Top Banner

of 40

07 Congestion Lewis

Apr 06, 2018

Download

Documents

Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    1/40

    HAMILTONTHE

    PROJECT

    Advancing Opportunity,

    Prosperity and Growth

    The Brookings Institution

    Americas TrafcCongestion Problem:Toward a Frameworkor Nationwide Reorm

    D I S C U S S I O N P A P E R 2 0 0 8 - 0 6 J U L Y 2 0 0 8

    David Lewis

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    2/40

    The Hamilton Project seeks to advance Americas promise o

    opportunity, prosperity, and growth. The Projects economic

    strategy reects a judgment that long-term prosperity is best

    achieved by making economic growth broad-based, by

    enhancing individual economic security, and by embracing a

    role or eective government in making needed public

    investments. Our strategystrikingly dierent rom the

    theories driving economic policy in recent yearscalls or fscal

    discipline and or increased public investment in key growth-

    enhancing areas. The Project will put orward innovative

    policy ideas rom leading economic thinkers throughout the

    United Statesideas based on experience and evidence, not

    ideology and doctrineto introduce new, sometimes

    controversial, policy options into the national debate with

    the goal o improving our countrys economic policy.

    The Project is named ater Alexander Hamilton, the

    nations frst treasury secretary, who laid the oundation

    or the modern American economy. Consistent with the

    guiding principles o the Project, Hamilton stood or sound

    fscal policy, believed that broad-based opportunity or

    advancement would drive American economic growth, and

    recognized that prudent aids and encouragements on the

    part o government are necessary to enhance and guide

    market orces.

    HAMILTONTH E

    PROJECT

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    3/40

    JULY 2008

    HAMILTONTHE

    PROJECT

    Advancing Opportunity,

    Prosperity and Growth

    Thi dicuion paper i a propoal rom the author. A emphaized in The Hamilton Project

    oriinal tratey paper, the Project a deined in part to provide a orum or leadin thiner

    acro the nation to put orard innovative and potentially important economic policy idea

    that hare the Project road oal o promotin economic roth, road-aed participation

    in roth, and economic ecurity. The author are invited to expre their on idea in dicuion

    paper, hether or not the Project ta or adviory council aree ith the pecic propoal.

    Thi dicuion paper i oered in that pirit.

    Americas Trafc Congestion

    Problem: Toward a Frameworkor Nationwide Reorm

    David LeiHDR Corporation

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    4/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    2 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    Copyriht 2008 The brooin Intitution

    Abstract

    A large and growing burden on the nations economy, trac congestion arises or various

    reasons, and more than one mechanism is needed to combat it. It is most unlikely, howev-

    er, that serious inroads to address the problem will be made without undamental reorm

    in the way consumers are charged or their use o congested highways. Congestion pricesare tolls that refect the economic costs o congestion, including productivity losses rom

    trac delays, increased accidents, higher emissions, and more. Congestion prices would

    help reduce these economic costs and guide transportation investment resources to their

    highest and best usewhich would include a better balance between highway and transit

    investment. In addition, such prices would generate revenues to help nance new invest-

    ment and compensate low-income people and others or whom toll payments are especial-

    ly burdensome. Requiring ederal, state, and local engagement, such reorm is a necessary

    step in the development o an eective, ecient, and sustainable highway system or the

    twenty-rst century.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    5/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008

    Contents

    1. Introduction 5

    2. The Prolem 7

    . A Propoal or Conetion Pricin 14

    4. Eect, benet, and Cot o Reorm 19

    5. Ditriutional Impact and Method o Redre 24

    6. Quetion and Concern 0

    7. Concluion 4

    Reerence 5

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    6/40

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    7/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 5

    1.0. Introdction

    M

    obility, and the transportation inra-

    structure needed to enable it, is ounda-

    tional to American culture and econom-ic activity. In 1860, President Lincoln campaigned

    on the importance o internal [inrastructure]

    improvements. Almost a century later, President

    Eisenhower spearheaded construction o the in-

    terstate highway system. To nance it, he created

    the Highway Trust Fund. The latter years o the

    twentieth century witnessed a continuous series o

    innovative legislative initiatives in Congress to a-

    cilitate mobility as a vital national priority. In 2005,

    President George W. Bush signed into law the Sae,

    Accountable, Flexible, Ecient TransportationEquity Act: A Legacy or Users (SAFETEA-LU).

    With guaranteed unding or highways, highway

    saety, and public transportation totaling $244.1

    billion, SAFETEA-LU represents the largest sur-

    ace transportation investment in the nations his-

    tory. Two landmark bills preceded SAFETEA-LU:

    the Intermodal Surace Transportation Eciency

    Act o 1991 (ISTEA) and the Transportation Eq-

    uity Act or the 21st Century (TEA-21). Between

    them, these bills introduced important new saety

    programs, designated the national highway systemto extend ederal nancial assistance to principal

    roads beyond interstate highways, extended the eli-

    gibility o dedicated Highway Trust Fund revenues

    to transit projects, and provided fexibility or states

    and localities to employ innovative methods o -

    nance and congestion management.

    Despite the nations history o sustained investment

    to create and maintain what is the most extensive

    system o roads and bridges in the world, our mo-

    bility and economic productivity is being eroded bytrac congestion at an alarming rate. Suburbaniza-

    tion and urban sprawl continue apace (Lewis and

    Williams 1999). Public transit attracts less than 10

    percent o total passenger trips (Transportation

    Research Board [TRB] 2006). Although the digital

    revolution enables twenty-rst-century industry

    to adopt just-in-time production, distribution, and

    inventory management systems, the clogged twen-

    tieth century transportation system is not up to the

    task o enabling the ast and reliable just-in-timedeliveries on which such systems depend in order to

    deliver enhanced productivity and competitiveness.

    Although some congestion is a blessingan indica-

    tor o vibrant economic and social activitybeyond

    a certain point, the delay and uncertainty people

    and goods endure in trac jams constitute net eco-

    nomic and social burdens.

    Compounding the congestion problem is the reality

    that the nations primary source o unds or inra-

    structure investmenttaxes on gasolineis dwin-dling. In the rst quarter o 2008, the average state

    gasoline tax was $0.214 per gallon, plus $0.184 per

    gallon o ederal tax, making the total tax $0.47 per

    gallon. For diesel, the average state tax was $0.292

    per gallon, plus $0.244 per gallon ederal tax, mak-

    ing the total tax $0.536 per gallon. For much o the

    twentieth century, gas taxes, with occasional modest

    increases, were sucient to keep pace with inra-

    structure costs. But the advent o more uel-e-

    cient vehicles, infation in the cost o inrastructure

    construction and maintenance, and resistance tohigher taxes is changing that situation. Unless there

    is a sharp increase in gasoline tax rates, the Highway

    Trust Fund is projected to be bankrupt by the end

    o 2009. A recent ederal commission reports that

    the gas tax would need to be increased by $0.25 to

    $0.41 per gallon in order to close the gap between

    projected inrastructure requirements and available

    unds (National Surace Transportation Policy and

    Revenue Study Commission 2007).

    To ocus discussion o Americas congestion prob-lem on the shortage o gas tax revenues, however,

    is to misdirect attention rom the more undamen-

    tal issue. In the progressively more complex and

    dynamic twenty-rst-century economy, America

    needs not just more inrastructure investment, but

    better investment, in the right amount, at the right

    locations, and in the right balance between roads

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    8/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    6 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    and transit. The ocus o this paper is on the need to

    reorm the way we charge or the use o congested

    roads as a means o guiding inrastructure invest-

    ment dollars to their highest and best use; this paper

    will not examine the way we pay or inrastructure.

    Instituting congestion prices (tolls that refect the

    true economic cost o using congested roads) would

    provide a powerul incentive to shit travel away

    rom the peak hours, encourage greater use o mass

    transit, reduce pressure to expand highway capacity,

    and direct investment dollars to highway and public

    transit projects o the highest value. In act, charg-

    ing people the true cost o using congested roads

    would help raise the money needed to pay or such

    projects and could compensate low-income people

    who are disadvantaged by the advent o road charg-es. It would be a win-win-win proposition: better

    investment, the money to pay or it, and equitable

    treatment o disadvantaged groups.

    To augment the motivation or state and local gov-

    ernments to implement congestion pricing, this pa-

    per recommends that Congress (through legislation)

    and the executive branch (through implementation

    o regulations) redesign the way in which ederal

    highway grants are established or projects on cer-

    tain new and existing roads. Under one version o

    this approach, designated projects to be undertaken

    without the coincident introduction o congestion

    pricing would be eligible or less than the high-est ederal nancial match that would otherwise

    be allowable. Rather than diminish the allowable

    match, another version o this approach would o-

    er a higher match, a premium, or designated types

    o projects implemented with congestion pricing.

