Top Banner
Advanced and Contemporary Topics in Macroeconomics I Alemayehu Geda Email: [email protected] Web Page: www.alemayehu.com Lecture 1 Introduciton & The Solow Swan/Neoclassical Model Addis Ababa University Departement of Economics PhD Program 2014
115

Alemayehu Gedaalemayehu.com/PhDMacro1Web/Lecture 1 Final Version... · 2014. 7. 12. · Romer, David th(2012). Advanced Macroeconomics.4 Edition Barro, Robert Jr. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin

Feb 07, 2021

Download

Documents

dariahiddleston
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • Advanced and Contemporary Topics in

    Macroeconomics I

    Alemayehu Geda Email: [email protected]

    Web Page: www.alemayehu.com

    Lecture 1

    Introduciton & The Solow Swan/Neoclassical

    Model

    Addis Ababa University

    Departement of Economics

    PhD Program

    2014

  • Course Content/Outline 2014 • Lecture 0*: Review of Advance [Dynamics]

    Mathematics [Optional]

    • Lecture 1: The Solow-Swan/Neoclassical

    Grwoth Model [Exogenous Saving]

    • Lecture 2: The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans

    Growth Model [Endogenous Saving]

    • Lecture 3: The Diamond/ OLG Model

    • Lecture 4: The Endogenous Growth Models

  • Course Content….Cont’d

    • Lecture 5: Real Business Cycle Models

    • Lecture 6: The Political Economy of Grwoth

    (in Ethiopia and Africa)

    • Micro-Foundation

    • Lecture 6: Consumption

    • Lecture 7: Investment

    • Lecture 8: The Labour Market

    • Lecture 9*: Dynamic General Macroeconomic

    Equilibrium Models & DSGE [Optional]

  • Literature For the Course

    Main Readings/Books

    Romer, David (2012). Advanced Macroeconomics.4th Edition

    Barro, Robert Jr. and Xavier Sala-i-Martin (2004). Economic Growth.

    Valdes, Benigno(1999).Economic Growth: Theory ,Empirics and Policy

    Acemoglu, Daron (2008).Introduction to Economic Growth.

    Nudulu et al (2008). The Political Economy of Grwoth in Africa, 2 volumes

    (AERC and Cambridge University Press.

    Alemayehu Geda (2008) The Political Economy of Grwoth in Ethiopia (In

    the same book above/Nudulu et al, Vol 1, Ch 4)

    • Chiang, Alpha C (1992). Elements of Dynamic Optimization. New York,

    McGraw-Hill/Or

    • Sydsaeter et al (2005). Further Mathematics for Econ Analysis (PTO)

    • Taylor, Lance (2004). Reconstructing Macroeconomics. Princeton: Princeton

    University Press.

    • Weeks, John (2013). False Paradigm: The Irrelevance of Neoclassical

    Macroeconomics. London: Edward Edgar

  • . .

    Relevant Articles

    • Solow, Robert M. (1956). “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic

    Growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70:65-94.

    • Baumol, William (1986). “Productivity Growth, Convergence, and

    Welfare," American Economic Review, 76:1072-85

    • DeLong, J. Bradford (1988). “Productivity Growth, Convergence, and

    Welfare: Comment," American Economic Review, 78:1138-54.

    • Mankiw, Gregory N., David Romer, and David N. Weil (1992). “A

    Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth," Quarterly Journal

    of Economics, 107:407-37..

    Klenow, Peter J. and Andres Rodriguez-Clare (1997). “The

    Neoclassical Revival in Growth Economics: Has It Gone Too Far?"

    NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 12:73-103.

    Hall, Robert E. and Charles I. Jones (1999). “Why Do Some Countries

    Produce So Much More Output per Worker than Others," Quarterly

    Journal of Economics,114:83-116

    .

  • . Phelps, Edmund S., “The Golden Rule of Accumulation: A Fable for Growth men,” American Economic Review, September 1961, pp. 638-643

    Oded Galor, Unified Growth Theory (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,

    2011).

    Romer (1986) „Increasing Returns and Long run Growth‟ Journal of Political

    Economy, 94:1002-1037.

    Romer (1990) „Endogenous Technological Change’, Journal of Political

    Economy, 98: 71-102.

    Frankel (1962)

    Domar, Evsey D. (1946), “Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth and Employment”,

    Econometrica 14: 137-147.

    Harrod, Roy (1939),“An Essay in Dynamic Theory”,Economic Journal 49: 14-33.

    Kaldor, Nicholas (1963), “Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth”, In

    Proceedings of a Conference Held by the International Economics Association,

    Friedrich A. Lutz and Douglas C. Hague (editors). London: Macmillan.

    Swan, Trevor W. (1956), “Economic Growth and Capital Accumulation”,

    Economic Record 32: 334-361.

    .

  • Class schedule:

    Lucas, Robert E. Jr., “Why Doesn‟t Capital Flow from Rich to Poor

    Countries?” American Economic Review, May 1990, pp. 92-96.

    Uzawa, Hirofumi (1961), “Neutral Inventions and the Stability of the

    Growth Equilibrium!”, Review of Economic Studies 28: 117-124

    William A. Brock and M. Scott Taylor, “The Green Solow Model,”

    Journal of Economic Growth, June 2010, pp. 125-153.

    Aghion, P and P. Howitt (1992) „A Model of Growth through Creative

    Destruction‟ Econometrica, 60: 323-351.

