Top Banner

of 19

A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

Apr 14, 2018

Download

Documents

Alex Lenferna
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    1/19

    A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America1

    By Georges Alexandre (Alex) Lenferna

    University of Kansas Philosophy DepartmentNSF IGERT C-CHANGE Research Associate

    Email:[email protected]

    Thesis Statement: This paper argues that putting in place a carbon tax in the United States is a policy

    which adheres to conservative principles, and will also help to promote more equitable economic growth

    and can, relative to other climate legislation, tackle problems of social inequality, poverty and climate

    change among other societal problems hence why it has also been appreciated by democrats.

    This paper will attempt to provide a comprehensive argument in support of the carbon tax, but will not

    neglect the shortcomings that such a policy might have. My aim is to provide an argument illustrating

    why when starting from conservative principles a carbon tax is the most sound policy choice in response

    to climate change. My first task will be to elucidate many of the potential benefits of a carbon tax, such

    as job creation, efficiency promotion and environmental protection, and then respond to some of the

    major objections that are voiced against it. While keeping in mind the potential shortcomings of a

    carbon tax, the paper will continuously explore why a carbon tax is better than its three major

    competing policies: environmental regulation of greenhouse gases (GHGs) through the EPA; government

    subsidies for clean energy; and neither of the above.2 Although these are not necessarily mutually

    exclusive policies, I aim to show why a carbon tax best adheres to conservative principles and why

    conservatives should support it as the dominant policy instrument aimed at effectively leveraging the

    economy towards a sustainable paradigm of growth. Following from that I will then go on to argue why

    significant opposition to a carbon tax exists within the US and why much of the opposition is morally

    suspect, after which I shall end with a discussion as to why it is of particular moral significance that the

    US takes on such an action.

    1Alternate title: A Republicans Guide to Shooting Yourself in the Foot with Climate Legislation

    2I have not included cap-and-trade both, because there is great evidence to suggest a carbon tax works much

    more effectively and, mostly, because on a national level it seems that a cap-and-trade bill is simply a political non-

    starter, especially following the major failure of the Waxman-Markey Bill which attempted to introduce such

    legislation. In the more poetic words of Jonathan Chait, no possible scenario, not even if John Boehner were

    ordered to pass a cap-and-trade bill by a returning Jesus Christ, bearing legislative text, could result in Congresss

    passing a cap-and-trade law (2013).

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    2/19

    The Political Context

    For the sake of our children and our future, we must do more to combat climate

    change...I urge this Congress to pursue a bipartisan, market-based solution to climate

    change. But if Congress wont act soon to protect future generations, I will. I will direct

    my Cabinet to come up with executive actions we can take, now and in the future, to

    reduce pollution, prepare our communities for the consequences of climate change, and

    speed the transition to more sustainable sources of energy Barack Obama (2013)

    The above quote from President Barack Obamas State of the Union address lays down a challenge to

    the US Congress, either they work together to come up with a market-based solution to climate

    change3, or President Obama uses his executive powers in order to address climate change, which

    involves expanding the powers of the Environmental Protection Agency to further regulate greenhouse

    gases under the Clean Air Act. Following up on his challenge Obama is currently pursuing the option of

    using the EPA to regulate greenhouse gas emissions (among other avenues4) because congress has so far

    failed to rise to Obamas challenge and put in place a market-based solution to climate change. For both

    conservatives and democrats alike, the continued inaction of congress should be seen as a mistake, for

    as this paper will argue, the market-based option, if pursued in the form of a carbon tax5, is the most

    effective way to bring about action on climate change in a form which is most beneficial (and least

    detrimental) to the US (and the rest of the world), and which not only adheres to conservative

    principles, but can also most efficiently bring a bring about a just transition to a more equitable,

    environmentally-benign and labour intensive paradigm of growth.

    3This paper agrees with the overwhelming scientific consensus that anthropogenic greenhouse gas emissions are

    causing devastating climate change. This scientific consensus and the details thereof (which this is not the place to

    get into) are outlined in detail in the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Fourth Assessment Report (IPCC,

    2013) among other places,3and while the supposed debate rages on in many circles within the United States, I

    will take for granted, as the relevantly qualified global scientific community does, that consensus from those who

    are relevantly qualified on matters related to climate change is virtually unanimous. The controversy, as far as I can

    tell (being a former climate skeptic myself (Cf. Lenferna, 2011)) comes not from legitimate scientific concerns, but

    from a malignant fossil fuel industry funded disinformation campaign (Cf. Conway & Oreskes, 2010). What does

    remain uncertain is how far we will allow this crisis to grow and how devastating the effects thereof will be, not

    that we are causing the problem, for that we know with virtual scientific certainty3.

    4http://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/image/president27sclimateactionplan.pdf

    5A carbon tax is somewhat of a misnomer, for even though much of our worries around anthropogenic climate

    change revolve around our emissions of carbon dioxide, other greenhouse gasses are also important to consider.

    Thus under many proposed carbon taxes other greenhouse gasses such as methane and nitrous oxide are

    included and measured according to their carbon dioxide equivalency5, such that where carbon emissions are

    taxed per ton of carbon other greenhouse gasses can be taxed according to their relative global warming

    potential5. A carbon tax in the US would hopefully do likewise.

    http://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/image/president27sclimateactionplan.pdfhttp://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/image/president27sclimateactionplan.pdfhttp://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/image/president27sclimateactionplan.pdfhttp://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/image/president27sclimateactionplan.pdf
  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    3/19

    The Economics of a Carbon Tax

    A carbon tax is a Pigovian tax which works by putting a price on carbon dioxide emissions and/or

    greenhouse gas equivalents. The aim is to internalize the costs that are now externalized by using the

    atmosphere as a free sink within which to pump our pollution. The costs of such emissions are referred

    to as the social cost of carbon6, referring to the fact that the costs of the emissions are not borne by the

    companies themselves, but rather by society at large. Thus a carbon tax aims to make companies pay for

    the costs that they are foisting upon society and which are not included in the way that we currently

    determine the price of goods and operations. Far from this being a radical distortion of the free market

    system as opponents of the tax often claim, such a tax corrects a distortion of our current system by

    attempting to make companies pay for the full price of their production and processes. Indeed by doing

    so a carbon tax adheres to a fundamental conservative and free market principle of ensuring that

    companies pay for their full costs, and are not subsidized by society at large through foisting the costs of

    their production upon society. As Brian Andrew (2008) points out, a perfect market is one where all

    parties bear the full costs and receive the full benefits of their production and consumption. Indeed, it is

    if for such reasons among others that major conservative economists, such as Art Laffer and Greg

    Mankiw, have supported such a tax (Cf. Ryan, 2013), while many carbon intensive industries, attempting

    to protect their perverse subsidy/privilege have attempted to fight it off.