    A dierent ederal match would be in recognition

    o the extra burden o highway maintenance and

    congestion costs that untolled roads create by stim-

    ulating excess demand, delays, and environmental

    emissions during peak periods. States and localities

    could opt out o the congestion pricing incentive,but would need to weigh the advantages o doing so

    against incentivized ederal unding as well as the

    loss o access to the signicant revenues available

    rom congestion pricing. This proposal also in-

    cludes mechanisms by which to mitigate the eects

    o congestion pricing on low-income people.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    9/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 7

    2.0. The Problem

    R

    esearch unded by the Federal Highway Ad-

    ministration (2005) and conducted by the

    Texas Transportation Institute (TTI) reportsthat urban trac congestion in 2005 caused the av-

    erage peak-period traveler to spend an extra thirty-

    eight hours o travel time and consume an addi-

    tional twenty-six gallons o uel a year, amounting

    to a cost o $710 per traveler (TTI 2007a). These

    statistics are part o a worsening trend. In all such

    places,

    trips take longer,

    congestion exists during more o the day,

    congestion aects weekend travel and ruralareas,

    congestion aects more personal trips and

    reight shipments, and

    trip travel times are increasingly unreliable.

    I current policies and trends continue, analysts

    oresee that by 2030 as many as eleven additional

    urban areas could reach or exceed todays level o

    congestion in Los Angeles, the nations most con-

    gested urban area (Hartgen and Fields 2006). The

    average traveler in Los Angeles spends an estimat-ed seventy-two hours a year stuck in trac (TTI

    2007a).1

    Although population growth, inexpensive down-

    town parking, urban sprawl, and inadequate inra-

    structure investment are correctly cited as causes o

    congestion, the way we chargeor, rather, the way

    we do not chargeor the use o roads and bridges

    is in act a central cause. To appreciate the point,

    consider the role that prices play in enabling the

    economy in general to unction without persistentshortages and queues. The price o a good or a

    service signals to prospective consumers the true

    economic cost o using up the scarce resources

    required in supplying it (the capital, the labor, andso on). Based on personal tastes and preerences,

    and within the limits o their disposable income,

    consumers establish their willingness, or unwilling-

    ness, to pay the true cost by sizing up whether or

    not the benets they will enjoy make paying the

    price worthwhile. I people are not willing to pay

    or all the washing machines available, or example,

    producers resources are quickly shited into the

    supply o other goods and services or which people

    are willing to pay.

    In this way, prices guide consumers to make mil-

    lions o individual cost-benet decisions every day,

    and thereby bring about the allocation o resources

    that achieves, more or less, an eciently unction-

    ing economy. In short, prices send cost signals to

    consumers who, through the benet-cost choices

    they make o what to buy and what not to buy, sig-

    nal back to producers how to deploy resources and

    avert persistent shortages, queues, and surpluses.

    Apart rom a handul o places around the country,there are no roadway prices to signal consumers

    about the real economic cost o their decisions to

    travel during congested times o day. It should be

    no surprise, thereore, that we witness an apparent

    shortage o road space yet little use o public transit.

    In deciding when and how to travel, people cer-

    tainly take into account their private costs, such as

    gas, oil, insurance, and so on. They also consider the

    congestion they expect to encounter. Travelers do

    not, however, consider the costs their trips impose

    on otherswhen they add to the congestion (Mohring1999). These costs are external to peoples trip-mak-

    1. By many measures, Los Angeles aces the most severe trac congestion in the nation. According to the most recent Urban MobilityReport rom the TTI, drivers in the greater Los Angeles region lost about 490 million hours due to congestion delays in 2005. About62 percent o the lane miles in greater Los Angeles were congested during the peak period, and about 86 percent o peak period traveloccurred in congested conditions. TTI estimates the cost o congestion in the greater Los Angeles regionin terms o wasted time andwasted uelat about $9.3 billion dollars annually. This represents a more-than-ourold increase rom 1985, when the annual cost (incurrent dollars) was estimated to be $2.2 billion.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    10/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    8 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    ing decisions; economists thus call them external

    costs.

    They include the economic value o time wasted

    in delayed and unreliable conditions, the extra gas

    and other vehicle operating costs o stop-and-godriving, and the environmental damage and related

    costs to human health. Although studies dier in re-

    lation to denitions and methods, recent estimates

    o external roadway costs vary rom $0.13 per ve-

    hicle mile to $0.29 per vehicle mile (HDR|HLB

    Decision Economics 2005; see also Small and Ve-

    hoe 2007, Chapter 3). Compared with the private

    costs o driving (about $0.52 per vehicle mile based

    on AAA 2007), external costs thus exceed private

    costs by some 25 to 56 percent. I the price o any

    other good or service were set so ar below its cost,it would surprise no one to nd that its demand

    routinely outstripped its supply and that there

    would be very low demand or substitutes.

    Time spent in trac jams is the maniestation o

    roadway supply alling short o the demand or

    travel. Delay is an economic cost because it means

    less time available or productive work as well as

    or nonwork activities that people value. Moreover,

    unreliable conditionswide day-to-day variation

    in the time needed to drive rom Point A to PointBlead people to guard against the risk o being

    late or work and appointments by leaving early.

    This time spent is at the expense o yet more time

    or productive work, as well as more time at home

    in the morning or amily or other personal busi-

    ness.

    For trucks, unreliable transit times are o special

    signicance because o just-in-time penalties built

    into many delivery contracts. A pattern o late de-

    liveries or the receivers o goods can lead them tobear the cost o holding extra inventoriesshock

    stocksto guard against the risk o material short-

    ages in just-in-time production systems (Shirley

    and Winston 2004).

    In 2005, autos and trucks lost an estimated 4.2 bil-

    lion hours to trac delays and to the eects o cush-

    ioning against the risk o being late. The monetaryequivalent value o these losses, when combined

    with the 2.9 billion gallons o uel wasted in stop-

    and-go conditions, amounted to an estimated $78

    billion lost during that year.2 Even with the exclu-

    sion o environmental costs, $78 billion equates to

    105 million weeks o vacation and 58 ully loaded

    supertankers (TTI 2007b).

    While statistics on the nationwide eects o

    congestion are indicative o its importance as a

    problem o national strategic signicance, the im-pacts o congestion on people and their well-being

    are elt locally. A recent analysis o trac in New

    York City nds that, even ater allowing or some

    congestion as part and parcel o a vibrant economy,

    congestion there has passed the tipping point

    (Partnership or New York City 2006), stripping the

    metropolitan economy o more than $13 billion a

    year, including about $6 billion in wasted time and

    workday productivity.

    The study reports that shippers who rely on pre-dictable pickups and deliveries in order to maintain

    low inventory costs (and to obtain value rom their

    investments in just-in-time technologies and busi-

    ness processes) hold costly shock stocks that reduce

    productivity and competitiveness. Trucking rms,

    which incur nancial penalties or late deliveries,

    cushion against the risk o such penalties by leav-

    ing earlier than they would under more reliable and

    predictable travel time conditions, thereby reduc-

    ing their productivity and competitiveness.

    Congestion imposes an economic burden on a wide

    range o industries. Those directly aected by con-

    2. Economists assign monetary-equivalent value to time based on actors such as wage rates (which refect the value o productive work done)and peoples willingness to pay to save time or nonwork purposes, including commuting and leisure activities. Recent studies have revealedthat the rate at which road users value reliable andpredictable journey times actually exceeds the rate at which they value improvements inaverage journey times almost threeold (Small, Noland, Chu, and Lewis 1999).

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    11/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 9

    TABLE 1

    The Cost Brden o Congestion on Indstry in the New York City Region (selected sectors)

    Indstry and

    type o congestion CBD Rest o

    cost eect Manhattan Manhattan Bron Brooklyn Qeens Richmond Nassa

    Retail indstry

    Reduction in revenue,

    Us$ million/year $99.5 $8.5 $1.2 $7.0 $7. $4.7 $20.9

    Increae in operationalcot, Us$ million/year $66.5 $7.8 $4. $15.6 $15.9 $4.8 $17.0

    Reduction in employment,

    FTE/year 41 5 -5 29 0 19 87

    Restarants

    Reduction in revenue,

    Us$ million/year $214.7 $7.4 $12. $22.0 $14.5 $1.0 $8.4

    Increae in operational

    cot, Us$ million/year $5.0 $0. $0.1 $0. $0.5 $0.1 $0.4

    Reduction in employment,FTE/year 2,054 71 -117 -210 -19 -9 80

    Arts & entertainment

    Reduction in revenue,

    Us$ million/year $181.7 $0.5 $11.6 $2. $21.7 $.0 $2.