    – To be worked out/ Flexible Modular

    – 3 to 6 hours lecture per week

    Additional articles are given on the Course CD that Contains the

    lecture slides

  • Course Assesement Course Assessment

    A) Each Candidate will write a review of literature in 4/5 topical areas of the work

    based on 5 to 10 latest working papers/and Presentation. (20%)

    B) There will be bi-weekly/Weekly drill on each of the lectures (to be handled by a

    teaching assistant) (25%)

    C) A Group paper on African Business Cycle (A group of 2 in each team) (20%)

    D) Class Presentation and participation (10%)

    E) Individual term paper on grwoth in Ethiopia or Africa on the following topics, 20

    pages in a model of AER, Journal of African Economies etc (30%)

    A) A Solow-Swan Model for Ethiopia OR

    B) Human Capital Augmented Solow-Swan Model for Ethiopia

    C) Ramesy-Cass-Koopman Model for Ethiopia

    D) Endogenous Grwoth Model for Ethiopia

    E) The Political Economy of Grwoth in Ethiopia: Political, Institutions and

    Grwoth

    F) A Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model for Ethiopia/Kenya

    G) Modelling Investment (or Public Private Investment Interaction) in Ethiopia

    H) Modelling Consumption/Saving in Ethiopia

  • .

    Chapter One

    The Solow –Swan Model

    [The Neoclassical Model]

  • Lecture One contents I. Introduction and Review of Advanced Mathematics

    II. The Solow Model

    Assumptions

    Inputs and outputs

    Production function

    Evolution of inputs into production

    Solution

    III. The Dynamics of the Model

    The Dynamics of k

    The Balanced Growth Path

    IV. Comparative Dynamics: Impact of a Change in Savings

    Rate

    The Impact on Output

    The Impact On Consumption

  • . V. Quantitative Implication Steady State: Quantitative Importance of Savings Rate in Affecting

    Income Per Capita in the Long Run

    Transition Dynamics: The speed of Convergence

    VI. The Central Questions of Growth in the Solow Model

    VII. Empirical Applications

    Growth Accounting

    Convergence

    VIII. Conclusion

  • .

    General Introduction about

    Growth: Some basic facts about

    economic growth

  • Method: Sherlock Holems’

    Method!

    • Sherlock Holems‟ 4 Rules of Scientific inquiry

    Rule 1: Begin with the Data

    Rule 2: Build a theory (or thoeries) capable of covering the facts that are know to u

    Rule 3: Do not take for grants that your theory is correct because it cover all the facts (as new facts may come and other theories may cover that too)

    Rule 4: If new evidence can not be accommodated with exiting theories reconsider your theories.

    {See Valdes, Page 8-10)

  • Kaldor’s “Stylized Facts” about

    Growth • In 1961 article he outlined empirical regularities: • “Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth” in F.A. Lutz and D.C. Hague

    (eds). The Theory of Capital. New York: St Martin Press.

    • SF1: Standard of living always increase from one generation to the next – Per capita income and labour productivity (y=Y/L) is increasing

    (y grows at positive rate )

    • SF2: The capital output ratio has no upward or downward trend (K/Y -no change in the long run )

    • SF3: The functional distribution of income remains constant in the long run Π/K=profit, constant and hence Wage share is total income less profit share

    • SF4: There are a variety of growth rates of percaptia income across the world

  • Kaldor’s “Stylized Facts”

    • SFacts (1) and (2) imply the following:

    • SFacts (2) and (3) together imply the following:

    oo

    oo

    oo

    ykL

    Y

    L

    K

    L

    Y

    Y

    K

    Y

    K

    Y

    K

    0

    0/constant

    /Y)( -1 W/Ydefinationby 1)W/Y/ (hence YWGiven

    constant. be alsomust / capital physicl of share income

    theS3by constant also is / and S2by constant is K/Y since

    ; ..

    Y

    Y

    K

    Y

    K

    YK

    Y

    YK

  • Some basic facts about economic growth

    Standards of living in industrialized economies have

    increased dramatically over the centuries

    In the U.S and Western Europe real incomes is 10 – 30 times larger

    than 100 years ago and 50 – 300 times larger than 200 years ago

    Worldwide growth has not been constant

    Average growth rates in industrialized countries were higher in the

    twentieth century than in the nineteenth century, still growth rates

    were higher in the nineteenth century than in the eighteenth

    century…

    Productivity growth has slowed down

    In many industrialized countries annual growth in output per

    person has slowed down since the 1970s

  • Standards of living vary enormously across countries

    Real income is more than 20 times higher in the U.S than in

    Bangladesh

    Large variations in growth rates

    Growth miracles, e.g. Japan, NICs

    Growth disasters, e.g. Sub-Saharan Countries, Argentina

    Over the modern era, cross-country income differences has

    widened – enormous differences in human welfare across

    different part of the world.

    Some basic facts about economic growth:

    (cont..)

  • An important quote fro Lucas(1988):

    – When you think of the implication of a

    solution to grwoth problem for mankind…..

    “Once one start to think about economic

    growth, it is hard to think about anything

    else.”

    (Robert E. Lucas, 1988)

  • .

    Chapter One

    The Solow –Swan Model

  • I. Introduction

    As the first step, in order understand the role of

    proximate causes (see nxt Slide) of economic

    growth we develop a simple framework. We take

    the Solow-Swan model as our starting point.

    The model is named after Robert Solow and

    Trevor Swan, who published two seminal papers

    in the same year (1956).

  • Introduction.......cont’d

    Robert Solow developed many applications of the

    model, and was later awarded the Nobel prize in

    economics.

    This model has not only become the centerpiece of

    growth theory but has also shaped the modern

    macro theory.

  • Introduction.......cont’d

    The central model of macroeconomics before the

    Solow model came along was the Harrod-Domar

    model, which was named after Roy Harrod and

    Evsey Domar (Harrod (1939) and Domar (1946)).

    The Harrod-Domar model focused on

    unemployment and growth.

