Top Banner

of 8

Capitalism in Medieval Islam

Jun 01, 2018

Download

Documents

Fauzan Rasip
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    1/19

     Cambridge University Press and Economic History Association are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Journal of Economic History.

    http://www.jstor.org

    Economic History ssociation

    Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    Author(s): Subhi Y. LabibSource: The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 29, No. 1, The Tasks of Economic History (Mar.,

     1969), pp. 79-96Published by: on behalf of theCambridge University Press Economic History AssociationStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2115499Accessed: 15-03-2015 09:48 UTC

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available athttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of contentin a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=cuphttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ehahttp://www.jstor.org/stable/2115499http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/2115499http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ehahttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=cuphttp://www.jstor.org/

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    2/19

    Capitalism

    in

    Medieval

    Islam

    E

    who

    looks

    for

    the

    term

    "capitalism"

    n the

    Islamic

    sources

    of

    the

    Middle

    Ages

    will

    look

    in

    vain.

    On

    the

    other

    hand,

    the

    term

    "capital"

    has

    been

    known

    since

    the

    beginning

    of Islamic

    culture.

    Even

    in

    the

    Holy

    Book

    of

    Islam,

    in

    the

    Siirat

    al-Bakara,

    the idea

    of

    capital

    appears

    in

    connection

    with

    trade,

    business,

    and the

    illicit

    practice

    of

    loaning

    for

    profit-usury.

    "O

    you

    who

    believe,

    keep

    your

    duty

    to

    Allah

    and relinquish

    what

    remains

    [due]

    from usury,

    if

    you are believers. But if you do [it] not, then be apprised of war

    from

    Allah

    and

    His

    messenger;

    and

    if you

    repent,

    then you

    shall

    have

    your

    capital.

    Wrong

    not,

    and you

    shall

    not

    be wronged."

    In

    the

    same

    Sirah

    God

    forbids

    usury

    but

    not

    Bai', trading,

    or buying.

    At

    another

    place

    God's

    commands

    clear

    the

    way

    for

    investments.

    "O

    you

    who

    believe,

    devour

    not your

    property

    among yourselves

    by

    il-

    legal

    methods,

    although

    you

    may engage

    in

    trading

    by

    mutual

    con-

    sent.

    And

    kill not your

    people.

    Surely

    Allah

    is

    merciful

    to

    you."'

    The

    Islamic

    merchant

    tried to follow this system of ethics.

    I

    Islam

    approved

    of trading,

    and

    not only

    because

    of

    the revelation.

    Also,

    trading was

    enhanced

    by

    its

    milieu.

    The

    Islamic

    merchant

    was

    born

    into

    an active

    trading

    community,

    and

    the Prophet

    himself

    had

    engaged

    in

    trade.

    The

    caravan

    trade

    between

    the Indian

    Ocean

    and

    the Mediterranean Sea had passed through the Arabian Peninsula

    ever

    since

    antiquity.

    Mecca,

    the

    birthplace

    of Islam,

    arose

    as

    a

    South

    Arabian

    settlement

    around

    a shrine

    and

    acquired

    significance

    as

    a

    marketing

    town

    and

    religious,

    spiritual

    pilgrimage

    center

    after

    the

    Qurais

    tribe

    had

    captured

    it.

    The

    main

    caravans,

    one in the

    summer

    and one

    in the winter,

    were

    communal

    undertakings

    in which

    whole

    tribes

    took part.

    These conditions

    led eventually

    to a

    familiarity

    with

    money

    economy.

    Although

    barter

    predominated,

    in

    Mecca

    Byzantine

    and

    Persian

    coins

    circulated.

    Mecca and Medina were not only the

    holy

    places

    of

    Islam

    but

    also

    the cradle

    of its

    culture,

    its

    business,

    and

    its

    government.

    1

    The

    Holy

    Book

    of

    Islam:

    Sirat al-Bakara,

    vers No. 275;

    Sfirat

    al-Nisa',

    vers

    No.

    29.

    79

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    3/19

    80

    Subhi

    Y.

    Labib

    United through

    he ProphetMuhammad,

    upportedby a

    religious

    faith, and favored

    by the decline

    of the world powers of the

    time,

    the Arabsstreamed n strictlydisciplinedarmiesvictoriously nto the

    neighboring

    countriesand

    founded

    an

    empire which extended

    from

    western

    Turkestan

    to the

    Atlantic Ocean.

    Three

    quarters of

    the

    coastlandsof the Mediterranean

    ea, once the focal point of Roman

    culture, now

    belonged

    to

    Islam.

    Furthermore,

    he Arab

    expansion

    ended the long Roman-Persian

    hallenge in the

    Middle East, and

    the Islamic Empire

    favored

    more than before

    the

    interrelationship

    of the Mediterraneanand the Indian Ocean politically and eco-

    nomically.

    Araband Persian

    raderspushed

    vigorously o India, Malaya,

    and

    Indonesia. Merchantsof the Islamic

    world became

    indispensable

    middlemen

    because

    of their contact

    with the

    West-either

    through

    the Mediterranean

    r

    the Baltic-and also

    the Far

    East. In

    conse-

    quence

    of their

    worldwide

    trade

    relationships,

    he Arabs

    brought

    sugarcane

    rom

    India,

    cotton

    to

    Sicily

    and

    Africa,

    and

    rice

    to

    Sicily

    and Spain.They learnedfrom the Chinese how to producesilk and

    paper and

    took

    this

    knowledge

    with them

    into

    all

    parts

    of

    their

    empire. From

    China

    they

    introduced

    the

    use of

    the

    compass

    and

    from India

    the so-called

    Arabic

    numbers.

    Everywhere that

    Islam

    entered,

    it

    activated business

    life,

    fostered an

    increasing

    exchange

    of

    goods,

    and

    played

    an

    important

    part

    in the

    development

    of

    credit.

    Tradingprofits

    ormedan

    important

    ourceof

    income

    both for

    states

    and

    individuals.

    However,

    we must

    not

    overlook the

    fact

    that

    the

    prosperityof the world under Islam always depended mainly on

    agriculture,

    and with

    it,

    the

    closely

    connected

    handicraft

    ndustry.

    In the

    early

    Middle

    Ages

    a

    Pax

    Islamica

    was the

    foundationof an

    economic

    golden age

    of which

    the

    protagonists

    n the

    field of

    trade

    were

    Arabs,

    Persians,Berbers,Jews,

    and Armenians.

    slamic

    trade

    reached

    from

    Gibraltar o the Sea of China.

    The

    voyages

    of

    Chris-

    tians,

    in

    contrast,

    were

    limited

    to

    modest

    coastal

    journeys

    along

    the shores

    of the Adriatic and southern

    Italy

    and

    between

    the

    islands

    of

    the Greek

    Archipelago.

    It was

    centuries

    before

    the

    courageous

    citizens

    of

    Italian

    republics

    were

    able,

    thanks

    to their

    political

    development

    and

    their

    maritime

    progress,

    o

    make an

    end

    to

    Islamic-Byzantine

    ominationof the Mediterranean.

    Oriental

    and Occidental

    (Frankish)

    merchants

    together

    created

    a

    phase

    of

    activity

    which can be called commercial

    capitalism,

    but

    we

    should not

    overlook two essential differences between

    the

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    4/19

    Capitalism in

    Islam

    81

    Christian

    West and

    Islamic East.

