Microsoft Word - China's Visible Hand.docx36
China’s Visible Hand: An Analysis of the Chinese Government’s
Intervention in its Economy During 2015–17
Kerry Liu
Author Note
Kerry Liu, Associate at the China Studies Centre, University of
Sydney, Australia
The author would like to thank Xiaoming Feng, the Managing Editor
Scott Jeffrey, and three anonymous referees for helpful comments.
This research did not receive any specific grant from funding
agencies in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit
sectors.
Correspondence concerning this article should be addressed to Kerry
Liu, kerry.luke@gmail.com
Abstract
While the Washington Consensus supports limited government
involvement in economic life, the new structural economics holds
that government can play a facilitating role. This paper
contributes to this debate by examining examples of the Chinese
government’s intervention in its economy during 2015–2017. The
Chinese government’s intervention has been generally successful,
including significant reduction in overcapacity in the steel and
coal industry, reduced liquidity of Chinese real estate as an asset
class, and change in investment style through direct intervention
in stock markets. Under President Xi Jinping, the governance model
of China Inc. resembles family ownership and family management;
thus, with Xi Jinping as an owner–manager, it is expected that the
current government would outperform its predecessors, under
presidents who were mainly managers. This study is the first of its
kind to examine the performance of Chinese government intervention
from the perspective of financial economics.
Keywords: Washington Consensus; new structural economics; China;
government intervention; overcapacity; real estate market; stock
market; family ownership; Xi Jinping
37
The rise of China is one of the most important events in world
economic history since
the Industrial Revolution, and the Chinese government is believed
to have played a highly positive role in the process (Wen, 2015).
For example, China has a capable mercantilist government with both
highly centralized command power and a highly decentralized
administrative structure. The Chinese government can mobilize,
organize and manage its national economy through both central
planning and decentralized intra-national competition among local
administrative regions for economic growth and governance; and it
can self- correct major policy errors through controlled nationwide
experiments and pragmatic institutional innovations at both the
upper and lower administrative levels (Wen, 2015). These aspects of
the Chinese government are aligned with the new structural economic
framework, which recognizes a facilitating role of the state in the
process of industrial upgrading (Lin, 2011; Lin, Monga, Velde,
Tendulkar, Amsden, Amoako, & Lim, 2011). The China Model’s
powerful state has a hand on the levers of capitalism (The
Economist, 2009). This contrasts with the focus of the Washington
Consensus on open markets and limited government involvement in
business (Williamson, 1989), an approach that has been criticized
for resulting in economic collapse and stagnation in many
transition economies and “lost decades” in other developing
countries in the 1980s and 1990s (Lin, 2015), and for exacerbating
inequality and unleashing violence (SCMP, 2017). China is trying to
export its development model, such as by helping the government of
Grenada prepare a national development plan (Chen, 2017). For all
these reasons, the role of government in economic development is a
hot topic.
This paper contributes to the debate on the role of government –
especially the Chinese
government – in economic development by examining evidence from
2015–17. The first section presents recent evidence of government
intervention in the Chinese economy during 2015–17, with respect to
overcapacity in the steel and coal industries, the property market
and the stock market. The second section presents some theoretical
analysis of the performance of Chinese government. The third
section concludes this paper.
Chinese government intervention in the economy, 2015–17
Xi Jinping was elected as the President of China on 14 March 2013.
During the early
stages of his first 5-year term, he gradually consolidated his
power through an anti-corruption campaign, and by 2015 had assumed
responsibility for the Chinese economy, which was traditionally the
responsibility of the Premier. At the Third Plenary Session of the
18th Central Committee of the Communist Party of China (CPC) held
in November 2013, it was stated that China would let the market
play the decisive role in resource allocation. However, few noticed
the following statement; that China would also let the government
play its role (Xinhua News, 2013). At the 19th Central Committee of
the CPC held in November 2017, these two statements were reiterated
(Xinhua News, 2017). They imply that China’s visible hand has been
playing and will continue to play a significant role in Chinese
economy. In this section, three examples from 2015–17 are examined:
interventions in the property market, the stock market, and the
steel and coal industries.
Overcapacity in steel and coal
38
China’s NBS also began to publish capacity utilization by
sub-sector. Various government departments such as the State
Information Centre also sporadically publish such information
through news reports, articles and conference proceedings.
Since the 1990s, the Chinese government dealt with five separate
overcapacity
problems – in 1999–2000, 2003–04, 2006, 2009–10, and 2013 (Yu and
Cui, 2016). The industries that most often experienced overcapacity
were steel, coal, cement, electrolytic aluminium and flat glass,
but primarily the steel and coal industries (Yu and Jin, 2017). In
2015–17, a 6th program sought to resolve overcapacity in the steel
and coal industries.
During 2011–15, China’s annual steel output was around 1.13 billion
tons. However,
capacity utilization for crude steel declined from 79% in 2010 to
around 70% in 2015. The whole steel industry had been running at
low profitability, and experienced an overall loss in 2015 (Y. Liu,
2018). Similarly, the coal mining industry had been struggling for
a long time as the result of overcapacity. Its gross profit margin,
defined as the ratio of revenue minus cost of goods sold to
revenue, reached its peak level of 31.1% in November 2008, and
continuously declined to an historic low of 14.2% in August 2015.
During the same period, the growth rate of industry-level profit
declined continuously from 91.9% to negative territory in
mid-20161.
