Top Banner
Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing
31

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Dec 25, 2015

Download

Documents

Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

1

Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

Page 2: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

2

Introduction

• Annual subscriptions generally cost less in total than one-off purchases

• Buying in bulk usually offers a price discount– these are price discrimination reflecting quantity discounts– prices are nonlinear, with the unit price dependent upon the

quantity bought– allows pricing nearer to willingness to pay– so should be more profitable than third-degree price discrimination

• How to design such pricing schemes?– depends upon the information available to the seller about buyers– distinguish first-degree (personalized) and second-degree (menu)

pricing

Page 3: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

3

First-degree price discrimination 1

• Monopolist can charge maximum price that each consumer is willing to pay

• Extracts all consumer surplus

• Since profit is now total surplus, find that first-degree price discrimination is efficient

Page 4: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

4

First-degree price discrimination 2• Suppose that you own five antique cars • Market research indicates that there are collectors of different

types– keenest is willing to pay $10,000 for a car, second keenest $8,000,

third keenest $6,000, fourth keenest $4,000, fifth keenest $2,000– sell the first car at $10,000– sell the second car at $8,000– sell the third car to at $6,000 and so on– total revenue $30,000

• Contrast with linear pricing: all cars sold at the same price– set a price of $6,000– sell three cars– total revenue $18,000

Page 5: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

5

First-degree price discrimination 3

• First-degree price discrimination is highly profitable but requires– detailed information

– ability to avoid arbitrage

• Leads to the efficient choice of output: since price equals marginal revenue and MR = MC– no value-creating exchanges are missed

Page 6: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

6

First-degree price discrimination 4

• The information requirements appear to be insurmountable– but not in particular cases

• tax accountants, doctors, students applying to private universities

• No arbitrage is less restrictive but potentially a problem

• But there are pricing schemes that will achieve the same outcome– non-linear prices

– two-part pricing as a particular example of non-linear prices• charge a quantity-independent fee (membership?) plus a per unit

usage charge

– block pricing is another• bundle total charge and quantity in a package

Page 7: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

7

Two-part pricing 1

• Jazz club serves two types of customer– Old: demand for entry plus Qo drinks is P = Vo – Qo

– Young: demand for entry plus Qy drinks is P = Vy – Qy

– Equal numbers of each type

– Assume that Vo > Vy: Old are willing to pay more than Young

– Cost of operating the jazz club C(Q) = F + cQ

• Demand and costs are all in daily units

Page 8: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

8

Two-part pricing 2

• Suppose that the jazz club owner applies “traditional” linear pricing: free entry and a set price for drinks– aggregate demand is Q = Qo + Qy = (Vo + Vy) – 2P

– invert to give: P = (Vo + Vy)/2 – Q/2

– MR is then MR = (Vo + Vy)/2 – Q

– equate MR and MC, where MC = c and solve for Q to give

– QU = (Vo + Vy)/2 – c

– substitute into aggregate demand to give the equilibrium price

– PU = (Vo + Vy)/4 + c/2

– each Old consumer buys Qo = (3Vo – Vy)/4 – c/2 drinks

– each Young consumer buys Qy = (3Vy – Vo)/4 – c/2 drinks

– profit from each pair of Old and Young is U = (Vo + Vy – 2c)2

Page 9: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

9

Two part pricing 3This example can be illustrated as follows:

Price

Quantity

Vo

Vo

Price

Quantity

Vy

Vy

Price

Quantity

Vo

Vo + Vy

MC

MR

(a) Old Customers (b) Young Customers (c) Old/Young Pair of Customers

Vo+Vy

2- c

c

Vo+Vy

4+ c

2h i

jk

a

bd

e

fg

Linear pricing leaves each type of consumer with consumer surplus

Page 10: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

10

Two part pricing 4

• Jazz club owner can do better than this

• Consumer surplus at the uniform linear price is:– Old: CSo = (Vo – PU).Qo/2 = (Qo)2/2

– Young: CSy = (Vy – PU).Qy/2 = (Qy)2/2

• So charge an entry fee (just less than):– Eo = CSo to each Old customer and Ey = CSy to each Young

customer• check IDs to implement this policy

– each type will still be willing to frequent the club and buy the equilibrium number of drinks

• So this increases profit by Eo for each Old and Ey for each Young customer

Page 11: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

11

Two part pricing 5

• The jazz club can do even better– reduce the price per drink

– this increases consumer surplus

– but the additional consumer surplus can be extracted through a higher entry fee

• Consider the best that the jazz club owner can do with respect to each type of consumer

Page 12: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

12

Two-Part Pricing$

Quantity

Vi

Vi

MR

MCc

Set the unit price equalto marginal cost

Set the unit price equalto marginal cost

This gives consumer surplus of (Vi - c)2/2

This gives consumer surplus of (Vi - c)2/2

The entry chargeconverts consumersurplus into profit

Vi - cSet the entry charge

to (Vi - c)2/2

Set the entry chargeto (Vi - c)2/2

Profit from each pair of Old and Young is now d = [(Vo – c)2 + (Vy – c)2]/2

Using two-part

pricing increases themonopolist’s

profit

Page 13: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

13

Block pricing

• There is another pricing method that the club owner can apply– offer a package of “Entry plus X drinks for $Y”

