Top Banner

of 36

38-Uncertainity and Governance

Apr 09, 2018

Download

Documents

Girmay Abrham
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    1/36

    1

    Ref # 124140

    Governance Under Uncertainty:

    Transactions Costs, Real Options, Learning, and Property Rights

    Jay B. Barney&

    Woonghee Lee

    Fisher College of BusinessThe Ohio State University

    310 Hagerty Hall1775 College Rd.

    Columbus, OH 43210-1399Tel: 614-688-3161Fax: 614-292-3172

    Email (Jay Barney): [email protected] (Woonghee Lee): [email protected]

    Submission to:

    Business Policy and Strategy Division

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    2/36

    2

    ABSTRACT (50 words)

    Governance Under Uncertainty:Transactions Costs, Real Options, Learning, and Property Rights

    Transactions Cost explanations of governance emphasize opportunism. RealOptions explanations emphasize flexibility. These objectives should beaugmented by recognizing the impact that learning and securing the right to investin an opportunity have on governance. Together, these four objectives can beused to explain a diverse set of governance phenomena.

    Key Words; Real Option; Transaction Cost; Learning

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    3/36

    1

    Consider the following decision situation. 1 A bio-technology firm has developed a

    product prototype. While this prototype has shown some potential for treating certain physical

    conditions, it has yet to receive regulatory approval for commercial development. To receive this

    approval, it must first be tested in clinical trials. These clinical trials and subsequent government

    evaluations can last from 10 to 12 years. Thus, this firm will not know, with any degree of

    certainty, whether or not its product prototype is economically viable for at least 10 to 12 years.

    Despite this uncertainty, this firm must make some critical decisions about how to

    manufacture this product. First, it needs to decide how it will obtain sufficient quantities of this

    product for clinical trials, and second, it needs to decide how it will obtain sufficient quantities

    for the commercialization of this product, if in fact it turns out to be economically viable. This

    manufacturing decision is complicated by the fact that manufacturing this type of product is very

    complex. It usually takes a firm several years to develop the equipment, procedures, and skills it

    needs to reliably manufacture this type of product. However, it is generally the case that much of

    the equipment and many of the procedures and skills needed to manufacture this type of product

    in quantities sufficient for clinical trials are at least partly transferable to the manufacture of this

    type of product in quantities sufficient for commercialization.

    This bio-technology firm has at least four options in thinking about how to manufacture

    its product prototype first for clinical trials and then for possible commercialization. First, it

    could vertically integrate into manufacturing for both clinical trials and commercial production.

    Second, it could out-source the manufacture of its product prototype for clinical trials, and then

    1 The decision situation described here is not uncommon among bio-technology firms. A more detailed version of this situation is described by Pisano (1990).

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    4/36

    2

    vertically integrate into manufacturing for commercial production. 2 Third, it could vertically

    integrate into manufacturing for clinical trials, and then outsource manufacturing for commercial

    production. Finally, it could outsource manufacturing both for clinical trials and commercial

    production. Of course, deciding among all these options is complicated because at least some of

    these choices must be made before clinical trials can begin, at least 10 to 12 years before the

    economic viability of this product can be known.

    In one sense, the manufacturing options facing this bio-technology firm are classic

    vertical integration governance decisions. And there is, in the field of organizational economics,

    a well known, and often applied, theoretical model for helping firms make these kinds of

    transaction governance decisions: transactions cost economics (Williamson, 1975, 1985).

    However, the decision facing this bio-technology firm is complicated by two factors that are not

    generally included in transactions cost economics models of governance to the same degree as

    they exist in this situation. First, these governance choices are sequentially linked; because it

    takes years to develop the capability to manufacture this type of product, and because at least

    some of this learning is partly transferable from manufacturing for clinical trials to

    manufacturing for commercialization, decisions this firm makes about manufacturing its product

    for commercialization are linked to decisions it makes about manufacturing for clinical trials.

    Second, these governance choices are made under conditions of very high uncertainty. While

    transactions cost economics recognizes the impact that uncertainty about sources of opportunism

    in a transaction can have on governance choices (Williamson, 1975, 1985), this bio-technology

    2 Outsourcing of manufacturing could take several forms, including licensing arrangements, contract manufacturing,or even forming a joint venture with another firm to manufacture the product.

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    5/36

    3

    firm faces significant uncertainty not only about sources of opportunism, but also significant

    uncertainty about whether or not this entire investment opportunity will be economically viable.

    The purpose of this paper is to develop a theoretical model for guiding decisions about

    governance under these conditions, i.e., where different governance decisions are at least

    partially linked sequentially, and where very high levels of uncertainty about the future of a

    transaction exist. This model draws on several inter-related literatures, including transactions

    cost economics (Williamson, 1975, 1985), real options theory (Myers, 1977; Bowman and Hurry,

    1993), theories of organizational learning (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Hamel, 1990), and

    property rights economics (Grossman and Hart, 1986; Hart and Moore, 1990). Not only does this

    model provide practical guidance for firms making governance choices under these conditions, it

    also adds a necessary building block in the development of a more complete theory of

    governance in the field of organizational economics (Barney and Hesterly, 1996).

    The paper begins by reviewing transactions cost economics under conditions of high

    uncertainty. Inconclusive and contradictory empirical findings in this area of work suggest that

    other theoretical perspectives may also be important. These other perspectives, including real

    options theory, learning, and property rights theory, are then discussed and integrated with the

    transactions cost perspective to develop a more complete model of governance choices under

    uncertainty. Some of the empirical implications of this model are then discussed.

