Top Banner

of 29

10.1.1.37.8983

Apr 04, 2018

Download

Documents

udelkingkong
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    1/29

    RATIONAL PRICING OF INTERNET COMPANIES

    REVISITED

    September 2000

    Eduardo S. Schwartz

    Anderson School at UCLA

    Mark Moon

    Fuller & Thaler Asset Management

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    2/29

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    3/29

    3

    capital expenditures and decreases with depreciation. This feature of the model is

    important for Internet companies that require large investment in fixed assets.

    Fourth, we attempt to improve the bankruptcy condition in the model by allowing

    the cash balances to become negative. This allows for future equity and debt financing.

    The optimal financing is that which maximizes the value of the firm.

    Fifth, we suggest a number of simplifying assumptions that considerably facilitate

    the practical implementation of the model. One of these is to set all the speeds of

    adjustment in the model equal to one another and derive them from the half-life of the

    company to becoming a normal firm. Another is to have only one market price of risk

    in the model by assuming that the growth rates in revenues and variable costs are

    orthogonal to the market returns.

    Sixth, we relate the half-life of the deviations to analysts (or the evaluators)

    expectations about future revenues. This comes from the fact that the speed of

    adjustment of the growth rate in revenues is the most critical one for valuation purposes.

    The expanded model, then, has six state variables, three of which are stochastic

    and three of which are deterministic (although path dependant). The three stochastic

    variables are revenues, the growth rate in revenues and variable costs. The three

    deterministic variables are the amount of cash available, the loss-carry-forward and the

    accumulated Property, Plant and Equipment. We solve the problem by Monte Carlo

    simulation which can easily deal with this number of state variables and the complex

    path-dependencies of the problem.

    In Section 2 we present the model with all the new features described above in its

    continuous-time version. Since the model is solved by simulation using an interval of

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    4/29

    4

    time that can be quite long, such as one quarter or one year, Section 3 discusses in detail a

    discrete time approximation. Section 4 provides an illustrative example of the approach

    by pricing Exodus Communications stock and Section 5 presents comparative statics with

    respect to some of the key parameters. Section 6 concludes.

    2. CONTINUOUS-TIME MODEL

    Consider an Internet company with instantaneous rate of revenues (or sales) at

    time t given by R(t). Assume that the dynamics of these revenues are given by the

    stochastic differential equation:

    (1) 1)()()()( dztdtt

    tRtdR +=

    where )(t , the drift, is the expected rate of growth in revenues and is assumed to follow

    a mean reverting process with a long-term average drift . That is, the initial very high

    growth rates of the Internet firm are assumed to converge stochastically to a more

    reasonable and sustainable rate of growth for the industry to which the firm belongs.

    (2) 2)())(()( dztdtttd +=

    The mean-reversion coefficient () affects the rate at which the growth rate is expected to

    converge to its long-term average, and )/(2ln can be interpreted as the "half-life" of the

    deviations in that any growth rate is expected to be halved in this time period.

    The unanticipated changes in revenues are also assumed to converge

    (deterministically) to a more normal level whereas the unanticipated changes in the

    expected growth rate are assumed to converge (also deterministically) to zero.

    (3) dtttd ))(()( 1 =

    (4) dtttd )()( 2 =

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    5/29

    5

    The unanticipated changes in the growth rate of revenues and the unanticipated changes

    in its drift may be correlated:

    (5) dtdzdz 1221 =

    The costs at time t have two components. The first is a variable component,

    which is assumed to be proportional to the revenues. The second is a fixed component.

    (6) FtRttCost += )()()(

    The variable costs parameter (t) in the cost function is also assumed to be

    stochastic reflecting the uncertainty about future potential competitors, market share, and

    technological developments. It follows the stochastic differential equation:

    (7) 33 )())(()( dztdtttd +=

    The mean-reversion coefficient (3) describes the rate at which the variable costs are

    expected to converge to their long-term average, and 32ln )/( can be interpreted as the

    "half-life" of the deviations in that any deviation is expected to be halved in this time

    period. The unanticipated changes in variable costs are also assumed to converge

    (deterministically) to a more normal level

    (8) dtttd ))(()( 4 =

    We also allow for correlation between unanticipated changes in variable costs and

    both revenues and growth rates in revenues:

    (9) dtdzdz1331

    = (10) dtdzdz2332

    =

    The after tax rate of net income to the firm, Y(t), is then given by

    (11) )1))(()()(()( ctDeptCosttRtY =

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    6/29

    6

    The corporate tax rate c in (11) is only paid if there is no loss-carry-forward (i.e.

    if the loss-carry-forward is positive the tax rate is zero) and the net income is positive.

