Top Banner
A Brief History of Game Theory From various sources
21

A Brief History of Game Theory

Feb 24, 2016

Download

Documents

Fritz

A Brief History of Game Theory. From various sources. The first known solution to such a two-person zero-sum game is contained in a letter dated 13 November 1713 from James Waldegrave to Pierre- Remond de Montmort concerning a two player version of the card game le Her. . De Montmort - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: A Brief History of Game Theory

A Brief History of Game Theory

From various sources

Page 2: A Brief History of Game Theory

The first known solution to such a two-person zero-sum game is contained ina letter dated 13 November 1713 from James Waldegrave to Pierre-Remond deMontmort concerning a two player version of the card game le Her.

Page 3: A Brief History of Game Theory

De Montmortwrote to the mathematician Nicolas Bernoulli (perhaps best known, at least amongeconomists, for his formulation of the St. Petersburg Paradox).

Page 4: A Brief History of Game Theory

The great French mathematician and probabilist, Emile Borel published fournotes on strategic games between 1921 and 1927.

Page 5: A Brief History of Game Theory

Borel gave the first formal definition of what we shall call a mixed strategy and demonstrated the existence of the minimax solution to two player zero-sum games with either three or five possiblestrategies. He initially conjectured that games with more strategies would not have such a solution but, being unable to find a counter example, he later considered that to be an open question.

Page 6: A Brief History of Game Theory

That question was answered by the Hungarian (and later American) mathematician John von Neumann in 1928.

Page 7: A Brief History of Game Theory

Wikipedia describes von Neumann as having “made major contributions to a vast range of fields, including set theory, functional analysis, quantum mechanics, ergodic theory, continuous geometry, economics and game theory, computer science, numerical analysis, hydrodynamics (of explosions), and statistics, as well as many other mathematical fields.”

Page 8: A Brief History of Game Theory

In 1913 the German mathematician Ernst Zermelo, most famous for his axiomatisation of set theory, gave a statement concerning a result about what we would now call extensive form games. In a game like chess either white can guarantee that he wins or black can guarantee that he wins or both players can guarantee at least a draw.

Page 9: A Brief History of Game Theory

There were a number of substantial advances in the book by von Neumann and Morgenstern: the axiomatic development of the theory of expected utility; the formal definition of normal form games and extensive form games; the elaboration of the minmax theorem for two-person zero sum games; and the definition of whatare now called cooperative or coalitional games.

Page 10: A Brief History of Game Theory

In the early 1950s John Nash [1950,1951] proposed a definition of equilibrium, that we now call the Nash equilibrium, that has become the central solution concept for noncooperative game theory.

Page 11: A Brief History of Game Theory

Nash as an older man, after he won the Nobel Prize in Economics.

Page 12: A Brief History of Game Theory

That’s not Nash. That’s Russel Crowe in one of his best performances in a film about Nash’s life.

Page 13: A Brief History of Game Theory

1994 Nobel Prize in Economics was award to John Nash, John C. Harsanyi and Reinhard Selten "for their pioneering analysis of equilibria in the theory of non-cooperative games".

Page 14: A Brief History of Game Theory

In two papers, Extensive Games (1950) and Extensive Games and the Problem of Information (1953), H. W. Kuhn included the formulation of extensive form games which is currently used, and also some basic theorems pertaining to this class of games.

Page 15: A Brief History of Game Theory

Lloyd Shapley in his paper A Value for N-Person Games characterised, by a set of axioms, a solution concept that associates with each coalitional game,v, a unique out-come, v. This solution in now known as the Shapley Value.

Page 16: A Brief History of Game Theory

In the same year, 1953, Shapley published a paper on “Stochastic Games,” introducing a new and important model of games.

Page 17: A Brief History of Game Theory

In 2012, Shapley won the Nobel Prize in Economics with Al Roth "for the theory of stable allocations and the practice of market design".

Page 18: A Brief History of Game Theory

Robert J. Aumann's greatest contribution was in the realm of repeated games, which are situations in which players encounter the same situation over and over again.

Page 19: A Brief History of Game Theory

Aumann was the first to define the concept of correlated equilibrium in game theory, which is a type of equilibrium in non-cooperative games that is more flexible than the classical Nash equilibrium. Furthermore, Aumann has introduced the first purely formal account of the notion of common knowledge in game theory. He collaborated with Lloyd Shapley on the Aumann-Shapley value. He is also known for his agreement theorem, in which he argues that under his given conditions, two Bayesian rationalists with common prior beliefs cannot agree to disagree.

Page 20: A Brief History of Game Theory

In 2005 Aumann won the Nobel Prize in Economics with Thomas C. Schelling "for having enhanced our understanding of conflict and cooperation through game-theory analysis".

Page 21: A Brief History of Game Theory