    The distinguishing feature of the Solow model is

    the neoclassical aggregate production function.

  • II. The model

    The Solow model focuses on four variables: –Output (Y)

    –Capital (K)

    –Labour (L)

    –Effectiveness of labour (A)

    The Production function takes the form:

    where t denotes time, which enters indirectly into the production function through K, L and A.

    )1.1.(.........., tLtAtKFtY

  • Some properties of the production function:

    Output changes over time only if input changes over

    time

    The amount of output obtained from given quantities

    of capital and labour rises over time only if there are

    technological progress, i.e. the effectiveness of labour

    increases over time.

    A and L enter multiplicatively into the model such that

    the term AL is referred to as „effective labour‟ meaning

    that technological progress is labour-augmenting

    (Harrod-neutral).

  • Some critical assumptions regarding the production

    function:

    CRS – doubling input doubles output (A held constant):

    • Implicitly assumes that the economy is sufficiently large that

    any gains from specialization has been exhausted

    • Implicitly assumes that other production factors (e.g. land) is

    relatively unimportant

    )2.1.........(..........0,, cALKcFcALcKF

  • With CRS, an intensive form of the production

    function is easily specified:

    Set

    Hence (1.3) can be rewritten in intensive form production

    function as:

    ALc /1

    )3.1........(..........,11,AL

    YALKF

    ALAL

    KF

    AL

    KkWhere

    kfyAL

    KFALKF

    ALAL

    Y

    )4.1......().........()1,(),(1

  • The intensive form production function is assumed

    to satisfy the following conditions:

    0)('lim

    )('lim

    0)(''

    0)('

    00

    0

    kf

    kf

    kf

    kf

    f

    k

    k

    f(k)

    k

  • . Since it follows that the

    marginal product of capital,

    {see equation 1.3}

    Thus the assumptions that is positive and

    is negative imply that the marginal product of

    capital is positive ,but that it declines as capital

    (per unit of effective labor) rises.

    )(),(AL

    KALfALKF

    ).()1

    )((),(

    kfALAL

    KfAL

    K

    ALKF

    )(kf )(kf

  • . These conditions (which are stronger than needed

    for the model‟s central results) states that the

    marginal product of capital is very large when the

    capital stock is sufficiently small and that it

    becomes very small as the capital stock becomes

    larger;

    their role is to ensure that the path of the economy

    does not diverge.

  • Example:

    Cobb-Douglas production function:

    First order condition:

    Second order condition:

    kkfy

    kAL

    K

    AL

    ALK

    AL

    Y

    ALKY

    )(

    )(

    )5.1 ...(........................................ 10,)(

    1

    1

    0)1(

    1)(''

    2

    2

    k

    kkf

    0)()( 1

    kkfk

    k

    k

    kf

  • The Evolution of the Inputs into Production

    The remaining assumptions of the model concern how

    the stock of labour, knowledge, and capital change over

    time.

    The model is set in continuous time(i.e., the variables

    are defined every point in time)

    Labour and knowledge (technology) is assumed to

    grow at a constant rate over time:

    where n and g are exogenously given constant growth

    rates and a dot over a variable denotes a derivative w.r.t

    time

    )9.1(..............................).........(

    )8.1.(..............................).........(

    tAgA

    tLnL

    )/)()(( dttdLtL

  • . The growth rate of a variable refers to its

    proportional rate of change .(i.e., the phrase the

    growth rate of X refers to the quantity .

    Thus equation (1.8) implies that the growth rate of

    L is constant and equal n , and equation (1.9)

    implies that A‟s growth rate is constant and equal

    to g .

    )(

    )(

    tX

    tX

  • . A key fact about growth rates is that the growth

    rate of a variable equals the rate of change of its

    natural log. i.e.,

    To see this: since lnX is a function of X and X is a

    function of t, using the chain rule to write:

    .)(ln

    )(

    )(

    dt

    tXd

    tX

    tX

    )10.1.(....................).........()(

    1)(

    )(

    )(ln)(lntX

    tXdt

    tdX

    tdX

    tXd

    dt

    tXd

  • . Applying the result that a variable‟s growth rate

    equals the rate of change of its log to (1.8) and

    (1.9) tells us that the rate of change of the logs of

    L and A are constant and that they equal n and g,

    respectively. Thus,

    )12.1.........(....................,.........)]0([ln)(ln

    )11.1.........(....................),........)]0([ln)(ln

    gtAtA

    ntLtL

  • . • Where L(0) and A(0) are the values of L and A at

    time 0. Exponentiating (or taking the ant-log) both

    sides of these equations gives us

    Thus our assumption is that L and A each grow

    exponentially.

    )14.1.(..................................................)0()(

    )13.1.(..................................................)0()(

    gt

    nt

    eAtA

    eLtL

  • . Coming to our model: Output is used to either consumption or investment (saving).

    • The saving rate (s) is assumed to be constant and

    exogenously given.

    – For simplicity one can assume that one unit of

    investment is equal to 1 unit of new capital.

    • Existing capital depreciates at a rate δ.

    These assumptions imply that the capital stock

    grows according to:

    )15.1..(..........).........()()( tKtsYtK

  • . Although no restrictions are placed

    ,their sum is assumed to be positive .i.e.,

    This completes the model.

    The Solow model is grossly simplified in a

    number of ways.

    There is only one good

    No government

    Fluctuation in employment are ignored

    , andgn

    0 gn

  • . Production is described an aggregate production

    function with just three inputs

    The rate of saving, deprecation, population growth

    and technological progress are constant

    Etc….