    The dynamics of the loss-carry-forward are given by:

    (12) dL(t) = - Y(t)dt if L(t) > 0

    dL(t) = Max [- Y(t)dt , 0] if L(t) = 0

    The accumulated Property, Plant and Equipment at time t, P(t), depends on the

    rate of capital expenditures for the period, Capx(t), and the corresponding rate of

    depreciation, Dep(t). Planned capital expenditures, CX(t), are known for an initial

    period and after that they are assumed to be a fraction CR of revenues. Depreciation is

    assumed to be a fraction DR of the accumulated Property, Plant and Equipment.

    (13) dttDeptCapxtdP )}()({)( =

    (14) ttfortCXtCapx = )()(

    ttfortRCRtCapx >= )(*)(

    (15) )(*)( tPDRtDep =

    Then, the amount of cash available to the firm, given by X(t), evolves according

    to:

    (16) dttCapxtDeptYtrXtdX )}()()()({)( ++=

    The untaxed interest earned on the cash available is included in the dynamics of the cash

    available to make the valuation results insensitive to when the cash flows are distributed

    to the security-holders. Since in the risk neutral framework we discount risk adjusted

    cash flows at the risk free rate of interest, we also need to accumulate cash flows at the

    same risk free rate. For all purposes, except for determining the bankruptcy condition,

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    7/29

    7

    this is equivalent to discounting the cash flows generated by the firm when they occur as

    opposed to at the horizon T.

    To avoid having to define a dividend policy in the model, we assume that the cash

    flow generated by the firms operations remains in the firm and earns the risk free rate of

    interest. This accumulated cash will be available for distribution to the shareholders at an

    arbitrary long-term horizon T, by which time the firm will have reverted to a normal

    firm.

    The firm is assumed to go bankrupt when its cash available reaches a

    predetermined negative amount, X

    *

    . The purpose of this is to allow for future financing.

    The optimal amount of new financing in the future is the one which maximizes the

    current value of the firm, though we recognize that in many practical situations firms go

    bankrupt before their value reaches zero. To obtain the optimal amount of new financing

    we decrease X* until firm value is maximized.

    The objective of the model is to determine the value of the Internet firm at the

    current time. According to standard theory this value is obtained by discounting the

    expected value of the firm at the horizon under the risk neutral measure (the equivalent

    martingale measure) at the risk free rate of interest, which for simplicity is assumed to be

    constant1. The value of the firm at the horizon T has two components. First, the cash

    balance outstanding and second, the value of the firm as a going concern, the value which

    is assumed to be a multiple M of the EBITDA at the horizon T:

    (17) ])]}()([)({()0(rT

    Q eTCostTRMTXEV+=

    1 It would be easy to incorporate stochastic interest rates into our framework.

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    8/29

    8

    The model has three sources of uncertainty. First, there is uncertainty about the

    changes in revenues, second, there is uncertainty about the expected rate of growth in

    revenues and third, there is uncertainty about the variable costs. We will assume that only

    the first source of uncertainty has a risk premium associated with it and later on we will

    relate this risk premium to the beta of the stock. Under some simplifying assumptions

    (see for example Brennan and Schwartz (1982)), the risk adjusted processes for revenues

    can be obtained from the true processes as in:

    (18) *1)()]()([)(

    )(dztdttt

    tR

    tdR +=

    where the market price of factor risk is constant. This market price of risk is equal to

    the correlation of the revenue process and the return on aggregate wealth (proxied by the

    market portfolio) times the standard deviation of the return on aggregate wealth (proxied

    by the market portfolio). Since the rate of growth in revenues process and the variable

    cost process do not have risk premiums attached to them the true and the risk adjusted

    processes are the same.

    Most analysts and investors are more interested in the price of a share than in the

    value of the whole company. To obtain the price of a share we need to examine the

    capital structure of the company in detail. We need to know how many shares are

    currently outstanding and how many shares are likely to be issued to current employee

    stock option holders and convertible bondholders. We also need to know how much of

    the cash flows will be available to the shareholders after coupon and principal payment to

    the bondholders.