    First,

    capitalism

    was able

    to de-

    velop much

    earlier in the

    Islamic

    regions than

    in the

    Occident.

    The

    process of the reagrarianization and the dismantling of the great

    exchange

    economy

    which began in Europe in late antiquity

    was

    in-

    tensified

    in the time of the

    barbarian

    invasions

    and continued

    beyond

    the

    Carolingian

    period.

    In the

    agrarian society

    of

    Europe, trade,

    although

    it

    never

    wholly disappeared,

    played only

    a subordinate

    role.

    In contrast,

    the Orient

    at

    this time was

    not

    affected by

    any

    barbarian

    invasions

    and a growing

    trade

    economy

    was able

    there to

    attain its peak.

    The essential difference

    between the economic

    development

    of

    East and West came

    about during

    the late Middle

    Ages.

    Internal

    trade

    in

    the entire

    Islamic area

    could

    not keep pace

    with

    interna-

    tional

    commercial

    developments,

    for

    the Islamic

    lands

    of Asia, which

    were

    affected

    by

    the Mongolian

    invasions, lost

    much

    of

    their produc-

    tivity,

    and

    as a result their business

    potential

    diminished.2

    II

    Although

    trade was

    not

    able

    to

    change

    the

    social structure

    of

    Islamic

    society

    much,

    or

    to influence

    its

    social

    thought

    very

    basically,

    nevertheless

    it had considerable

    effect on

    the economy,

    the accumu-

    lation

    of capital,

    and the

    development

    of

    production.

    The great

    expense

    of

    equipping

    armies

    cannot be

    paid

    from

    an

    empty

    state

    treasury or

    the modest

    depository

    of an

    Emir. Only

    a

    financially

    stable upper class can satisfy its desire for precious stones and

    jewelry.

    The cradle

    of Islamic

    capitalism

    was

    in

    the

    main

    cities

    of

    the

    Islamic

    world.

    In

    the

    early

    Middle

    Ages

    Baghdad

    was the

    com-

    mercial

    metropolis

    and

    exerted

    a marked influence

    on

    the whole

    of

    Islamic

    big

    business.

    With

    the tenth

    century,

    however,

    the

    weight

    of Islamic

    commerce

    was

    gradually

    shifted from

    Iraq

    and the

    Persian

    Gulf

    to

    Eygpt,

    the

    Red

    Sea,

    and

    the harbors of the

    Arabian Penin-

    sula on the Indian Ocean. Cairo became the leading city. The state

    fleets

    of Fatimid Egypt

    and

    private

    ships

    of its

    high

    ranking

    dig-

    nitaries

    strengthened

    commercial

    links in the

    Mediterranean,

    above

    all

    with Sicily, Tunisia,

    and

    Syria.

    For

    Egypt's

    relations with

    the West the

    emergence

    of the

    Karim-s,

    2

    B.

    Spuler,

    Geschichte

    Mittelasiens seit

    dem Auftreten

    der Thirken, n

    Handbuch

    der

    Orientalistik,

    erste Abteilung

    (Leiden,

    1966),

    Bd. 5, pp.

    215-27.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    5/19

    82

    Sub/i Y. Labib

    a unique group

    of capitalistic

    entrepreneurs,

    was of

    great impor-

    tance. This group

    of large-scale

    merchants,

    of whom

    we first hear

    in the eleventh century, was distinguished by its enterprise and

    competence,

    and soon attained wealth and

    influence

    in all important

    eastern

    markets and-through

    its

    considerable

    financing

    activities

    -in the

    field of

    politics too. From

    the twelfth

    century, the

    Kdrimis

    and

    the Franks

    came by degrees

    to dominate

    the important trade

    between

    East

    and West

    and displaced

    the Christian

    and Jewish

    merchants

    of the Byzantine,

    Ayyubid, and Mamluk

    empires.

    Through

    commercial privileges obtained in return for military services to

    the

    Byzantine

    emperors,

    the

    Italians

    succeeded

    in

    eliminating

    Greek

    merchants

    almost entirely, while

    Saladin's support for the Muslim

    Karimis meant

    the

    end

    of the

    important

    position

    of

    the Coptic

    and

    Jewish

    merchants

    of

    Egypt.

    Kdrimi

    funduqs

    sprang up

    on the main

    trade routes

    from

    the

    Indian

    Ocean

    to

    the

    Mediterranean,

    in

    par-

    ticular

    in

    Cairo,

    Alexandria, Qus

    in

    Egypt;

    in

    Aden,

    Ta'iz, Zabid,

    Ghalafiqua,

    Bi'r

    ar-Rubdhiyya

    in

    Yemen;

    in

    Mecca, Medina,

    and

    Jidda in Hijdz. The Siiq al-'Att-ar-n r Al-Buhar was presumably the

    center

    of

    all the

    Kdrim1 rading

    in

    Alexandria.

    Kdrimi

    trade routes

    by

    sea

    led

    through

    the Red

    Sea

    and

    the Indian Ocean

    as far

    as

    China,

    and

    the

    land

    routes

    in times

    of

    peace

    went

    from

    Egypt

    through

    Syria, Iraq, and

    Iran.

    As

    the

    Ottomans

    conquered

    important

    parts

    of Asia

    Minor, the

    Karimls

    expanded

    their

    trading

    activities

    into this area.

    In

    Africa they

    traded not

    only

    on

    the west

    coast of

    the

    Red Sea but also

    on the caravan routes

    with

    Nubia

    and

    Ethiopia.

    Their trading activities reached into distant Ghana and Mali, where,

    from

    the most

    important gold

    mines

    of

    the

    world, they

    obtained

    gold.3

    If

    one

    estimated

    the

    average

    capital

    of

    a

    wholesale

    merchant,

    either

    Muslim

    or

    non-Muslim,

    at

    approximately

    30,000

    dinars

    before

    the

    Karimi

    period

    in

    Egypt,

    the wealth

    of

    many

    Karim1

    merchants

    would

    amount

    to

    at least

    100,000,

    or of

    a few to

    1

    million

    dinars

    or

    more.

    From

    the

    biographical

    sources

    of

    the fourteenth

    century,

    we

    learn

    the

    following

    about

    the

    Kariml

    NMsir

    al-Din Muh.

    b. Musallam

    (died 1374):

    "He

    was,

    as far as his wealth

    was

    concerned,

    the

    marvel

    of

    his

    time."4It is

    reported

    further

    that not one of his

    slaves

    who

    worked

    for him in oriental

    markets

    such as

    India, Yemen,

    3

    S.

    Labib,

    Handelsgeschichte

    Agyptens

    im

    Spdtmittelalter

    (Wiesbaden,

    1965),

    pp.

    102-3,

    116.

    4

    Labib,

    p.

    115.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    6/19

    Capitalism

    in Islam

    83

    Ethiopia, Ghana,

    and Mali

    had died abroad,

    and thus the

    business

    from this

    standpoint

    had suffered

    no

    setbacks. The

    ancestors

    of

    this Karimlmerchanthad likewisebeen merchants.His grandfather

    ibn

    Yasir

    al-B-alis

    as also

    amongthe

    most famous

    merchants

    of the

    Orient, f

    not the

    world. His wealth

    is

    said to have

    amounted

    o 10

    million

    dinars.