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    6/36

    4

    Transactions Cost Under Conditions of High Uncertainty

    Uncertainty about sources of opportunism in economic transactions is an important

    variable in transactions cost models of governance. When there is no uncertainty about the

    sources of opportunism in a transaction, parties to that transaction will be able to rely on

    relatively simple market contracts to manage their exchange. However, as uncertainty about

    sources of opportunism increases, it may be necessary for parties to a transaction to adopt more

    complicated forms of governance, including intermediate forms of governance like strategic

    alliances and joint ventures. In these more hierarchical forms of governance, sources of

    opportunism in a transaction can be discovered over time, and appropriate protections and

    remedies can be developed. Under conditions of even higher uncertainty about the sources of

    opportunism in an exchange, it may be necessary to adopt hierarchical forms of governance. In

    general, high levels of ex ante uncertainty about sources of opportunism in a transaction can lead

    to high levels of ex post opportunism. Increased levels of threat due to ex post opportunism, in

    turn, leads to the adoption of progressively more hierarchical forms of governance (Williamson,

    1975, 1985).

    A straightforward transactions cost analysis of the governance options facing the bio-

    technology firm discussed at the beginning of this paper suggests that this firm should vertically

    integrate in manufacturing both for clinical trials and commercial production. Only through

    vertical integration would this firm be able to protect itself from the threat of opportunism that

    attends this highly uncertain set of transactions. For example, outsourcing manufacturing, either

    for clinical trials or commercial production, may force this firm to reveal proprietary information

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    7/36

    5

    about its prototype product, its underlying bio-chemistry, and its ultimate commercial

    applications. This information could then have been appropriated by this firms manufacturing

    partner for its own purposes. Vertically integrating into manufacturing effectively eliminates

    these opportunistic threats.

    Of course, this general hypothesis about uncertainty and governance has not gone

    untested. Unfortunately, empirical efforts to examine this hypothesis have generated decidedly

    mixed results. Some authors report results that are consistent with transactions cost expectations

    (e.g., Helfat and Teece, 1987; Anderson and Schmittlein, 1984; John and Weitz, 1988; Masten,

    1984), where transactions characterized by high uncertainty are managed through more

    hierarchical forms of governance and transactions characterized by low uncertainty are managed

    through less hierarchical forms of governance. Other authors report mixed results (Walker and

    Weber, 1984, 1987; Masten, Meehan, and Snyder, 1991) (where different kinds of uncertainty

    have different effects on governance choices, or the effects are not linear), and still others report

    exactly the opposite relationship between uncertainty and governance than what is predicted by

    transactions cost logic (Harrigan, 1986). For example, Walker and Weber (1987) show that

    certain types of transaction uncertainty actually leads firms to adopt less hierarchical forms of

    governance rather than more hierarchical forms of governance. In a similar vein, Balakrishnan

    and Werenerfelt (1986) and Kogut (1991) show that the desire to maintain flexibility can lead

    firms to adopt less hierarchical forms of governance under conditions of high uncertainty, a result

    that directly contradicts transactions cost predictions.

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    8/36

    6

    Real Options Theories of Governance

    The mixed empirical results of tests of transactions cost explanations of the impact of

    uncertainty on governance choices have lead some authors to begin to examine alternative

    theories of this relationship. The most popular of these alternative explanations has come to be

    known as real options theory (Myers, 1977; Bowman and Hurry, 1993; Kogut, 1991; Chi and

    McGuire, 1996; Folta and Leiblein, 1994). Originally developed as a response to the inability of

    traditional net present value methods of valuing an investment to include the option value of that

    investment (Myers, 1977), real options theory has more recently been applied as a way to explain

    the impact of uncertainty on governance choices.

    Real options theories of governance under uncertainty generate predictions that are

    precisely the opposite of transactions cost predictions of governance under uncertainty. Real

    options logic suggests that the critical objective of firms making governance choices under

    conditions of uncertainty is the maintenance of their flexibility. Only by maintaining flexibility

    will it be possible for firms to make appropriate decisions in the future, should the uncertainty

    facing that firm be resolved one way or another. The maintenance of flexibility under

    conditions of high uncertainty becomes a governance issue because some forms of governance

    are less flexible than others. In particular, it is generally assumed that it is more costly for firms

    to alter hierarchical forms of governance in response to the change of the level of uncertainty in

    an exchange than it is to alter less hierarchical forms of governance (Kogut, 1991). Altering

    hierarchical forms of governance involves changing numerous explicit and implicit contracts that

    constitute this form of governance (Mahoney, 1992). Changing less hierarchical forms of

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    9/36

    7

    governance usually involves altering a smaller number of usually explicit contracts. This

    reasoning suggests that, under conditions of very high uncertainty in an exchange, firms will

    adopt less hierarchical forms of governance instead of more hierarchical forms of governance.

    This real options theory of governance under uncertainty also can be applied to the bio-

    technology firm described at the beginning of the paper. An application of this logic suggests

    that this firm should out source both its clinical and commercial manufacturing operations. This

    is the case since the level of uncertainty about the economic viability of this product prototype is

    so high. Outsourcing maximizes the flexibility of this firm as it goes forward. If it turns out that

    this product prototype is not economically viable, then this firm will not have invested heavily in

    manufacturing capabilities that turn out to not have been valuable. If it turns out that this product

    prototype is economically viable, and that the best way to manufacture this product is in-house,

    then this firm can shift from outsourcing its manufacturing to in-house manufacturing. It will

    still have to develop the manufacturing capabilities it needs to accomplish this in-house

    manufacturing, and this will still take some time. However, this capability development can now

    occur in a setting where the firm knows, with a high degree of certainty, that it will pay off.

    Just like transactions cost theories of governance under conditions of high uncertainty,

    real options theories of governance under these conditions have also been subject to empirical

    test. Some of this empirical work is consistent with real options: under conditions of high

    uncertainty, firms opt for less hierarchical rather than more hierarchical forms of governance

    (Balakrishnan and Wernerfelt, 1986; Kogut, 1991; Hurry, Miller, and Bowman, 1992).