There are multiple and complicated reasons for industrial
overcapacity in China. As Yu
and Jin (2017) argued, while structural factors and restructuring
can cause overcapacity and fluctuations in capacity utilization are
part of the economic cycle, Chinese economic characteristics are
also important. First, Chinese firms tend to invest in industries
which have been successful in more developed countries. However,
many Chinese firms made investment decisions based on incomplete
information, forming a "wave" that resulted in concentrated
investment in particular industries. Product prices dropped,
leading to overcapacity (Lin, Wu and Xing, 2010). Second, Chinese
governments play a significant role in driving overcapacity. For
example, local governments vie to attract investment to increase
local GDP, taxes and employment. Accordingly, low-cost land supply
and tax relief have become main methods of promoting investment and
have boosted capacity expansion. Some local governments even set up
bankruptcy exit barriers to help firms reorganize in order to
protect local investment and employment, which have further
increased the difficulties of resolving overcapacity issues (Yu and
Jin, 2017; Zhou, 2004). Furthermore, the Chinese central government
played a significant role in the 2008–09 global financial crisis
(GFC), launching a massive economic stimulus program characterized
by heavy investment in infrastructure projects, which significantly
expanded the capacity of upstream industries including steel and
coal (Zhang, 2014). Third, the incompleteness of the entire market
mechanism in China is an underlying driver of overcapacity. The
pricing mechanism for the factors of production is very distorted
and the market is not fair and competitive. The exit channels for
overcapacity are premature. For these reasons, overcapacity in
China has worsened over time (Yu and Jin, 2017).
The Chinese government has been very concerned about the
consequences of
39
2015, 2016 and 2017 respectively2. Overcapacity has become a major
factor suppressing economic growth. Yu and Jin (2017) also argued
that overcapacity can increase corporate debt, potentially
triggering systemic financial risks. Also, overcapacity can trigger
international trade disputes. China is facing numerous
international anti-dumping cases related to its steel industry,
which has been suffering serious overcapacity.
Government policies. The Chinese government’s response to the
overcapacity issue is part of the so-called “supply-side structural
reform” initiated in November 2015 at the Central Economic Work
Conference (CEWC) (Xinhua News, 2015), a high-level annual meeting
of policymakers and senior Chinese Communist Party leaders,
including the president, Xi Jinping. The reform process followed
official recognition that Keynesian demand-side policies had run
their course. Years of boosting the economy with monetary and
fiscal stimulus had given rise to structural imbalances and
financial risks. Easy credit had caused “zombie companies” to
proliferate in industries with overcapacity, the financial system
was exposed to a massive property overhang caused by
overinvestment, and domestic firms were not producing the goods and
services that local consumers demanded. The 2015 CEWC identified
five areas of focus: cutting industrial overcapacity, destocking
the property inventory, corporate deleveraging, lowering corporate
costs and improving “weak links” (EIU, 2017).
There are two main ways to deal with overcapacity. The first is
through the mechanism
of market clearing: through competition from the market, the less
efficient capacity will be forced out of the market by bankruptcy
or restructuring. The second is through government action: through
enforced compliance with industrial policy and work health and
safety regulations, or administrative measures, the less efficient
capacity will be forced out of the market. Chinese government
mainly relies on the second approach, for two reasons. First,
overcapacity is closely associated with overinvestment, and
overinvestment is associated with the low-cost factor of
production; therefore, reform of the pricing of factors of
production is essential (an ongoing and probably lengthy task).
Second, many overcapacity firms are either state-owned or closely
associated with local government taxes and employment, and thus,
are partially insulated from market forces.
Professor Justin Yifu Lin from Peking University cited an example
of how the Chinese
government deals with high inflation (China News Weekly, 2017). In
the 1980s, China faced very high inflation; the typical
market-oriented response would have been to raise interest rates,
but because most projects were state-funded, raising rates would
have caused substantial losses. In order to support employment,
government would have to provide subsidies, the Chinese
government’s deficit would rise, and this would have to be resolved
by issuing more money, thereby exacerbating inflation. Instead, the
government simply cut investment projects through administrative
measures.
In the same way, the Chinese government relied mainly on
administrative measures and
compliance requirements to cut recent overcapacity in the steel and
coal industries. In February 2016, the State Council (China’s
central government) issued a guideline on resolving overcapacity
issue in the steel industry (State Council, 2016a). This document
stated that starting from 2016, China would reduce its crude steel
production capacity by 100–150 million tons over five years. By end
2016, 65 million tons of steel capacity had already been
eliminated3. In February 2016, another State Council guideline on
resolving overcapacity in the coal
40
industry (State Council, 2016b) stated that China would reduce coal
production capacity by 800 million tons in 3–5 years. By end 2016,
290 million tons of coal capacity had been eliminated4.
Effect of government policies. Capacity utilization has improved
significantly since the beginning of the most recent round of
overcapacity reduction. Capacity utilization for the ferrous
metal smelting and rolling processingsteelindustry gradually
increased from 72.3% in Q2, 2016 to 77% in Q4, 2017. In addition,
the capacity utilization ratio for the non-ferrous metal (such as
aluminium and magnesium) smelting and rolling processing industries
increased from 75.7% in Q4, 2016 to 79.6% in Q4, 20175. In the coal
industry, capacity utilization increased from 58.4% in Q2, 2016 to
70.5% in Q4, 2017.
The Producer Product Price (PPI) has also improved significantly.