    The economic effects of

    increasing the prices of carbon

    intensive goods through

    internalizing the social cost of

    carbon can partly be understood

    by way of a simple supply and

    demand analysis. As the graph

    6According to Ackerman (2010), in the United Kingdom, where carbon pricing and cost calculations have a longer,

    better-researched history, the latest estimates of the social costs of carbon is a range of $41 to $124 per ton of

    CO2, with a central case of $83. The U.S. administrations interagency working group that has been studying the

    SCC, however, has come up with a range of values, with a central estimate of $21 per ton of CO2. What this

    means, if we follow their estimates, is that only part of the cost of carbon will be added into the price, and this is

    problematic. However, many U.S. proposals for a carbon tax currently on the table, some of which I will explore

    later, aim to better factor in a carbon price closer to the true social costs of carbon, although determining the

    exact price of carbon is a complex, uncertain, methodologically-dependent and value-laden affair (Cf. Watkiss &

    Hope, 2011).

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    4/19

    alongside illustrates internalising the costs leads to a higher price per unit for carbon intensive products,

    and thus leads to an upward shift along the demand curve, creating a higher price and smaller demand

    for carbon intensive goods. Through increasing the costs of carbon intensive products their less carbon

    intensive competitors become more competitive, as they will have less of a tax to bear depending on

    how much less carbon intensive they are. Thus depending on the short- and long-term elasticity of the

    respective market and the relative competitiveness of competitors to carbon intensive goods, including

    the cost of carbon into the price will lead to a shift away from carbon intensive goods. As Dieter Helm

    points out, when it comes to carbon, nobody particularly wants it. Demand for carbon is indirect

    (Helm, 2012, p. 179). Thus, for instance, in the energy sector such a tax would lead to a move towards

    more natural gas, wind and solar rather than coal, and in the agricultural sector it would involve a move

    away from more fossil fuel-intensive modes of production towards less carbon-, more labour-intensive

    (read: job-creating) modes of farming, many of which are already emerging or exist as cost-effectivecompetitors.7 In Australia, for instance thanks to a carbon price wind energy is currently cheaper than

    coal despite the fact that it is a country with some of the worlds most abundant fossil fuel resources,

    thus illustrating the efficacy of putting a price on carbon (Paton, 2013).

    Furthermore, the carbon tax through setting a set price on carbon gives certainty as to the costs of

    climate legislation, and thus unlike uncertain wind subsidies or fluctuating prices caused by the

    uncertainties inherent in a cap-and-trade system, the carbon tax sends a clear price signal to the market,

    which will arguably unleash much needed nascent investment in the clean energy economy. Indeed, the

    world is moving towards a low-carbon renewable energy economy, and quite uncoincidentally most of

    the major economic leaders are also leaders in clean energy. According to the 2013 Global Climate

    Leadership Review, France, Japan, China, South Korea, Germany and the UK are leaders in clean energy

    on top of the low-carbon competitiveness index, while the US is ranked 11 th (The Climate Institute,

    2013). A carbon tax, through sending important and clear market signals can help the U.S. take the lead

    and remain competitive in the emerging low-carbon economy. Given that the National Renewable

    Energy Laboratory (Mai, Sandor, Wiser, & Schneider, 2012), claims that the United States can meet 80

    7Using Hotellings Model to understand demand, for instance, in the oil sector, an increase in price of oil caused by

    a carbon tax would lead to decreases in current output of oil and shifting of production to the future. That is

    because by not having priced oil properly we have over-allocated resources in the present relative to a production

    profile that aims to maximize gains (Cf. Dahl, 2004, p. 300) . Hotellings Model ignores ethical constraints and

    focuses solely on maximizing profit, but nonetheless on this barebones economic model we find that by including

    an SCC we push production to the future, which gives more time for the development of alternative sources of

    energy and production.

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    5/19

    percent of its electricity needs in 2050 through renewable energy generation using just current (never

    mind future) technology, this represents great potential for growth and job creation.

    Job Killer or Creator?

    Policy designed for creating jobs is often a goal more associated with the left than conservative

    principles. Republican Congress members, however, are arguing against a carbon tax on the grounds

    that it will kill jobs. While job creation may not be a fundamental concern for conservatives, a policy that

    would reduce jobs in the United States would arguably not be a welcome outcome for conservatives.

    However, evidence points to the fact that the Republican opposition to carbon tax on the grounds of job

    loss is unfounded as a carbon tax can actually assist in creating jobs. Indeed implementing a carbon tax

    will create many more jobs in the long run than not doing so would. That is not to say that some jobs

    wont be lost in the transition to a clean economy, as just like in any economic transition or progress,

    some jobs will be gained while some will get lost, but overall if the carbon tax is implemented the gains

    in jobs will be significant, and so the Republican opposition on the grounds of job loss is a bit more than

    suspect. Allow me to expand.

    Consider, as Dan Hind (2012) points out, that the triumph ofproductivity has perverse consequences,

    insofar as the abundance of energy and mechanical labour provided by fossil fuels and associated

    technologies has made more and more people economically unnecessary, shifting them to the margins

    of our economy, while those who have access to the fruits of the fossil fuel revolution richly reap its

    rewards. Furthermore, as Huber (2009) argues, and as is evidenced by vast income disparities in the U.S.

    and the world over, by decisively shifting productive forces from human labour to machines, fossil fuels

    generalised the conditions for a class monopoly over the means of production thus reducing the amount

    of meaningful jobs available and creating great inequalities.8 Clean energy, however, when compared to

    fossil fuels, uses far more of its budget on hiring people and less on acquiring vast machines, supplies,

    land and energy itself (Cf. Pollin, Heintz, & Garrett-Peltier, 2009).