    However, recall that some of the empirical work testing transactions cost predictions about

    uncertainty and governance were consistent with transactions cost logic: under conditions of

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    10/36

    8

    high uncertainty, firms opt for more hierarchical rather than less hierarchical forms of

    governance (e.g., Helfat and Teece, 1987; Anderson and Schmittlein, 1984; John and Weitz,

    1988; Masten, 1984). Results that are consistent with transactions cost expectations about the

    relationship between uncertainty and governance contradict real options expectations about the

    relationship between uncertainty and governance.

    Limitations of Transactions Cost and Real Options Theories of Governance Under

    Uncertainty

    Taken as a whole, the empirical literature on the relationship between uncertainty and

    governance suggests that it would be inappropriate to conclude that either transactions cost

    explanations of governance under uncertainty or real options explanations of governance under

    uncertainty have received consistent empirical support. Given this state of contradictory

    empirical findings, it seems that additional theoretical refinements are required before definitive

    predictions can be made. In particular, we argue that both transactions cost and real options

    arguments adopt overly simplistic characterizations of the objectives of firms in making

    governance decisions under conditions of uncertainty. Only by recognizing the full range of

    these objectives, and how they interact with each other, will it be possible to make definitive

    predictions about governance under uncertainty.

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    11/36

    9

    Opportunism and Flexibility

    Transactions cost economics has long been criticized for its single minded focus on

    making governance choices that minimize the threat of opportunism (Ghoshal and Moran, 1996;

    Hill, 1990). The mixed empirical findings in the study of governance under uncertainty suggests

    that while minimizing the threat of opportunism may be one of the objectives of firms making

    governance choices under uncertainty face, it may not be the only such objective. Indeed, real

    options theory suggests that at least one more objective for firms in these settings: maximizing

    flexibility.

    However, real options theory seemingly replaces a single minded focus on making

    governance choices that minimize the threat of opportunism with a single minded focus on

    making governance choices that maximize flexibility. It is almost as if real options theorists

    believe that opportunism threats do not exist under conditions of very high uncertainty, and that

    all firm efforts should focus on maximizing flexibility. It may well be that a single minded focus

    on maximizing flexibility in making governance choices under conditions of high uncertainty is

    just as naive as a single minded focus on minimizing the threat of opportunism in making these

    choices.

    Indeed, it has been suggested by some authors (Folta and Leiblen, 1994) that both these

    objectives are simultaneously important in making governance decisions under uncertainty, and

    that the task firms face is understanding which of these objectives should take precedence and

    when. In an empirical test of this assertion, Folta and Leiblen (1994) generated results that

    suggest that, under conditions of low and moderate uncertainty, opportunism minimization is the

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    12/36

    10

    primary determinant of governance form. Thus, following transactions cost logic, in conditions

    of low uncertainty, firms adopt less hierarchical forms of governance; under conditions of

    moderate uncertainty, they adopt more hierarchical forms of governance. Folta and Leiblein

    (1994) also found that under conditions of high uncertainty, flexibility maximizing becomes

    more important than opportunism minimizing, and thus firms adopt less hierarchical forms of

    governance, in a way consistent with real options logic. Later in this paper, we extend this logic

    to describe other conditions under which opportunism minimizing and flexibility maximizing

    will each be emphasized by a firm in making its governance choices under conditions of

    uncertainty.

    Learning and Governance

    However, even recognizing that both opportunism minimizing and flexibility maximizing

    are important in making governance choices under conditions of uncertainty still understates the

    complexity of this decision. For example, both of these simple objectives fail to recognize the

    sequential nature of some of these governance decisions, a sequential nature that implies lessons

    learned from governance decisions made early on can have significant implications for

    governance decisions made later. Thus, not only must governance under uncertainty take into

    consideration minimizing the threat of opportunism and maximizing firm flexibility, it must also

    take into account the impact that governance choices have on the ability of a firm to learn about

    the value of its investments in a highly uncertain world.

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    13/36

    11

    Of course, more sophisticated versions of real options theory have long recognized the

    importance of sequential investments, and the role that learning plays in making these

    investments over time (Bowman and Hurry, 1993; Sharp, 1991). Indeed, in his seminal work on

    a real options theory of governance, Kogut (1991) argued that under conditions of high

    uncertainty, firms should adopt intermediate forms of governance (e.g., joint ventures) because

    they simultaneously allow a firm to remain flexible and to learn about the value of their uncertain

    investments. How governance options besides joint ventures affect learning, and the conditions

    under which more or less hierarchical forms of governance will be adopted to facilitate learning,

    in connection with minimizing the threat of opportunism and maximizing flexibility, are

    discussed below.

    Securing Property Rights and Governance

    Finally, even if governance decisions under uncertainty take into consideration the threat

    of opportunism, flexibility, and learning, still another important consideration presents itself:

    securing the property right to make an investment once uncertainty about the value of that

    investment is resolved. For example, suppose a firm adopts a governance mechanism that

    minimizes the threat of opportunism and maximizes flexibility, and through the use of that

    mechanism learns that a particular investment opportunity is economically valuable. All this

    effort has no positive economic benefit for this firm unless it is able to use the information it has

    learned through its governance device to invest in this opportunity. Under some conditions, it

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    14/36

    12

    may be necessary for firms to use a governance device to secure their property rights to make an

    investment, once the value of that investment is learned.

    Again, Kogut (1991) emphasized the ability of joint ventures to partially secure a firms

    property right to invest into a particular market or industry, once the value of that investment

    becomes known. As was the case with learning, below we extend Koguts (1991) analysis by

    examining the impact of more and less hierarchical forms of governance on the ability of firms to

    secure property rights to invest in an opportunity, and discuss the conditions under which these

    different forms of governance will need to be implemented to secure these property rights.