Starting from
December 2011, the PPI for the metallurgical industry (steel
industry) remained in negative territory continuously for 56 months
until June 2016, when it rebounded. Starting from June 2012, the
PPI for the coal and coking industry remained in negative territory
continuously for 51 months until August 2016, then gradually
rebounded6. As a result of rising prices, profits in these
industries have also rebounded significantly.
Generally, the Chinese government’s approach to overcapacity in the
steel and coal
industries has been successful. The Economist (2017) stated that
growth normally comes from investment in new facilities, not the
closure of those in use, showing that China’s case is a rare one.
By taking on extreme overcapacity, its cutbacks have provided an
economic boost for China and for the global economy. However,
Chinese state-owned enterprises (SOEs) still face a soft-budget
problem. If low-efficiency SOEs continue to receive preferential
treatment in the form of credit support from Chinese banks and
government guarantees, there is a risk that the overcapacity issue
will re-emerge.
Conclusions. China’s steel and coal industry had been suffering
from serious overcapacity issues for a long time. Starting from
2016, the Chinese government began to address this issue through
compliance and administrative measures as a part of supply-side
structural reform. This has been successful so far, but while
administrative measures are quick and effective, there are some
prominent drawbacks. In the coal industry, overcapacity reduction
caused a 50% hike in the coal price in the summer of 2016, which
brought large volatility to downstream industries. With respect to
steel, it has always been very challenging for the government to
accurately forecast the market demands (Ji, Zhang and Zhao, 2017).
The Chinese real estate market
There has been considerable academic discussion of China’s booming
real estate market (e.g. Chen and Wen, 2017; Glaeser, Huang, Ma,
& Shleifer, 2017). Official data from the NBS of China show
that between June 2010 and December 2017, the real estate price in
tier one cities (Beijing, Shanghai, Shenzhen and Guangzhou)
increased around 100%, while tier two cities (including 22 cities
such as Chongqing and Tianjin) increased around 50%, and tier 3
cities (74 smaller cities) increased around 30%. However, these
data do not give a full picture of the Chinese real estate market:
Deng, Girardin and Joyeux (2016) argued that government housing
prices may suffer from the well-documented downward bias.
Moreover,
41
China has the second highest price-to-income ratio, just behind
Hong Kong, among eighty- nine countries in one leading
database7.
The stock market provides more information. Table 1 below shows the
performance and risk-adjusted performance of the MSCI China Real
Estate Index and MSCI China Index. The MSCI China Real Estate Index
is designed to capture the large and mid-cap segments of the China
equity markets. All securities in the index are classified in the
Real Estate Sector according to the Global Industry Classification
Standard. The MSCI China Index captures large and mid-cap
representation across China H shares, B shares, Red chips, P chips
and foreign listings (e.g. American Depositary Receipts). With 152
constituents, the index covers about 85% of the China equity
universe. H Shares are securities of companies incorporated in the
People’s Republic of China (PRC) that trade on the Hong Kong Stock
Exchange. They are traded in Hong Kong dollars. B Shares are
securities of Chinese incorporated companies that trade on either
the Shanghai or Shenzhen stock exchanges. They are traded in US
dollars on the Shanghai Stock Exchange and Hong Kong dollars on the
Shenzhen Stock Exchange. A Red Chip is a company incorporated
outside the PRC that trades on the Hong Kong Stock Exchange and is
substantially owned, directly or indirectly, by Mainland China
state entities with the majority of its revenue or assets derived
from Mainland China. A P Chip is a company controlled by Mainland
Chinese companies or individuals, with the establishment and origin
of the company in Mainland China. It must be incorporated outside
the PRC and traded on the Hong Kong Stock Exchange with a majority
of its revenue or assets derived from Mainland China.
Table 1. performance and risk-adjusted performance of MSCI China
Real Estate Index and MSCI China Index
Table 1 shows that China’s real estate sector has consistently,
significantly, outperformed the market. The average gross return of
China’s real estate sector during the past
7 Data source: Numbeo, a collaborative online database which
enables users to share and compare information about the cost of
living between countries and cities.
Index performance – gross return (%, 31 January 2018)
1Y 3Y 5Y 10Y
since 30 December 1994
MSCI China Real Estate Index 120.27 30.87 13.77 8.67 12.74
MSCI China Index 62.57 16.61 11.88 6.98 4.14
Sharpe ratio
0.96 0.56 0.39 0.42
42
23 years is around 13%, higher than the market return of 4.14%.
This high performance is especially significant during the past
three years. Table 1 also shows the Sharpe ratio – the average
return earned in excess of the risk-free rate per unit of
volatility or total risk. The greater the value of the Sharpe
ratio, the more attractive the risk-adjusted return. The Sharpe
ratio indicator confirms that China’s real estate sector has
significantly outperformed the market during the past 23
years.
The GFC showed the role of the real estate market. After a
sustained boom, real estate
prices collapsed, triggering a financial crisis and fall in
household expenditures which – paired with macroeconomic frictions
– led to a slump in employment (Mian and Sufi, 2014). In the case
of China, movements in housing prices affect fixed investments,
magnifying business cycle fluctuations (Pesenti, 2016). The major
near-term risk of the real estate market is the housing bubble in
top-tier cities expanding to smaller cities, which increases the
likelihood and costs of a sharp correction in house prices. This
would weaken growth through slowing real estate investment and
private consumption, and affect financial stability by reducing
developers’ funding and mortgages of financial institutions (Ding,
Huang, Jin, and Lam, 2017). Chen, Liu, Xiong, and Zhou (2017)
showed that rising real estate prices affect investment by
mitigating the financial constraints firms face, called the
“collateral channel”. The increased real estate prices may induce
firms, particularly those with land holdings and thus access to
finance, to speculate on real estate price appreciation at the
expense of their other investments, called the “speculation
channel”. In response to an increase in real estate prices, banks
may grant more credit to land-holding firms, crowding out credit to
firms without land holdings, called the “crowding out channel”.