    More than simply not hurting jobs, much evidence shows that the transition spurred on by the carbon

    tax will help to create many more jobs than the fossil fuel industry does. Even in West Virginia (which

    has the highest dependence on coal in the country with the coal industry directly employing 3% and

    indirectly 9% (McIlmoil, Hansen, Boettner, & Miller, 2010)), comparative studies show that a developed

    renewable resources industry could provide far better fiscal returns to the county and state than coal

    8Cf. Wealth Inequality in America:http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=QPKKQnijnsM

    http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=QPKKQnijnsMhttp://www.youtube.com/watch?v=QPKKQnijnsMhttp://www.youtube.com/watch?v=QPKKQnijnsMhttp://www.youtube.com/watch?v=QPKKQnijnsM
  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    6/19

    presently does, while raising wages and expanding overall employment opportunity (Cf. Hansen, Collins,

    Hendryx, Boettner, & Hereford, 2008). According to Robertson (2010), the coal mining industry

    maintains 82,595 jobs nationwide, while the wider coal industry supports 174,000 permanent jobs

    nationwide, despite the fact that coal accounts for around 40% of energy production. On the other

    hand, conservative estimates for a transition to just 20 percent national power generation from wind

    shows 500,000 jobs created (Robertson, 2010). Already in 38 states and the District of Columbia, job

    growth in the clean energy economy outperformed total job growth between 1998 and 2007 (Pew

    Charitable Trusts, 2009). Just the currently underdeveloped solar industry currently employs more

    people than there are ranchers in Texas, actors in California and coal miners nationally (Spross, 2013).

    Indeed significant amounts of evidence show there is a great net gain in job creation through the switch

    to a clean economy, and the jobs gained, furthermore, are healthier and more environmentally benign.

    Pollin et al. (2009) found that for every $1

    million invested in renewable energy as

    compared to the fossil fuel industry, more

    jobs would be created at more than a 3-1

    margin. Indeed as the graph9 alongside only

    begins to reveal, a move towards a clean

    energy economy can help reverse trends

    towards the obsolescence of human capital,

    i.e. the transition will help create more jobs, and more ecologically friendly ones at that. Thus the slogan

    of green jobs and the clean economy is not a mere rhetorical political slogan, but is underpinned by the

    reality that the fossil fuel industry is based more on exploiting natural resources, while the clean

    economy is based more on the use of human capital. A carbon tax by shifting production and R&D

    towards a clean economy can help us to accrue such gains, and although there will be losses in the fossil

    fuel industry, overall jobs will increase substantially. Thus, as the Financial Times Editorial Board points

    out, the claim made by more than 85 Republican members of Congress that carbon taxes would kill

    millions more jobshas no evidence to support it (2013).

    As Joseph Schumpeter argues, the process of industrial mutation that incessantly revolutionizes the

    economic structure from within is one of the underpinning strengths of capitalism (in Gilding, 2013).

    Economies are not static entities, and thus protecting the fossil fuel industry by not implementing a

    9Created from data in Robertson (2010)

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    7/19

    carbon tax would not only result in fewer jobs, it would be equivalent to protecting the telephone

    industry from the development of cell phones or the horse-and-cart industry from the development of

    cars, an unjustifiable form of protectionism preventing technological progress clearly against good

    conservative principles as well as broader job creation and pollution reduction. As conservatives are

    fond of pointing out, government shouldnt be in the job of picking winners and losers, but protecting

    the fossil fuel industry from the full costs of the production does just that with the losers being broader

    society and the environment. That is not to say that we shouldnt perhaps think about assisting those

    who might lose out as we transition to clean energy, as, for instance, a 2009 bill from Rep. Larson has. 10

    However, shielding the fossil fuel industry from the full costs of their production in order to save the

    limited jobs they create, which is less than would be created otherwise, is both bad for job creation and

    contrary to conservative principles of a free, fair, transparent and accountable market.

    Shrinking Government, Reducing Taxes and Helping the Poor

    I believe that any conservative who heard that a policy could shrink government, reduce taxes and help

    the poor, would be more than happy to support such a policy, all other things being equal. Well, a

    carbon tax when compared to its alternative, could do all of the above depending on how it is

    structured, and so, given that the alternative of EPA regulations is pretty much inevitable if a carbon tax

    is not put in place11, a carbon tax should be a conservatives cup of tea, so to speak.

    Firstly, if the U.S. is to go ahead with expanded EPA regulation of greenhouse gasses emission under the

    Clean Air Act instead of a carbon tax, then doing so involves expanding the EPAs reach to cover power

    stations and other stationary sources, which would involve creating the regulatory framework and

    enforcing the regulations at each and every source a contested process that is currently underway (Cf.

    Chait, 2013). That is certainly quite a substantial government feat, which would require substantial

    growth of the EPA i.e. government hardly a goal of most conservatives. Efforts to block the EPA,

    furthermore, will be stalling the inevitable as the Supreme Court has granted EPA authority to do so, and

    10Cf.http://www.carbontax.org/blogarchives/2009/03/06/new-larson-bill-raises-the-bar-for-congressional-

    climate-action/11

    To quote from theCitizens Climate Lobby: Efforts to block new EPA regulations are destined to be an exercise in

    futility amounting to little more than political grandstanding. Such legislation has no chance of moving in the

    Democrat-controlled Senate. Even if it passed in both chambers, the President would veto any such bill.