    Types of Learning, Property Rights, and Governance

    In the discussion that follows, it is important to recognize the existence of two types of

    learning in an economic exchange: exogenous learning and endogenous learning. Exogenous

    learning is learning about the value of an uncertain investment from sources that are external to

    the governance mechanisms that are put in place to manage that investment. For example, for

    the bio-technology firm described earlier in this paper, exogenous learning could occur if the

    value of its prototype product could be estimated based on changes in government policy (e.g.,

    the government announces that all biological compounds with the attributes of this prototype will

    never receive permission for commercialization) or on the basis of research published in

    academic journals (e.g., a published study demonstrates that a very similar compound has shown

    commercial potential in a commercial application). Note that the information that enables this

    firm to value its uncertain investment does not, in any sense, pass through whatever

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    15/36

    13

    governance devices it has put in place to manage manufacturing or any other transaction. In this

    sense, the nature of the governance device put in place to manage a highly uncertain investment

    has no impact on exogenous learning.

    Endogenous learning, on the other hand, is learning about the value of an uncertain

    investment through the governance device that is put in place to manage that investment. For the

    bio-technology firm, the ability to learn about how to manufacture this type of bio-technology

    product depends critically on the type of governance that is put in place in order to manage its

    manufacturing operations. It is extremely unlikely that these manufacturing capabilities can be

    learned solely by reading published reports and studies. Rather, they require a great deal of

    learning by doing, and the development of a great deal of tacit knowledge about the

    manufacturing process. Obviously, the type of governance device that is put in place to manage

    this manufacturing process is going to have a substantial impact on the quality of endogenous

    learning. Indeed, some governance choices may actually make it virtually impossible for

    endogenous learning to take place. Other governance choices may facilitate this type of learning.

    Learning and Governance

    Suppose that a firm making governance decisions under conditions of high uncertainty

    has as its primary objective maximizing its ability to learn about the value of its uncertain

    investment, at the lowest cost possible. What type of governance device would it adopt?

    In general, if the type of learning that is most likely to enable a firm making an uncertain

    investment to estimate the value of that investment is exogenous learning, then this firm will

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    16/36

    14

    prefer less hierarchical forms of governance over more hierarchical forms of governance. The

    reasoning behind this assertion is simple: if the most critical learning is likely to be exogenous,

    then the ability of a firm to learn about the economic value of its uncertain investment does not

    depend upon the nature of the governance devices it uses to manage its learning. In this setting,

    the firm should adopt the least costly governance devices possible. Following Williamson (1985,

    1991), less hierarchical governance (i.e., market forms of governance) are less costly than more

    hierarchical forms of governance. Thus, if the type of learning that is most likely to enable a firm

    making an uncertain investment to estimate the value of that investment is exogenous learning,

    then less hierarchical forms of governance will be preferred over more hierarchical forms of

    governance.

    On the other hand, if the type of learning that is most likely to enable a firm making an

    uncertain investment to estimate the value of that investment is most likely to be endogenous

    learning, then more hierarchical forms of governance will be preferred over less hierarchical

    forms of governance. The quality of endogenous learning is significantly effected by governance

    choices. Recent work on the knowledge-based theory of the firm suggests that more hierarchical

    forms of governance can facilitate the transfer of tacit and subtle knowledge, compared to less

    hierarchical forms of governance (Conner and Prahalad, 1996; Spender, 1996). Thus, since

    endogenous learning is likely to be tacit, subtle, and involve a great deal of learning by doing,

    and since governance choices can have a significant impact on the quality of this type of learning,

    if the type of learning that is most likely to enable a firm making an uncertain investment to

    estimate the value of that investment is most likely to be endogenous learning, then more

    hierarchical forms of governance will be preferred over less hierarchical forms of governance.

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    17/36

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    18/36

    16

    decision about whether or not to vertically integrate into manufacturing during commercial

    production (Kester, 1984).

    Securing Property Rights and Governance

    Suppose that a firm making governance choices under conditions of high uncertainty has

    as its primary objective securing the right to invest in an opportunity should it turn out to be

    economically viable, but that they would like to be able to secure this right at the lowest cost

    possible. What type of governance device would it adopt?

    The type of learning that is most likely to enable a firm to learn the value of its uncertain

    investment also has an impact on the type of governance that firms will use to secure their

    property rights to invest in opportunities once their true value is known. If this type of learning is

    most likely to be endogenous, then only those firms that have actually learned endogenously will

    be aware of the information needed to value an uncertain investment. This is because

    endogenous learning is often of the learning by doing and tacit variety--learning that cannot be

    exogenous in character. Because only those firms that have learned endogenously have obtained

    this information, this type of learning, per se, secures the right of a firm to exploit this

    information by investing in an opportunity if it turns out to be valuable.

    Since endogenous learning secures the right of a firm to invest in an opportunity should it

    turn out to be valuable, no additional governance is required to secure that right. This means that

    firms in this setting should choose the least costly form of governance possible: less hierarchical

    (i.e., market forms) of governance. When a firm learns about the value of its uncertain

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    19/36

    17

    investment endogenously, it does not require any other guarantees about its ability to invest in its

    opportunities, and thus prefers less hierarchical forms of governance.

    On the other hand, when this learning is most likely to be exogenous, then the

    information about the value of an opportunity is available to any interested firm. This type of

    learning, per se, cannot secure the property rights to invest if it turns out that the investment is

    economically valuable. In this setting, firms will opt for more hierarchical forms of governance,

    because these more hierarchical forms of governance can provide contractual and other

    guarantees that, should an opportunity turn out to be valuable, will enable a firm to invest in

    them. When learning, per se, does not secure this property right, more hierarchical governance

    is required, even though it is more costly than less hierarchical governance.