    The model omits many obvious features of the real

    world which are important for growth

    But the purpose of a model is not to be realistic

    (NB Positivist Method!). After all, we already

    possess a model that is completely realistic-the

    world itself (see my 2nd Trade book Ch4

    Appendix)

  • III. The Dynamics of the Model

    Here we want to determine the behavior of the

    economy we have just described in the previous

    slides.

    The evolution of two of the three inputs into

    production, labor and knowledge, is exogenous.

    Thus to characterize the behavior of the economy,

    we must analyze the behavior of the third input,

    Capital.

  • a) The Dynamics of k

    Because the economy may grow over time, it is much easier

    to focus on the capital stock per unit of effective labour, k,

    than on the unadjusted capital stock K.

    Since k(t)=K(t)/A(t)L(t), i.e. a function of K, L and A, which

    are all functions of t, the chain rule applies and we can find

    the intensive form of the capital growth equation from

  • .

    kAL

    Kwhere

    tA

    tA

    tLtA

    tK

    tL

    tL

    tLtA

    tK

    tLtA

    tK

    tLtAtLtAtLtA

    tK

    tLtA

    tK

    dtdKtKtAtA

    tktL

    tL

    tktK

    tK

    tktk

    t

    tLtA

    tK

    tk

    simply is

    )(

    )(

    )()(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )()(

    )(

    )()(

    )(

    (1.16)

    )()()()([))()((

    )(

    )()(

    )(

    etc...../)( NB )()(

    )()(

    )(

    )()(

    )(

    )()(

    )(

    )()(

    )(

    )(

    2

  • Since from (1.8) and (1.9) ,

    respectively

    Substituting these facts into (1.16) &using (1.15)

    yields:

    ntL

    tL

    )(

    )(g

    tA

    tA

    )(

    )(

    )18.1...(........................................).........()(

    ))(()()(

    )(fact that the UsingAnd

    )()()()()(

    )(

    (1.17)

    )()()()(

    )()()()(

    )()(

    )()(

    tkgntksf

    tkftLtA

    tY

    tgktnktktLtA

    tYs

    gtkntktLtA

    tKtsYgtkntk

    tLtA

    tKtk

    Break-even investment Total investment

  • Equation (1.18) is the key equation in the Solow model.

    It states that, the rate of change in the capital stock per unit of

    effective labour is the difference between total investment

    per effective labour unit and the amount of investment

    needed to keep the capital-to-effective labour-ratio constant.

    The first term, sf(k), is actual investment per unit of effective

    labor

    The second term, (n + g + )k is break-even investment, i.e.

    the amount of investment that must be done to keep k at its

    existing level. Investment is needed to prevent k from falling

    because the existing capital deprecates at rate , which is

    captured by k term, and also because the quantity of effective

    labor is also growing at rate (n+g), which is captured by the

    term (n+g)k.

  • .

    Therefore, when the actual investment per unit of

    effective labor exceeds the break-even investment, k

    rises, and vice-versa.

    Moreover, when the two are equal, k is constant.

    This is depicted in figure 2 below.

    • The figure plots the two terms of the right-hand side of

    the fundamental law of motion as functions of k. Since

    F(0,L,A) = 0 it implies that f(0) = 0, and therefore

    actual investment and break-even investment are equal

    at k = 0.

  • . Furthermore, the Inada conditions imply that as k goes to zero f’(k) becomes very large. Therefore

    sf(k) is steeper than break even investment line

    around k = 0; and actual investment is larger than

    break-even investment.

    • The Inada conditions also imply that f’(k) falls to

    zero as k becomes very large. As a result, at some

    point the slope of he actual investment curve

    becomes less than the slope of the break-even

    investment line, implying that the two lines must

    eventually cross

  • Figure 2: Actual investment and break-even

    investment

  • . Finally, due to diminishing returns, fkk < 0, the two lines intersect only once. Let k* be the value

    where actual investment equals break-even

    investment, or in other words there is no change in

    capital per unit of effective labor, .

    This value of k is also called the steady state value

    of k.

    The next figure shows that the economy converges

    to k regardless of where it starts.

    0k

  • Figure 3: Steady State

    When k < k* actual investment exceeds break-

    even investment as a result .

    When k > k* the actual investment is less than

    break-even investment and therefore .

    Finally for k =k*, .

    0k

    0k

    0k

  • b) The Balanced Growth Path

    How are output, capital and consumption growing

    in this economy when k = k*.

    We know that L and A are growing at

    exogenously given rates - n and g, respectively.

    The capital stock K = ALk, and since k is constant

    at k*, the aggregate capital stock of the economy

    is growing at the rate(n+g).

  • . With both capital and effective labor growing at the same rate (n+g), the assumption of constant returns to scale

    implies that aggregate output is also growing at the rate (n

    + g). Since consumption is (1 − s)Y , where s is constant,

    consumption also grows at the same rate as output.

    Finally, capital per unit of labor, K/L, and output per unit

    of labor, Y/L, grow at the rate g.[Nb:! at (n+g)-n, n for the

    percpita handling!)

    Thus, the Solow model implies that regardless of its

    starting point, the economy converges to a balanced

    growth path, where each variable grows at a constant rate

  • . At this point we also need to discuss our assumption that technological change is labor augmenting.

    This is a restriction that is required for the existence of a

    balanced growth path.

    NB: Other types of technological change - Hicks-neutral

    (unbiased technological change) and capital augmenting-

    technical change - are not consistent with a balanced

    growth path. For a proof look at Uzawa (1961).

    Notice also that off the balanced growth path technological

    change is no longer required to be labor-augmenting. (Your

    reading assignment begin with Valdez)

  • . The idea of balanced growth though seemingly abstract has a parallel in the data.