    Reduction in employment,FTE/year 1,402 4 -89 -179 -167 -2 18

    Health care & social services

    Reduction in revenue,

    Us$ million/year $152.5 $26. $14.1 $44.7 $22.8 $7.7 $2.5

    Reduction in employment,FTE/year 1,626 280 151 477 24 82 250

    Constrction

    Reduction in revenue,Us$ million/year $280.6 $15.1 $28.8 $92.8 $20.9 $18.6 $78.5

    Increae in operational

    cot, Us$ million/year $4.1 $1.8 $.5 $11. $24.8 $2. $9.5

    Reduction in employment,FTE/year 1,142 61 117 78 80 76 20

    Manactring

    Reduction in revenue,

    Us$ million/year $488. $.2 $24.6 $12.8 $159.2 $.6 $91.7

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    12/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    10 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    Increae in operational

    cot, Us$ million/year $59. $0.4 $.0 $16.1 $19. $0.4 $11.1

    Reduction in employment,FTE/year 2,081 14 105 566 678 15 91

    Wholesale

    Increae in cot,Us$ million/year $688.1 $4.0 $17.0 $61.8 $70.0 $2.9 $52.4

    Total revenue/loUs$ million/yeara $1,62.5 $61.7 $4.8 $26.4 $62.9 $2.0 $20.7

    Increae in operatin

    cot, Us$ million/yeara $852.9 $14.4 $27.8 $105.0 $10.5 $10.5 $90.4

    Total jo lota 8,717 466 161 1,060 1,475 160 1,145

    source: Partnerhip or Ne Yor City 2006.

    Note: CbD = central uine ditrict; FTE = ull-time equivalent jo. Revenue and employment numer ith a neative in indicate ituation in hich conetion

    caue revenue or employment to increae due to the reditriution o trac.a. Total refect more ector than hon in the tale.

    gestion include the retail trades, restaurants, health

    care and social services, construction, manuactur-

    ing, wholesale trade, taxis, nancial and proes-

    sional services, the services and repair industry, and

    or-hire trucking. Table 1 summarizes the estimated

    cost burdens borne by a selection o these sectors.

    The impact o congestion on the retail, restau-

    rant, entertainment, and other consumption-based

    trades, or example, stems partly rom a reduction in

    trips or consumption purposes. By increasing thecost o traveling to such destinations, congestion

    deters some consumers rom using those services

    and causes others to use them less oten than they

    otherwise would. As a result, retailers earn less rev-

    enue and employ ewer workers. Congestion also

    adds to the logistics costs o retailers by reducing

    the reliability o delivery times or merchandise

    and supplies. This adds to costs by inhibiting the

    adoption o inventory-saving and other productiv-

    ity-enhancing strategies. Congestion imposes costs

    on the nancial and proessional services industries,

    due (inter alia) to the time spent by employees in

    highly congested conditions when traveling to

    business meetings. Frequently, proessional work-

    ers will guard against the risk o being late or miss-

    ing a meeting altogether by allowing extra time intheir travel schedules. Less congestion would make

    additional time available or productive work in the

    oce. In sum, the New York study nds that trac

    jams in the region add millions o dollars to produc-

    tion and distribution costs and erode the economy

    o nearly ty-ve thousand jobs.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    13/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 11

    2.1. Why Are Congestion Prices Rare onAmerican Roads?

    Congestion pricestolls that vary by time o day

    to refect the costs travelers impose on each other

    when electing to use a congested roadwayarerare in America; they apply to less than 1 percent

    o congested U.S. roadways. Congestion pricing is

    not rare or lack o know-how or technology. In-

    deed, dierent approaches and technologies have

    been developed or a wide range o dierent cir-

    cumstances. As shown in Box 1, tolls can be applied

    over an entire geographic network, on particular

    roads only, or on particular lanes.

    Nor is congestion pricing rare or lack o successul

    examples. Consider the SR-91 express lanes acilityin Caliornia. Opened in 1988, it is a our-lane, ten-

    mile toll road built in the median o the Riverside

    Freeway on the line between Orange and Riverside

    counties, and the Costa Mesa Freeway (SR-55).

    Users o SR-91 express lanes pay tolls rom pre-

    paid accounts using a transpondera pocket-sized

    radio transmission device mounted to the inside o

    the vehicles windshield. This electronic toll col-

    lection technology eliminates the need or travel-

    ers to stop and pay tolls at traditional tollbooths,

    thus helping acilitate the fow o trac on tolledlanes. One-way tolls or the ten-mile stretch vary

    rom $1.20 during o-peak periods to as much as

    $10.00 or travel during the busiest times o day.

    As shown in Figure 1, SR-91 results are impres-

    sive, with the priced lanes generating considerably

    higher speeds than the ree lanes.

    BOx 1

    Types o Congestion Prices Available toStates and Localities

    Areawide charges: Charges based on conges-tion level on all congested roads within a geo-

    graphic area. Some believe this approach to be

    the most eective means o reducing congestion

    and vehicle emissions.

    Variable charges on particlar roadways:

    Tolls administered to both roads and bridges,

    including rush hour ees on acilities that cur-

    rently are toll ree. Examples include 407 ETR

    (Toronto), Sanibel Bridge (Lee County, Florida),

    New Jersey Turnpike, and the Port Authority oNew York and New Jersey interstate crossings.

    Variably priced lanes and managed lanes:

    Variable tolls implemented on separated lanes

    within a highway, such as express toll lanes or

    high-occupancy toll (HOT) lanes. Examples

    include Interstate 15 (I-15), State Route 91 (SR-

    91), and I-680 (under development) in south-

    ern Caliornia; I-10 Katy Freeway (Houston);

    I-394 (Minneapolis); I-25 (Denver); and SR-

    167 (Washington state, our-year pilot).

    Cordon charges:Charges to drive within or into

    a congested area within a city. Examples include

    London (England), Stockholm (Sweden), Sin-

    gapore, Oslo, Trondheim, Bergen (Norway),

    San Francisco (Caliornia; study), and New York

    (New York; proposal).

    Zonal charges: Similar to cordon charging,

    but with adjacent charging zones. Examples in-

    clude trials in Trondheim (Norway), Helsinki(Finland), and Copenhagen (Denmark).

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    14/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    12 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    London (England) provides another example. A

    ee introduced in 2003 requires motorists to pay

    8.00 (about $16.00) to drive into central London

    on weekdays between 7:30 a.m. and 6:30 p.m. Some vehicles are exempt, including licensed taxis, mo-

    torcycles, vehicles used by people with disabilities,

    certain alternative uel vehicles, buses, and emer-

    gency vehicles. Since introduction o this ee, au-

    tomobile trac in central London has declined by

    a reported 20 percent, average trac speeds have

    increased 37 percent, and peak period congestion

    delays are down 30 percent or autos and 50 per-

    cent or buses. Importantly, net revenues (more

    than $100 million a year) rom congestion prices in

    London are used to nance increased public transitcapacity. Reports indicate that people who change

    their travel patterns due to the ee have transerred

    to public transit (Litman 2006).3 Other people

    change their routes to avoid central London, travel

    outside the charging period, or use taxis. Stockholm

    (Sweden) has since introduced a similar ee, with

    similar results.

    Congestion pricing in the United States is not rare

    or lack o unding to study it, experiment with it,

    or implement it: Congress rst set up a program to

    assist localities with local congestion pricing initia-

    tives in 1991. In addition, under the Urban Part-

    nerships Program established in 2006, the ederal

    government makes more than $1 billion available

    to localities or congestion management initiatives.

    Although the number o lane miles on which con-

    gestion pricing has been introduced remains pro-

    portionately very small, especially on existing roadsas distinct rom newly constructed roads, more

    than orty congestion pricing programs have been

    undertaken since 1991 with the support o ederal

    unds.

    3. The share o total trips made by car ell rom 12 to 10 percent between 2003 and 2005.

    source: Environmental Deene 2007.

    Average Trafc Speed on SR-91, Peak Hours Eastbound, Friday Afternoons 2004

    Congested General Purpose Lanes Toll Managed Lanes

    40

    50

    60

    70

    30

    20

    10

    0

    FIGuRE 1

    Recent Trafc Statistics or the SR-91 Epress Lane Facility

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    15/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 1

    2.2. A Political Impasse at the State andLocal Levels

    So why is congestion pricing rare? An important

    reason is political impasse at the state and local lev-

    els, especially when it comes to introducing conges-tion pricing on existing roads as opposed to the con-

    struction o new capacity. Voters dislike new taxes.

    Congestion prices are not taxes; they are prices that

    mirror real economic costs. But explaining the di-

    erence to voters is challenging. Compounding this

    conusion is the public perception that congestion

    prices constitute a double tax since existing roads

    have indeed been paid or with tax dollars. Impor-

    tantly, there also is concern about the risk o mak-

    ing poor households poorer, perhaps even driving

    some low-income households into poverty due tothe economic burden congestion tolls could place

    on them and the smaller market area over which

    poor householders could aord the costs o travel

    to jobs.