    Equally futile would be attempts to block CO2 regulations through the court system. In 2007, theSupreme Court

    ruled that the EPA has the authorityandthe obligation to regulate greenhouse gases that contribute to global

    climate change. And just last year, a three-judge panel from the U.S. Court of Appeals for the District of

    Columbiaupheld a finding from EPAthat greenhouse gas emissions endanger public health.

    http://www.carbontax.org/blogarchives/2009/03/06/new-larson-bill-raises-the-bar-for-congressional-climate-action/http://www.carbontax.org/blogarchives/2009/03/06/new-larson-bill-raises-the-bar-for-congressional-climate-action/http://www.carbontax.org/blogarchives/2009/03/06/new-larson-bill-raises-the-bar-for-congressional-climate-action/http://www.carbontax.org/blogarchives/2009/03/06/new-larson-bill-raises-the-bar-for-congressional-climate-action/http://citizensclimatelobby.org/sept-6-editorial-packet/http://citizensclimatelobby.org/sept-6-editorial-packet/http://citizensclimatelobby.org/sept-6-editorial-packet/http://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/03/washington/03scotus.html?ex=1333339200&en=e0d0a1497263d879&ei=5124&partner=permalink&exprod=permalinkhttp://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/03/washington/03scotus.html?ex=1333339200&en=e0d0a1497263d879&ei=5124&partner=permalink&exprod=permalinkhttp://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/03/washington/03scotus.html?ex=1333339200&en=e0d0a1497263d879&ei=5124&partner=permalink&exprod=permalinkhttp://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/03/washington/03scotus.html?ex=1333339200&en=e0d0a1497263d879&ei=5124&partner=permalink&exprod=permalinkhttp://www.nytimes.com/2012/06/27/science/earth/epa-emissions-rules-backed-by-court.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/2012/06/27/science/earth/epa-emissions-rules-backed-by-court.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/2012/06/27/science/earth/epa-emissions-rules-backed-by-court.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/2012/06/27/science/earth/epa-emissions-rules-backed-by-court.htmlhttp://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/03/washington/03scotus.html?ex=1333339200&en=e0d0a1497263d879&ei=5124&partner=permalink&exprod=permalinkhttp://www.nytimes.com/2007/04/03/washington/03scotus.html?ex=1333339200&en=e0d0a1497263d879&ei=5124&partner=permalink&exprod=permalinkhttp://citizensclimatelobby.org/sept-6-editorial-packet/http://www.carbontax.org/blogarchives/2009/03/06/new-larson-bill-raises-the-bar-for-congressional-climate-action/http://www.carbontax.org/blogarchives/2009/03/06/new-larson-bill-raises-the-bar-for-congressional-climate-action/
  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    8/19

    they will do so unless we accept Obamas challenge and implement a market -based solution like the

    carbon tax.

    A carbon tax, on the other hand, if implemented, would avoid the need for copious EPA greenhouse gas

    regulation, and could be levied upstream at the source of fossil fuels, at bottlenecks of production, andat the border, which would drastically reduce the need for government expansion, such that by

    collecting the tax from upstream fuel producers and a few big sources of CO2 the government would

    only have to charge thousands of businesses, not millions of Americans (Washington Post Editorial

    Board, 2013). The carbon tax would thus eliminate the need for the massive central planning and

    spending required to more broadly enforce the Clean Air Act. Indeed, according to an overwhelming

    majority of the IGM Experts Panel of economists, a carbon tax would be the least expensive way to

    reduce carbon-dioxide emissions (IGM Experts Panel, 2011).

    Furthermore, if a carbon tax becomes the predominant policy for dealing with climate change it could

    reduce the need for clean energy subsidies and its associated lobbying and rent-seeking. This is a

    potential gain, for as any good conservative will tell you, markets are neutral and look for the most

    efficient responses whereas governments pick winners and losers in subsidy choices, and sometimes

    they get it wrong and create lock-in to incumbent technologies and businesses, foreclosing

    opportunities to spur innovation (Cf. Hsu, 2011).12 Furthermore, as Dieter Helm points out, with

    subsidies not only do we often pick the wrong winners, but typically the better-off invest and get the

    subsidies, and the poor pay a disproportionate part of the bill (2012, p. 89). Thus a carbon tax can most

    effectively tackle climate change, reduce the size of government, and, if designed correctly, even assist

    the poor.

    12Subsidy removal, however, cannot be on sided, for if we remove subsidies to the clean energy industry they

    need to be accompanied by removal of the much larger subsidies to the American fossil fuel industry, which

    receives $502 Billion in subsidies annually through direct support to those industries, consumer rebates and

    avoided taxes on pollution (International Monetary Fund, 2013).

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    9/19

    According to Handley (2013), the House Republican leadership has pledged to reject any climate

    measure that generates revenue for the government, this, however, still leaves political room for two

    different forms of carbon tax which do not increase government revenue. The first is revenue-neutral

    tax swaps and the second is a carbon fee and dividend. A revenue-neutral tax swap starts from one of

    the few uncontroversial conclusions of economics, that it is better to tax bads than goods (Financial

    Times Editorial Board, 2013). Realizing that, the aim is to move taxes away from goods, such as income

    and payrolls, towards bads such as pollution. A revenue neutral carbon tax-swap does just that, thus

    promoting the goods and not the bads. Some might worry that such tax-swaps would

    disproportionately affect the poor. However, according to a study done by MIT, depending on how one

    structures such revenue-neutral tax swaps the carbon tax could actually be structured so as to reverse

    its potentially regressive nature and make it a progressive tax which helps the poor (Rausch & Reilly,

    2012- see table below). Thus a revenue-neutral tax swap could reduce the size of government, reduce

    other taxes and be progressive and assist the poor, while tackling climate change all good conservative

    goals. 13 As the Congressional Budget Office has pointed out, many analyses point to the projection that

    a tax swap could actually lead to a net increase in output, albeit a less carbon intensive increase in

    output (Congressional Budget Office, 2013, p. 11).

    13CTCorp = Corporate Tax Swap; CTPersin = Personal Marginal Income Tax Rate Swap; CTPayroll = Payroll Tax

    Swap; CTTranser = Carbon tax revenue used to increase transfer payments e.g. social security, Medicaid, etc.