    The Kaldor‟s stylized facts, Kaldor (1963), show

    that while output per capita grew, the capital-

    output ratio (K(t)/Y (t)), the interest rate(r(t)), and

    the distribution of income between labor

    (w(t)L(t)/Y (t)) and capital (R(t)K(t)/Y (t)) remain

    roughly constant.

    The figure below shows the factor shares for the

    US since 1929.

  • Figure 4: Labor and capital shares in value added in the U.S.

  • IV. Comparative Dynamics: Impact of a Change in

    Savings Rate

    The parameter of the Solow model that policy is

    most likely to affect is the savings rate.

    • What is the effect of (unanticipated) change in the

    savings rate s?

    • Consider an economy that is on a balanced growth

    path, and suppose that there is a permanent

    increase in s. The increase in s shifts the actual

    investment curve upwards, thereby resulting in an

    increase in k*.

  • A. The Impact on Output

    • Initially, when s increases and the curve shifts up,

    at the initial steady-state value of k the actual

    investment exceeds break-even investment.

    • Thus is positive resulting in an accumulation of

    k, which continues till it reaches the new steady-

    state value of k.

    • This is depicted in the figure below.

    k

  • Figure 5: Effect of change in savings rate on investment

  • .

    • Y/L, we concluded grew at rate g when k = k*.

    • However, when k is increasing, as the economy moves

    from one steady-state to another, Y/L grows at a rate

    higher than g (because the source of growth is not

    only the growth rate of A[=g], but also growth rate

    of k (which was constant when k=k* hence y*=f(k*)

    before s increased to s*).

    • Once k reaches its new steady-state value, growth rate

    of Y/L falls back to g.

    • Thus a permanent increase in s produces temporary

    increase in in the growth rate of output per worker, k

    rises for some time but eventually it reaches a level at

    which additional savings are devoted to maintaining

    the higher level of k.

  • Figure 6: Effect of an increase in savings rate

  • Figure 6: Effect of an increase in savings rate

  • Effect of increase in saving, 2nd diagram explained

    • After the transition period of “T” the new steady

    state log y will follow the trajectory {At+T=log

    y*t+T, At+T+1=log y*t+T+1,…}

    – This is above &parallel to the previous steady state

    – In the transition period (T) the slop of log y [which is

    grwoth rate] is greater than both stead states. (ie

    during transition percapita income growth at a rate

    greater than “g”

    – Note that y=(Y/L) is one-to-one linked to y~= (Y/AL)

    through A, y=A(y~), Thus as y~ growth at growth

    rate of A=g (since it is f(k*) in which k is constant at

    steady state), so is y will be growth (at “g‟ rate).

    – The reason behind this dynamics is the diminishing MPK

  • . • At the end of the day a change in s has a level effect but not a growth rate effect:

    – ie. it changes the balanced growth path of the economy

    and its level of output per worker, but it does not affect

    the growth rate of output of per worker on the new

    balanced growth path.

    • In fact in the Solow model only changes in the rate

    of technological progress have growth effects of

    percaipita income; all other changes have level

    effects.

  • B. The Impact on consumption

    • Since consumption per unit of effective labor c =

    (1 − s)f(k), an increase in s at the initial steady-

    state level of k results in an initial decrease in c

    and then as k rises to its new level c also rises.

    • Whether or not c exceeds its original level can be

    seen by writing down the expression for

    consumption per unit of effective labor.

  • Steady-state consumption is given by:

    • An increase in s raises k. Thus, c will rise in

    response to an increase in s if the marginal product

    of capital, fk, is greater than (n + g + δ).

    • Intuitively when k rises investment must increase

    by (n + g + δ) times k in order to sustain the new

    level of k.

    )20.1.(..........),,,(*)]()),,,(*([*)19.1...(..................................................*,........)(*)(*

    s

    gnskgngnskf

    s

    c

    kgnkfc

    k

  • . • If fk is less than (n + g +δ ), then the additional output from a higher k is not enough to support the higher

    level of k.

    • As a result c must decline in the long run to maintain

    the stock of capital.

    • On the other hand, if fk exceeds (n+g+δ) there is more

    than enough output to support the higher level of k,

    and therefore c increases in the long run.

    • However, if the steady-state value of k to start with is

    changed duet to s in such a way that fk = (n + g + δ)

    then a marginal change in s does not change c.

  • . • This value of k is called the golden rule level of the capital stock (& the associate saving “saving gold”).

    • At the golden rule level of capital, consumption is at

    its maximum level {see the next 2 slides).

    • Since s is exogenous in the Solow model, there is no

    guarantee that k will be at its golden rule level.

    • This cases are depicted in the figures below.

    – See the implications of this for the choice of either

    current or future consumption (hence Ramsey

    model) & OLG models!! see Barro &Sala-i-

    Martin, p. 34 on dynamic inefficiency [also briefly

    in few slides ahead]

  • Figure 7: Output, investment and consumption on the

    balanced growth path

  • V. Quantitative Implications of the Model

    • A) Effect of saving on per capita income

    • B) A little bit about Dynamic inefficiency

    • C) Transition dynamics – the speed of

    convergence from y to y* /or from k to k*

  • A. Steady State: Quantitative Importance of Savings

    Rate in Affecting Income Per Capita in the Long Run

    • In our discussions we saw that income per capita varies significantly across countries. Can the savings

    rate have a quantitatively important impact on income

    per capita so as to explain such large income

    differences?

    • The long run effect of a change in savings rate on

    output per unit of effective labor is given by: (see

    derivation of 1.21, next slide)

    )()(

    )()(

    )21.1.....(........................................),,,(

    )(

    *

    **

    **

    *

    kfsgn

    kfkf

    s

    gnskkf

    s

    y

  • . • Where is the level of output per unit of effective

    labor on the balanced growth path.