    Though understandable, these concerns, as this

    paper goes on to show, are either inaccurate or re-

    solvable through a range o policy approaches. And

    despite the political impasse, there is signicant

    evidence o emerging (latent) political support and

    consensus with regard to congestion pricing. Latentsupport, on its own, appears insucient however to

    overcome signicant grassroots opposition. In New

    York City, a mayoral plan to introduce congestion

    pricing or vehicles entering Manhattan won City

    Council approval. It did however ace an uphill bat-

    tle to gain grassroots political consensus and ulti-

    mately ailed to obtain the necessary approval rom

    the state legislature.4 An analysis o public opinion

    surveys conducted in November 2007 nds that a

    majority o surveys (56 percent) show support or

    tolling and road pricing. Opposition was encoun-

    tered in 31 percent o the surveys. Mixed results

    (i.e., neither majority support nor opposition) oc-

    curred in 13 percent o them (Zmud 2007). These

    results show that in many parts o the U.S., a wide

    gap exists between elected ocials perceptions o

    what the public thinks about tolling and road pric-ing and what public opinion actually is (Peters

    2008, 3). In London and Stockholm, broad-based

    support has indeed been achieved, albeit ater the

    politically unpopular decision to implement con-

    gestion pricing had been taken and people saw the

    results or themselves.

    That the nations transportation inrastructure is in

    trouble is not in doubt; nor is there much doubt

    that ailure to charge congestion tolls is a signicant

    source o the problem. We know, too, that charg-ing congestion prices is easible, that it would help

    optimize the use o existing transportation acilities

    in the short run, and that it would provide inorma-

    tion vital to optimizing the characteristics o such

    acilities in the long run (Mohring 1999). The op-

    timization o investment would occur as the prices

    o tolls signal which roadways have the highest level

    o demand.

    It seems almost certain that, with congestion pric-

    ing in place, ewer trips would be made by car dur-ing busy periods, more people would use public

    transit, and the allocation o investment resources

    between highways and transit would better refect

    the true transportation needs and preerences o

    travelers relative to the costs o satisying those

    needs. It is time or the ederal government to step

    in to help break the state and local political impasses

    that stand between congestion pricing and the re-

    alization o an ecient, sustainable, and aordable

    surace transportation system or the twenty-rst

    century.

    4. To understand the diculty in obtaining grassroots support or this proposal, see: Editorial, Reducing the cost o congestion,New YorkTimes, December 10, 2006; Editorial, Let NYC study pay-to-drive plan, Newsday.com, December 8, 2006; Clearing the air on tracproblem, Crains New York Business, December 10, 2006.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    16/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    14 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    3.1. Federal Reorm

    Notwithstanding the apparent political risk

    taken to introduce congestion pricing in

    London and Stockholm, making politically

    unpopular decisions in the hope that broad-based

    support will ollow is rare in the development o

    transportation policy. Nevertheless, the evidence

    and analysis outlined above indicates the latent po-

    litical acceptability o congestion pricing. A key to

    overcoming the political impasse at the state and

    local levels o government lies in policy innovation

    at the ederal level. To be sure, Congress and theexecutive branch have already displayed signi-

    cant leadership with innovative programs designed

    to promote and encourage local experimentation

    with, and implementation o, congestion pricing.

    The next step is or Congress to create powerul

    incentives that make the adoption o congestion

    pricing widely compelling at the local level.

    Congresss ability to establish such incentives ex-

    ists by virtue o the ederal-state relationship with

    regard to highway inrastructure investment. Al-though the execution and administration o trans-

    portation policy, planning, and investment in the

    United States belongs with state and local govern-

    ments, the ederal government plays a signicant

    nancial role. The interstate highway system and

    many other primary roads have been built and

    maintained with 90 percent ederal and 10 percent

    state and local unds. The signicant ederal nan-

    cial role in transportation brings with it a great deal

    o leverage over policy and planning at the state and

    local levels. In return or ederal highway dollars,the ederal government mandates planning require-

    ments, environmental impact analyses, saety stan-

    dards, restrictions on the size and weight o trucks

    that are allowed to use the roadways, and a range o

    other conditions that Congress and the executive

    branch deem to be in the national interest.

    Against this background, the main policy attributes

    o the existing ederal approach to congestion pric-ing are permissive and acilitating, but certainly not

    mandatory. One option going orward would thus

    be to add congestion pricing to the range o man-

    datory requirements or state and local receipt o

    ederal nancial assistance. A mandatory approach

    would be clear and straightorward to administer

    but would run counter to the trend in ederal policy

    o seeking to grant fexibility to states and localities

    to innovate and choose across the widest possible

    array o technological, planning, nancial, and pro-

    curement mechanisms.

    3.1.1 Proposal: Congestion Pricing Financial

    Incentive Program

    An alternative to mandatory application o the con-

    gestion pricing approach would be to redesign the

    way ederal highway grants are established to create

    a choice and an incentive or localities to introduce

    congestion pricing in association with projects in

    highly congested urban areas and congested inter-

    city routes. Under this approach, construction and

    major reconstruction projects with designated at-tributes would be eligible or less than the other-

    wise highest allowable ederal match i they are to

    be undertaken without the coincident introduction

    o congestion pricing. The reduction in allowable

    match would be determined by a method or or-

    mula that recognizes the external congestion costs

    that untolled roads create by stimulating excess

    demand and corresponding increases in delay, ve-

    hicle operating expenses, and environmental and

    accident costs. One practical way in which to es-

    tablish such a ormula would draw on analyticalevidence regarding the extent to which conges-

    tion pricing, by diminishing demand, reduces the

    cost o highway maintenance and expansion. For

    example, according to model-based scenario analy-

    ses by the Federal Highway Administration (2006),

    applying congestion tolls to all congested roads in

    3.0. A Proposal or Congestion Pricing

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    17/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 15

    the national highway system could reduce the cost

    to maintain the system by about 27 percent (U.S.

    Department o Transportation [DOT] 2006). Tak-

    ing this percentage as a hypothetical estimate (the

    DOT emphasizes the very preliminary nature o

    the estimate) o the amount by which the absence ocongestion pricing increases the burden o highway

    inrastructure investment on ederal resources, the

    ederal matching ratio would be reduced propor-

    tionately: an 80 percent match would be reduced to

    about 58 percent, a 75 percent match to 55 percent,

    and so on. States and localities would still be ree to

    choose the lower match and the option o not insti-

    tuting congestion pricing, but would need to weigh

    the advantages o abstaining against the reduction

    in ederal unds, as well as the loss o access to the

    revenues rom congestion pricing.

    An alternative to creating an incentive by reducing

    the base ederal matching ratio or projects without

    congestion pricing would be to institute a higher

    match instead. This might be viewed as less disrup-

    tive to the present equity characteristics o the ed-

    eral program. An approach that lies between these

    two alternatives is also possible, o course.

    In addition to the incentive outlined above, this

    proposal calls or Congress to direct the DOT andthe IRS cooperatively to design a model template

    or a progressive reundable mobility tax credit

    (PRMT) program or states and localities to adopt

    in conjunction with congestion pricing. Since the

    allocation o toll revenue between tax credits, direct

    rebates, and inrastructure investment must be de-

    termined and administered locally to align with local

    circumstances and preerences, the model template

    would be a guide to states and localities or them to

    implement as they see t. As such, the PRMT tem-

    plate design would provide wide local latitude with

    regard to the choice o income thresholds, program

    qualications, and other program parameters. At

    the same time, however, the PRMT model would

    provide states and localities sucient technical and

    administrative specicity, and any necessary ederalauthorities, to acilitate ull-scale implementation.

    In ollowing this recommendation, Congress can

    help ensure that states and localities have the means

    to put in place administrative machinery through

    which to help protect low-income individuals and

    other disadvantaged groups. The PRMT would be

    nanced rom a portion o toll revenues and thus

    would be scally neutral.

    A considerable amount o work is needed to trans-

    late the hypothetical approach given above into apractical basis or policy. As discussed next, Con-

    gress should direct the DOT to establish the exact

    method or ormula by which dierential matching

    ratios are to be established. The DOT would also

    determine the class o projects to which the incen-

    tive plan will apply. The Internal Revenue Service

    (IRS), in collaboration with the DOT, would be

    directed to develop the model PRMT. Congress

    would remove ederal prohibitions on the applica-

    tion o congestion pricing to existing roadways.5

    3.1.2 Enactment: Congestion Pricing Financial

    Incentive Program

    Due or reauthorization in 2009, SAFETEA-LU

    (see 1 above) is the principal legislative mecha-

    nism through which Congress establishes national

    transportation law. As part o the reauthorization

    process, Congress should establish that

    by 2020, a ederal nancial congestion pricing

    incentive program is in place or a designated

    5. Importantly, such a prohibition presently applies to the interstate highway system. Some steps in the direction o removing such restric-tions have been taken already. The Interstate Highway System Construction Toll Pilot Program authorizes up to three acilities on theinterstate system to toll or the purpose o nancing the construction o new interstate highways. A state or an interstate compact o statesmay submit a single candidate project under this program. Each applicant must demonstrate that nancing the construction o the acilitywith the collection o tolls is the most ecient and economical way to advance the project. The state must agree not to enter into a non-compete agreement with a private party, under which the state would be prevented rom improving or expanding the capacity o publicroads in the vicinity o the toll acility to address conditions resulting rom trac diverted to nearby roads rom the toll acility. There is nospecial unding authorized or this program. Interstate maintenance unds may not be used on a acility or which tolls are being collectedunder this program.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    18/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    16 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    category o highway projects associated with

    both new and existing capacity; and that

    by 2015, the DOT will have established regula-

    tions and guidelines enabling states and locali-

    ties to begin planning or 2020 implementation;and

    by 2015, the IRS will have designed the pro-

    gram template or a PRMT, and put in place

    the necessary authorities to enable its imple-

    mentation by states and localities.