    This logic, when applied to the example bio-technology firm, suggests that this firm

    would decide to out source manufacturing during clinical trials, and then decide upon an

    appropriate governance structure for commercial production manufacturing later. This is because

    learning about manufacturing in this industry is endogenous. If this firm learns about

    manufacturing endogenously, it will not require any other governance devices to secure its right

    to exploit this learning, should the product prototype turn out to be valuable. From the point of

    view of simply securing this property right, a less hierarchical form of governance (i.e.,

    outsourcing) is all that is required, since endogenous learning, per se, secures the right of this

    firm to invest in its product prototype if, in fact, it turns out to be economically viable.

    Governance Objectives and Governance Choices Under Uncertainty

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    20/36

    18

    Thus far, it has been suggested that firms making governance choices under conditions of

    high uncertainty may have at least four objectives: minimizing the threat of opportunism,

    maximizing flexibility, learning about the value of an uncertain investment, and securing the

    property rights to invest in that opportunity should it turn out to be economically viable.

    Moreover, each of these objectives have different, and sometimes contradictory, implications for

    the type of governance devices that firms should adopt under conditions of high uncertainty. As

    summarized in Figure One, transactions cost economics suggests that the threat of opportunism

    under conditions of high uncertainty is minimized through the adoption of more hierarchical

    forms of governance. Real options theory suggests that flexibility is maximized under conditions

    of high uncertainty by the adoption of less hierarchical governance. Theories about

    organizational learning suggest that, if learning is likely to be exogenous, less hierarchical

    governance is preferred (because it is less costly then alternatives, and the quality of exogenous

    learning is not affected by governance devices). However, if learning is likely to be endogenous,

    then more hierarchical governance is preferred (because more hierarchical governance can

    facilitate learning about tacit knowledge and learning by doing). Property rights theories suggest

    that, if learning is likely to be endogenous, less hierarchical governance is all that is required

    (because endogenous learning, per se, secures a firms property rights). However, if learning is

    likely to be exogenous, more hierarchical forms of governance will be required to secure a firms

    rights to invest in an opportunity should it turn out to be economically viable (because exogenous

    learning does not secure a property right, per se, while more hierarchical governance can, through

    the use of contracts and other guarantees).

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    21/36

    19

    [Insert Figure One About Here]

    Given these multiple conflicting prescriptions about the type of governance that a firm

    should adopt under conditions of high uncertainty, an important question becomes: when are

    these different objectives more or less important for firms making governance choices under

    uncertainty? Once we understand when these different objectives will be more or less important

    for firms in making their governance choices, it will be possible to make specific predictions

    about what those governance choices will be. Some situations where different of these

    governance objectives will be more or less important are described below.

    Transaction Specific Investment and Governance Choices

    Consider first the threat of opportunism. Following transactions cost logic, the threat of

    opportunism in an exchange is due to two factors: the level of uncertainty about sources of

    opportunism in that exchange and the level of transaction specific investment in that exchange

    (Williamson, 1975, 1985). Indeed, most recent research seems to suggest that the level of

    transaction specific investment in an exchange is a more important determinant of the threat of

    opportunism in that exchange than the level of uncertainty (Williamson, 1985; Riordan and

    Williamson, 1985).

    Consider the governance choices of two firms. The first firm (Firm A) must make

    governance choices under conditions of both high uncertainty and high transaction specific

    investment. The second firm (Firm B) must make governance choices under conditions of high

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    22/36

    20

    uncertainty and low transaction specific investment. It is not hard to see that the threat of

    opportunism facing Firm A is considerably greater than the threat of opportunism facing Firm B.

    Empirically, this suggests that Firm A is likely to make governance choices that are very

    consistent with transactions cost logic, i.e., Firm A is likely to adopt more hierarchical forms of

    governance in order to minimize the threat of opportunism. Firm B, on the other hand, faces

    some threat from opportunism. However, Firm Bs governance choices will take into

    consideration maximizing flexibility, learning, and securing property rights to a greater extent

    than Firm As governance choices. Thus, Firm B may make governance choices that are

    different then what would be expected if adopted only a transactions cost perspective.

    Types of Uncertainty and Governance Choices

    Two types of uncertainty have already been identified in this discussion: uncertainty

    about sources of opportunism in an exchange, and uncertainty about the economic value of that

    exchange. In many circumstances, these two types of uncertainty seem likely to be related. For

    example, suppose a firm is investing in a particular type of opportunity for the very first time. It

    would not be surprising for this firm to be unsure about the economic viability of this investment.

    Moreover, given this firms lack of experience in making this type of investment, it would also

    not be surprising for it to be not fully aware of all the different ways that exchange partners could

    behave opportunistically over the course of this investment. Indeed, since the economic value of

    an investment for a particular firm depends, in part, in how much of that value is appropriated by

    exchange partners through their opportunistic actions, uncertainty about sources of opportunism

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    23/36

    21

    in an exchange can be an important cause of uncertainty about the value of an investment

    opportunity.

    However, in other circumstances, there may be substantial uncertainty about the

    economic viability of an investment, but little or no uncertainty about potential sources of

    opportunism associated with that investment. For example, suppose a firm has a great deal of

    experience in making a particular type of uncertain investment. The economic viability of this

    particular investment may depend on the reactions of customers, competitors, suppliers, and so

    forth, and thus may be uncertain. However, if this investment turns out to be viable, this firm

    may be able to anticipate, with a great deal of accuracy, the potential sources of opportunism

    associated with this investment. Their ability to anticipate these sources of opportunism reflects

    their substantial experience in making this type of investment; their inability to be certain about

    the economic viability of this investment reflects the unique properties of this particular

    investment.