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    9/29

    9

    To simplify the analysis, we assume that if the firm survives options will be

    exercised and convertible bonds will be converted into shares.2 This means that in each

    of the paths of the simulation where the company does not go bankrupt, we adjust the

    number of shares to reflect the exercise of options and convertibles. To obtain the cash

    flows available to shareholders from the cash flows available to all security-holders

    (which determine the total value of the firm), we subtract the principal and after-tax

    coupon payments on the debt and add the payments by option holders at the exercise of

    the options. Since we are assuming that the firm pays no dividends, the exercise of the

    options and convertibles occurs at their maturity. If all option holders exercise their

    options optimally, the above procedure overvalues the stock by undervaluing the options

    and convertibles, since there might be some states of the world where the firm survives

    but it is not optimal to exercise the options or convert the convertible.

    In addition, it is well known, that for diversification purposes, employee stock

    options are frequently exercised before maturity, if they are exercisable, to allow for the

    sale of the underlying stock. Also, even if they are in the money, not all the options will

    be exercised since many of the employees will leave the firm before their options become

    vested. However, over time the firm will likely issue additional employee stock options

    to existing and new employees. If the number of shares to be issued at exercise and

    conversion is small relative to the total number of shares outstanding, the impact of these

    issues on the share value is likely to be very small.

    Implicit in the model described above is that the value of the firm and the value of

    the stock at any point in time are functions of the value of the state variables (revenues,

    expected growth in revenues, variable costs, loss-carry-forward, cash balances and

    2 The Longstaff and Schwartz (2000) approach could be used to obtain a more precise exercise strategy.

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    10/29

    10

    accumulated Property, Plant and Equipment) and time. That is, the value of the stock can

    be written as:

    (18) ),,,,,,( tPXLRSS

    Applying Itos Lemma to this expression we can obtain the dynamics of the stock value

    (19)

    ddSdRdSdRdSdSdS

    dRSdtSdPSdXSdLSdSdSdRSdS

    RR

    RRtPXLR

    ++++

    ++++++++=

    2

    212

    21

    2

    21

    The volatility of the stock can be derived directly from this expression

    (20) 2313122222 222 222)()()(

    SVS

    SSS

    SSS

    SS

    SS

    SS

    S RRRRRR +++++=

    The partial derivatives of the stock value with respect to the level of revenues, to

    the expected rate of growth in revenues, and to the variable costs are obtained by

    simulation3. Since the volatility of the expected growth rate of revenues (0) is one of the

    most critical parameters in the valuation model and is difficult to estimate, equation (20)

    is used in the implementation of the model to imply 0 from the observed volatility of the

    stock.

    Finally, using expression (19) and the continuous time return on the market

    portfolio, and noting that only the revenue process has a risk premium associated with it,

    we can write the beta of the stock as:

    (21)222

    )()(

    M

    R

    M

    MRMR

    M

    SM t

    S

    RSt

    S

    RS

    ===

    Expression (21) establishes the relation between the market price of risk in the model and

    the beta of the stock, and can be used to infer the value of the market price of risk, .

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    11/29

    11

    3. DISCRETE-TIME APPROXIMATION OF THE MODEL

    The model developed in the previous section is path-dependent. The cash

    available at any point in time, which determines when bankruptcy is triggered, depends

    on the whole history of past cash flows. Similarly, the loss-carry-forward and the

    depreciation tax shields, which determine when and how much corporate taxes the firm

    has to pay, are also path-dependent. These path-dependencies can easily be taken into

    account by using Monte Carlo simulation to solve for the value of the Internet company.

    In the implementation of the model we assume that all the mean reversion

    coefficients are equal and their unique value is inferred from the expected half-life of

    their deviations. To perform the simulation we use the discrete version of the risk-

    adjusted processes:4

    (22)})(]

    2

    )()()({[ 1

    2

    )()(

    ttt

    ttt

    etRttR+

    =+

    (23) 22

    )(2

    1)1()()(

    t

    eetett

    ttt

    ++=+

    (24) 3

    2

    )(2

    1)1()()(

    t

    eetett

    ttt

    ++=+

    where

    (25) )1()( 0tt eet

    +=

    (26) tet = 0)(

    (27) )1()( 0tt eet

    +=

    3 The initial value of the revenues (the rate of growth in revenues and the variable costs) is perturbed toobtain new values of the equity from which these derivatives are computed.