    3.2. Reglatory Direction to the DOT and the

    IRS

    In enacting the congestion pricing incentive program,

    Congress would direct the DOT to promulgate bySeptember 2013 a Notice o Proposed Rulemaking

    establishing the specic planning and implementa-

    tion requirements or the Congestion Pricing Finan-

    cial Incentive Program. As a means o indicating con-

    gressional intent, ederal agencies would be directed

    to address seven matters through regulatory and

    administrative action.

    1. The DOT would dene the method or ormula

    by which dierential matching ratios are to be

    established. The DOT would also dene themanner in which incentive program unding

    relates to specic projects within the Statewide

    Transportation Improvement Plans (STIP) that

    provide the basis or ederal unding approvals.

    It is not contemplated here, or example, that

    matching unds or the entire STIP would hinge

    on the treatment o projects that pertain only to

    congested roads.

    2. The DOT would dene the attributes o project

    applications that would deem them to be subjectto the nancial incentive program. Attributes to

    be considered would include the extent o exist-

    ing congestion, and the extent to which the ap-

    plicant road or (roads) would provide indepen-

    dent utility as a congestion-priced acility.

    3. The DOT would also establish principles and

    guidelines regarding the level o congestiontolls with due regard or both the economic

    cost o congestion and the eect o such tolls on

    the diversion o trac to unpriced roads. The

    DOT should enable and encourage project ap-

    plicants to set balanced rates, with due regard

    or evidence that tolls set to mirror the ull cost

    o congestion can risk diverting so much trac

    to unpriced routes that the aggregate economic

    costs o travel over the entire network would be

    greater than those roads with no tolls.6

    4. The DOT would ensure both that states and lo-

    calities provide reasonable alternatives to priced

    roads, and that they apply a stipulated minimum

    or reasoned percentage o the revenues rom

    congestion pricing to monetary reimbursement

    or disadvantaged groups and investment in pub-

    lic transit. Others point out that the demand or

    transit, which is likely to rise signicantly in some

    localities with the advent o congestion pricing,

    will automatically reveal the appropriate extent

    o new investment and generate sucient rev-enues to nance it. The DOT rulemaking needs

    to strike a balance between such approaches,

    while leaving maximum easible fexibility or

    local choice and innovation (see 5, this paper).

    5. The DOT would also provide a ramework with-

    in which states and localities are to adopt com-

    mon technology platorms or toll collection to

    ensure regional and national interoperability in

    the use o congestion-priced highways. Similarly,

    automobile and truck manuacturers should begiven rules by which to make provisions or all

    new automobiles and trucks sold ater January

    6. Mohring (1999), or example, reports that congestion tolls on expressways in the Twin Cities would need to be set at about 25 percent othe ull economic cost o congestion to ensure that spillover trac would not cancel the eciency gains o congestion pricing. He alsoreports that Singapore overdid it: Congestion outside the cordon was so great that, despite ree fow within it, travel times per bus orauto trip to central area destinations did not change (194).This problem has not been experienced in the case o Londons cordon pricingprogram (see 2.1, this paper).

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    19/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 17

    2015 to be equipped with onboard electronic de-

    vices compatible with the common platorms to

    be employed at the state and local levels.

    6. For roads nanced with a combination o ederal

    and private sector nancing (i.e., public-privatepartnerships), the DOT regulations would stipu-

    late the requirement that sucient revenues be

    reserved or compensation programs and that,

    where revenues rom congestion pricing lead to

    private sector prots that exceed economic rates

    o return, such excess revenues are to be made

    available or public reinvestment.

    7. The IRS and the DOT would collaboratively

    develop the detailed model template or PRMT,

    including the means by which to set incomethreshold provisions, eligibility qualications,

    administrative procedures, and ederal authori-

    ties to enable states and localities to implement a

    program with local discretion as to actual income

    cut-os and other program criteria.

    3.3. General Applicability o the Proposal

    Although we cannot orecast the take-up o the

    proposed congestion-pricing nancial-incentive

    program, we can examine its scope o application

    under book-end conditions. I the proposal were tolead to congestion pricing on all roads with conges-

    tion above a 70 percent volume-to-capacity ratio,

    pricing would apply to 15.3 percent o all road mile-

    age (including interstates, other reeways, arterials,

    and collectors) and cover 41.1 percent o all vehicle

    miles traveled (at 2005 trac levels). The more-de-

    tailed perspective on road mileage in Table 2 and

    on travel in Table 3 indicates a similar pattern. Just

    22.3 percent o the interstate highway systems road

    mileage is seriously congested (with the volume-to-

    capacity ratio exceeding 95 percent), but these roadshandle nearly 40 percent o vehicle miles traveled

    on the interstate system (see nal column o Table

    3).

    3.4. State and Local Reorm

    The ederal nancial incentive program outlined

    above provides or a ederal policy ramework and

    regulatory oundation, but leaves much to be done

    at the state and local levels. Importantly, there is

    no need to deer the implementation o congestionpricing programs to the 2020 deadline, especially

    on congested roads that are not part o the ederal

    system. In addition,

    states with legislative prohibitions against the

    implementation o tolls that might wish to take

    advantage o the incentive program need to take

    steps to remove such prohibitions;

    states and localities need to begin now to evalu-

    ate alternative congestion pricing mechanismsand to establish those o relevance and best value

    to their various local and regional circumstanc-

    es, taking ull advantage o ederal programs

    designed to assist in that endeavor;

    states and localities need to begin now to

    engage the general public, stakeholder groups,

    and community opinion leaders regarding the

    nature o congestion pricing and the kind o

    opportunities and issues entailed in the ederal

    incentive program; and

    states and localities need to begin now to assess

    the range o ways and means by which to help

    mitigate the negative eects o congestion pric-

    ing on disadvantaged groups, partly through the

    development o a PMRT (see 5).

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    20/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    18 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    TABLE 2

    Road Mileage by Level o Congestion (as Measred by Volme-to-Capacity Ratio or urban Roads),2005

    Road type Percentage o road length mile in road category by VC Percent ototal road

    Le than 0.710.79 0.800.95 greater mile y Percent o0.71 than unctional coneted

    0.95 cateory road mile

    Intertate 48.1 10.8 18.8 22. 5. 17.1

    Other reeay 6.0 8.0 1.5 15.5 .6 8.2

    Other principal arterial 81. 6. 7.5 4.9 20.9 24.4

    Minor arterial 86. 4.2 4.5 5.0 4.4 29.5

    Collector 90.7 2. 2.8 4.1 5.9 20.8

    source: Author calculation uin Federal Hihay Adminitration 2005.

    TABLE 3

    Share o Travel (Measred in Vehicle Miles) on urban Roadways, Categorized by Volme-to-CapacityRatio

    Road type Percentage o travel volme, by volme-to-capacity ratio

    greater

    Le than 0.710.79 0.800 .95 than0.71 0.95

    Intertate 27. 10.9 2.0 8.8

    Other reeay 6.1 8.8 21.0 4.1

    Other principal arterial 71.8 8.4 10.7 9.2

    Minor arterial 77.9 4.7 8.6 8.9

    Collector 79.8 .5 8.0 8.6

    source: baed on FHwA run on hihay ection in the Hihay Perormance Monitorin sytem (HPMs) dataae.

    Note: The volume o trac ued to calculate percentae hare in the lat column include local trac. Minor arterial and collector have een comined.

    VC = volume to capacity.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    21/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 19

    B

    y making people aware o the ull economic

    costs o their travel choices, the widespread

    application o congestion pricing would en-courage roadway users to determine whether the

    benets o using the road at busy times o the day

    are worth the ull economic implications o doing

    so. Many would continue to use the newly tolled

    roads. Some would change to alternative routes,

    change their schedule, switch to another mode such

    as public transit, or ride a bicycle or walk. Some

    would change their mind about making the trip or

    perhaps combine it with another trip. Such changes

    in behavior would help optimize the use o exist-

    ing transportation acilities in the short run, andprovide inormation and revenue to help optimize

    investment in the long run (Mohring 1999). As a

    result, the nations highways and transit systems

    would be more eective, more economically e-

    cient, and more nancially sustainable.