    When uncertainty about the economic viability of an investment is high, while

    uncertainty about sources of opportunism associated with that investment is low, opportunism

    minimizing objectives will be less important than other objectives in making governance choices

    to manage this investment. This suggests that governance choices will be made in ways that are

    more consistent with real options, learning, and property rights objectives. On the other hand,

    when both uncertainty about sources of opportunism in an investment and uncertainty about the

    economic viability of an investment are high, opportunism minimizing objectives are likely to

    increase in importance, and governance choices are likely to be more influenced by transactions

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    24/36

    22

    cost reasoning than would be the case if uncertainty about sources of opportunism in a

    transaction was low.

    Endogenous Learning Over Time and Governance Choices

    One of the fundamental conundrums detailed in this discussion, and summarized in

    Figure One, has to do with endogenous learning and its impact on governance to facilitate

    learning and governance to secure investment opportunities. A firm that makes governance

    choices solely on the basis of facilitating endogenous learning will opt for more hierarchical

    governance; a firm that makes governance choices solely on the basis of securing property rights,

    given endogenous learning, will opt for less hierarchical governance.

    One way to resolve this contradiction is to recognize that the need to learn about the value

    of an uncertain investment, and the need to secure property rights to invest in an opportunity, can

    vary over the life of an investment. For example, when a firm is first making a highly uncertain

    investment, it must learn a great deal about the value of this investment. Moreover, if this

    investment in occurring in a highly competitive environment, this firm has a strong incentive to

    learn as much as it can about the value of this investment as quickly as it can, in order to obtain

    whatever first mover advantages may be associated with this investment (Montgomery and

    Lieberman, 1988). If the type of learning that is likely to help this firm learn what it needs to

    know to value this investment is endogenous, it will probably invest in more hierarchical forms

    of governance, since, as was suggested earlier, more hierarchical forms of governance can

    facilitate endogenous learning.

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    25/36

    23

    However, once a firm has used its more hierarchical governance to facilitate its

    endogenous learning, it no longer needs that governance to secure the property right to invest in

    this opportunity. That right is secured by the endogenous learning, it self. Only those firms that

    have experienced this endogenous learning will be able to exploit this information in valuing an

    investment opportunity. Thus, more hierarchical governance is no longer required, and will be

    replaced, as quickly as possible, by less hierarchical forms of governance.

    Thus, for investments where endogenous learning is critical to evaluating the economic

    viability of an investment, more hierarchical forms of governance are likely to be adopted during

    the early stages of an investment (in order to facilitate endogenous learning), and less hierarchical

    forms of governance are likely to be adopted during the later states of an investment (because

    hierarchical governance is no longer needed to secure rights to invest in this opportunity).

    Indeed, this pattern of governing transactions has already been described in the literature and is

    called a learning race (Hamel, 1991).

    In a learning race, at least two firms join in a more hierarchical form of governance in

    order to learn from each other. This more hierarchical form of governance is typically some type

    of joint venture (Hamel, 1991). Since these two firms are learning from each other, learning in

    this exchange is, by definition, endogenous. Once at least one of these firms learns all it needed

    to learn in this relationship, it abandons the more hierarchical form of governance put in place to

    facilitate endogenous learning, and substitutes a less hierarchical form of governance. It can

    adopt this less hierarchical form of governance and not fear losing the opportunity to use the

    information it has gained to invest in an opportunity, if that opportunity turns out to be valuable,

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    26/36

    24

    because the endogenous learning it has experienced secures that right for it, without the cost of

    any additional governance.

    Exogenous Learning Over Time and Governance Choices

    How does this situation change if the critical type of learning in an investment is likely to

    be exogenous? If learning is likely to be exogenous, then learning will not be facilitated by more

    hierarchical forms of governance. If a firm making this kind of investment was only interested in

    facilitating learning at the lowest cost possible, then it would adopt non-hierarchical (i.e., market

    forms) of governance.

    However, this firm must also be interested in securing a property right to invest in an

    opportunity, should it turn out to be valuable, since exogenous learning, per se, cannot secure this

    right for the firm. To do this, this firm must invest in more hierarchical forms of governance

    then would be the case otherwise. Thus, in the early stages of this investment, this firm will

    adopt a more hierarchical, rather than a less hierarchical approach to governance. With this

    governance in place, this firm simply waits until exogenous learning occurs.

    Suppose exogenous learning occurs, and it becomes clear that this opportunity is, in fact,

    economically valuable. Now, this firms need to secure its property rights are increased. Since

    all interested firms have access to exogenous learning, in order to secure this property right, this

    firm will need to implement an even more hierarchical form of governance. Thus, unlike the

    endogenous learning case, where more hierarchical forms of governance are replaced by less

    hierarchical forms of governance once endogenous learning occurs, when learning is exogenous,

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    27/36

    25

    more hierarchical forms of governance are replaced by even more hierarchical forms of

    governance, once exogenous learning occurs and the positive value of the investment is

    established.

    This is the situation described by Kogut (1991). Kogut describes firms adopting more

    hierarchical forms of governance (e.g., joint ventures) under conditions of high uncertainty.

    These more hierarchical forms of governance may be used to facilitate endogenous learning, or

    they may be used to secure the right to invest in an opportunity should it prove to be valuable

    through exogenous learning. The purpose of this initial joint venture is revealed by actions that a

    firm takes subsequent to learning. If a firm abandons its joint venture subsequent to learning and

    replaces it with a less hierarchical form of governance, the purpose of that joint venture was to

    facilitate learning, and this investment was most likely characterized by endogenous learning. If,

    on the other hand, a firm abandons its joint venture subsequent to learning and replaces it with a

    more hierarchical form of governance, the purpose of that joint venture was to secure investment

    rights, and this investment was most likely characterized by exogenous learning.