    • Thus to find , we need to find

    • To do this, note that k* is defined by the condition

    ; thus k* satisfies

    • Equation (1.22) holds for all values of s(and of n, g, and δ)

    *)(* kfy

    s

    y

    *

    s

    k

    *

    0k

    )22.1......(..........).........,,,(*)()),,,(*( gnskgngnsksf

  • . • Thus the derivatives of the two sides with respect to s are equal:

    Where the arguments of k* are omitted for simplicity.

    • Rearranging (1.23) gives :

    )23.1..(..............................*

    )(*)(*

    *)(s

    kgnkf

    s

    kkfs

    )25.1..(..............................*)()(

    *)(*)(**

    *

    *

    obtained be could (1.21) rulechain and ) (1.24 using

    )24.1..(........................................*)()(

    *)(*

    kfsgn

    kfkf

    s

    y

    s

    k

    k

    y

    kfsgn

    kf

    s

    k

  • . Two changes help in interpreting this expression.

    • First convert (1.25) into an elasticity by

    multiplying both sides by s/y*

    • Second use the fact that to substitute for s .

    *)(*)( kgnksf

  • Making these changes results:

    *)](/*)(*[1

    *)(/*)(*

    (1.26)

    *)](/*)(*)()*)[((

    *)(*)(*))(

    *)(

    *)('

    *)()*)((

    *)(

    *)()(

    *)(*)(

    *)(

    *

    *

    kfkfk

    kfkfk

    kfkfkgngnkf

    kfkfkgn

    kf

    kf

    kfsgnkf

    ksf

    kfsgn

    kfkf

    kf

    s

    s

    y

    y

    s

  • . • is the elasticity of output with

    respect to capital at k=k*.Denoting this by

    • If markets are competitive and there are no externalities,

    capital earns its marginal product . In this case, the total

    amount received by capital (per unit of effective labor) as

    the share of output on the balanced growth path is

    *)(/*)('* kfkfk

    have we*),(kk

    )27.1....(..................................................*)(1

    *)(*

    * k

    k

    s

    y

    y

    s

    k

    k

    *).( *),(/*)('* korkfkfk k

  • • The elasticity of output w.r.t. saving depend on capital share of

    income, . ie – With competitive markets and no externalities capital earns its marginal

    product.

    – & On the balanced growth path the share of income attributed to capital

    must be

    • Capital share of income is found to be about 1/3 in most

    countries, which implies that (from eqn 1.27 above) the

    elasticity of output w.r.t. saving is about 0.5:

    – Thus, a 10% increase in savings rate increases per worker output in the

    long run by 5% relative to the path it would have followed. For a 50%

    change in savings rate y rises by only 25%.

    – . Thus, big changes in savings rate have only a moderate effect on the

    level of output on the balanced growth path

    *)(kK

    *)(*)(/*)('* kkfkfk K

    5.03/11

    3/1

    *)(1

    *)(*

    *

    k

    k

    s

    y

    y

    s

    k

    k

  • B. Saving, Dynamic inefficiency and the prelude

    to Ramesy-Cas-Koopman Model

    • A little bit about Dynamic inefficiency here:

    – If higher saving leads to higher level of income (higher

    steady state) [though no higher growth rate], the best saving

    rate will be 100% - but this is tautological [ie higher s,

    higher k, higher Y etc….]

    – Specifically in SS model a saving rate above the golden rule

    reduces per capita consumption at steady state [called

    dynamically inefficient/over saving – hence the need to

    reduce it from s2 (the need to increase it form s1 in the next

    diagram)

    – From a societies welfare perspective high saving is not

    necessarily good and low saving necessarily bad when once

    see it dynamically either -partly because higher saving

    today means lower consumption today (may be higher

    consumption in the future!).

    – .

  • Saving, Dynamic inefficiently and the prelude to

    Ramsy-Cas-Koopman Model

    – If we follow Keynes: “consumption is the sole end and

    objective of all economic activity” so we can use it for

    societal welfare indications

    – However the welfare depends on hh valuation of future

    versus current consumption (or themseleves versus future

    generation).

    – Thus, the optimal saving of a nation (hence investment)

    should be inferred from the optimal level of

    consumption/utility it generates over time

    – Thus the importance of inter-temporal view and hence the

    Ramesy-Kass-Koopman model: !!how much should a

    nation save?!!Ramesy

    – See Barro and Saal-i-Martin, p. 34, & nxt slide

  • Saving, Dynamic inefficiently and the prelude to

    Ramsy-Cas-Koopman Model

    • A little bit about Dynamic efficiently here:

    – See Barro and Saal-i-Martin, p. 34, nxt slide

  • C. Transition Dynamics: Speed of Convergence

    How rapidly does k approach k* when s changes?

    – The growth of capital per unit of effective labour depends on

    the size of the capital-to-effective labour ratio:

    – At the point where we know that .

    – These conditions imply that a first order Taylor-series

    approximation of around the point give:

    )(kkk

    *kk 0k

    )(kk *kk

    */)(*)()( kkkkkktktk

  • In the neighbourhood of the balanced growth path, k converges to

    k* at a speed that is approximately proportional to its distance from

    k*. Hence, the gap between k(t) and k* narrows at a rate that is

    approximately constant and equal to :

    To find an expression for we differentiate

    w.r.t. k and evaluate the resulting equation at the point k=k*:

    *)0(*)( kkektk t

    )()()( tkgntksftk

    gnk

    kf

    kfkgngn

    gnksfk

    kk

    K

    kk

    *)(1

    *)(

    )('*

    *)(')(

    *

  • Using the expression for we can conclude that the speed of convergence of the capital stock is:

    A reasonable assumption is that . With we have .

    k moves 4% of the remaining distance toward k* per year

    It takes approximately 17 years for k to get half the way to its balanced growth path if k(t) is in the vicinity of k* to begin with.