    4.1. EectivenessAnticipating the quantitative eects o congestion

    pricing on travel and trac behavior is both ana-

    lytically dicult and dependent on the degree to

    which states and localities would adopt it under theproposed ederal incentive program, yet evidence

    rom actual experience and analytical models is

    uniorm in suggesting that journey speeds, travel

    times, and travel time reliability would improve.Based on a model that synthesizes various strands

    o empirical evidence, the analysis reported in Table

    4 indicates that average speeds on the nations most

    severely congested roads might increase, on aver-

    age, between 11 and 16 percent ater the introduc-

    tion o congestion pricing. On the most congested

    interstates and reeways, improvements in speed

    would likely be even greater. These results depend

    on estimates o toll rates and the elasticity o de-

    mand or highway travel when those tolls cause the

    cost o travel to rise.

    Toll rates are calculated to refect the delay cost one

    driver driving one mile imposes on all other drivers

    on the same road at the same time. The delay costs

    depend on the level o congestion on a given road at

    a given time and the value o time lost, which I es-

    timate at between $18 and $40 per hour.7 I assume

    the elasticity o demand or highway travel is in the

    range o 0.4 to 0.8.

    While signicant in relation to current trac con-ditions, the eects suggested above are likely con-

    4.0. Eects, Benefts, and Costs o Reorm

    TABLE 4

    Estimated Impact o Congestion Pricing on Trafc Volme and Speed on Interstates and Freeways

    dring Peak Periods with Volme-to-Capacity Ratio above 0.95 (percent)

    Trafc and speed Baseline elasticity and Alternative elasticity andvale o time assmption vale o time assmptions

    Increae in peed +11 +16

    Reduction in vehicle mile

    o hihay travel 12 19

    source: Adapted rom HDR|HLb Deciion Economic 2005.

    Note: baeline aumption place the value o time at $18 per hour and elaticity o demand or hihay travel at -0.4. The alternative aumption place the value o

    time at $40 per hour and the elaticity o demand or hihay travel at -0.8. Conetion pricin i aumed to e applied on Intertate and reeay ith volume-to-

    capacity ratio aove 0.7. The etimated eect on trac peed on all Intertate and reeay ith volume-to-capacity ratio o 0.7 and aove i +7 percent and +10

    percent repectively, or the to aumption cenario. The etimated eect o conetion pricin on vehicle mile o hihay travel on Intertate and reeay ith

    volume-to-capacity ratio o 0.7 and aove i -10 percent and -16 percent repectively, or the to aumption cenario.

    7. The wide range o values or time refects evidence that the empirically measured metric value o time is up to three times the prevail-ing wage rate when travel times are not only high but also widely variable rom day-to-day and thus especially hard or people to predict(Small, Noland, Chu and Lewis 1999).

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    22/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    20 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    servative, understating potential improvements in

    speed and overstating the potential reduction in the

    volume o travel. This is because the model does

    not mirror the dynamics o trac volume and travel

    time under the most severely congested conditions

    (wherein at certain times tracin the absence ocongestion pricingcomes to a virtual standstill).8

    This is indeed a problem with traditional analyti-

    cal transportation models. Presently, a great deal o

    research eort is going into improving the state o

    the art o analytic models.

    These results are similar to those obtained by

    Mohring and Anderson (as cited in Mohring 1999)

    in their simulations o congestion pricing in the

    Twin Cities. They nd that putting tolls on all con-

    gested roads would reduce expressway vehicle milesby 19 percent, and nonexpressway vehicle miles by

    8 percent.

    The discussion above pertains to the change in travel

    on highways during busy periods: the change in the

    total volume o travel will depend on the extent to

    which those who reduce their use o highways dur-

    ing peak times shit to other times o day, or to other

    modesin particular to public transit. The extent

    to which a decline in total travel is mitigated will

    depend importantly on the use o congestion pric-ing revenues to invest in additional transit capacity.

    A strong program o transit investment could go ar

    toward minimizing the disruption o daily lie that

    might otherwise arise with congestion pricing.

    4.2. Economic Efciency Although the quantitative estimates vary widely,

    economic theory, analysis, and evidence rom eld

    applications point to the same thing: a more eco-

    nomically ecient transportation system.

    The immediate economic eciency benets o road

    pricing arise in the orm o time savings to roadway

    users, reductions in vehicle operating costs, ewer

    collisions and related accident costs, and improved

    environmental conditions. In the longer term, we

    can expect less pressure to build highway capacity,

    more cost-eective highway investment decisions

    (due to the way prices help signal where investment

    is most needed and worthwhile), and a level playingeld or transit, resulting in a better balance o in-

    vestment between highway construction and public

    transit.

    The costs o congestion pricing include the capital

    and lie-cycle expenses o toll collection and admin-

    istration; and the loss o economic and social value

    incurred by highway users in various categories.

    Such groups include

    highway users who cut back the total number ojourneys they make,

    highway users who adopt new activity schedules

    they nd less convenient,

    highway users who switch to transit or other

    modes o travel (like walking) that they preer

    less than driving,

    highway users who make shorter journeys than

    beore,

    highway users who divert to auto routes they

    preer less because they are more circuitous or

    inconvenient because o intersections and traclights, and

    highway users who experience increased conges-

    tion on roads to which people divert in order to

    avoid tolls.

    Even a partial analysis o the benets o conges-

    tion pricing in relation to a more comprehensive

    examination o costs indicates a strong likelihood

    o a quantitatively signicant gain in economic e-

    ciency. Employing the same model and assumptions

    as those used above in assessing trac impacts inTable 4, Table 5 compares the estimated economic

    benets due to time savings and reduced accidents

    to the loss o value to highway users who divert to

    8. This point pertains to the diculty modelers have in representing the backward-bending relationship between trac volume and traveltime during periods o hypercongestion. Indeed, the model underlying Table 4 assumes a monotonically increasing relationship betweentravel volume and travel time per trip.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    23/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 21

    other times o day, other routes, or other modes

    and the costs o toll collection and administration.

    The analysis indicates net benets, over a twenty-

    year period, o $113 billion. By the twentieth year

    o the program, the ratio o benets to costs is an

    estimated 2.7:1.0 ($2.70 in benets or each $1.00in cost).

    Though not dissimilar rom other benet-cost as-

    sessments o congestion pricing, the estimated e-

    ciency gain (net benet) given above almost cer-

    tainly understates the gain likely to ollow rom the

    introduction o nationwide congestion pricing or

    our reasons.9 First (and as stated above) the model

    does not mirror the dynamics o trac volume and

    travel time under the most severely congested con-

    ditions.

    Second, the gures in Table 5 do not account or

    reduced uel costs, reductions in environmental

    emissions, and savings that might arise rom a re-

    duction in pressure to build new highway capacity

    9. See, or example, Mohring and Andersons analysis o congestion pricing in the Twin Cities (in Mohring 1999).

    TABLE 5

    Time Savings and Accident Cost Savings rom Congestion Pricing Relative to the Loss o EconomicVale (Consmer Srpls) or those Priced O Roads (Interstates and Freeways with Volme-to-Ca-

    pacity Ratio above 0.7)

    Economic benefts and costs Year 1 o Year 20 ocongestion pricing congestion pricing

    Benefts (u.S. billions, 2002 dollars)

    1 Travel Time savin to Road Uer ho stayon the Road and Accident Cot savin $1.68 $26.84

    Costs (u.S. billions, 2002 dollars)

    2 Lo in Economic Value to Road Uer ho Reduce theNumer o Trip They Tae or Divert to Other Time

    o Day, Other Road or Other Mode $0.70 $2.

    Cot o Toll Collection $6.20 $7.60

    4 Total Cot: (2)+() $6.90 $9.9

    5 Net benet: (1)-(4) $6.78 $16.91

    Net beneft (net present vale) over 20 years (7 percent discont rate) $113 billion

    source: Adapted rom HDR|HLb Deciion Economic 2005.

    Note: Time avin repreent $4.8 illion (5 percent) o total enet in Year 1 hile the ocial enet rom accident reduction account or $8.9 illion (65 percent).

    by the tentieth year, time avin and accident cot avin account or 44 percent and 56 percent, repectively, o total enet. Time avin are proaly

    undertated due to the implied verion o the underlyin peed-fo relation ued. Reearch i onoin in relation to thi iue.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    24/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    22 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    due to the reduced peak period demand. Analy-

    sis presented in the DOTs (2006) report on the

    conditions and perormance o the nations high-

    ways and transit systems reports that universal

    congestion pricing, by improving the perormance

    o current highway system, could signicantlyreduce the level o uture highway investment that

    would be required to maintain or improve the

    condition o our highways. The DOT report in-

    dicates that applying congestion tolls to all o the

    congested roads in the system could reduce the cost

    to maintain the system by $21.6 billion per year, or

    27.5 percent, leaving capital needs at $57.2 billion,

    well below the current level o capital spending.

    Third, eciency gains are probably underesti-

    mated in Table 5 due to exclusion o the possibleeect o congestion pricing on the quality o u-

    ture investment decisions. The proound linkage

    between economically correct prices and the qual-

    ity o resource allocation and investment decisions

    means that congestion pricing could well give rise

    to better highway and transit investment decisions

    going orward. Prices send better signals to trans-

    portation planners as to where capacity expansion

    is most critical.