    The fame of his

    financial

    ability went beyond

    the

    business circles of

    Egypt. A contemporary

    described

    him

    as being

    the wealthiest Karimi

    merchant

    of his

    time.

    Indian merchants

    who

    traded

    in

    Egypt

    and Mecca

    confirmed

    that no Indian

    possessed

    wealth as great as that of this merchantwith the exceptionof an

    unbeliever (of India)

    of

    whom

    he

    was

    a business colleague.Also

    interesting

    s the

    statement of

    the world

    traveler

    Ibn

    Battfita

    that

    the wealth

    of the KarimI

    merchants

    was comparable

    o that

    of the

    greatest middlemen

    of China.5

    Among the

    most

    important merchant

    families were

    the al-

    Kharrfibi,

    al Kaubak

    (written

    also al-Kuwaik),

    Yasir, al-Mahalll,

    and the

    al-Damdnlniwho

    inherited

    the traditions

    of

    the

    Karimi

    group. It should be emphasizedthat these trading establishments

    were

    family

    businesses.

    Each

    generation

    inherited

    the

    experience,

    assets,

    and customers of

    their ancestors.

    A Karimi prepared

    his

    children

    for

    their

    profession,

    and

    sent them

    to various countries

    to

    gather

    necessary experience

    and

    to entrench

    the family

    business

    more

    firmly.

    The

    Karimimerchants

    n

    addition

    had

    agents,

    free and

    slave, who represented

    heir houses,

    imported

    and

    exported

    wares,

    and recruited

    for

    them.

    In

    addition

    to their

    business

    activity,

    these

    houses

    played

    an

    important

    ole in the historyof Islamiccapitalism

    thanks to

    their

    important

    inancial

    potential.

    The

    financing

    of

    great

    projects

    was

    one

    of

    their

    methods of acquiring

    capital,

    and

    they

    conducted

    a

    type

    of

    banking

    nstitution

    or loans and

    deposits.

    Their

    best customerswere

    not

    only

    Frankish

    merchants

    but also

    Sultans

    and Emirs, whom they

    helped

    with

    credits

    and also with

    soldiers

    and

    weapons

    if

    necessary.

    In the historyof Islamiccapitalismthe Karim-merchantsdiffer

    from other

    entrepreneurs

    f their

    time

    outside

    of the

    Egyptian

    Em-

    pire

    and

    from the wholesale

    merchants

    of

    this

    empire

    before

    their

    time

    (before

    the twelfth

    century)

    in

    one

    important

    way:

    They

    were

    neither

    andlords

    nor tax collectors.

    Their

    capitalism

    rested on

    trade

    and

    financial transactions.

    This remained the basic

    characteristic

    5Labib, p. 116.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    7/19

    84 Subhi Y. Labib

    of their

    activity. The most importantJewish merchant families in

    Egypt up to the end of the Fatimidperiod and also outside of Egypt

    (primarily in Iraq and Iran) were wholesalers, bankers, and tax

    farmers of entire provinces. To Joseph b. Phineas and Aaron b.

    'Amran, ourtbankers,a certainvizier had to pay 30 percent interest

    on

    a

    loan of

    10,000 dinars which he borrowedfrom them. The re-

    lationshipof such Jewish financierswith the Abbasidcaliph and his

    viziers

    at

    the beginning of the tenth century s an importantchapter

    in the history of oriental capitalismas they loaned the Caliph and

    his viziers large sums of money. Ibn 'Allanal-Yahiidli, ho died in

    1079,was

    a

    tax farmerof Basraand served the caliphsfor more than

    20

    years. He was extremelywealthy and granted a loan of 100,000

    dinars to

    Nizam

    al-Mulk.6

    In the

    history

    of Islamic

    trade we find from the beginning the

    itinerantmerchant,

    al-Thjir

    as-Salfhr,

    eside the resident merchant,

    al-Ta-jir

    l-Muqim.To

    the former, adventure,associatedwith busi-

    ness, became

    an

    essential part of

    his

    life. We know of

    a

    substantial

    number of merchantswho traveled between China and Andalusia,

    many of whom went

    for

    learning

    n

    additionto

    business. Many

    tales

    from the ArabianNights give importantand well-known examples

    and

    reconstruct

    or

    us

    the

    picture

    of the adventurousmerchant

    of

    the Islamic

    early

    Middle

    Ages.

    From the late Middle

    Ages

    a

    typical

    example

    which

    has

    some

    informative

    data

    is

    the

    following:

    The

    merchant Muhamed

    b.

    'Abd al-Rahmanb. Ism-a il

    al-JazlrI died

    1302),

    one of the most

    respected

    merchantsof

    his

    time,

    traveled

    betweenSyria,Mecca, Egypt, Iraq,and the PersianGulfandunder-

    took three trips to

    China.At

    the beginning

    of his

    career

    he

    possessed

    500 dinars

    as

    capital.

    At his

    death he left

    behind the sum of

    50,000

    dinars.

    Often

    clever

    and

    ambitiousbusiness

    entrepreneurs

    were

    the

    am-

    bassadors

    of

    their

    countries,

    and

    it

    was not

    exceptional

    for

    an

    am-

    bassador

    to

    combine

    a

    diplomatic duty

    with

    a

    good

    business

    deal

    whenever

    the

    opportunitypresented

    itself. An

    interesting example

    is the

    following:

    Fakhr al-Din

    'Uthmdn,

    he Ambassadorof

    Egypt

    to Aragon

    in

    the

    year 1304,

    borrowed

    60,000

    dirhams

    before he

    started

    his

    journey

    n

    order

    to

    buy goods

    which

    he

    hoped

    to

    sell

    in

    Aragon

    or

    a

    good profit.7

    6

    W.

    Fischel, "The Origin

    of Banking

    in Medieval

    Islam,"

    Journal

    of

    the

    Royal

    Asiatic Society,

    1933.

    7

    Labib, p.

    79.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    8/19

    Capitalism in Islam

    85

    The political picture

    of Islamic

    capitalism would remain

    incom-

    plete if I did not refer

    to

    al-Sawdmilli.

    Professor Aubin, in

    his

    work

    "Les Princes d'Ormuz" spoke not only of the importance of the

    capitalist

    merchant

    al-Sawdmilli,

    but also of the

    position of

    Hurmuz

    Harbor, which from

    the thirteenth

    to the fifteenth centuries

    pre-

    sented

    the unusual picture

    of an autonomous

    oriental city.8

    In this

    important

    seaport, economic activity

    went hand

    in hand with politi-

    cal

    independence.

    I have looked in

    vain in Arabic

    sources for a

    con-

    nection between the

    K-ariml

    merchants

    and

    al-Sawamili.

    Steady traffic and relative safety of the roads contributed con-

    siderably

    to the growth of trade.

    However, the

    distance and danger

    of the route as well as

    the scarcity

    of wares influenced prices.

    1bn

    Khaldfin

    analyzed these

    things well

    and arrived at the conclusion

    that

    usually

    the merchants who traded

    and

    exchanged their mer-

    chandise

    in

    distant

    marketplaces could acquire

    great wealth.9

    On

    the other hand, merchants

    who simply

    traveled between cities

    and

    villages

    of one province could count

    on only

    small profits, since

    in

    most cases their merchandise was obtainable in large quantities.