    Source: Rausch and Reilly 2012

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    10/19

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    11/19

    flight from those countries. Indeed, the United Kingdom provides an important example of this, for

    through regionally focused climate policy they have reduced their regional emissions over the past

    decade. However, when it comes to looking at overall emissions, including those associated with the

    goods they consume, the UK has actually increased their emissions by 10% since 1993 by importing

    carbon intensive goods mostly from countries like China (House of Commons Committee on Energy and

    Climate Change, 2012). Indeed, about half the increase in Chinas CO2 emissions from 2002-2005 were

    linked to the export of goods to the US and EU (Wijkman & Rockstrom, 2012, p. 43). Thus, given that the

    US is already the largest importer of embedded emissions from China, it is argued that climate

    legislation would simply enhance that trend further. Such an objection, when levelled against EPA

    regulations or regional cap and trade, is a justifiable one, as such policies only focus on national

    emissions. However, this is where a carbon tax once again proves to be a more effective policy, as one

    of the carbon taxes complimentary policies, border taxing, can move us away from such limited regionalaction towards a more global and effective response to climate change, which protects the U.S.

    economy from competition from other countries that do not take on climate legislation. Allow me to

    explain.

    A border tax works by ensuring that products that are exported from the U.S. to countries that do not

    have a carbon price are granted carbon tax exemption, and are thus competitive in such countries.

    Goods that are imported into the United States are taxed according to their carbon content so that they

    do not have an unfair advantage in the U.S. over locally produced goods that were already subject to the

    carbon tax. Given that U.S. production is often more energy efficient than, for instance, Chinese

    production, a carbon tax with border taxing may actually help to promote U.S. products, and thus

    enhance US competitiveness. Further aiding the U.S. competitiveness, the revenue gained from the

    border taxes import tax could go to the U.S., which also provides major incentive to other countries to

    implement such a tax themselves in order to keep the revenue from such a tax, rather than see it go

    elsewhere. Thus, as Dieter Helm argues, a carbon tax coupled with border taxing is is a pragmatic

    mechanism for gradually translating bottom-up carbon taxes into an international agreement (2012, p.

    192) or for muscling countries like China and India into climate action, a task the U.S. has long claimed it

    hopes to achieve.

    Although border taxing is a complex process and it will be difficult to gain exact precision, it is both a

    possible and integral element to ensuring the integrity and efficacy of climate legislation, for otherwise

    we will continue to shoot ourselves in the feet by exporting production to dirtier parts of the wold

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    12/19

    through regionally limited legislation. In response some have argued that it would violate WTO

    regulation on fair competition. However, as world renowned WTO scholar Professor Joost Paulewyn

    shows, the WTO has exemptions for environmental considerations and border taxing should pass WTO

    scrutiny (Pauwelyn, 2012). Despite the fact that such a tax could pass WTO scrutiny my proposal would

    be that the revenue gained from the import taxes, and the import taxes alone, be directed towards a

    climate change fund such as the Green Climate Fund, otherwise such a proposal might be fought against

    on the grounds that it serves as a way for the US government to siphon off funds from the rest of the

    world. Even if my suggestion was put in place, a carbon tax coupled with border taxing still has the

    major benefits not only of protecting the U.S. from unfair competition and promoting broader

    international action on climate change, but also of reducing both carbon production and consumption,

    unlike the UKs policy did and the EPA would. Thus a carbon tax, unlike much other climate legislation,

    ensures that any climate gains are not rendered meaningless by carbon intensive imports. Thus for anyconservative concerned about free market fairness, the carbon tax once again proves to be truer to it

    than EPA regulations could be, thus putting paid to the misleading argument put forward by Jay

    Timmons, the National Association of Manufacturers (NAM) President and CEO16, which said that a

    carbon tax will severely harm the U.S. ability to compete with other nations. If anything, by attempting

    to block a carbon tax the NAM is ensuring that EPA regulations will emerge which will indeed hinder U.S.

    competitiveness and damage meaningful action to tackle climate change by focusing only on national

    emissions and not on the global picture as carbon taxing can.

    Morally Corrupt Opposition

    Bertrand Russell once wrote about the American

    revolutionary Thomas Paine, "He had faults, like

    other men; but it was for his virtues that he was

    hated and successfully calumniated. Likewise with

    a carbon tax, the fossil fuel industry seems to

    recognize the virtues of such legislation will mean a

    move away from their perverse privilege/subsidy of

    being able to pollute the atmosphere freely. Thus

    much of the industry is doing anything in their

    means in order to protect their perverse privilege,

    16Cf.http://www.nam.org/Communications/Articles/2013/02/A-Carbon-Tax-Would-Wallop-Our-Economy.aspx

    http://www.nam.org/Communications/Articles/2013/02/A-Carbon-Tax-Would-Wallop-Our-Economy.aspxhttp://www.nam.org/Communications/Articles/2013/02/A-Carbon-Tax-Would-Wallop-Our-Economy.aspxhttp://www.nam.org/Communications/Articles/2013/02/A-Carbon-Tax-Would-Wallop-Our-Economy.aspxhttp://www.nam.org/Communications/Articles/2013/02/A-Carbon-Tax-Would-Wallop-Our-Economy.aspx
  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    13/19

    including fabricating disinformation, spreading lies, creating/funding biased and/or flawed studies17 and

    investing millions in dishonest lobbying. Worst of all they are masking their attempts in the name of

    conservative principles, whereas their campaign is actually a perversion of good conservative principles

    (or pretty much any set of principles that isnt solely based on protecting the fossil fuel industry bottom-

    line). Thus Republicans in Congress who toe the industry line by opposing a carbon tax are rather

    hypocritically and arguably corruptly being untrue to conservative principles. Furthermore they are

    ignoring the core of democracy by ignoring the will of the people, for as Ryan Koronowski (2013)

    reports, according to polling, a revenue neutral carbon tax that would provide dividends back to

    taxpayers and invest in renewable energy received 70 percent support, and US voters favor a carbon tax

    over spending cuts by a 4-1 margin. 93 percent of Democrats favored a carbon tax, and 66 percent of

    Republicans did too. Thus according to my argument it seems that

    congressmen who oppose a carbon tax do not do so because they trulyrepresent their constituency or for principled reasons; they do so most

    likely because they are either misinformed or corrupt and beholden to a

    small high-paying portion of their constituency, the fossil fuel industry.