    The ourth reason why the estimated twenty-yeareciency gain o $113 billion given in Table 5

    might be understated is that it ignores the impact o

    longer-run changes in consumer behavior, such as

    the possibility that travelers would lobby employ-

    ers or widespread introduction o staggered work-

    hours in order to avoid congestion prices during

    peak periods, and would alter the pattern o their

    residential location choices in avor o shorter work

    trips and higher density (less automobile-intensive)

    living patterns. A study by Langer and Winston

    (2008) reports as ollows:

    Based on a sample o the ninety-eight largest Met-

    ropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs) in the nation, we

    nd that ecient road pricing would generate $120

    billion in annual revenues (2000 dollars), while re-

    ducing the value o the annual fow o services rom

    housing $80 billion (2000) dollars, thus generating

    an annual net benet o $40 billion. Our estimate

    o the benets o congestion pricing is considerably

    greater than previous estimates that do not account

    or adjustments in land use and represents a rst

    step toward accounting ully or road pricings ben-

    ets. We conclude that policymakers should rec-ognize that road pricing mitigates congestion and

    improves the quality in lie in a metropolitan area

    by improving land use.

    Langer and Winstons estimate o $40 billion

    annually in net benets rom congestion pricing

    radically exceeds the estimated twenty-year net

    benet o $113 billion reported in Table 5.

    4.3. Eqity

    While the discussion above indicates that con-gestion pricing is likely to generate a gain in the

    eciency o the road system, it does not account

    or the increase in driving costs that tolls impose

    and the implications or individuals. In the cost-

    benet analysis in Table 5, toll payments are treated

    as a transer o resources rather than as a cost to

    society. However, this social cost-benet analysis

    does not take into account the eects o toll pay-

    ments on individuals. For some the value o time

    savings rom reduced congestion is greater than the

    amount o the toll, but or others congestion pric-ing would leave them worse o. Proessor Robin

    Lindsey states it thus:

    Tolling raises drivers private costs, as indeed

    it must i travel is curtailed. The revenue rom the

    toll accrues to the toll-road operator, which is usu-

    ally assumed to be a government agency. Unless

    the government uses the revenue to expand road

    capacity, to improve an alternative orm o trans-

    port, to reduce other user charges, or to provide

    rebates to drivers in some lump-sum ashion, driv-ers end up worse o (Lindsey 2006).

    But we also know the ollowing rom Mohring:

    That tolls would eliminate the deadweight [e-

    ciency] losses rom unpriced congestion and lower

    the time cost o still-made trips guarantees that

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    25/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 2

    increased toll revenues would exceed consumer

    losses. Hence, in principle, a compensation system

    or losers could be ound that would not only leave

    them better o, but also provide unds or the high-

    way authority to perorm good works (Mohring

    1999, 186187).

    In other words, while congestion pricing dispro-

    portionately hurts certain drivers with low time

    savings, especially low-income drivers, the govern-

    ment could use the revenue rom the tolls, and oth-

    er transers i necessary, to ully oset any negative

    distributional impact and leave everyone better o.

    I toll revenue alone is not enough to ully com-

    pensate or consumer losses, the government can

    use the toll revenue to at least partially oset these

    eects. I discuss using revenues rom congestionpricing to compensate or consumer losses in 5.

    4.4. Financial ContetProjected toll revenues rom congestion pricing

    can be placed in a nancial context by compar-

    ing them with DOTs estimated requirements or

    highway investment over the next two decades. One

    preliminary estimate o toll revenues rom apply-

    ing tolls on all congested interstates and reeways

    places them at about $105 billion annually (in con-

    stant 2002 dollars; HDR|HLB Decision Econom-ics 2005).According to the DOTs report (2006) on

    conditions and perormance, the average annual

    cost to maintain highways (and bridges) or the

    twenty-year period 200524 is an estimated $78.8

    billion (in 2004 dollars). These gures represent

    the estimated level o investment by all levels o

    government required both to maintain the existing

    level o bridge deciencies in constant dollar terms

    and to keep the physical condition and operational

    perormance o the highway system at a level su-

    cient to prevent average highway user costs (in-

    cluding travel time costs, vehicle operating costs,and collision costs) rom rising above the existing

    level in constant dollar terms. Congestion prices

    would not only provide signicant revenues to -

    nance these requirements but would also reduce

    the cost o these requirements by lowering demand

    or highways and reducing their wear and tear. For

    transit, the National Surace Transportation Policy

    and Revenue Commission (2007) puts average an-

    nual investment requirements in the range o $21

    billion to $32 billion annually. Estimated revenues

    rom congestion prices could help nance these re-quirements as well.

    The DOT (2006) report also gives the average

    annual maximum economic investment level or

    highways and bridges or the twenty-year period

    200524. This value, estimated to be $131.7 billion

    (in 2004 dollars), represents the level o investment

    by all levels o government required to implement

    all the highway and bridge improvements judged in

    the DOT model to be cost-benecial improvements

    on highways and bridges. As indicated earlier, theDOT nds that congestion pricing would, by im-

    proving the perormance o highways and bridges,

    reduce total investment requirements. Thus even

    under a maximum economic investment scenario,

    the revenues rom congestion pricing are relatively

    signicant.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    26/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    24 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    =$100,00

    0

    10

    0

    1

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    8

    9

    AverageAnn

    ualExpenditurePerHouseholdon

    C

    ongestionTolls,

    dollars

    Household Income

    AverageAnnualExpenditurePerHouseholdon

    Conges

    tionTollsasPercentofIncome

    2,500

    2,000

    1,500

    1,000

    500

    0

    Average Annual Expenditure Per Household on Congestion Tolls as % of IncomeAverage Annual Expenditure Per Household on Congestion Tolls, dollars

    I

    ntroducing congestion pricing would increase

    the eciency o the road network, but additional

    steps need to be taken to ensure that benets arebroadly shared. The immediate eect o congestion

    pricing would be to penalize those who pay the tolls

    or take ewer road trips to avoid the tolls. This e-

    ect would, moreover, be regressivenamely, it

    would be inversely related to the incomes o those

    aected, as can be seen in Figure 2 and Table 6. 10

    I states and localities eventually adopt congestion

    pricing on all congested interstates and reeways(those where the ratio o volume to capacity exceeds

    70 percent), Figure 2 indicates that additional out-

    lays would be proportionately higher or lower-in-

    come households.

    10. A correlation between income and the requency o use o roads with congestion prices is evident is surveys o users o the SR-91 expresslane acility. They show that commuters in the high-income group (those earning more than $100,000 a year) are slightly more than twiceas likely as commuters in the low-income group (earning less than $25,000 a year) to be requent toll lane users (23 versus 10 percent):high-income users are about hal as likely as low-income users to be nonusers (37 versus 73 percent).

    FIGuRE 2

    Income Distribtional Conseqences o Congestion Pricing on Congested Roads in urbanized Areas

    source: Author etimate aed on 2001 National Houehold Travel survey and an averae conetion chare o $0.25 per mile. Fiure plotted in thi ure are hon

    in Tale 6.

    5.0. Distribtional Impacts and Methods o Redress

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    27/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 25

    TABLE 6

    Income Distribtional Impact o Congestion Charges on Interstates and Freeways with Volme-to-Capacity Ratio above 0.7

    Gross annal Annal hosehold Annal hosehold Annal cost ohosehold income ependitre on ependitre on compensation or

    congestion charges congestion congestion charges

    per hosehold charges as a to hoseholds

    percentage o

    annal income

    (Billions o 2007 dollars)

    < $5,000 $428.55 8.6% $1.0

    $5,000$9,999 $655.28 8.7% $.4

    $10,000$14,999 $622.0 5.0% $2.9

    $15,000$19,999 $90.49 5.% $5.

    $20,000$24,999 $1,061.29 4.7% $5.1

    $25,000$29,999 $1,198.90 4.4% $7.9

    $0,000$4,999 $1,4.4 4.1% $5.8

    $5,000$9,999 $1,50.65 4.1% $10.0

    $40,000$44,999 $1,540.55 .6% $4.94

    $45,000$49,999 $1,70.82 .6% $9.61

    $50,000$54,999 $1,858.29 .5% $4.80

    $55,000$59,999 $1,890.05 .% $8.47

    $60,000$64,999 $1,871.12 .0% $.57

    $65,000$69,999 $1,950.9 2.9% $6.2

    $70,000$74,999 $2,24.0 2.9% $.58

    $75,000$79,999 $2,146.45 2.8% $5.98

    $80,000$99,999 $2,248.22 2.5% $11.