    Therefore, the more

    experienced merchants

    were advised

    to buy

    goods through long-distance

    trade

    when the goods were

    in

    season

    and

    in

    demand. This

    in turn required

    a thorough knowledge

    of the

    conditions of the wares

    in their

    original locations. Traders

    had to

    learn whether

    or not a product

    might be found

    there

    in

    large or

    small quantities;

    whether it was expensive

    or

    inexpensive; whether

    or not

    it

    turned out scanty or faulty;

    and whether

    or

    not

    the

    routes

    for import were safe or impeded. Some of this information had to be

    obtained

    through inquiries

    and close questioning

    of

    caravans.

    In

    other words, business

    required many rational decisions

    and

    prepara-

    tory

    calculations.

    Of

    great significance

    for

    the medieval

    capitalistic

    trade

    of

    Islam

    was

    the establishment

    of the

    funduqs, specialized

    large-scale

    com-

    mercial institutions

    and

    markets

    which

    developed

    into

    virtual

    stock

    exchanges.

    They

    dominated the

    townscape

    of

    the

    great

    cities in

    the

    entire

    Islamic

    world.

    A

    few examples

    which give

    an

    approximate

    idea of

    the trade transactions which

    took

    place

    there

    are

    as

    follows:

    At the time

    of the

    Crusades

    Cairo

    possessed

    four

    funduqs

    for

    the

    8

    J.

    Aubin,

    "Les Princes

    d'Ormuz

    du

    XIIIe

    siecle,"

    Journal

    Asiatique,

    1953;

    Labib,

    p. 117.

    9

    Ibn Khaldfin, Prolegomena

    (English

    translation by

    Franz

    Rostenthal,

    New

    York,

    1958)

    Vol. II,

    pp.

    298 if.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    9/19

    86 Subbi

    Y. Labib

    commercial

    exchange

    between

    Egypt

    and Syria. One of them was

    concerned

    with the import

    of

    oil from Syria.

    According

    to the

    sources,an oil traderwho lived in the fourteenthcenturydisbursed

    20,000

    silver dirhams

    for

    his oil imports

    and

    a further90,000

    for

    other goods he imported

    from Syria. In

    the

    Dar

    at-Tuffah

    n Cairo

    the

    wholesale

    fruit merchants

    of

    Egypt and Syria

    stored

    their goods

    -apples,

    pears, quinces,

    etc.-after

    having

    purchased

    them at the

    fruit

    market,

    the funduq Qiisiin.

    funduq al-'Ambar

    pecialized

    in

    amber which

    was imported

    even

    from the Baltic

    region

    and which

    found a ready market in Egypt, for it was-and still is-a popular

    ornament

    in

    the

    Egyptian countryside.

    In addition

    to Egyptian

    products,

    goods of Chinese,

    Indian,

    African,

    Western,

    and Levan-

    tine

    origin were

    sold in

    the Cairene

    funduqs.

    The fur

    market

    of

    Cairo

    grew

    rapidly toward

    the

    end of the fourteenth

    century, for

    fur was

    in this

    period

    much in demand

    in male

    fashion.

    W-alls

    and

    provincial

    governors

    could

    profit from

    this trade;

    thus, we

    hear for

    instance

    of

    a

    Wall

    (and

    merchant)

    who brought

    at one

    time 300,000

    garmentsof gray squirrel o sell on the Cairenemarket.Funduqsfor

    grain

    or textiles

    belonged

    in the

    pictureof

    all large

    cities such

    as

    Baghdad,

    Cordova,and

    Damascus.

    Baghdad

    had a

    special market

    for

    Chinese

    imports

    where profits

    reached many

    times the original

    cost.

    III

    Among

    the important ines

    of business

    were

    the

    grain

    trade,

    the

    spice trade, and mining;becauseof lack of space only the produc-

    tion

    of

    textiles

    will be

    described

    here.

    The

    trade

    in

    fabrics was

    especially

    highly

    esteemed.

    The

    Caliph

    Abi Bakr himself had been

    a

    textile

    merchant.

    "If

    there were

    trade

    in

    Paradise,

    I

    would

    choose cloth-trade

    because

    Abii

    Bakr

    al-Siddiq was

    a

    fabric-merchant."'0

    he

    production

    of

    fabrics

    n

    which the

    entire

    family participated

    hroughspinning

    and

    weaving

    was

    done

    not

    only

    in

    the

    home for home use but

    it was

    also encouragedby the state,which eventuallymonopolized he in-

    dustry.

    The

    Umayyads

    and Abbasids

    housed

    in their

    palaces

    the

    cloth

    mills

    which

    made cloth for

    their

    wardrobes,

    or the

    covering

    of

    the

    Ka'baas

    well

    as

    for

    royal

    presentations

    robes

    of

    honor)

    and

    gifts.

    The

    importance

    of these fabrics

    ncreased

    under

    the

    splendor-

    10

    al-Dimashki/H.

    Ritter,

    "Ein arabisches

    Handbuch

    der

    Handelswissenschaft,"

    Der Islam,

    17,

    1917.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    10/19

    Capitalism

    in Islam

    87

    loving Fatimids.

    Royal

    factories, called Dar al-Tiraz,

    were

    of course

    built not

    only

    in

    Egypt

    and Syria; they were

    all over the

    Islamic

    world.

    In

    Spain

    they

    were in

    Almeria, Murcia,

    Sevilla, Granada,

    and Malaga;

    in Asia Minor there

    was a Tiraz

    factory at the Saljuq's

    court. Even

    in Sicily, where the

    Arabs ruled

    for a long time, the

    tradition

    of state factories

    was preserved and

    in Palermo

    the regium

    ergasterium

    produced

    finely woven silk down

    to the thirteenth

    cen-

    tury. The same system

    also spread

    in Persia.

    In

    Iraq,

    Baghdad re-

    mained

    the most important center

    of royal

    production.

    Factories built and maintained by the state were not only produc-

    ing for the private

    needs of

    the rulers, which were in

    fact very

    great, but

    also for commerce. Tinnis

    (Egypt)

    is an important ex-

    ample:

    5000 looms

    and a factory of the court

    were producing

    tex-

    tiles. The export of

    Tinnis textiles was considerable,

    and

    down to the

    year 360/971

    reached a value of

    20-30,000 dinars

    annually. It is sig-

    nificant

    that the treasuries of the

    towns of

    Tinnis, Damiette, and

    Al-Ashminayn

    in

    363/974 (Fatimid period)

    could pay

    200,000

    dinars into the treasury in one day. The expenditure for gold thread

    was

    usually 31,000,

    and

    under the Fatimid

    Caliph

    al-Amir it

    even

    mounted

    to

    43,000

    dinars.

    Through

    the

    Resala-ye Falakiyyd

    it

    is

    pos-

    sible

    to

    give

    a

    few

    examples

    of

    capitalistic

    Mongolian

    court proce-

    dures

    of the late Middle

    Ages: Baghdad

    manufactured

    royal

    garments

    (Bayt al-Athw-ab)

    with a budget

    of 20,000

    dinars."1

    Tabriz

    produced

    them

    with

    a

    budget

    of 10,000

    dinars

    and

    at the

    same time

    manu-

    factured

    brocade

    (Bayt

    al-Zarduziyya)

    with

    a

    budget

    of

    20,000

    dinars. For the production of calico in the royal weaving mills of

    the

    city

    of Isfahan

    10,000

    dinars were

    used. For the

    production

    of

    taffeta

    (Bayt

    al-Taftagat), with

    which

    the

    city

    of Yazd

    supplied

    the

    court,

    20,000

    dinars

    were spent.