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    12/29

    12

    Equations (25) - (27) are obtained by integrating (3), (4) and (8) with initial values 0 ,

    0 and 0 . 1 , 2 and 3 are standard correlated normal variates.

    Note that as time grows the volatilities in the model converge to:

    (28) =)(

    (29) 0)( =

    (30) =)(

    and the growth rate in revenues converges to

    (31) =)(

    This implies that the revenue process converges to

    (32) 1)(

    )(dzdt

    R

    dR +=

    The net income after tax is still given by equation (11) where all variables are

    measured over the period t . Similarly, the discrete versions of the dynamics of the

    loss-carry-forward, the accumulated Property, Plant and Equipment, and the amount of

    cash available are immediate

    Depending on the situation, the unit of time t chosen for the analysis is one quarter

    or one year. The advantage of using the latter is that it allows for smoothing of seasonal

    effects and is more consistent with typically annual longer-term analyst projections.

    4. ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLE

    In this section we apply the model described in previous sections to value Exodus

    Communications. Exodus is one of the leading providers of Internet web-page hosting

    4 Note that there is a typo in the equation corresponding to (23) in Schwartz and Moon (2000).

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    13/29

    13

    for companies with high-traffic web sites. It was founded in 1994 and by August 2000 it

    had a market capitalization of over 22 billion dollars.

    The results obtained from our valuation approach, like those of any other valuation

    approach, depend critically on the assumptions we make about future revenues, rates of

    growth in revenues, and costs. In what follows we describe how we estimate the

    parameters needed to run the Monte Carlo simulation from the past and present data

    available for Exodus, and from analysts forecasts relating to the company. Since most

    forecasts of capital expenditures, revenues and costs are available on an annual basis, all

    our simulations are done on an annual basis.

    Revenue Dynamics

    As the starting value for the revenue simulation we take the actual revenues for

    1999 of $242.2 million. The initial volatility of revenues is obtained from quarterly data

    from the first quarter of 1997 to the second quarter of 2000, and annualized to give 0.135.

    This volatility is assumed to decrease with time to the long-term volatility of revenues of

    0.065. The half-life of this deviation and of all the others in the model are assumed to be 2

    years. Later on we explain in more detail this last assumption.

    Growth Rate of Revenues Dynamics

    The initial growth rate in revenues is taken to be 120% per year which is what

    analysts expect it to be from 1999 to 2000. It is assumed that in the long run, when

    Exodus becomes a normal firm, this growth rate will decrease to 5% per year. The

    initial annual volatility of the growth rate, which is one of the critical parameters in the

    model, is unobservable. We imply it from the volatility of the stock. Figure 1 shows the

    weekly implied volatility of Exodus options from September 25, 1998 to August 4, 2000.

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    14/29

    14

    The average implied volatility of the stock during this period was 96.2%. Figure 2

    illustrates the relation between the model price and volatility of the stock and the

    volatility of the growth rate of revenues. As an input to the model we choose the

    volatility of the growth rate of revenues, 0.23, which gives a model stock volatility which

    approximates the market volatility. Note that the corresponding level of the stock price is

    $49.92.

    Variable Costs Dynamics

    Using actual data for 1998 and 1999, and analyst estimates for 2000 to 2009,

    Figure 3 reports the results of regressing cash costs on revenues. From these results we

    take 0.56 as the initial variable cost as a fraction of revenues, and $382 million as the

    annual fixed cost. Since it is unlikely that the firm will continue to have such large profit

    margins forever, we assume that in the long run variable costs will increase to $0.75 per

    dollar of revenue. Similarly, we assume that the initial volatility of variable costs of 0.06

    will decrease in the long run to 0.03.

    Half-Life of Deviations and Correlations

    As mentioned earlier, to simplify the analysis we have assumed that all the mean

    reversion processes in the model have the same speed of adjustment coefficient. But only

    the one which determines how fast the initial growth rate in revenues reverts to the long-

    term rate has a significant effect on valuation. This is not surprising. If we start with an

    initial growth rate of 120% and we assume that in the long run it decreases to a more

    normal 5%, then the speed at which it decreases will have a tremendous impact on future

    revenues. Figure 4 shows the expected revenues up to year 10 (year 2009) for different

    assumptions about the half-life parameter. Note that if we increase the half-life from the

    5 The valuation results are not sensitive to this parameter.

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    15/29

    15

    assumed 2 years to 2.2 years, the expected revenues in year 2009 increases from $18.2

    billion to $23.8 billion. Clearly, this should have a major impact on valuation. Finally

    note that the analysts expectation of eventual revenues of $30.3 billion seems too large

    in our view.

