the Marketed Asset Disclaimer assumption that we can estimate the present value of the underlying without flexibilities by using traditional net present value techniques.

Another important difference between financial and real options is that most financial options are side bets.

They are not issued by the company on whose shares they are contingent, but rather by independent agents who write them and buy those that are written.

Consequently, the agent that issues a call option has no influence over the actions of the company and no control over the company’s share price.

Page 51: Chap 4 Comparing Net Present Value, Decision Trees, and Real Options.

Real options are different because management controls the underlying real assets on which they are written.

The act of enhancing the value of the underlying real asset also enhances the value of the option.

Finally, with both financial and real options, risk – the uncertainty of the underlying – is assumed to be exogenous.

The actions of a company that owns a real option may affect the actions of competitors, and consequently the nature of uncertainty that the company faces.