    In fact, Kogut (1991) studied the impact of exogenous learning on the structure of

    governance. In particular, Kogut (1991) shows that when shipment growth increases in excess of

    long term expectations, firms with joint ventures conclude that the uncertain investment they

    have made is economically viable. However, because information about shipment growth is

    publicly available (i.e., a form of exogenous learning), the ability to exploit this information in

    making what is now a more certainly valuable investment requires the use of more hierarchical

    forms of governance. Thus, this market signal leads firms that have made this kind of investment

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    28/36

    26

    to acquire their former alliance partners, an action that is consistent with the predictions of

    governance choices under conditions of exogenous learning described here.

    Governance When Learning is Endogenous and Exogenous

    Recognizing the different impacts that endogenous and exogenous learning can have on

    governance choices over the lifetime of an investment helps resolve an apparent contradiction in

    the literature on joint ventures. Some authors see joint ventures as primarily a learning race,

    where joint venture forms of governance are replaced by less hierarchical forms of governance

    once the value of an uncertain investment becomes known. Other authors see joint ventures

    primarily as a prelude to acquisition, where joint venture forms of governance are replaced by

    even more hierarchical forms of governance one the value of an uncertain investment becomes

    known. The theory developed here suggests that whether a joint venture should be seen as a

    learning race or as a prelude to acquisition depends upon the type of learning that is likely to

    have the greatest impact on the ability of a firm to value its uncertain investment. If this type of

    learning is endogenous, then the learning race analysis of joint ventures is appropriate; if this

    type of learning is exogenous, then the analysis of joint ventures as a prelude to acquisition is

    most appropriate.

    Of course, this situation is complicated when learning about the value of an uncertain

    investment can be either endogenous or exogenous; that is, when firms can learn about the value

    of their uncertain investments either through the governance devices they put in place to manage

    those investments, or from sources external to that governance. In this setting, governance

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    29/36

    27

    decisions may depend more on the learning capabilities of firms than on the type of learning that

    may occur. If a firm has developed endogenous learning capabilities, it is likely to treat this

    situation as if endogenous learning was more likely to occur then exogenous learning, and adopt

    the learning race approach to governing this investment. If a firm has developed exogenous

    learning capabilities, it is likely to treat this situation as if exogenous learning was more likely to

    occur than endogenous learning, and adopt the joint venture as a prelude to acquisition approach

    to governing this investment.

    The concept of absorptive capacity has been proposed as a way to conceptualize the

    ability of a firm to learn (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). The analysis in this paper suggests that

    there may be different kinds of absorptive capacity--the ability to learn endogenously and the

    ability to learn exogenously--and that these different types of absorptive capacity can have

    differential effects on governance choices. It may well be the case that there are other types of

    absorptive capacity, and that these two may have differential impacts on governance choices.

    That firms may differ in their ability to engage in different types of learning also suggests

    that the governance choices described here may be sources of competitive advantage. Suppose,

    for example, a firm has developed the capability of learning endogenously, but that the type of

    learning that is required in a particular setting is exogenous learning. If this firm attempts to use

    it endogenous learning capability in this setting and treats this investment as a learning race, it

    might find itself at a competitive disadvantage compared to a firm that is highly capable in

    exogenous learning and is seeking to make this investment. In a similar way, a firm skilled at

    exogenous learning may find itself at a competitive disadvantage if it engages in a learning race

    with a firm skill at endogenous learning. These observations are consistent with what might be

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    30/36

    28

    called a resource-based theory of competitive advantage based on governance choices (Barney,

    1986; 1991).

    Conclusion

    Decisions about governance can occur under conditions of high uncertainty. In these

    settings, a simple transactions cost analysis, with its emphasis on making governance choices that

    minimize the threat of opportunism, receives only mixed empirical support. A simple real

    options analysis, with its emphasis on making governance choices that maximize flexibility, also

    receives only mixed empirical support. What is required is an approach to making governance

    choices that takes into consideration not only minimizing the threat of opportunism and

    maximizing flexibility, but also maximizing the ability of a firm to learn about the value of its

    uncertain investment, as well as maximizing the ability of a firm to invest in this opportunity

    should it prove to be economically feasible. The theory developed here consider all four of these

    objectives for firms making governance choices under conditions of high uncertainty.

    Unfortunately, each of these different objectives can lead a firm to make different

    governance choices. It has been shown how incorporating information about the type of learning

    that is most likely to enable a firm to value its uncertain investment--whether it is endogenous

    learning or exogenous learning--can help sort out what kinds of governance decisions firms will

    make and when.

    Thus, when the level of transaction specific investment is high, along with the level of

    uncertainty, opportunism minimizing is a relatively more important determinant of governance

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    31/36

    29

    choices. When the level of transaction specific investment is low, even though the level of

    uncertainty is high, opportunism minimizing is a relatively less important determinant of

    governance choices. Also, when the level of uncertainty about sources of opportunism is high,

    along with uncertainty about the value of an investment, opportunism minimizing is a relatively

    more important determinant of governance choices, in comparison to situations where the level

    of uncertainty about sources of opportunism is low, even though the level of uncertainty about

    the value of an investment is high.

    Also, by recognizing that governance choices can vary over the life cycle of an

    investment, and that this variance depends at least in part on the type of learning that occurs in

    different investments, it is possible to make some predictions about governance choices

    overtime. When the critical learning in an uncertain investment is most likely to be endogenous,

    firms will treat this investment as a learning race, will opt for more hierarchical governance

    before learning occurs, and less hierarchical governance after learning has occurred. On the other

    hand, when the critical learning in an uncertain investment is most likely to be exogenous, firms

    will treat this investment as a precursor to acquisition, and will opt for more hierarchical

    governance before learning occurs, and even more hierarchical governance after learning has

    occurred.

    Finally, the observation that different firms may have different learning capabilities

    suggests that governance choices can lead to competitive advantages for some firms some of the

    time. If a firm is highly skilled in endogenous learning, it can obtain competitive advantages in

    settings where endogenous learning is likely to be important, compared to firms that are highly

    skilled in exogenous learning. On the other hand, if a firm is highly skilled in exogenous

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    32/36

    30

    learning, it can obtain competitive advantages in settings where exogenous learning is likely to

    be important, compared to firms that are highly skilled in endogenous learning. This then

    becomes a resource-based theory of competitive advantage based on governance choices (Lee,

    1998).