    The

    same

    figure

    is

    given

    by

    the

    city

    of

    Nishapur

    for

    their

    production

    of silk damask

    (al-Kamkh-awt).

    It

    was only

    with

    the decline of

    the

    great

    Muslim

    empires

    that

    the

    Tiraz production

    system

    came to

    an end.

    Ibn Khaldfin

    tells

    us

    that

    the fabrics

    and

    garments with

    Tirazes were

    no

    longer

    made

    in

    their

    factories

    and

    palace

    workshops

    in

    Egypt

    or

    produced

    by

    the

    state

    in

    its

    own

    buildings,

    but

    what

    the state

    required

    was

    simply

    woven

    in

    the houses of

    the

    weavers.'2

    In fact

    throughout

    the

    Middle

    11

    W.

    Hinz,

    "Das

    Rechnungswesen

    orientalischer Reichsfinanziimter,"

    Der

    Islam,

    28, 1950.

    12

    Encyclopaedia of

    Islam,

    article

    "Tirdz";

    S.

    M. Imamuddin,

    The

    Economic His-

    tory of Spain (Asiatic

    Society of Pakistan,

    Dacca, 1963),

    pp. 197

    ff.; Labib,

    pp. 293-

    94.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    11/19

    88

    Subbi

    Y.

    Labib

    Ages textiles

    were manufactured

    in private

    homes

    as well

    as

    in the

    state factories.

    In

    Almeria (Spain),

    where 800

    looms

    were working

    in Idrisi's time, valuable brocades,

    siqlatun

    and silver, were made in

    the style

    of those

    of Djurdjan

    and

    Isfahan.

    In the

    Nile

    Delta, in the

    early Islamic

    period,

    the lot of

    the

    private cloth

    makers was

    wretched.

    Their

    private

    production

    was strictly controlled-at

    least

    during

    the

    Fatimid

    period. They

    had to obtain

    their

    materials

    from

    the Caliph's

    officials.The

    finished

    fabrics

    could

    only

    be sold through

    brokers

    appointed

    by

    the

    state

    and a government

    official

    kept a

    record

    of all

    transactions

    because

    of the

    Caliph's

    large

    profits

    from

    this business.

    Many governors

    invested in the

    fabric

    business

    through contracts.

    They sometimes

    had their

    own

    house factories,

    the

    production

    of

    which

    was

    considerable.

    A few examples

    are

    known

    of respected dignitaries

    who

    carried

    on the home

    weaving.

    It

    is related

    that on

    his accession

    Hisham

    I

    (788-96

    A.D.) sent

    for

    Mus'ab

    b. 'Imrdn

    al-Hamad-ahn,whom

    he desired to

    appoint

    as chief

    Qadi

    of Cordova.

    His

    wife was

    seen regulating

    the loom while

    Mus'ab was at a distance from her preparing the threads. It cannot

    be

    determined how

    much the scholar

    in

    question

    produced

    for

    the

    market.

    The

    weavers

    were

    divided

    into

    two groups:

    the

    artisans

    who

    worked

    for

    wages

    and the owners

    of

    weaving

    looms. Some

    of

    the

    latter processed

    the already

    woven

    threads

    which

    were

    brought

    to

    them

    by

    their

    employers.

    A

    contract

    was

    drawn

    up

    to determine

    wages

    and conditions

    for

    production.

    Other weavers

    themselves

    bought the thread and turned it into fabrics to be sold. In every

    large city

    there was

    a

    qaysariyya

    for

    the trade

    of

    fabrics;

    in

    small

    towns

    it was

    a

    sfiq (bazaar).

    Textiles of

    all

    kinds and

    types

    were

    offered

    at

    weekly

    markets

    and trade

    fairs.

    Every piece

    of

    cloth,

    whether

    woolen

    or

    cotton,

    silk or linen,

    cheap or dear,

    bore

    the

    name

    of

    the

    producing

    city,

    so

    that the

    purchaser

    could

    know

    for

    what

    he was

    paying.

    IV

    There

    is

    much

    material which

    shows

    that the free loan was

    known

    in the

    Islamic

    world,

    but

    it

    was

    customary

    for the creditor

    to

    cal-

    culate

    his

    interest

    and include

    it in the sum

    owed without

    stating

    it separately

    in

    the

    credit

    agreement.

    Money

    changers

    and

    private

    bankers worked

    on a

    capitalistic

    basis

    and

    played

    a

    major

    role in the

    deposit

    and

    loan business

    and

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    12/19

    Capitalism

    in

    Islam 89

    in

    the

    clearinghouse raffic.Some businessmenhad greater trust

    in

    judges, however,

    and

    in

    some dependable scholars who accepted

    their deposits and managed the settlementof their accounts. The

    deposit

    and loan business

    conducted under

    state supervisionwas

    also not unheard of, although our

    knowledge about this is very

    limited.

    Currencyproblems and the decline in

    value of coins forced a

    search for safer

    forms of payments,

    particularly n the late Middle

    Ages. This

    tendency to devise a traffic in money independent of

    coinage troublescharacterizes he wholehistoryof paymenttransac-

    tions in

    the Islamic

    era, particularlyregarding large private and

    state (official) transactions.One of the

    results was that the bill of

    exchange obtained a solid place in state and

    private commerce.It

    was

    so familiar

    that it

    appeared

    in

    the

    adage:

    "Take out

    a bill of

    exchange on your mother"; his advice was

    given to

    a

    son who

    wanted

    his mother

    broughtsafely

    to Basra.

    Adam Mez

    collected the best

    material

    on

    suftajahs

    (bills of ex-

    change) that we findin the earlyIslamicliterature.He said:

    A savant who

    journeys

    to

    Spain

    takes

    with

    him

    a letter of

    credit (suftajah),

    and 5,000 dirhams n

    cash.

    NMsir-i

    Khusraureceived from an

    acquaintance in

    Asuan

    a

    blank letter of

    credit

    addressed

    to

    his

    agent (wakil) in

    'Aidhdb,

    of

    the

    following

    content: "Give NMsir

    all that

    he

    may

    demand,

    obtain a

    receipt

    from him

    and

    debit the sum to me."

    The Viceroy

    of

    Egypt

    sent his

    representa-

    tive

    in

    Baghdad

    letters

    of credit for the

    cashiered vizier. The

    representative

    accepted them,

    and

    put

    the

    money

    at

    the vizier's

    disposal.

    A

    sort of bill

    of

    exchange

    was

    the

    sakk

    . . .

    In

    Audagusht

    in

    the western

    Sudan,

    ibn

    Hauqal

    saw a checkfor42,000 dinarsdrawn by a man of Sijihmasahn one Muhammad

    ibn 'All Sa'dfin

    n

    Sijihmasah;

    t

    was

    officiallycertified.

    The

    paper

    had

    travelled

    through

    a

    great part of

    the

    Sahara.