• To maximize profit apply two rules– set the quantity offered to each consumer type equal to the amount

that type would buy at price equal to marginal cost

– set the total charge for each consumer type to the total willingness to pay for the relevant quantity

• Return to the example:

Page 14: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

14

Block pricing 2Old$

Quantity

Vo

Vo

Young$

Quantity

Vy

Vy

MC MCc c

Quantity supplied to each Old customer

Quantity supplied to each Young

customer

Qo Qy

Willingness to pay of each

Old customer

Willingness to pay of each

Young customer

WTPo = (Vo – c)2/2 + (Vo – c)c = (Vo2 – c2)/2

WTPy = (Vy – c)2/2 + (Vy – c)c = (Vy2 – c2)/2

Page 15: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

15

Block pricing 3

• How to implement this policy?– card at the door

– give customers the requisite number of tokens that are exchanged for drinks

Page 16: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

16

A final comment

• One final point– average price that is paid by an Old customer = (Vo

2 – c2)/2(Vo – c) = (Vo + c)/2

– average price paid by a Young customer = (Vy2 – c2)/2(Vo – c) =

(Vy + c)/2

– identical to the third-degree price discrimination (linear) prices

– but the profit outcome is much better with first-degree price discrimination. Why?

• consumer equates MC of last unit bought with marginal benefit

• with linear pricing MC = AC (= average price)

• with first-degree price discrimination MC of last unit bought is less than AC (= average price) so more is bought

Page 17: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

17

Second-degree price discrimination

• What if the seller cannot distinguish between buyers?– perhaps they differ in income (unobservable)

• Then the type of price discrimination just discussed is impossible

• High-income buyer will pretend to be a low-income buyer – to avoid the high entry price

– to pay the smaller total charge

• Take a specific example– Ph = 16 – Qh

– Pl = 12 – Ql

– MC = 4

Page 18: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

18

Second-degree price discrimination 2

• First-degree price discrimination requires:

– High Income: entry fee $72 and $4 per drink or entry plus 12 drinks for a total charge of $120

– Low Income: entry fee $32 and $4 per drink or entry plus 8 drinks for total charge of $64

• This will not work– high income types get no consumer surplus from the package

designed for them but get consumer surplus from the other package

– so they will pretend to be low income even if this limits the number of drinks they can buy

• Need to design a “menu” of offerings targeted at the two types

Page 19: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

19

Second-degree price discrimination 3

• The seller has to compromise

• Design a pricing scheme that makes buyers– reveal their true types

– self-select the quantity/price package designed for them

• Essence of second-degree price discrimination

• It is “like” first-degree price discrimination– the seller knows that there are buyers of different types

– but the seller is not able to identify the different types

• A two-part tariff is ineffective– allows deception by buyers

• Use quantity discounting

Page 20: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

20

Second degree price discrimination 4High-income Low-Income

$

Quantity Quantity

16

16

12

12

4 MC 4 MC

12 88

$328

$16$32

$

Offer the low-incomeconsumers a package of

entry plus 8 drinks for $64

Offer the low-incomeconsumers a package of

entry plus 8 drinks for $64

$32

$32

The low-demand consumers will bewilling to buy this ($64, 8) package

The low-demand consumers will bewilling to buy this ($64, 8) package

So will the high-income consumers:because the ($64, 8)

package gives them $32consumer surplus

So will the high-income consumers:because the ($64, 8)

package gives them $32consumer surplus

$64

$32

$8

So any other packageoffered to high-income

consumers must offer atleast $32 consumer surplus

So any other packageoffered to high-income

consumers must offer atleast $32 consumer surplus

This is the incentivecompatibility constraint

High income consumers arewilling to pay up to $120 for

entry plus 12 drinks if no otherpackage is available

High income consumers arewilling to pay up to $120 for

entry plus 12 drinks if no otherpackage is available

So they can be offered a packageof ($88, 12) (since $120 - 32 = 88)

and they will buy this

So they can be offered a packageof ($88, 12) (since $120 - 32 = 88)

and they will buy this

$24

Low income consumers will notbuy the ($88, 12)

package since theyare willing to payonly $72 for 12

drinks

Low income consumers will notbuy the ($88, 12)

package since theyare willing to payonly $72 for 12

drinks

$8

Profit from each high-income consumer is$40 ($88 - 12 x $4)

Profit from each high-income consumer is$40 ($88 - 12 x $4)

$40

And profit fromeach low-income

consumer is$32 ($64 - 8x$4)

And profit fromeach low-income

consumer is$32 ($64 - 8x$4)

$32

These packages exhibitquantity discounting: high-

income pay $7.33 per unit andlow-income pay $8

Page 21: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

21

Second degree price discrimination 5High-Income Low-Income

$

Quantity Quantity

16

16

12

12

4 MC 4 MC

12

$

Can the club-owner do even

better than this?