    Why the U.S.?

    The question that many might ask when faced with the prospect of a

    U.S. carbon tax is, Why America?. This is indeed a very important

    question, which has many answers. Firstly, implementing such a policy

    in the United States may be the most effective single policy to tackle

    climate change, given the that the U.S. is the biggest historical emitter

    of greenhouse gas emissions, and one of the biggest current net and per

    capita greenhouse gas emitters, and arguably the center of world

    consumption. Even though China currently produces the highest

    amount of greenhouse gasses, the US currently imports the highest

    amount of Chinese goods than anywhere else and if the imported

    carbon was included in the U.S. emission count it would probably make

    the U.S. the highest net greenhouse gas emitter in the world. Indeed,

    the American populace consumes 25 percent of the worlds energy

    17Cf. The Institute for Energy Researchs (Murphy, 2013), the NAMs (Lavoie, 2013), American Institute for

    Petroleums (Mufson, 2012) and American Legislative Exchange Councils Koch-funded Beacon Hill Institute study.

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    14/19

    despite representing just 5 percent of global population five times more than the average Chinese

    person and 160 times more than a Bangladeshi18 such that, if we take the projections of climate

    science seriously, the average American is responsible, through his or her greenhouse gas emissions,

    for the suffering and or deaths of one or two future people (Nolt, 2011). Furthermore, in order to feed

    the growing demand for energy the U.S. has been waging many inordinately expensive wars, both literal

    and metaphorical, on both the environment and humans across the globe.

    For those who think America is unfairly being targeted it is worth keeping in mind that other countries

    are already doing their bit and generally more than the US, as the table on the previous page shows.

    Furthermore even developing countries like China and South Africa are soon set to join the ranks of

    countries with a price on carbon, and even the worlds poorest countries are putting in place mitigation

    strategies to reduce their emissions (Cf. King, 2013). While many developed countries are meeting more

    ambitious climate targets, as the graph below from Bianco et al. (2013) shows, even if regulations under

    the EPA were expanded and

    states acted incredibly

    ambitiously on climate change,

    which they arguably wont, the

    States still wouldnt meet its

    international climate change

    goals, which are the lowest of all

    developed country goals and

    arguably much less than their

    fair share of world emission

    reductions.19 Similarly Burtraw et al. (2011) showed that new EPA regulations will at best reduce

    greenhouse gas emissions in 2020 by only 13%. Bianco et al. thus conclude that major climate legislation

    is needed in order to get us to those goals.

    Carbon tax legislation arguably can get us to meet U.S climate goals. According to John Millers analysis

    of EIA data, If the predictions that carbon taxes and reduced fossil fuels consumption will help expand

    the economy based on a substantial expansion of renewable energy supplies, energy efficiency

    technology improvements, and expanded green jobs is correct, then the $100/MT level of carbon taxes

    18(Biello, 2013),

    19Cf.http://climateactiontracker.org/countries/usa.html?utm_&&&

    http://climateactiontracker.org/countries/usa.html?utm_&&&http://climateactiontracker.org/countries/usa.html?utm_&&&http://climateactiontracker.org/countries/usa.html?utm_&&&http://climateactiontracker.org/countries/usa.html?utm_&&&
  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    15/19

    energy policy should effectively achieve most of its claimed goals (2013). Furthermore analysis from

    Charlie Komanoff of the Carbon Tax Center study show that H.R. 1337 Americas Energy Security

    Trust Fund Act of 2009 which puts a steadily increasing price on carbon dioxide emissions, could

    achieve Americas target ofan 80% reduction in CO2 emissions by 2050 (Robertson, 2010, p. 20). Even

    more than that what is important to remember is that these numbers focus only on carbon emissions

    from production in the U.S. and not carbon consumption from imports, which would also be reduced

    through the use of border taxing, thus carbon taxing would make even greater reductions on

    greenhouse gas emissions.

    Furthermore, the question, Why America? is a question that sees a carbon tax as a burden, and while it may

    indeed be a short-term burden through rising prices on carbon-intensive goods and practices, as I have

    hopefully shown throughout this paper it is arguably less of a burden than alternative policies such as EPA

    regulation, which will be put in place if a carbon tax is not. Furthermore, in the long run it will be a policy

    which will have great benefits for us and our children that outweigh the short-term burdens. Given that we

    are often so willing to make sacrifices for our children and the future, this is arguably one of the short-term

    sacrifices we need to make, and arguably easily more justifiable than the sacrifices imposed upon the U.S.

    populace through the sequester.

    In the face of wartime the American populace was willing to work together to make sacrifices to shift the

    economy, and the moral imperative in the climate case is arguably even stronger, as climate change could

    halt and substantially reverse global progress on poverty reduction, and cause innumerable conflicts,

    suffering and environmental degradation among many other negative effects.20

    As was the case when the

    U.S. ended slavery, it realized that even though slavery made certain activities profitable, those profits were

    not worth the exploitation involved. Similarly with regards to reigning in industrys ability to freely pollute the

    atmosphere, while certain industries remain profitable because of the perverse privilege/subsidy of foisting

    their costs onto society at large, it is time we realized that such exploitation is unacceptable. Doing so is

    moral and societal progress that has no political color to it. Whether you are a Republican, a Democrat, an

    Independent, a plain American, or a citizen of the world, ensuring that we have a liveable world with a

    thriving society and economy is a goal I like to think that we all share, rather than ensuring (through our

    obstinacy) that a massive relatively inefficient EPA regulative apparatus is put in place instead. Nonetheless,

    in asking the U.S. to make the smaller relative sacrifice of a carbon tax for the greater good, it is important to

    put that sacrifice into perspective, so I end with a quote from Carl Safina (N.d.):

    20http://hdr.undp.org/en/mediacentre/humandevelopmentreportpresskits/2013report/

    http://hdr.undp.org/en/mediacentre/humandevelopmentreportpresskits/2013report/http://hdr.undp.org/en/mediacentre/humandevelopmentreportpresskits/2013report/http://hdr.undp.org/en/mediacentre/humandevelopmentreportpresskits/2013report/http://hdr.undp.org/en/mediacentre/humandevelopmentreportpresskits/2013report/
  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    16/19