    In

    Islamic

    metropolises

    the

    sakk

    was

    a

    regular check

    in

    connection

    wherewith

    the

    banker

    plays

    an

    important part.

    In

    the 3rd/9th century (to which the anecdotes

    connected

    with Harfin

    al-

    Rdshldbelong)

    a

    magnate

    drew

    checks

    on

    his bankers.About

    300/900

    a

    great

    man

    paid

    a

    poet

    in

    this way, only the

    banker refused the

    check,

    so

    that the

    disappointed poet

    composed

    a

    verse to the

    effect that he would

    gladly pay

    a

    million on

    the

    same plan.

    A

    patron

    of the same

    poet

    and

    singer (320/936)

    during a concert wrote a check (ruq'ah, "note") in his favour on a banker

    (5airaft)

    for 500 dinars.When paying,

    the

    bankergave

    the

    poet

    to understand

    that

    it was

    customary o charge

    one

    dirhem discount

    on each

    dinar, i.e.,

    about

    ten

    per cent. Only

    if

    the poet would spend

    the

    afternoon and

    evening

    with

    him, he would make no deduction. Anotherbanker

    (Jahbadh),

    who

    was

    even

    a

    greater patron

    of

    the fine

    arts,

    not

    only

    made

    no

    deduction,

    but

    presented

    the

    poet

    with

    an

    extra 10

    per

    cent. There

    was

    therefore

    plenty

    of

    employment

    for

    bankers,

    and it

    is

    not

    surprising

    that

    in Isfahan there

    were 200

    banks in

    the Bankers'

    Bazaar-for these too

    sat

    together.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    13/19

    90 Subbi

    Y. Labib

    About 400/1000 the banker had made himself indispensable

    in

    Basrah:

    every

    trader had his banking account, and

    paid only in checks on his bank

    (Khatt-

    saraf) in the bazaar. This would appearto have been the most importantrefine-

    ment

    of

    monetary operation in the

    empire, on the frontier between

    Faris and

    Iraq. For the people of Basrah, the Persians of

    Faris,

    and the South Arabians

    were the best traders among the

    Believers, and had their colonies wherever

    anything could be produced. About the year 290/902 al-Faqlh

    al-Hamadhanli

    observes: "The people of Basrah

    and the Himiarites are the greatest money-

    grubbers.One who travels to the remotest

    region of Ferghanah or the Western

    edge of Morocco s sure to find a

    man from Basrahor a Himiaritethere."'3

    Ibn Battiita discussesan occasionworthy of notice in which credit

    brought an enormousprofit:

    Every person proceeding to the court

    of the King of India, Sultan Muhammad

    Shah, must needs have a gift ready to present to him, in order to gain

    his

    favours. The sultan requites him for

    it by a gift many times its value. When

    his subjects grew accustomed to this practice, the merchants n Sind and

    India

    began to furnish each newcomer

    with thousands of dinars as a loan, and to

    supply him with whatever he might desire to offer as a gift or to use

    on his

    own behalf, such as riding animals,

    camels, and goods. They place both their

    money and their persons at his service, and stand before him like attendants.

    When

    he

    reaches the Sultan, he receives

    a magnificent gift from him and pays

    off

    his debt to them. This trade of

    theirs is a flourishingone and brings in

    vast

    profits.

    Ibn

    Battfta

    himself made use of the occasion.

    He

    says:

    On

    reaching Sind

    I

    followed this

    practice

    and

    bought horses, camels,

    white

    slaves

    and other

    goods

    from the

    merchants.

    I

    had

    already bought

    from

    an

    IraqImerchant

    n

    Ghazna about thirtyhorses and

    a camel

    with

    a load

    of

    arrows,

    for

    this

    is

    one of the

    things presented

    to the

    sultan. This

    merchant

    went off

    to

    Khurdsdn

    nd on

    returning o

    India received his money

    from

    me.

    He

    made

    an

    enormousprofitthroughme and became one of the principal

    merchants.'4

    Interest

    and

    usury

    were legally prohibited;

    however

    they

    were

    customary.Usury and excessive profit played

    an

    important

    role in

    Islamic

    capitalism.

    Neither Muslims

    nor

    Christians

    nor

    Jews

    shunned

    usuriousbusiness dealings.

    Even

    Caliphs, Sultans,

    and Emirs

    re-

    ceived loans carryingtoo high an interestrate.

    These

    credit

    dealings were

    not carried out

    only

    to

    gain profit

    in

    the

    form

    of interest.From

    the

    heads of

    states

    one

    could

    ask

    for

    im-

    portant trade, tariff,rent,

    and tax privileges

    instead.

    With the

    growth

    of commerce

    trading companies

    were

    formed.

    13

    A. Mez,

    Die Renaissance

    des Islam (Heidelberg,

    1922)

    p. 448.

    14

    H. A.

    R. Gibb,

    Ibn Battfita, Travels

    in Asia and

    Africa (London, 1929), pp.

    184-85.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    14/19

    Capitalism

    in Islam

    91

    Some were

    family

    enterprises

    n

    which the profits

    went into a

    com-

    mon fund

    without

    an accurate

    settlement of

    the

    accounts of

    the

    various partners.The exampleof the prophet Muhammadhimself

    serves

    as

    a prototype.

    It was

    no secretthat

    the

    prophetand

    his

    wife

    Khadija had

    established

    a commenda.

    The principle

    of

    the

    com-

    menda was

    that within

    the

    association he

    partners

    were equal,

    and

    one furnished

    the

    capital

    while the other

    managed

    the business.

    I

    found a rare

    commenda

    contractsetting

    forth this type

    of

    agreement

    between

    a

    Venetian

    and a native

    made in

    the early fifteenth

    century

    with Alexandriaas the place of the agreement.' While this record

    does

    not deal

    with the details

    of

    the contract,

    t does

    reportthat

    the

    native sent

    a letter

    to the

    Venetian

    consul in

    Alexandria

    o inform

    him

    that

    certainproblems

    which had arisen

    had

    been cleared

    up

    in

    the

    meantime,

    and

    that he

    and others

    had written

    to the

    Q-dd

    al-

    Qud-h

    in

    Alexandria o

    that the

    Venetianmerchant

    would

    no

    longer

    be prosecuted.

    The

    suppliersof

    the monies

    of the

    commenda

    com-

    panies

    were not

    only

    merchants

    but also

    the wealthy

    who

    wanted

    to invest theirsurplus n trade for profit.

    As

    we know,

    the

    commendawas

    intended

    to be a

    form

    of capital

    investment

    wherein

    the profits

    were

    distributed

    according

    to

    what

    the partners

    had agreed

    upon.

    Here we

    have

    a

    capitalistic

    calcula-

    tionof accounts.

    The

    original

    capital

    invested

    is compared

    with

    the

    final

    sum

    and

    the surplus

    is

    marked profit

    to

    be

    distributed.

    This

    type

    of settlement

    was

    not

    unknown

    n

    the

    civilized

    countrieswhich

    the Arabs

    conquered.

    However, it was

    not widely

    utilized

    in

    the

    Islamic civilizationuntil the introductionof numerals.At the begin-

    ning of the

    ninth century

    the

    Islamic mathematician

    Muh.

    b. Musa

    al-Khwarizmi

    ntroduced

    he

    Indian

    positional

    numeralswith

    index

    value

    and

    zero.