    Since output per effective worker only depend on k, k and y converges to k* and y* at the same speed.

    The impact of a change in the saving rate on output is both quite small and fairly slow!

    *)0(*)( *)(1 kkektk tgnkK

    %6 gn 3/1K

    %41 gnK

  • VI. The Central Questions of Solow model the

    growth theory

    – Why are some economies much richer than others?

    – Are income levels converging across nations?

    The Solow model identifies two potential source to why output per

    worker varies across countries and over time:

    1. Differences in capital per worker (K / L)

    2. Differences in the effectiveness of labour (A)

    Due to convergence of k to k* changes in the effectiveness of labour is

    the only factor that lead to permanent changes in the growth rate

  • • There are two ways to see that the Solow model implies that differences in

    capital accumulation cannot account for large differences in income:

    1. Required differences in output per worker**

    • Differences in incomes between rich and poor countries roughly

    corresponds to a factor of 10. This implies that the capital stocks in rich

    and poor countries differs by a factor of .

    In the real world one observes that the capital-to-labour ratio in rich

    countries are 20 to 30 times larger than in the poor countries. Moreover,

    capital-to-output ratios tend to be fairly constant over time.

    2. Required differences in the rate of return to capital

    • If markets are competitive the rate of return to capital equals its marginal

    product minus depreciation.

    – A tenfold difference in capital per worker implies a difference in the rate of

    return to capital by a factor of 100.

    – MPK in poor countries would be so high that there would be no reasonable

    answer to why not all capital in the world relocates to the poor countries.

    )3/1(100010 /1 KK

  • VII. Empirical Application

    A. Growth Accounting

    In the Solow model ,long run growth of output per worker

    depends only on technological progress.

    But short run growth can result from either technological

    progress or accumulation.

    Thus the model implies that determining the sources of

    short run growth is an empirical issue

    Thus the growth accounting relates to an empirical

    extension that allows to distinguish between different

    sources of growth.

  • . Growth accounting is pioneered by Abramovitz(1956) and

    Solow(1957)

    To see how it works, consider the production function

    given as

    ).()(

    )()(

    )(

    )()(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    yeilds side handright on the terms therewriting and )(by sides bothe Dividing

    .ly respective,][ and ][ denote and where

    )()(

    )()(

    )(

    )()(

    )(

    )()(

    is derivative totalits implies, This).()(),(()(

    tRtL

    tLt

    tK

    tKt

    tA

    tA

    tA

    tY

    tY

    tA

    tL

    tL

    tL

    tY

    tY

    tL

    tK

    tK

    tK

    tY

    tY

    tK

    tY

    tY

    tY

    L(AL)

    YA

    (AL)

    Y

    A

    Y

    L

    Y

    tAtA

    tYtL

    tL

    tYtK

    tK

    tYtY

    tLtAtKFtY

    LK

  • . Note that

    is the elasticity of output with respect to labor

    at time t,

    is the elasticity of output with respect to

    capital at time t and

    .

    )(tL

    )(tK

  • . Subtracting from both sides and using the fact that results an expression for the

    growth of output per worker as:

    Note that:

    The growth rate of Y,K and L are straight forward

    to measure

    If capital earns its marginal product, can be

    measured using data on the share of income that

    goes to capital

    )(

    )(

    tL

    tL

    1)()( tt KL

    )35.1..(..........).........(])(

    )(

    )(

    )()[(

    )(

    )(

    )(

    )(tR

    tL

    tL

    tK

    tKt

    tL

    tL

    tY

    tYK

    K

  • . R(t) then can be measured as the residual in

    equation (1.35) above.

    Thus equation (1.35) provides a way of

    decomposing the growth of output per worker into

    the contribution of growth of capital per worker

    and a remaining term, the Solow Residual

    The Solow residual –some times interpreted as a

    measure of the contribution of technological

    progress (TFP).

    But as derivation shows, it reflects all sources of

    growth other than the contribution of capital

    accumulation via its private return

  • . Growth Accounting has been applied to many

    issues:

    Yong(1995)-used detailed growth accounting to argue that

    the higher growth in the newly industrialized countries of

    East Asian than the rest of the world is mainly Due to

    rising investment, increasing labor force participation, and

    improving labor quality(in terms of education),and not to

    rapid technological progress other forces affecting the

    Solow residual

    See:Hsieh(1998a); Denison(1985); Bailyand

    Gordon(1988); Griliches(1988);and Jorgeson(1988) for a

    classic application of growth accounting

    Alemayehu (2008; 2013) used it to examine Ethiopia‟s

    growth “Miracle” 2000-2013.

  • Table 2.3: A Growth Accounting Exercise for Ethiopia in the Last Decade (2000-2010)

    Note: The growth accounting is based on the result of econometric estimation reported in Alemayehu and Befekadu (2005) and Alemayehu et al (2008). Using various models (both macro and micro) these

    studies have come up with the capital share coefficient (β) that ranges from 0.28 to 0.36. We have used

    0.30. The capital stock is generated using the perpetual method (Geda, 2013/14).

    Year

    GDP Growth The Contribution of

    Capital

    The Contribution of

    Labour

    The Contribution of Total

    Factor Productivity (TFP)

    2000/2001 7.4 0.6 2.6 4.2

    2001/2002 1.6 0.8 2.7 -1.9

    2002/2003 -2.1 1.0 2.6 -5.7

    2003/2004 11.7 0.7 2.7 8.3

    2004/2005 12.6 1.2 2.6 8.8

    2005/2006 11.5 1.1 2.7 7.7

    2006/2007 11.8 1.5 2.2 8.1

    2007/2008 11.2 2.1 2.2 6.9

    2008/2009 9.9 1.8 2.3 5.9

    2009/2010 10.4 2.7 2.2 5.5

    Average(2003/04-2009/10) 11.3 1.6 2.4 7.3

  • B. Convergence

    Are poor countries growing faster than the rich ones, i.e. is

    there convergence?