    In this illustration we have assumed that the three stochastic processes are

    uncorrelated. In the next section we look at the effect of possible correlations between

    the variables.

    Balance Sheet Data

    The cash and marketable securities available after two bond issues on July 6, 2000

    was $1,720.2 million and the loss-carry-forward at the end of the second quarter of 2000

    was $337.9 million. The accumulated property, plan and equipment at the end of 1999

    was $390.6 million.

    The number of shares outstanding after the stock split of June 20, 2000 was

    412.36 million shares. In addition the company had 110.3 million employee stock

    options outstanding with a weighted average life of 8.9 years and a weighted average

    exercise price of $7.71.6 Finally, the firm had six debt issues and two convertible bond

    issues for a total outstanding amount of $2,547 million. This information, together with

    the maturity, coupon and conversion ratios (for the convertibles) is used to determine the

    price of the stock starting from the total value of the firm.

    Capital Expenditures and Depreciation

    Analysts have made forecasts of the capital expenditures of Exodus for the next 9

    years starting form $1,350 million in year 2000 and decreasing to $600 million in year

    2008. We use these as inputs to the model and starting from 2009 we assume that capital

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    16/29

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    17/29

    17

    In all cases we use 10,000 simulations with steps of one year and up to a horizon

    of 20 years. At the horizon we assume that the value of the firm is a multiple of ten times

    earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization (EBITDA).

    Simulation Results

    Using the parameters described above, the model stock price for Exodus

    Communications that we obtain is $49.92, with model volatility and beta that closely

    match (by construction) observed volatility and beta of the stock. The model (risk

    neutral) probability of bankruptcy is 3.4% with default occurring in years 5 to 9 (0.2% in

    year 5, 0.8% in year 6, 1.2% in year 7, 0.7% in year 8, and 0.6% in year 9).

    On August 9, 2000 the market price of Exodus at the close was $54.75. This is

    approximately 10% above the model price.

    Figures 7, 8 and 9 show the frequency distribution of revenues, growth rates in

    revenues and variable costs, respectively, at the end of year 3 implied by the above

    parameters. As can be seen from the figures there is substantial uncertainty about the

    state variables of the model even three years in the future. (Note that with only 10,000

    simulations the frequency distributions do not appear as smooth as they really are.)

    5. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS

    In this section we perform some sensitivity analysis on the more critical or

    controversial parameters of the model.

    Correlations

    Consider the situation in which the firm is in a competitive environment such that

    increases in profit margins (i.e. decreases in variable costs) are associated with decreases

    in growth rates in revenues. This implies a positive correlation between variable costs

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    18/29

    18

    and growth rates in revenues. We run the program with the same data described above,

    but assuming a correlation of 0.8. The market price of risk and the volatility of the

    growth rate had to be adjusted slightly to match the volatility and the beta of the stock.

    The model price decreased only slightly to $49.60, but the (risk neutral) probability of

    default decreased substantially to 1.9%. The effect of this correlation on prices increases,

    however, with the volatility of variable costs.

    Variable Costs

    As expected long-term variable costs have a big effect on prices. If long-term

    variable costs are increased from 0.75 to 0.80, the model stock price goes to $38.91 and if

    they are decreased to 0.70, the model stock price goes to $60.35. In both cases small

    adjustments are needed in the market price of risk to match the beta of the stock. This

    result is not surprising: a 20% increase or decrease in the profit margin has a similar

    effect on model stock prices.

    Bankruptcy Level

    Changes in the amount of future financing allowed has a very small effect on

    stock prices since we seem to be close to the optimal amount of future financing. If we

    increase the financing constraint from $3 billion to $3.5 billion the stock price increases

    only to $50.00 and if we decrease it to $2.5 billion the stock price decreases only to

    $49.82. These differences are well within simulation error.

    Half-Life of Deviations

    As mentioned earlier and as Figure 4 shows, the speed of adjustment has an

    important impact on expected future revenues and therefore on valuation. If we increase

    the half-life parameter from 2 to 2.2 years, the stock price increases to $73.55 (recall that

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    19/29

    19

    expected revenues in year 10 increase from $18.2 billion to $23.8 billion). If we decrease

    the parameter to 1.8 years the stock price decreases to $33.39 (the expected revenues in

    year 10 decrease to $13.9 billion).