    One

    began

    thinking

    in

    numbers

    and the numerical

    system

    became

    the

    framework

    or the

    capitalistic

    ndustrial

    conomy.

    In

    the

    introduction

    al-Khwarizmi

    himself

    states

    that his book

    was

    compiled to

    meet

    the

    needs

    of

    people

    in

    solving

    questions

    of

    in-

    heritance,wills,

    purchase

    and

    sales

    agreements,

    n

    money

    exchange,

    in surveying,

    in the cleaning

    and

    digging

    of

    rivers

    and

    canals,

    in

    the

    measuring

    of

    goods,

    and

    in technical

    matters.'6

    We

    must

    not

    forget

    that

    the

    Fiqh

    schools

    placed

    great

    emphasis

    on the fact

    that

    their

    graduates

    distinguished

    hemselves

    n

    having

    a

    good

    knowledge

    of

    Arabic

    mathematics.

    A

    glance

    at the

    introduction f

    mathematical

    15

    Labib, p.

    501 (b. Private

    No.

    2).

    16

    Labib,

    p. 216.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    15/19

    92

    Subbi

    Y. Labib

    works

    is

    enough

    to

    confirm

    that this knowledge was not

    only re-

    quired of merchants

    but also was

    part of the trainingof the

    'Ulamda'.

    Thepreferenceof the orientalprivatebusinessmenand of the scribes

    of

    the state

    for mental

    arithmetic

    and fingerarithmetic,as well as

    the use of

    the mysterious

    Siydq

    and

    coptic numerals

    has been main-

    tained until moderntimes. We should

    not be

    deceived into thinking

    that

    the

    introductionof Arabic

    numbers was

    to be of importance

    mostly

    in

    the development

    of privateaccounting.

    Al-Dimasql,

    n

    his

    often quoted

    booklet about trade, advised

    the

    merchants:"Everythinghat is being bought and sold shallbe mea-

    sured by

    the dry measure,or by

    time, or in

    numbers.Thereforea

    merchantshould

    know the swindler and the

    methods which

    he

    ap-

    plies when

    measuring,

    weighing and counting,

    so that he

    shall not

    be

    dependent

    upon unreliable

    people."'17

    Credit

    transactions

    as

    well

    as the organizationof

    trading

    com-

    panies

    made

    accurate accounting imperative.

    Bankers

    and money

    changers

    were required

    o keep recordsand to

    enter the

    transactions

    of theirclientsaccuratelyn ledgers,although hey werenot required

    to specify

    their own profit. Generally

    bankers

    received deposits

    which

    could be

    withdrawn

    by

    means of

    a

    written

    assignment.

    The

    double

    entry

    method was

    an

    importantpart

    of a

    merchant'sskill.

    It allowed

    him

    to watch

    not only the flow of

    single values

    but also

    the circulation

    of the

    capital, and

    it

    enabled

    him to register

    quanti-

    tatively its change

    and transformation

    nd to controlthe success

    and

    the

    developmentof the

    business.

    The accountswere of goods or of completedbusiness. Normallya

    merchant

    would settle

    a sale immediately

    and would enter

    the

    profit

    or

    loss

    in

    his ledger.

    This method gave

    a

    current

    account

    of

    profit

    and

    loss. A periodic

    balancing

    was therefore

    not necessary.

    If one

    was

    made,

    it

    only

    served

    the

    purpose

    of

    a control. This information

    on

    medieval Islamic

    accounting,

    unfortunately,does

    not come

    from

    commercial

    ccounting edgers,

    since to

    this

    day

    we

    have been

    unable

    to

    find any such books,

    but rather it

    is

    a

    compilation

    of details

    which

    I

    have

    been

    able

    to

    crystallize

    rom

    egal

    books,

    notarial

    books,

    and

    treatiseson

    financialadministration.

    The

    private

    business

    of

    the Islamic

    princes

    was

    extensive.

    The

    state

    treasury

    was

    in

    reality

    also

    the

    privy purse

    of the

    prince.

    Viziers'

    households and

    businesses

    were separated

    n name

    only.

    Their en-

    17

    al-Dimashki/H. Ritter,

    p. 62.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    16/19

    Capitalism

    in Islam

    93

    terprises

    were

    among

    the largest

    capitalistic

    undertakings

    of their

    time

    and needed

    accurate

    accounting

    so

    that

    they

    might

    not lose

    sight of their credits and debits. In medieval Islam, rulers bought,

    sold,

    and filled

    their

    magazines

    with

    native

    and

    foreign

    goods;

    the

    Fatimid

    Caliphs possessed

    many

    funduqs

    and

    thousands

    of

    shops

    and

    were

    at the same

    time the

    largest

    merchants,

    producers,

    and

    consumers

    in

    their

    realm.

    Leasing

    the

    privilege

    of

    collecting

    taxes

    was

    the

    surest way

    to

    build capital

    in the

    Islamic

    Orient.

    It was well

    known that

    oriental

    tax farming was essentially

    a concession

    by the

    state

    to a

    private

    or

    official

    finance contractor

    who

    as a rule

    had to put

    up his own

    means

    as collateral

    in collecting

    the

    revenue

    debit

    due.

    These

    tax farmers

    understood well

    how to let

    profits

    work

    for

    them in

    new

    business

    undertakings.

    They were

    active

    in trade and

    manufacturing,

    where

    they invested

    their surplus.

    There

    are

    many examples

    which

    show

    how deeply

    tax

    farmers

    and

    officials

    penetrated

    into

    the economy.

    V

    Islamic capitalism

    was

    mainly

    a

    commercial

    and consumer-credit

    capitalism,

    and its unstable organization

    is revealed

    in

    the

    fact

    that

    princes

    and

    regents were

    bad debtors.

    They not

    only

    failed to

    pay

    their

    obligations

    but

    in

    times of

    need

    they

    confiscated

    the wealth

    of

    their creditors.

    Confiscation

    in

    times

    of unrest

    and invasion

    was

    the

    order of

    the

    day.

    On

    the

    other

    hand,

    the privileges

    and advantages

    received from the heads of state brought such high profits that some

    creditors were

    able

    to amortize

    the debts

    and

    cover even

    the

    losses.

    Neither

    Islamic

    law nor

    the Islamic

    rulers

    recognized

    the

    inde-

    pendence

    of the

    city-nor

    did

    they

    offer

    it

    autonomy.

    In

    addition,

    the

    urban

    community,

    which

    was

    supposed

    to

    remain

    religiously

    oriented,

    was unable to develop

    into

    a

    politically

    effective

    com-

    munity-neither

    through

    autonomy

    nor

    by

    compromises

    with

    the

    rulers.

    This had

    a definite

    influence

    upon

    the

    economy.

    The

    Islamic state did not take steps to found a national bank.

    Savings

    or

    checking

    accounts

    were not new

    to the Islamic world,

    and pawning,

    loaning,

    trusts,

    money

    changing,

    transfer

    of

    credit,

    and

    transfer

    of

    debts were

    all

    important

    divisions

    of business

    life

    in

    any

    large

    Islamic

    city.