Chen, Liu, Xiong, and Zhou (2017) concluded that netting out these
channels means a 100% increase in commercial land prices leads to a
loss of 9% to aggregate total factor productivity due to
misallocation of capital. Chinese governments have launched a
series of policies in response to the risks posed by this real
estate boom.
Responses from Chinese governments. During the two decades to 2017,
Chinese governments launched monetary policy, credit policy, tax
and fee policy and land usage policy to manage the property boom.
Nevertheless, the Chinese real estate market is still one of the
most inflated in the world, and its fundamental issues are not
resolved.
There are three main reasons for the Chinese real estate boom. The
first consists of fundamental factors that drive rising demand,
such as China’s unprecedented income growth (Chen and Wen, 2017),
as well as increasing population and urbanization (Bian and Gete,
2015). China’s urbanization rate increased from 33.4% in 1998 to
58.5% in 20178, driving house prices upwards. This urbanization
process is part of China’s economic transition, which features
labor reallocation from the traditional low-productivity sector to
the newly emerging high-productivity sector. However, this
reallocation will eventually end when surplus labor is
depleted.
Second, the working-age population (defined as people aged 15–59
years) ratio reached its peak of 69.8% in 20119, then gradually
decreased. The Chinese government’s policy on real estate market
tightened from 2011–13 (Cooper and Cowling, 2015; Ren, 2017). The
booming Chinese property market since 2014 has been mainly driven
by expansionary monetary policy. Real-estate has increasingly
become a preferred asset class for household and institutional
investors (Ren, 2017).
43
Third, the Chinese government has played a significant role in the
real estate boom. As Shatkin (2016) argued, land price increases
present states with opportunities and challenges, leading them to
develop new land management strategies that seek to exploit
urbanization processes in the interest of extending state power.
Governments in much of Asia, including China, have sought to
monetize land – to use government land management powers to realize
substantial increases in land values, in order to extend state
power either by directly extracting revenue for government from
land development, or by distributing the profits of land
development to powerful corporate backers of the state. This
explains why Chinese governments before 2017 had no intention of
cooling the real estate market.
The Chinese public sector retains control over future prices and
real estate construction
(Glaeser et al., 2017). Thus, Chinese governments’ previous
policies toward the real estate market aimed to monetize it further
and promote it as an asset class for individual and institutional
investors. However, things began to change from the end of 2016.
During the CEWC held in December 2016, the Chinese central
government’s stated position on real estate was that houses are for
living in, not for speculation. This statement was reaffirmed in
the communique of the 19th National Congress of the Communist Party
of China held in October 2017 (Xinhua News, 2017).
As part of this new position, the Chinese government announced
restrictions on real
Figure 1. Real estate price, development investment completed and
new construction area: June 2011 – December 2017 Source: Wind
Info
Conclusions. The Chinese real estate market has been booming for a
long time, posing risks to Chinese economy and financial system.
Before 2017, Chinese government policies toward this sector had
been about further monetizing this real estate market and the real
estate become an asset class for investment. The Chinese
government’s policy from 2017 is that real estate is for living in,
not for speculation. Accordingly, Chinese governments adopted
restrictions on sale policy designed to reduce the liquidity of
this asset class. As a result, Chinese real estate price growth has
slowed, while investment remains still stable.
The stock market since 2015 The Chinese stock market entered
turbulence with the popping of the stock market
bubble on 12 June 2015, which ended in early February 2016. The
Shanghai Stock Exchange Composite Index (SSE Composite Index, a
stock market index of all stocks traded at the Shanghai Stock
Exchange) reached its peak level of 5166 points on 12 June 2015,
then fell to 2927 points on 26 August 2015, a fall of around 43% in
just two months. The Shenzhen Stock Exchange Component Index (SZSE
Component Index, an index of 500 stocks traded at the Shenzhen
Stock Exchange) lost around 49% between 12 June and 15 September
201510.
On both 4 January and 7 January 2016, the Chinese stock market
experienced sharp
sell-offs of about 7%. During the first 15 minutes of the first
trading day, the stock market fell by 5% before regulators halted
trading. It was eventually reopened, and stocks fell until trading
was again halted after 15 minutes (Xie and Hong, 2016). During the
whole of January 2016, the SSE Composite Index lost around 23%, and
the SZSE Component Index around 26%11.
In January 2016, Chinese stock markets traded A shares in 2,809
listed companies12.
When the market was in most serious situation, around 2000
companies fell to the down limit
10 Data source: Wind Info 11 Data source: Wind Info 12 Data source:
Wind Info
10
0
10
20
30
40
40
30
20
10
0
10
20
30
Accumulated Growth of Housing New Construction Area (%)
Accumulated Growth of Real Estate Development Investment Completed (%,
RHL)
Real Estate Price Growth (%, YoY, RHL)
45
of 10%13, and 1,346 companies’ shares were suspended (Apple Daily,
2015). The whole Chinese stock market was encountering serious
liquidity issues.