    > = $100,000 $2,277.41 1.8% $18.92

    Total $41.4

    source: Author etimate, aed on data rom 2001 National Houehold Travel survey and aumption in the note.Note: Aumption are (1) the percentae o vehicle mile o travel (VMT) in uran area i equal to 55 percent o total VMT (aumption aed on 2001 Hihay

    Perormance Monitorin sytem (HPMs) run otained rom FHwA); (2) the percentae o VMT in conetion condition exceedin VC o 0.7 i equal to 41 percent(aumption aed on 2001 HPMs run otained rom FHwA); and () the expenditure on conetion cot include a chare o $0.25 per mile or all mile driven in

    coneted condition. Annual compenation i calculated a the averae expenditure on conetion chare in Column 2, multiplied y the numer o houehold in

    income racet cateory. Income roupin hon refect 2001 condition, herea toll paid refect 2007 price.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    28/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    26 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    One way in which to help redress the regressivity

    o congestion pricing would be to reimburse house-

    holds below a designated income level or some or

    all o the nancial losses they incur. The third (last)

    column o Table 6 estimates the annual cost o such

    an approach. Since the gures in Table 6 assumeexisting travel rates (i.e., no economic losses rom

    ewer trips, diversion to more circuitous routes and

    so on), the costs shown in column three might be

    sucient to compensate or both tolls paid by low

    income people who pay them and economic losses

    or those priced o. A major problem with this ap-

    proach, however, is that it would destroy the incen-

    tives to drive less or at less busy times. One way in

    which to minimize such incentive-blunting eects

    is to oer a degree o tax relie to lower income

    households that pay tolls rather than compensatingthem or the ull amount o the tolls they pay. This

    approach would also allow a share o the available

    revenues rom congestion tolls to be invested in

    transportation improvements.

    Indeed, investing congestion pricing revenues in

    improved alternatives to highway transportation is

    an important acet o any plan to help alleviate the

    distributional consequences o congestion pricing.

    Options include

    directing toll revenues or particular transit

    projects,

    establishing minimum quality standards or

    alternative ree routes as a precondition to

    imposing tolls, and

    establishing programs to encourage rms to

    permit fexible working hours, nancing the

    administration o ride-matching, ride-sharing

    programs, and the like.

    Whereas total revenues rom tolls are likely to besucient to mitigate the most egregious social

    costs, there is no economic rule by which to ascer-

    tain the allocation o such revenues best suited to

    alleviating problems or disadvantaged groups. The

    literature oers various approaches. Small (1992)

    proposes an allocation o one-third in monetary

    reimbursement to trip makers, one-third to oset

    general taxes presently used to und transporta-

    tion services, and one-third or new transportation

    services (transit, roads, or both). DeCorla-Souza

    (2004) proposes a scheme wherein tolls would be

    exempted or designated user groups (such as high-

    occupancy vehicles [HOVs]). In his plan, 70 percento net toll revenues would be employed or roadway

    and transit capital improvements, and 20 percent

    o net revenue would go to cash reimbursements

    against tolls and transit ares incurred by low-in-

    come travelers. Goodwin (1989) proposes a division

    o a one-third reduction in existing taxes; one-third

    in the construction o new roads, the improvement

    o existing roads, or the improvement o roadway

    maintenance standards; and one-third to improve

    public transport services. Goodwins suggestion is

    thus that about one-third o toll revenues wouldgo to direct reimbursement while ully two-thirds

    would be steered to indirect investment in mitigat-

    ing social costs through improved roads and tran-

    sit. Both Small and Goodwin recommend their ap-

    proach as being easy or the public to understand,

    and being a reasonable basis or widespread public

    support and consensus. These two attributes are

    also attributes o a compensation and mitigation

    program to which states and localities should pay

    particular attention.

    Under the proposal or reorm presented in this

    paper, Congress would stipulate that steps be taken

    to alleviate problems or disadvantaged groups, and

    would direct the DOT and the IRS to establish a

    model program or state or local implementation

    o a PRMT, along with specic guidelines, admin-

    istrative mechanisms, and authorities or doing so.

    The principal aim o the proposed congestion pric-

    ing policy ramework is to introduce the incentives

    needed to acilitate an eciently operating high-

    way system while ensuring that congestion pricingprogram is as equitable as possible. In particular,

    the policy ramework seeks to avoid leaving disad-

    vantaged groups worse o, such as groups with low

    incomes and people without access to alternative

    means o getting about. Congress would direct the

    DOT and IRS cooperatively to design the PRMT

    model program or states and localities to adopt

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    29/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    www.HAMILTONPROJECT.ORg|

    JULY 2008 27

    in conjunction with congestion pricing. The allo-

    cation o toll revenue between tax credits, direct

    rebates, and inrastructure investment must be de-

    termined locally so as to align with local circum-

    stances and preerences. As such, the PRMT model

    should provide wide local latitude with regard toincome thresholds, program qualications and

    other parameters. At the same time however, the

    PRMT model should provide states and localities a

    template o sucient technical and administrative

    specicity, and any necessary ederal authorities, to

    guide ull-scale implementation.

    To help illustrate the intent o this recommenda-

    tion, Table 7 gives a broad, hypothetical example o

    such a model template. Figures shown or average

    expenditures on tolls as a percent o income (second

    column) are based on the national data in Table 6. In

    this example, a 100 percent tax credit is occasionedby households within a designated income bracket

    with two or more wage earners. While progres-

    sively smaller credits are occasioned by households

    with ewer workers, households with no workers

    (such as retirees and people with disabilities who are

    not working) would be eligible. The intent o the

    model must be to balance the provision o nan-

    TABLE 7

    Progressive Rendable Mobility Ta Credit Program: Eample o A Model Template

    Annal Average

    income ependitre

    (dollars) on tolls as a

    percent o 0 wage 1 wage 2+ wage

    income earners earner earners

    09,999 8 2 4 810,00019,999 5 1.25 2.5 5

    20,00049,999 4 0.75 1.5 50,000+ 2 0 0 0

    Qalifcations

    Live and/or or ithin a conetion pricin area

    Live and/or or more than one-ourth mile rom tranit or eliile or ADA paratranit

    Other requirement pertainin to children, ae, diaility, invetment income, reidency, citizenhip, etc.

    Eample Hoseholds

    Rendable ta credit as a percent

    o earned income

    Hosehold #1

    Income: $15,000/year:

    To ae earner

    Livin in conetion pricin zone:

    Not livin ithin one-ourth mile o

    tranit or eliile or ADA paratranit

    Rendable credit; 5.0 percent o

    gross annal income = $750.00

    Hosehold #2

    Income: $25,500/year:

    One ae earner

    worin in conetion pricin zone:

    Not orin ithin one-ourth mile o

    tranit or eliile or ADA paratranit

    Rendable credit; 1.5 percent o

    gross annal income, $382.50

    Hosehold #3

    Income: $5,000

    No ae earner (retired couple)

    Reidin in conetion pricin zone

    Not reidin ithin one-ourth mile o

    tranit or eliile or ADA paratranit

    Rendable credit; 0.75 percent o

    gross annal income, $262.50

    source: Author calculation and tatitic rom Tale 6.

  • 8/3/2019 07 Congestion Lewis

    30/40

    AMERICAS TRAFFIC CONGESTION PROBLEM: TOWARD A FRAMEWORK FOR NATIONWIDE REFORM

    28 THE HAMILTON PROJECT|

    THE bROOkINgs INsTITUTION

    cial assistance to those who require it while avoid-

    ing the granting o windalls to those who would

    not incur losses rom congestion pricing. Limiting

    the maximum tax credit to households with two or

    more workers, as in the Table 7 example, might be

    appropriate in light o relevant commuting statis-tics. Mohring (1999), or example, nds that in the

    Twin Cities ewer than about one-th o house-

    holds, on average, have one or more members who

    travel during the morning peak period.

    In application, the PRMT model would provide

    guidance to states and localities as to how best to

    construct column two rom local survey analysis.

    Based broadly on the national data in Table 6, the

    cost o the example in Table 7 would be in the order

    o $20 to $25 billion annually. Administration o theprogram would add a urther 5 to 10 percent. These

    costs would be lower to the extent that the model

    program is designed to urther minimize windall

    gains (to those who do not drive at all, or exam-

    ple). The complete elimination o such windalls

    is probably impossible, however, without targeting

    the program so precisely as to blunt the incentive

    characteristics o congestion pricing.

    The model program illustrated above refects the

    evidence given earlier that, beore taking into ac-count the way in which the revenues rom tolls

    might be put to use, many people could be made

    worse o by congestion pricing. Mohring (1999)

    orecasts that, under areawide congestion pricing in

    the Twin Cities, the time-plus-money costs o travel

    or those people in the lowest quartile o house-

    hold income would almost double as they seek less-

    congested (thus lower-tolled), but more circuitous,

    routes. Mohring nds, moreover, that even higher-

    income groups would not be ully compensated

    or their tolls by the travel-time savings they gain.Sarova, Gillingham, Parry, Nelson, Harrington,

    and Mason (2004) draw similar conclusions in a

    2003 model simulation o congestion pricing in

    metropolitan Washington, DC.

    Equity depends importantly, thereore, on the way

    in which congestion pricing is implemented in a

    given local area, on the volume o revenue generated

    rom tolls, and on the way in which su