    Yet neither

    the

    government

    nor the

    busi-

    nessmen

    took

    upon

    themselves

    the task of

    founding

    a state

    bank

    which

    would

    take care of business transactions

    well

    and

    efficiently.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    17/19

    94 Subbi

    Y. Labib

    Such

    an

    institution

    would have become

    a political force

    and would

    have assumed

    an unusual

    position between state economy

    and

    private enterprise. It would have helped to prevent or overcome

    many

    a

    great

    economic catastrophe.

    The

    Maudi' al-Hukm might

    be called the preliminary

    step to such

    an institution. Al-Maudi'

    was a bank, a

    depository, a building, or a

    vault

    in

    which the state placed

    certain funds

    for definite purposes.

    Also

    the

    Qadi al-Hukm

    had

    a

    bank,

    a vault,

    in

    which he kept under

    his protection the possessions

    and important

    documents of orphans

    or of persons temporarily away from the

    city. In addition I

    have

    already mentioned

    that Qadis too occupied

    an important

    position

    in business circles.

    Amari, Dozy, Canale,

    and

    Quatremere

    were

    the

    first to

    refer

    to

    the

    very

    interesting appearance

    of the maona

    in the Islamic world.

    The maona

    was

    a

    kind

    of

    private

    bank

    which

    loaned out

    state

    money.

    The

    word

    maona

    (in

    Arabic

    ma'iina)

    means

    support

    or

    help

    or,

    as

    the case

    might

    be,

    reciprocal help.

    The

    Arabic

    maona

    did

    not

    undergo the same development as did the occidental maona; it was

    not used

    for

    financing

    wars

    or

    mining.

    The

    function of

    the

    ma'iina

    in

    Islamic

    society

    remained restricted

    to

    giving

    financial

    help

    on a

    very

    limited

    scale.

    Amari has

    established that

    the

    idea

    of the

    maona was

    used

    also in

    Tuscany

    and

    signified

    a

    general

    company

    founded

    for

    the

    exploitation

    of

    iron

    mines and

    a

    large

    trade

    in iron.'8

    One can find

    precursors

    of the

    modern

    bourse

    in

    Islam:

    there was

    not

    only

    the

    capitalistic

    business

    in

    the

    funduqs, but also business

    activity typical of the modern commodity exchange, i.e., the trading

    in wares not present

    at

    the

    marketplace

    but to be delivered later.

    Dates

    were

    legally

    sold at auction before

    they

    were

    ripe

    and

    har-

    vested.

    Even the

    wholesaling

    of

    many

    kinds of

    tuberous

    vegetables

    such

    as

    onions, garlic, carrots, turnips,

    radish,

    and

    colocasia took

    place

    before

    the

    products

    were out

    of

    the

    earth-that

    is,

    before the

    merchant

    ever

    saw

    the

    harvested

    product.

    According

    to

    many

    a

    jurist

    this was

    legal.

    Insurance

    however

    remained

    inaccessible

    to

    the

    purely

    religiously

    bound

    Islamic

    mentality.

    The insurance

    of wares

    by distributing

    and

    sharing

    the risk is of course included

    quite

    naturally

    in

    the com-

    menda but

    insurance

    in

    the

    service of the

    development

    of

    a

    capi-

    talistic

    business and the reduction

    of business

    risk

    remained

    18

    R.

    Dozy, Suppl6ment

    aux dictionnaires

    arabes

    (Leiden

    and Paris, 1927),

    article

    awana,

    ma 'fina;

    with

    references.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    18/19

    Capitalism

    in

    Islam

    95

    practically outside the scope of Islamic economic thought (except

    in Mughal India).

    One should neither consider nor treat the capitalism of the Middle

    Ages

    in

    terms of national economy or even from its point of view.

    Economics of the Middle Ages is the study of the house, of Oikos.

    The tradition of this system of economics in the Occident begins

    with

    Xenophon and Aristotle, and survives through Scholasticism

    of the Middle Ages to the modern period. In the Orient it is known

    as 'Ilm

    Tadbir

    al-Manzil. With this name, 'Ilm

    Tadbir

    al-Manzil, the

    Muslim refers to the second of the three sciences belonging to the

    Aristotelian scheme of practical philosophy, ethics, economics, and

    politics. An illustrative quotation follows:

    The

    goal

    of

    home economics is the knowledge of managing the household,

    which is composedof husband, wife, children, and slaves, with which its (the

    house's) state of affairs s arrangedand their (the mentioned persons') condi-

    tion is regulated. This assists the persons in developing virtues and avoiding

    evils. Brfis (that is, Bryson) from the ancients wrote about this and also other

    learned

    persons.19

    The

    elements of home economy are five: father, mother, children,

    slaves, and food supply. As with every community, the home requires

    cooperative endeavor. This depends primarily upon the

    man of

    the

    house. The man must look to the best interest of the family through

    maintenance and order. A statement of the Prophet Muhammad

    makes

    reference to this:

    "Every one

    of

    you

    is

    a

    shepherd

    and

    every

    one

    of you will be held accountable for his herd."

    The economy of the home included the totality of all its human

    relationships, the relationships

    of man

    to wife, parents

    to

    children,

    lord to servants (slaves),

    and the

    carrying out

    of

    their

    duties

    in

    the

    home. Home economy

    is

    not formed

    by

    the market or

    oriented

    toward

    it but toward

    the

    economy

    of

    the

    household

    and the farm.

    Trade

    is

    necessary

    and

    permissible

    insofar as

    it

    serves to

    supplement

    the

    self-sufficiency

    of the

    home;

    but

    in

    and

    of

    itself

    it

    may

    not

    be

    concerned

    with making money.

    Ancient

    thought

    and

    Islamic

    revela-

    tion

    confirm

    this idea.

    Ethics,

    or

    "practical philosophy,"

    is

    essentially

    a moral

    system

    for

    the individual,

    the head

    of the

    house,

    the statesman. Within

    the

    moral

    system

    it

    is

    possible

    for

    a

    man,

    a

    home,

    and

    a

    state to

    approach

    their

    "essence,"

    their

    true

    being.

    This remained the

    ultimate

    goal

    of

    19

    M.

    Plessner,

    Der

    Oikonomikoe

    des

    Neupythagoreers

    "Bryson"

    und

    sein Einfluss

    auf

    die

    islamische

    Wissenschaft (Heidelberg,

    1928), pp.

    40,

    59-61,

    144.

    This content downloaded from 152.118.24.10 on Sun, 15 Mar 2015 09:48:11 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/9/2019 Capitalism in Medieval Islam

    19/19

    96

    Subhi

    Y.

    Labib

    Islamic morality.

    Both

    Orient and Occident during the

    Middle Ages

    endeavored

    always to unite

    ethics, economics, and politics

    in a sys-

    tem of morality

    of the person,

    the head of the house, the

    statesman.

    There was

    a

    very strong

    "urge for gain"which cannot be

    overlooked,

    to be sure,

    but it was different

    from the factory production and the

    calculation

    of modern

    capitalism.

    In

    short, the concrete

    historical

    meaning of Islamic commerce

    (one

    can almost

    say "of Islamic

    capitalism")

    is to be found

    by proceeding from the

    concept of the

    "whole

    house" and not

    simply

    from the

    concepts

    of economics which

    have been formed by the modern market and are oriented toward it.

    With this we reach the

    core

    of

    the

    question

    concerning

    oriental

    capitalism.

    SUBHI

    Y.

    LABIB, University

    of Hamburg