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    33/36

    31

    Bibliography

    Anderson, E. 1985. The salesperson as outside agent or employee: A transaction cost analysis.Marketing Science, 4: 234-254.

    Anderson, E. & Schmittlein, D. C. 1984. Integration of the sales force: An empiricalexamination. Rand Journal of Economics, 15: 385-395.

    Balakrishnan, S. & Wernerfelt, B. 1986. Technical change, competition and vertical integration.Strategic Management Journal, 7: 347-359.

    Barney, J. B. 1986. Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck, and business strategy.Management Science, 42: 1231-1241.

    Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm resources and sustainable competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17 (1): 155-171.

    Barney, J. B., & Hesterly, W. 1996. Organizational economics. In S. Clegg, C. Hardy, & W.Nord (Eds.), The handbook of organization studies. Sage Publications.

    Bowman, E. H., & Hurry, D. 1993. Strategy through the option lens: An integrated view of resource investments and the incremental-choice process. Academy of Management

    Review, 18 (4): 760-782.

    Chi, T., & McGuire, D. J. 1996. Collaborative ventures and value of learning: Integrating thetransaction cost and strategic option perspective on the choice of market entry modes.Journal of International Business Studies, 27 (2): 285-307.

    Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. 1990. Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning andinnovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35: 128-152.

    Conner, K. R., & Prahalad, C. K. 1996. A resource-based theory of the firm: Knowledge versusopportunism. Organization Science, 7(5): 477-501.

    Folta, T. B. & Leiblein, M. J. 1994. Technology acquisition and the choice of governance byestablished firms: Insights from option theory in a multinomial logit model. In D. P.Moore (Ed.), Academy of management best papers proceedings: 27-31.

    Ghoshal, S., & Moran, P. 1996. Bad for practice: A critique of the transaction cost theory.Academy of Management Review, 21(1): 13-47.

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    34/36

    32

    Grossman, S. & Hart, O (1986). The cost and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical andlateral integration, Journal of Political Economy, 94: 691-719.

    Hamel, G. 1991. Competition for competence and inter-partner learning within internationalstrategic alliances. Strategic Management Journal, 12: 83-103.

    Harrigan, K. R. 1986. Matching vertical integration strategies to competitive conditions.Strategic Management Journal, 7: 535-555.

    Hart, O., & Moore, J. 1990. Property rights and the nature of the firm. Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 98(6): 1119-1158.

    Helfat, C. E., & Teece, D. J. 1987. Vertical integration and risk reduction. Journal of Law,Economics, and Organization, 3(1): 47-67.

    Hill, C. W. L. 1990. Cooperation, opportunism, and the invisible hand: Implications fortransaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review, 15(3): 500-513.

    Hurry, D., Miller, A. T., & Bowman, E. H. 1992. Calls on high-technology: Japanese explorationof venture capital investment in the United States. Strategic Management Journal, 13: 85-101.

    John, G. & Weitz, B. A. 1988. Forward integration into distribution: An empirical test of

    transaction cost analysis. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. 4: 337-355.

    Kester, W. C. 1984. Todays options for tomorrows growth. Harvard Business Review, March-April: 153-160.

    Kogut, B. 1991. Joint ventures and the option to expand and acquire. Management Science, 37:19-33.

    Lee, W. 1998. A theory of exchange governance: Real option alternative to transaction costtheory. Unpublished doctoral dissertation. The Ohio State University, Columbus, OH.

    Levy, D. T. 1985. The transactions cost approach to vertical integration: An empiricalinvestigation. Review of Economics and Statistics. 67: 438-445.

    Lieberman, B. M. & Montgomery, D. B. 1988. First-mover advantages. Strategic ManagementJournal, 9: 41-58.

    MacMillan, I., Hambrick, D. C. , & Pennings, J. M. 1986. Uncertainty reduction and the threat of supplier retaliation: Two views of the backward integration decision. OrganizationStudies, 7: 263-278.

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    35/36

    33

    Masten, S. 1984. The organization of production: Evidence from the aerospace industry. Journal

    of Law and Economics, 27: 403-417.

    Masten, S., Meehan, J. W., & Snyder, E. A. 1991. The cost of organization. Journal of Law,Economics, and Organization. 7: 1-25.

    Myers, S. C. 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5:147-175.

    Pisano, G. P. 1990. The R&D boundaries of the firm: An empirical analysis. AdministrativeScience Quarterly, 35: 153-176.

    Riordan, M. H., & Williamson, O. E. 1985. Asset specificity and economic organization.International Journal of Industrial Organization, 3: 365-378.

    Sharp, D. J. 1991. Uncovering the hidden value in high-risk investment. Sloan ManagementReview, Summer: 69-74.

    Spender, J.-C. 1996. Making knowledge the basis of a dynamic theory of the firm. StrategicManagement Journal, 17 (Winter Special Issue): 45-62.

    Walker, G., & Weber, D. 1984. A transaction cost approach to make or buy decisions.

    Administrative Science Quarterly, 29: 373-391.

    Walker, G., & Weber, D. 1987. Supplier competition, uncertainty, and make-or-buy decision.Academy of Management Journal, 30: 589-596.

    Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York:Free Press.

    Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Williamson, O. E. 1991. Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structuralalternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36: 269-296.

  • 8/8/2019 38-Uncertainity and Governance

    36/36

    Figure One.

    Governance Objectives and Governance Choices Under High Uncertainty

    Hierarchical Governance Non-Hierarchical Governance

    Facilitate Learning:

    When Learning is Exogenous ------------------------------>