Policy response from Chinese governments and regulatory
authorities. The
Chinese government and regulatory authorities enacted many measures
to stem the losses. For example, the Chinese State Council decided
to allocate over RMB 250 billion collected from unused and illegal
funds into areas in urgent need (State Council, 2015a). China’s
Ministry of Finance requested that stated-owned financial companies
should buy back stocks when their shares were below reasonable
prices (State Council, 2015b). China’s Ministry of Public Security,
which is the principal police and security authority in China and
the agency ultimately responsible for day-to-day law enforcement,
also stepped in to investigate any illegal and/or market
manipulating activities. The State-owned Assets Supervision and
Administration Commission of the State Council requested over 100
SOEs under direct supervision of Chinese central government not to
sell shares (State Council, 2015b). The People’s Bank of China
(China’s central bank) announced a Reserve Requirement Ratio cut of
25 base points to release extra liquidity to the market. The China
Insurance Regulatory Commission decided to increase insurance
funds’ ability to invest in blue-chip stocks. The China Securities
Regulatory Commission also launched a series of measures, including
reducing the number and fund- raising amount of IPOs; increasing
the registered capital of China Securities Finance Corp (CSFC) to
RMB 100 billion from RMB 24 billion, allowing it to provide further
funds to brokerage firms to buy back shares (CSRC, 2015a);
increasing the margin ratios of short selling through financial
futures; forbidding blockholders with more than 5% shares
outstanding from selling their own shares within six months (The
Paper, 2015); and after this six-month period, requiring that the
total number of shares sold within 3 months by the major
shareholders of a listed company through a centralized bidding
transaction did not exceed 1% of the total number of shares of the
company (CSRC, 2015b).
However, the most important measure was the direct intervention
from the so-called
National Team, which has four members: Central Huijin; the CSFC;
investment platforms under the State Administration of Foreign
Exchange (SAFE); and five mutual funds with full subscription from
the CSFC. Central Huijin is an organization through which the
Chinese government acts as a controlling shareholder for the
Chinese financial system, including the China Development Bank, the
“Big Four” commercial banks (the Bank of China, the Industrial and
Commercial Bank of China, the China Construction Bank, and the
Agricultural Bank of China), major insurance and reinsurance
companies, major security brokerages, and major asset management
firms. However, Central Huijin is not a newcomer to the Chinese
stock markets; its shareholdings are relatively stable, so it is
excluded from my calculation of National Team investments in
Chinese stock markets in 2015 and afterwards. The CSFC was founded
in 2011 with shareholders including the Shanghai Stock Exchange,
Shenzhen Stock Exchange, China Securities Depository and Clearing
Corporation, Shanghai Futures Exchange, China Financial Futures
Exchange, Dalian Commodity Exchange, and Zhengzhou Commodity
Exchange. Initially, the CSFC only provided margin financing loan
services to qualified brokerage firms, but starting from 2015, it
began to buy shares directly from the market as a special-purpose
vehicle for government intervention and play a major role in
stabilizing the markets. The SAFE has three investment platforms
for investing in domestic stock markets. Figure 2 below shows the
market capitalization of the stocks held by various
government
13 There is a daily price limit of general: ±10% in Chinese stock
markets. Source: Shanghai Stock Exchange
http://english.sse.com.cn/investors/shhkconnect/mechanism/rules/
46
vehicles and the aggregated fractions of government holdings in
stocks over total market capitalization during Q3, 2015 – Q3,
2017.
Figure 2. Market capitalization of the stocks held by various
government vehicles and the aggregated shares of government
holdings in stocks over total market capitalization during Q3, 2015
– Q3, 2017
Source: Li (2017), Wind Info
Figure 2 shows that the shares held by the Chinese National Team
were valued at RMB 800–1,150 billion during Q3, 2015 – Q3, 2017.
These shares account for 1.5%–2.5% of total market capitalization
of Chinese stock markets. The total market capitalizations and
fractions of these market capitalization have decreased from its
peak level in Q3, 2015, but are still at a high level.
The CSFC mainly invested in the financial service industry (45.3%);
the five mutual
funds also mainly invested in the financial service industry
(41.6%), and the SAFE mainly invested in the banking industry
(87.9%) in Q3, 2017. Together with other industry allocations, it
seems that these National Team Investment managers prefer blue-chip
companies (Li, 2017). In fact, from the very beginning of the
Chinese government’s intervention in Chinese stock markets,
blue-chip companies were the key line of defence (Financial Times,
2015).
Effects of government intervention. In academic literature,
although achieving price
stability and restoring investors’ confidence are the main goals of
intervention, the general view is that governments should avoid
intervening in stock markets since intervention transmits negative
signals and carries market-related side effects (Khan and Batteau,
2011). So, the question is, what are the effects of Chinese
government interventions in stock markets? To answer, we examine
the performance of the SSE 50 Index.
0.0%
0.5%
1.0%
1.5%
2.0%
2.5%
3.0%
0
200
400
600
800
1,000
1,200
Markt Cap of Shares held by SAFE (Unit: RMB Billion)
Markt Cap of Shares held by Five National Team Mutual Funds (Unit: RMB Billion)
Markt Cap of Shares held by CSFC (Unit: RMB Billion)
% of Government Holdings over Total Market Cap (RHL)
47
The SSE 50 Index is the stock index of the Shanghai Stock Exchange,
representing its top 50 companies by "float-adjusted"
capitalization. The objective of the SSE 50 is to give a complete
picture of those good-quality large enterprises, which are the most
influential in the Shanghai stock market (SSE, 2004). It consists
mainly of financial service firms, including 12 banks, 10 security
brokerage firms and four insurance companies. The others include
major airlines and automotive, construction, energy, real estate
and telecommunication firms. The SSE 50 index is regarded as
blue-chip, and its return on equity has consistently outperformed
the SSE Composite Index, which includes all stocks (not reported;
data available upon request). Figures 3 and 4 below show the
performance and volatilities of these two indices respectively. The
volatility is defined as the 200-trading day standard deviation of
the daily percentage change of index.