    Of all the psychopathology in the climate issue, the most counterproductive thought is that solving the

    problem will require sacrifice. As though our wastefulness of energy and money is not sacrifice. As

    though war built around oil is not sacrifice. As though losing polar bears, ice-dependent penguins, coral

    reefs, and thousands of other living companions is not sacrifice. As though withered cropland is not a

    sacrifice, or letting the fresh water of cities dry up as glacier-fed rivers shrink. As though risking seawater

    inundation and the displacement of hundreds of millions of coastal people is not a sacrificeand reckless

    risk. But dont tell me to own a more efficient car; that would be a sacrifice! We think we dont want to

    sacrifice, but sacrifice is exactly what were doing by perpetuating problems that only get worse; were

    sacrificing our money, and sacrificing what is big and permanent, to prolong what is small, temporary,

    and harmful. Were sacrificing animals, peace, and children to retain wastefulness while enriching those

    who disdain us. When we stop seeing our relationship with the whole living world as a matter of

    sustainability, and realize it is a matter of moralityof right and wrongwe might make the momentwe need.

    Bibliography:

    Andrew, B. (2008). Market Failure , Government Failure And Externalities In Climate Change Mitigation : The Case

    For A Carbon Tax. Public Administration and Development, 28, 393401. doi:10.1002/pad

    Bianco, N. M., Litz, F. T., Meek, K. I., & Gasper, R. (2013). Can The U.S. Get There From Here?Washington DC.

    Retrieved from http://pdf.wri.org/can_us_get_there_from_here_summary.pdf

    Burtraw, D., Fraas, A. G., & Richardson, N. (2011). Greenhouse Gas Regulation under the Clean Air Act: A Guide for

    Economists. Washington DC.

    Burtraw, D., Sweeney, R., & Walls, M. (2009). The Incidence of U.S. Climate Policy: Alternative Uses of Revenues

    from a Cap-and-Trade Auction. Washington DC. Retrieved from http://www.rff.org/RFF/Documents/RFF-DP-

    09-

    Chait, J. (2013, May). Obama Might Actually Be the Environmental President. New York Magazine. Retrieved from

    http://nymag.com/news/features/obama-climate-change-2013-5/

    Congressional Budget Office. (2013). Effects of a Carbon Tax on the Economy and the Environment. Washington DC.

    Retrieved from http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/44223_Carbon_0.pdf

    Conway, E. M., & Oreskes, N. (2010). Merchants of Doubt. New York: Bloomsbury Press.

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    17/19

    Dahl, C. (2004). International Energy Markets: Understanding Pricing, Policies, and Profits. PennWell Books.

    Financial Times Editorial Board. (2013, March 15). A least-worst tax. Financial Times. Retrieved from

    http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/699c1f18-8d79-11e2-a0fd-00144feabdc0.html#axzz2O6DXhRdK

    Gilding, P. (2013). Victory at Hand for the Climate Movement? Renew Economy. Retrieved March 19, 2013, from

    http://reneweconomy.com.au/2013/victory-at-hand-for-the-climate-movement-99405

    Handley, J. (2013). Sanders-Boxer Set Gold Standard But Write Off Fiscal Potential of Carbon Tax. Carbon Tax

    Center. Retrieved February 15, 2012, from http://www.carbontax.org/blogarchives/2013/02/15/sanders-

    boxer-set-gold-standard-but-write-off-fiscal-potential-of-carbon-tax/

    Hansen, E., Collins, A., Hendryx, M., Boettner, F., & Hereford, A. (2008). The Long-Term Economic Benefits of Wind

    Versus Mountaintop Removal of Coal on Coal River Mountain, West Virgina. Morgantown, WV. Retrieved

    from http://www.downstreamstrategies.com/Documents/reports_publication/Wind_vs_mountain

    Helm, D. (2012). Carbon Crunch: How were getting climate change wrong -- and how to fix it. Cumberland: Yale

    University Press. Retrieved from http://site.ebrary.com/lib/kansas/Doc?id=10607291&ppg=24

    Hind, D. (2012). Economics after scarcity.Aljazeera Online. Retrieved May 16, 2012, from

    http://www.aljazeera.com/indepth/opinion/2012/05/201251465149622626.html

    House of Commons Committee on Energy and Climate Change. (2012). Consumption-Based Emissions Reporting.

    London. Retrieved from

    http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201012/cmselect/cmenergy/1646/1646.pdf

    Hsu, S.-L. (2011). The Case for a Carbon Tax. Washington DC: Island Press.

    Huber, M. T. (2009). Energizing historical materialism: Fossil fuels, space and the capitalist mode of production.

    Geoforum, 40(1), 105115. doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2008.08.004

    IGM Experts Panel. (2011). Carbon Tax. IGM Forum. Retrieved March 20, 2013, from

    http://www.igmchicago.org/igm-economic-experts-panel/poll-results?SurveyID=SV_9Rezb430SESUA4Y

    International Monetary Fund. (2013). ENERGY SUBSIDY REFORM : LESSONS AND IMPLICATIONS. Washington DC.

    Retrieved from http://www.eenews.net/assets/2013/03/27/document_pm_05.pdf

    IPCC. (2013). Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Report Database. IPCC. Retrieved March 22, 2013, from

    http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.shtml#.UU0dbxyG2Sqhttp://ww

    w.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_and_data_reports.shtml#.UU0dbxyG2Sq

    King, E. (2013). Worlds poorest nations plan to take lead at climate talks. Responding to Climate Change.

    Retrieved March 27, 2013, from http://www.rtcc.org/worlds-poorest-nations-plan-to-take-lead-at-climate-talks/

    Koronowski, R. (2013). A Price Is Right: Carbon Tax Has Very Broad, Bipartisan Support (Outside Of Congress).