Can the club-owner do even

better than this?

8

Yes! Reduce the numberof units offered to eachlow-income consumer

Yes! Reduce the numberof units offered to eachlow-income consumer

Suppose each low-income consumer is offered 7 drinks

7

Each consumer will pay up to $59.50 for entry and 7 drinks

$59.50

Profit from each ($59.50, 7) package is $31.50: a reduction

of $0.50 per consumer

$31.50

A high-income consumer will pay up to $87.50 for entry and 7 drinks

7

$87.50

$28

So buying the ($59.50, 7) package gives him $28 consumer surplus

$28

So entry plus 12 drinks can be sold for $92 ($120 - 28 = $92)

$92

$28

Profit from each ($92, 12) package is $44: an increase of $4 per

consumer

$44

$48

The monopolist does better byreducing the number of units

offered to low-income consumerssince this allows him to increase

the charge to high-incomeconsumers

Page 22: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

22

Second-degree price discrimination 6

• Will the monopolist always want to supply both types of consumer?

• There are cases where it is better to supply only high-demand types– high-class restaurants

– golf and country clubs

• Take our example again– suppose that there are Nl low-income consumers

– and Nh high-income consumers

Page 23: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

23

Second-degree price discrimination 7

• Suppose both types of consumer are served– two packages are offered ($57.50, 7) aimed at low-income and

($92, 12) aimed at high-income

– profit is $31.50xNl + $44xNh

• Now suppose only high-income consumers are served– then a ($120, 12) package can be offered

– profit is $72xNh

• Is it profitable to serve both types?– Only if $31.50xNl + $44xNh > $72xNh 31.50Nl > 28Nh

This requires thatNh

Nl

<31.50

28= 1.125

There should not be “too high” a proportion of high-demand consumers

Page 24: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

24

Second-degree price discrimination 8

• Characteristics of second-degree price discrimination– extract all consumer surplus from the lowest-demand group

– leave some consumer surplus for other groups• the incentive compatibility constraint

– offer less than the socially efficient quantity to all groups other than the highest-demand group

– offer quantity-discounting

• Second-degree price discrimination converts consumer surplus into profit less effectively than first-degree

• Some consumer surplus is left “on the table” in order to induce high-demand groups to buy large quantities

Page 25: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

25

Non-linear pricing and welfare• Non-linear price discrimination

raises profit

• Does it increase social welfare?– suppose that inverse demand

of consumer group i is P = Pi(Q)

– marginal cost is constant at MC – c

– suppose quantity offered to consumer group i is Qi

– total surplus – consumer surplus plus profit –is the area between the inverse demand and marginal cost up to quantity Qi

Price

Quantity

Demand

c MC

Qi Qi(c)

TotalSurplus

Page 26: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

26

Non-linear pricing and welfare 2• Pricing policy affects

– distribution of surplus

– output of the firm

• First is welfare neutral

• Second affects welfare

• Does it increase social welfare?

• Price discrimination increases social welfare of group i if it increases quantity supplied to group i

Price

Quantity

Demand

c MC

Qi Qi(c)

TotalSurplus

Q’i

Page 27: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

27

Non-linear pricing and welfare 2• First-degree price

discrimination always increases social welfare– extracts all consumer surplus

– but generates socially optimal output

– output to group i is Qi(c)

– this exceeds output with uniform (non-discriminatory) pricing

Price

Quantity

Demand

c MC

Qi Qi(c)

TotalSurplus

Page 28: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

28

Non-linear pricing and welfare 3• Menu pricing is less straightforward

– suppose that there are two markets• low demand

• high demand

Price

QuantityPrice

Quantity

MC

MC

• Uniform price is PU

• Menu pricing gives quantities Q1s, Q2

s

PU

PU

QlU

QhU

• Welfare loss is greater than L

• Welfare gain is less than G

Qls

Qhs

L

G

High demand offered the

socially optimal quantity

Low demand offered less than

the socially optimal quantity

Page 29: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

29

Non-linear pricing and welfare 4Price

QuantityPrice

Quantity

MC

MC

PU

PU

QlU

QhU

Qls

Qhs

L

G

= (PU – MC)ΔQ1 + (PU – MC)ΔQ2

= (PU – MC)(ΔQ1 + ΔQ2)

ΔW < G – L

• A necessary condition for second-degree price discrimination to increase social welfare is that it increases total output

• It follows that

• “Like” third-degree price discrimination

• But second-degree price discrimination is more likely to increase output

Page 30: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

30

Page 31: Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing 1 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing.

Chapter 6: Price Discrimination: Nonlinear Pricing

31

The incentive compatibility constraint

• Any offer made to high demand consumers must offer them as much consumer surplus as they would get from an offer designed for low-demand consumers.

• This is a common phenomenon– performance bonuses must encourage effort

– insurance policies need large deductibles to deter cheating

– piece rates in factories have to be accompanied by strict quality inspection

– encouragement to buy in bulk must offer a price discount