Figure 3. The performance comparison between SSE 50 Index and SSE
Composite Index: 31 January 2013 – 31 January 2018
Source: Wind Info
75
85
95
105
115
125
135
145
48
Figure 4. Volatilities of SSE 50 Index and SSE Composite Index: 31
January 2013 – 30 June 2017 Source: Wind Info
Figure 3 shows that before Chinese government’s direct intervention
in 2016, the blue- chip SSE 50 Index had generally underperformed
the market (SSE Composite Index); after the intervention, this
situation reversed. Figure 4 shows that before 2016, the blue-chip
SSE 50 Index had higher volatility than the market, but after
intervention, it generally had lower volatility than the market
until May 2017. During June 2017 – January 2018, the risk-adjusted
return of the SSE 50 Index also outperformed the market. It seems
that Chinese government’s direct intervention in the stock markets,
with a special focus on blue-chip companies fundamentally changed
Chinese stock markets. It is also widely believed that the A share
market has undergone a huge shift of investment style, away from
extremely overpriced small and mid-caps to high-quality, reasonably
priced blue-chips (Mooney, 2018).
Conclusions. The Chinese government’s direct intervention from 2015
changed the stock markets and, accordingly, their investment style.
Value investing became more popular than momentum investing.
However, it should be noted that government intervention can also
damage stock markets, for example by endangering their integrity
and voiding their basic principles of functioning, namely, risk
transfer and price discovery (Khan and Batteau, 2011). The
long-term effect of the Chinese government’s intervention into the
stock markets should continue to be examined as data
accumulates.
Theoretical explanations
Market mechanisms are deemed essential for valuing the basic
ingredients of production and providing the right price signals and
an appropriate incentive system for the efficient allocation of
resources (Lin et al., 2011). Nevertheless, the Chinese government
has successfully managed its overcapacity issues, a booming
property market and stock market fluctuation through direct
intervention. There are three arguments as to why these non-market-
based and theoretically harmful measures have proved
successful.
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
49
The first argument is that, generally speaking, government
intervention has its own merits. Lin (2015) argued that many firms
in a transitioning economy are not viable in an open, competitive
market because they lack the comparative advantages determined by
the economy’s endowment structure. Their survival relies on the
government’s protections and subsidies through various
interventions and distortions. So, through the provision of
information, coordination of hard and soft infrastructure
improvement, and compensation for externalities, government
intervention is equally indispensable for helping economies move
from one stage of development to another (Lin, 2010). However,
while this argument provides some general justification for
government intervention, it does not address the uniqueness of the
Chinese government, which is discussed below.
The second argument is that the Chinese government has its own
special merits. Being
built on a politically stable one-party system that avoids some of
the dilemmas of both democracy and dictatorship that face
developing countries, the Chinese government can draw from its
administrative talents and gain support from the majority of the
population based on a merit-based leader selection system. Such a
system is not perfect, but has been China’s great comparative
political advantage (Wen, 2015). Wen (2015) also argued that the
Chinese government understands the nature of capitalism and the
developmental history of the West; therefore, it can take a very
long historical view of the evolution of human societies as it
designs and implements its development strategies. In contrast,
democratically elected politicians, who are often incompetent
economic managers, are prone to the manipulation of powerful
interest groups and constrained by voters’ short-sighted immediate
self-interests. However, this argument still does not answer the
question of how the incumbent Chinese government has successfully
managed the economic issues discussed in this paper, while previous
governments failed to do so. The answer lies in the following
argument.
The performance of the Chinese government under President Xi
Jinping differs from
that under his predecessors such as Hu Jintao and Jiang Zemin. For
example, overcapacity has been a problem for a long time – why did
previous governments fail to resolve it? Chinese government
intervention in its stock markets also has a long history; why did
previous interventions not turn Chinese stock markets towards value
investing? Why had previous Chinese governments’ interventions
helped the country’s property market become highly unaffordable? K.
Liu (2018) argued that the Chinese economy can be regarded as a
single corporation – China Inc., and that it is appropriate to
assume that the function of China Inc. is maximization of
stockholders’ wealth (output growth). China’s previous leaders, Hu
Jintao and Jiang Zemin, did not belong to the founding families of
modern China; Xi Jinping does. In the past, China Inc. was like a
firm controlled by management but with limited supervision from
shareholders; China Inc. under President Xi is more like a
family-owned and managed corporation. Academic researchers have
overwhelmingly concluded that family ownership outperforms
non-family ownership, and having a family member as CEO is also
positive associated with economic performance. This is the
fundamental reason why the Chinese government under President Xi
differs from previous ones, and why Chinese government’s
interventions into its economy during 2015–17 were
successful.
Xi Jinping, as the CEO and President of the China Inc., would
consider overcapacity to
50
business model by implementing heavier regulation on this sector.
He (and his family) may suffer personally from the resulting
slowdown of the real estate market, but will ultimately gain as the
(controlling) shareholders of China Inc. Finally, the stock market
is supposed to play the role of price discovery and risk transfer.