    Are income levels converging across nations?

    • Solow model suggests three reasons why countries are

    expected to converge: 1. The model predicts that countries converge to their balanced growth

    paths – to the extent that differences in output per worker depend on countries being at different stages relative to their balanced growth path, cross-country income differentials are expected to decrease.

    2. The model predicts that the rate of return to capital is lower in countries with more capital per worker, which induce capital to flow from rich to poor countries and result in convergence.

    3. Lags in technology diffusion can account for income differentials between countries and to the extent that poor countries gain access to state-of-the art technologies poor countries would catch up on rich countries.

  • .

    • For classic application on the convergence

    hypothesis see Baumol(1986), De

    Long(1988); also Findely, AER, 1996. The

    first two are discussed below

    • Reading Assignment on Beta and Sigma

    convergence/ Presentation - Seminar (form

    the convergence folder)

    Convergence… Cont‟d

  • Convergence… Cont‟d

  • Convergence… Cont‟d

    • De Long (1988) noted Baumol‟s Finding is

    largely spurious. Cause problems of:

    – (a) sample selection (countries that have long data

    series are those that are the most industrialized).

    Countries not rich 100 years ago and in the sample

    must be there if they grow fast

    – He included countries as rich as the 2nd poorest in

    Baumol‟s sample, Finland. This led to add more

    countries (see Diagram below)

  • Convergence… Cont‟d

  • Convergence… Cont‟d

    • De Long (1988) 2nd problem:

    – (b) measurement error: estimates of 1870 are

    imprecise. Measurement errors bias result

    towards convergence [if 1870 is overstated,

    growth 1870-79 is understated by an equal

    amount and vice versa (growth tends to be low

    where measured initial income is high even if no

    relation between initial income actual growth).

    – He then estimated the following model (see

    Diagram below)

    – This reduced the estimate of “b” to -0.566

  • Convergence… Cont‟d

  • Convergence… Cont‟d

    • For example: if we find measured growth is

    negatively related to initial income this could be

    – Either measurement error is not important and there

    is convergence OR

    – Measurement is important and there is no

    convergence

    – This is what is called “model identification problem”

    • However, De Long argues we can have an idea

    of the accuracy of the 1870 data

  • Convergence… Cont‟d • In term of standard value (SD), an SD of 0.01

    implies, we measured initial income with 1%

    error [-implausibly low] and SD=0.50 is 50%

    error [-Implausibly high]

    • He found even moderate SD has substantial

    impact on the result.

    – For unbiased sample an SD of 0.15 makes the estimate

    of “b” reaches 0 (no convergence); AND an SD of

    0.20 makes it 1 (convergence big time!)

    • Thus, a moderate measurement error could take

    most of the remaining Baumol‟s estimate of

    convergence (as we noted was already-0.566)

  • C. Human capital Augmented Solow-Swan Model

    • Attributed to Mankiew et al (1992)….

    • Good summary in Heijira (2009) P.411

  • The Augmented Solow Swan (Human

    Capital) Neoclassical Model

    1) The Puzzle :

    Emperical estimates of the speed of adjustment shows that values around

    (this is actually for the US & say 2% of the gap from the steady state is closed each year (i.e., the gap between

    However ,having this values and bench mark value for US and other DC‟s

    0226.0

    tt yy and

    estimate share capital theis 68.0)(

    of valuecomputable the,04.0 and 032.0

    gn

    gnα

    ygn

  • The augmented Solow Swan (Human

    Capital) Neoclassical Model ….. Cont’d

    However, the capital share for most DC‟s is about 30% .The question is what is happening. Why the SS model gives α=68% [see our Diagram bfr]

    2) Mankiw, Romer and Weil(1992) suggested a simple solution to this problem/ puzzle

    →we are not thinking about K in a right way. We take it as physical capital but it also incorporates human capital (skill)-this is because all output not consumed is not used to increase physical capital only; but also skill (health education, etc)

  • Human capital ….Cont’d • Key idea: add human capital to the model.

    • Technology:

    Y(t)= 𝐾(𝑡)αk+𝐻(𝑡)αH+[𝑍 𝑡 𝐿 𝑡 ]1−αk−α𝐻

    ( 0 < αK+ αH < 1)

    where H(t) is the stock of human capital and αK and αH are

    the efficiency parameters of the two types of capital

    (0 < αK, α H < 1).

    • In close accordance with the Solow-Swan model, productivity

    and population growth are both exponential (𝑍 (t)/Z(t) = nZ

    and 𝐿 (t)/L(t) = nL.

    • The accumulation equations for the two types of capital can

    be written in effective labour units as:

  • Human capital ….Cont’d

    • Stability: The phase diagram is give next

  • Human capital ….Cont’d

    • In Summary the model is given by:

    • Stability: The phase diagram is give next

  • Humanĸ capital ….Cont’d

    • Stability: The phase diagram is give next

    k

  • Human capital ….Cont’d

  • Human capital ….Cont’d

  • Human capital ….Cont’d

  • VIII. Conclusion

    Central conclusion from the Solow model:

    Only differences in the productivity of labour

    can account for vast differences in wealth across

    space and time (see slide 84&85 in this lecture).

    The „technology factor‟ is, however, exogenous to the Solow model – the model makes no prediction of what this

    factor really is, how it behaves or how it grows.

    END… END…. END