    6. CONCLUSION

    In this article we have substantially extended and perfected the model developed

    in Schwartz and Moon (2000) for pricing Internet companies. We introduce uncertainty

    in costs and we take into account the tax effects of depreciation. We use the beta and the

    volatility of the stock to infer two critical unobservable parameters of the model, the

    market price of risk and the volatility of growth rates in revenues. We improve the

    bankruptcy condition by allowing future financing by the firm. Finally, we facilitate the

    implementation of the model by assuming the half-life of all processes is the same and

    suggest that it can be estimated from evaluators expectations of future revenues.

    Like any other valuation method, our real options approach to value Internet

    companies depends critically on the parameters used in the estimation. The next step in

    the implementation of the model would be to use cross-sectional data of many Internet

    companies to estimate some of the parameters. Finally, since the growth rate in revenues

    is not observable learning models could be used to update this critical factor in the

    model when new information on revenues is revealed.

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    20/29

    20

    References

    Brennan, M.J. and E.S. Schwartz, (1982), "Consistent Regulatory Policy Under

    Uncertainty," The Bell Journal of Economics, 13,, 2, 507-521 (Autumn).

    Longstaff, F.A. and E.S. Schwartz, (2000), Valuing American Options by Simulation: A

    Simple Least-Square Approach, Review of Financial Studies (forthcoming).

    Schwartz, E.S. and M. Moon, (2000), Rational Pricing of Internet Companies,

    Financial Analysts Journal 56:3, 62-75 (May/June).

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    21/29

    21

    Figure 1

    Exodus: Implied Volatility (%)

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    24-Jul-98 01-Nov-98 09-Feb-99 20-May-99 28-Aug-99 06-Dec-99 15-Mar-00 23-Jun-00 01-Oct-00

    Implied

    Volatility

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    22/29

    22

    Figure 2

    Exodus Communications: Valuation

    40

    42

    44

    46

    48

    50

    52

    54

    56

    58

    0.18 0.19 0.2 0.21 0.22 0.23 0.24 0.25 0.26 0.27 0.28

    Volatiltiy of the Revenue Growth Rate

    StockPrice

    0.7

    0.8

    0.9

    1

    1.1

    1.2

    1.3

    1.4

    Volatility

    Stock Price

    Volatility

    0.97

    $49.92

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    23/29

    23

    Figure 3

    EXDS: Cash Costs vs. Revenues

    Not Including CAPX

    1998A, 1999A, E[2000-2009]

    y = 0.5623x + 382.4

    R2

    = 0.9991

    0

    2,000

    4,000

    6,000

    8,000

    10,000

    12,000

    14,000

    16,000

    18,000

    20,000

    0 5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000 30,000 35,000

    Annual Revenues ($MM)

    AnnualCostsinEBITDA($MM)

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    24/29

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    25/29

    25

    Figure 5

    EXDS returns vs. S&P500 returns

    (weekly data)

    y = 2.7758x + 0.031

    R2

    = 0.2686

    -0.500

    -0.400

    -0.300

    -0.200

    -0.100

    0.000

    0.100

    0.200

    0.300

    0.400

    0.500

    -0.150 -0.100 -0.050 0.000 0.050 0.100 0.150

    S&P500 Return

    EXDSReturn b

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    26/29

    26

    Figure 6Exodus Communication: Valuation

    46

    47

    48

    49

    50

    51

    52

    53

    54

    0.32 0.33 0.34 0.35 0.36 0.37 0.38 0.39 0.4 0.41 0.42

    Market Price of Risk

    StockPrice

    2

    2.2

    2.4

    2.6

    2.8

    3

    3.2

    Beta Stock Pric

    Beta2.74

    $49.92

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    27/29

    27

    Figure 7

    Frequency of Revenues in Year 3

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400500

    0 2000 4000 6000 8000 10000

    Revenues

    Frequency

    Mean=3300

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    28/29

    28

    Figure 8

    Frequency of Growth Rates in Revenues in Year 3

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    350

    400

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1

    Growth Rate in Revenues

    Frequency

    Mean=0.46

  • 7/29/2019 10.1.1.37.8983

    29/29

    Figure 9

    Frequency of Variable Costs in Year 3

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    350

    0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

    Variable Costs

    Frequency

    Mean=0.68