The asset allocations of the Chinese National Team have conveyed
signals of rational stock selection, serving to guide small
investors’ investments. This is essentially a means of more
efficiently allocating resources than is possible through market
mechanisms alone.
Final conclusion
The economic rise of China is indisputable, and the significance of
the role of the
Chinese government in the process also seems indisputable. While
the Washington Consensus holds that government involvement in
business should be strictly limited, the new structural economics
recognizes that government can play a facilitating role. This paper
contributes to this debate by examining examples of the Chinese
government’s intervention in its economy during 2015–17,
specifically to address overcapacity issues and reform both the
property market and stock market. These interventions seem to have
been successful to date, although some problems remain.
This paper also provides some theoretical explanations for the
success of the Chinese
government’s intervention. Lin (2010, 2015) argues that government
intervention has its merits, and Wen (2015) that the Chinese
government has its own special merits. Another novel analysis is
from the perspective of financial economics. K. Liu (2018) argued
that since the governance model of China Inc. under President Xi
Jinping is more like family ownership and management than a
publicly held corporation, Chinese government under President Xi
would outperform his predecessors, who were essentially just
managers. Accordingly, the main conclusion of this paper is not
that China’s government-controlled model performs better than
market economies, but rather that the Xi Jinping government
outperforms previous Chinese governments.
One limitation of this study is that it is based on a very short
time span and few
51
References
Ang, A., D. Papanikolaou, and Westerfield, M. M. (2014). Portfolio
choice with illiquid assets. Management Science 60.11:
2737-2761.
Apple Daily (2015). A-share suspension tide. Retrieved from
https://hk.news.appledaily.com/local/daily/article/20150709/19213633
(in Chinese) Bian, T. Y., and Gete, P. (2015). What drives housing
dynamics in China? A sign restrictions
VAR approach. Journal of Macroeconomics 46: 96-112. Chen, K., and
Wen, Y. (2017). The great housing boom of China. American
Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics 9.2: 73-114. Chen, T., Liu, L. Xiong, W.
and Zhou, L. A. (2017). Real estate boom and misallocation of
capital in China. Working Paper, Princeton University. China News
Weekly (2017). Lin Yifu: China’s economic achievements in the past
30 years
are a big miracle. Retrieved from
http://www.fmprc.gov.cn/zflt/chn/zxxx/t1518776.htm (in
Chinese)
China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) (2015a). China
Securities Finance
Corporation significantly increased capital and shares. Retrieved
from
http://www.csrc.gov.cn/pub/newsite/zjhxwfb/xwdd/201507/t20150703_280388.html
(in Chinese)
China Securities Regulatory Commission (CSRC) (2015b). The China
Securities Regulatory
Commission issued "Several Provisions on the Major Shareholders and
Directors of the Listed Companies to Reduce Shareholdings".
Retrieved from
http://www.csrc.gov.cn/pub/newsite/zjhxwfb/xwdd/201601/t20160107_289586.html
(in Chinese)
Cooper, A., and Cowling, A. (2015). China’s Property Sector. RBA
Bulletin, March: 45-54. Damodaran, A. (2005). The cost of
illiquidity. New York, NY: NYU Stern School of
Business. Deng, Y., Girardin, E. and Joyeux, R. (2016).
Fundamentals and the volatility of real estate
prices in China: A sequential modelling strategy. China Economic
Review. doi: 10.1016/j.chieco.2016.10.011.
Ding, D., Huang, X. Jin, T. and Lam, W. R. (2017). Assessing
China’s Residential Real
Estate Market. International Monetary Fund. Retrieved from
https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2017/11/16/Assessing-Chinas-
Residential-Real-Estate-Market-45337
Financial Times (2015). China blue-chips get Beijing boost.
Retrieved from
https://www.ft.com/content/34a2f2a6-247f-11e5-9c4e-a775d2b173ca
52
Glaeser, E., Huang, W. Ma, Y. and Shleifer, A. (2017). A real
estate boom with Chinese Characteristics. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 31, no. 1: 93-116.
Ji, M., Zhang, X., Zhao, T., (2017). Cutting overcapacity:
successes, problems, and historical
experiences. CF40 Working Paper Series NO. CF40WP2017020 Khan, S.,
and Batteau, P. (2011). Should the government directly intervene in
stock market
during a crisis? The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance
51.4: 350-359. Li, L. (2017). Shareholding analysis on the National
Team in Q3, 2017. Sinolink Securities,
Retrieved from
http://pg.jrj.com.cn/acc/Res/CN_RES/INVEST/2017/11/2/178391c2-
c60b-4b4f-b071-855ee7accac7.pdfLin, J. Y. (2011). New structural
economics: a framework for rethinking development. The World Bank
Research Observer 26.2: 193-221.
Lin, J. Y. (2015). The Washington Consensus revisited: A new
structural economics
perspective. Journal of Economic Policy Reform 18.2: 96-113. Lin,
J. Y., Monga, C. D. Velde, W. t., Tendulkar, S. D, Amsden, A.,
Amoako, Pack, K. Y. H.
and Lim, W. (2011). DPR debate: Growth identification and
facilitation: The role of the state in the dynamics of structural
change. Development Policy Review 29, no. 3: 259-310.
Lin, J. Y., Wu, H. and Xing, Y. (2010). “Wave phenomena” and
formation of excess
capacity. Economic Research 10: 4-19. Liu, K., (2018). Emperor Xi
Jinping: Good? Bad? A Perspective from Financial Economics.