    Climate Progress. Retrieved May 9, 2013, from http://thinkprogress.org/climate/2013/05/08/1702861/a-

    price-is-right-carbon-tax-has-very-broad-bipartisan-support-outside-of-congress/

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    18/19

    Lavoie, M. (2013). A Carbon Tax Would Wallop Our Economy. National Association of Manufacturers Website.

    Retrieved March 19, 2013, from http://www.nam.org/Communications/Articles/2013/02/A-Carbon-Tax-

    Would-Wallop-Our-Economy.aspx

    Lenferna, G. A. (2011). A Skeptics Approach to Climate Change.Adopt-a-Negotiator.org. Retrieved November 18,

    2011, from http://adoptanegotiator.org/2011/11/18/a-skeptics-approach-to-climate-activism/

    Mai, T., Sandor, D., Wiser, R., & Schneider, T. (2012). Renewable Electricity Futures Study: Executive Summary.

    Golden, CO. Retrieved from http://www.nrel.gov/docs/fy13osti/52409-ES.pdf

    McIlmoil, R., Hansen, E., Boettner, T., & Miller, P. (2010). Coal and Renewables in Central Appalachia: The Impact of

    Coal on the West Virginia State Budget. Retrieved from

    http://www.downstreamstrategies.com/Documents/reports_publication/DownstreamStrateg

    Miller, J. (2013). Should the U.S. Implement a Carbon Tax? The Energy Collective. Retrieved April 29, 2013, from

    http://theenergycollective.com/jemillerep/218116/should-us-implement-carbon-tax

    Mufson, S. (2012, November 12). With fiscal cliff looming, carbon tax getting closer look. The Washington Post.

    Retrieved from http://www.washingtonpost.com/business/economy/with-fiscal-cliff-looming-carbon-tax-getting-closer-look/2012/11/09/23ab935a-2aad-11e2-96b6-8e6a7524553f_story_1.html

    Murphy, P. R. (2013). Carbon Tax Swaps: A Critique and Review. Retrieved from

    http://www.instituteforenergyresearch.org/wp-content/uploads/2012/11/IER-Murphy-Carbon-Tax-Swap-

    Deals-A-Review-and-Critique.pdf

    Nolt, J. (2011). How harmful are the average Americans greenhouse gas emissions? Ethics, Policy and

    Environment, 14, 310. Retrieved from

    http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/21550085.2011.561584

    Obama, B. (2013). State of the Union Address. Washington DC. Retrieved from http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-

    press-office/2013/02/12/president-barack-obamas-state-union-address

    Paton, J. (2013, February 6). Australian Wind Energy Now Cheaper Than Coal, Gas, BNEF Says. Bloomberg News.

    New York. Retrieved from http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2013-02-06/australia-wind-energy-cheaper-

    than-coal-natural-gas-bnef-says.html

    Pauwelyn, J. (2012). Carbon Leakage Measures and Border Tax Adjustments under WTO Law. In D. Prevost & G.

    Van Calster (Eds.), Research Handbook on Environment, Health and the WTO (pp. 152). Edward Elgar.

    Retrieved from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2026879

    Petersen, L. C., & Conners, N. (2007). The 11th Hour. Warner Independent Pictures.

    Pew Charitable Trusts. (2009). The Clean Energy Economy: Repowering Jobs, Businesses and Investments AcrossAmerica. Washington DC. Retrieved from

    http://www.pewenvironment.org/uploadedFiles/PEG/Publications/Report/Clean Energy Economy.pdf

    Pollin, R., Heintz, J., & Garrett-Peltier, H. (2009). The Economic Benefits of Investing in Clean Energy: How the

    economic stimulus program and new legislation can boost U.S. economic growth and employment. Amherst.

    Retrieved from http://www.americanprogress.org/wp-

    content/uploads/issues/2009/06/pdf/peri_report_execsumm.pdf

  • 7/30/2019 A Conservative Case for a Carbon Tax in the United States of America

    19/19

    Rausch, S., & Reilly, J. (2012). Carbon Tax Revenue and the Budget Deficit : A Win-Win-Win Solution ?, (228).

    Robertson, J. (2010). Building a Green Economy: The Economics of Carbon Pricing & the Transition to Clean,

    Renewable Fuels. Retrieved from www.citizensclimatelobby.org

    Ryan, R. (2013, February 21). Want EPA or Free Market to Tackle Carbon? Wichita Eagle. Wichita, KS. Retrieved

    from http://www.kansas.com/2013/02/21/2684003/rebecca-ryan-want-epa-or-free.html#storylink=cpy

    Safina, C. (n.d.). The Moral Climate. Orion Magazine. Retrieved March 20, 2013, from

    http://www.orionmagazine.org/index.php/articles/article/3260/

    Shaw, C. (2013). Is it time to abandon the 2 degree warming target? Responding to Climate Change. Retrieved May

    10, 2013, from http://www.rtcc.org/is-it-time-to-abandon-the-2-degree-warming-target/

    Singer, P. (1972). Famine, Affluence and Morality. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 1(3), 229243.

    Spross, J. (2013). Solar Jobs Beat Out Ranchers In Texas, Actors In California, And Coal Miners Nationally. Climate

    Progress. Retrieved April 28, 2013, from http://thinkprogress.org/climate/2013/04/28/1911091/solar-jobs-

    beat-out-ranchers-in-texas-actors-in-california-and-coal-miners-nationally/

    The Climate Institute. (2013). Global Climate Leadership Review. Sydney. Retrieved from

    http://www.climateinstitute.org.au/verve/_resources/TCI_GlobalClimateLeadershipReview2013.pdf

    U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (2013). Glossary of Climate Change Terms. EPA Website. Retrieved March

    22, 2013, from http://www.epa.gov/climatechange/glossary.html#C

    Washington Post Editorial Board. (2013, March 2). Breaking the logjam. Washington Post. Washington DC.

    Retrieved from http://articles.washingtonpost.com/2013-03-02/opinions/37387576_1_carbon-tax-carbon-

    emissions-corporate-tax-rate

    Wijkman, A., & Rockstrom, J. (2012). Bankrupting Nature: Denying Our Planetary Boundaries (2nd ed.). Oxon:

    Routledge.