Working paper. China Studies Centre, University of Sydney,
Australia. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3295337 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3295337
Liu, Y., (2018). Analysis on the trend of de-capacity and Its
Impact on Chinese economy.
State Information Centre, 26 January Retrieved from
http://www.sic.gov.cn/News/455/8815.htm
Mian, A., and Sufi, A. (2014). What explains the 2007–2009 drop in
employment?.
Econometrica 82.6: 2197-2223. Mooney, A. (2018). UBS, Morgan
Stanley and Belgrave top 2017 table. Financial Times,
January 21 National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) (2018). National
industrial capacity utilization rate in the
fourth quarter of 2017 was 78.0%. Retrieved from
http://www.stats.gov.cn/tjsj/zxfb/201801/t20180119_1575361.html (in
Chinese)
Pesenti, P., (2016). Discussion of DSGE modeling of China’s
macroeconomy and housing
cycle. People’s Bank of China – FRBNY Joint Symposium: Global
Economy and Governance Under Monetary Policy Divergence,
March
Ren, Z., (2017). Two decades of regulation and control on
residential real estate sector of
China: a review. Founder securities, 12 February
53
Sadka, R. (2014). Asset class liquidity risk. Bankers, Markets
& Investors 128: 20-30. Shatkin, G. (2016). The real estate
turn in policy and planning: Land monetization and the
political economy of peri-urbanization in Asia. Cities 53: 141-149.
Shenzhen Stock Exchange (SSE) (2004). SSE 50 Index Methodology.
Retrieved from
http://www.sse.com.cn/market/sseindex/indexlist/indexdetails/indexmethods/c/Index
%20Handbook_EN_SSE%2050.pdf
South China Morning Post (SCMP), (2017). The liberal vision of
development is killing
people, warns UN expert. 20 October. Retrieved from
http://www.scmp.com/news/world/united-states-canada/article/2116238/liberal-
vision-development-killing-people-warns-un
State Council (2015a). Li Keqiang presided over the State Council
executive meeting.
Retrieved from
http://www.gov.cn/guowuyuan/2015-07/08/content_2893951.htm (in
Chinese)
State Council (2015b). Some good news about A shares. Retrieved
from
http://www.gov.cn/xinwen/2015-07/09/content_2894594.htm (in
Chinese) State Council (2016a). State Council’s opinions on the
steel industry to resolve excess
capacity and achieving development. Retrieved from
http://www.gov.cn/zhengce/content/2016-02/04/content_5039353.htm
(in Chinese)
State Council (2016b). State Council’s opinions on coal industry to
resolve excess capacity
and achieving development. Retrieved from
http://www.gov.cn/zhengce/content/2016-02/05/content_5039686.htm
(in Chinese)
The Economist (2009). Beware the Beijing mode. March 26. Retrieved
from
https://www.economist.com/node/13721724 The Economist, (2017).
Created destruction: Making sense of capacity cuts in China.
September 9, Retrieved from
https://www.economist.com/news/leaders/21728640-
investors-have-been-cheered-sweeping-cutbacks-they-should-look-more-closely-
making-sense
The Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU), (2017). China’s supply-side
structural reforms:
Progress and outlook. May The Paper (2015). Important shareholders
of listed companies are not allowed to reduce their
holdings within 6 months. Retrieved from
http://www.thepaper.cn/newsDetail_forward_1350269 (in
Chinese)
Wen, Y., (2015). The making of an economic superpower - unlocking
China's secret of rapid
54
Williamson, J., (1989). What Washington means by policy reform, in:
Williamson, John (ed.): Latin American readjustment: how much has
happened, Washington, DC: Institute for International
Economics.
Xie, Y., and Hong, S., (2016). Circuit breaker: China calls time on
stock market fall. Wall
Street Journal. Retrieved from
https://blogs.wsj.com/chinarealtime/2016/01/04/circuit-breaker-china-calls-time-on-
stock-market-fall/
Xinhua News (2013). Decision of the Central Committee of the
Communist Party of China
on several major issues concerning comprehensively deepening
reform. Retrieved from
http://cpc.people.com.cn/n/2013/1115/c64094-23559163.html (in
Chinese)
Xinhua News (2015). Xi Jinping presided over the eleventh meeting
of the Central Financial
and Economic Leading Group. Retrieved from
http://www.xinhuanet.com/politics/2015-11/10/c_1117099915.htm (in
Chinese)
Xinhua News (2017). Xi Jinping's report at the 19th National
Congress of the Communist
Party of China. Retrieved from
http://www.xinhuanet.com/politics/19cpcnc/2017-
10/27/c_1121867529.htm (in Chinese)
Yu, M. and Cui, X. (2016). China’s overcapacity and its
measurement. Academic Monthly
48.12 (2016): 52-62. Yu, M. and Jin, Y. (2017). The status quo of,
the cause and effect of, and response to over
capacity. China Centre for economic research of Peking University
working paper series, No.C2017015 2017-12-28
Zhang, Q. (2014). The current status, causes and countermeasures of
overcapacity in China.
July, State Information Centre, China. Retrieved from
http://www.sic.gov.cn/News/82/3068.htm (in Chinese)
Zhou, l. A. (2004). The Incentive and cooperation of government
officials in the political
tournaments: an interpretation of the prolonged local protectionism
and duplicative investments in China. Economic Research 6.1:
33-40