Top Banner
1 Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing
30

Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

Jan 03, 2016

Download

Documents

Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing. Introduction Annual subscriptions generally cost less in total than one-off purchases Buying in bulk usually offers a price discount these are price discrimination reflecting quantity discounts - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
Page 1: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

1

Chapter 6

Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

Page 2: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

2

Introduction• Annual subscriptions generally cost less in total than one-

off purchases• Buying in bulk usually offers a price discount

– these are price discrimination reflecting quantity discounts

– prices are nonlinear, with the unit price dependent upon the quantity bought

– allows pricing closer to willingness to pay– so should be more profitable than third-degree price

discrimination• How to design such pricing schemes?

– depends upon the information available to the seller about buyers

Page 3: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

3

– distinguish first-degree (personalized) and second-degree (menu) pricing

First-degree price discrimination• Monopolist can charge maximum price that each consumer

is willing to pay• Extracts all consumer surplus• Since profit is now total surplus, find that first-degree price

discrimination is efficient• Suppose that you own five antique cars • Market research indicates that there are collectors of

different types– keenest is willing to pay $10,000 for a car, second

keenest $8,000, third keenest $6,000, fourth keenest $4,000, fifth keenest $2,000

Page 4: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

4

– sell the first car at $10,000– sell the second car at $8,000– sell the third car to at $6,000 and so on– total revenue $30,000

• Contrast with linear pricing: all cars sold at the same price– set a price of $6,000– sell three cars– total revenue $18,000

• First-degree price discrimination is highly profitable but requires

• detailed information• ability to avoid arbitrage

• Leads to the efficient choice of output: since price equals marginal revenue and MR = MC– no value-creating exchanges are missed

Page 5: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

5

• The information requirements appear to be insurmountable– but not in particular cases

• tax accountants, doctors, students applying to private universities

• No arbitrage is less restrictive but potentially a problem• But there are pricing schemes that will achieve the same

outcome– non-linear prices– two-part pricing as a particular example of non-linear

prices• charge a quantity-independent fee (membership?) plus

a per unit usage charge– block pricing is another

• bundle total charge and quantity in a package

Page 6: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

6

Two-part pricing • Jazz club serves two types of customer

– Old: demand for entry plus Qo drinks is P = Vo – Qo

– Young: demand for entry plus Qy drinks is P = Vy – Qy

– Equal numbers of each type– Assume that Vo > Vy: Old are willing to pay more than

Young– Cost of operating the jazz club C(Q) = F + cQ

• Demand and costs are all in daily units• Suppose that the jazz club owner applies “traditional” linear

pricing: free entry and a set price for drinks

aggregate demand is Q = Qo + Qy = (Vo + Vy) – 2P

invert to give: P = (Vo + Vy)/2 – Q/2

MR is then MR = (Vo + Vy)/2 – Q

Page 7: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

7

equate MR and MC, where MC = c and solve for Q to give QU = (Vo + Vy)/2 – c

substitute into aggregate demand to give the equilibrium price PU = (Vo + Vy)/4 + c/2

each Old consumer buys

Qo = (3Vo – Vy)/4 – c/2 drinks

each Young consumer buys

Qy = (3Vy – Vo)/4 – c/2 drinks

profit from each pair of Old and Young is

U = (Vo + Vy – 2c)2

Page 8: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

8

Two part pricing

This example can be illustrated as follows:

Price

Quantity

Vo

Vo

Price

Quantity

Vy

Vy

Price

Quantity

Vo

Vo + Vy

MC

MR

(a) Old Customers (b) Young Customers (c) Old/Young Pair of Customers

Vo+Vy

2- c

c

Vo+Vy

4+ c

2h i

jk

a

bd

e

fg

Linear pricing leaves each type of consumer with consumer surplus

Page 9: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

9

Jazz club owner can do better than this• Consumer surplus at the uniform linear price is:

– Old: CSo = (Vo – PU).Qo/2 = (Qo)2/2

– Young: CSy = (Vy – PU).Qy/2 = (Qy)2/2

• So charge an entry fee (just less than):

– Eo = CSo to each Old customer and Ey = CSy to each Young customer• check IDs to implement this policy

– each type will still be willing to frequent the club and buy the equilibrium number of drinks

• So this increases profit by Eo for each Old and Ey for each Young customer

Page 10: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

10

• The jazz club can do even better– reduce the price per drink

– this increases consumer surplus

– but the additional consumer surplus can be extracted through a higher entry fee

• Consider the best that the jazz club owner can do with respect to each type of consumer

Page 11: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

11

Two-Part Pricing$

Quantity

Vi

Vi

MR

MCc

Set the unit price equalto marginal cost

Set the unit price equalto marginal cost

This gives consumer surplus of (Vi - c)2/2

This gives consumer surplus of (Vi - c)2/2

The entry chargeconverts consumersurplus into profit

Vi - cSet the entry charge

to (Vi - c)2/2

Set the entry chargeto (Vi - c)2/2

Profit from each pair of Old and Young is now d = [(Vo – c)2 + (Vy – c)2]/2

Using two-part

pricing increases themonopolist’s

profit

Page 12: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

12

Block pricing• There is another pricing method that the club owner can

apply– offer a package of “Entry plus X drinks for $Y”

• To maximize profit apply two rules– set the quantity offered to each consumer type equal to

the amount that type would buy at price equal to marginal cost

– set the total charge for each consumer type to the total willingness to pay for the relevant quantity

• Return to the example:

Page 13: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

13

Block pricing 2Old

$

Quantity

Vo

Vo

Young$

Quantity

Vy

Vy

MC MCc c

Quantity supplied to each Old customer

Quantity supplied to each Young

customer

Qo Qy

Willingness to pay of each Old

customer

Willingness to pay of each Young

customer

WTPo = (Vo – c)2/2 + (Vo – c)c = (Vo2 – c2)/2

WTPy = (Vy – c)2/2 + (Vy – c)c = (Vy2 – c2)/2

Page 14: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

14

• How to implement this policy?– card at the door– give customers the requisite number of tokens that are

exchanged for drinksOne final point• average price that is paid by an Old customer = (Vo

2 – c2)/2(Vo – c) = (Vo + c)/2

• average price paid by a Young customer = (Vy2 – c2)/2(Vo –

c) = (Vy + c)/2• identical to the third-degree price discrimination (linear)

prices• but the profit outcome is much better with first-degree price

discrimination. Why?– consumer equates MC of last unit bought with marginal

benefit

Page 15: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

15

– with linear pricing MC = AC (= average price)– with first-degree price discrimination MC of last unit

bought is less than AC (= average price) so more is bought

Second-degree price discrimination• What if the seller cannot distinguish between buyers?

– perhaps they differ in income (unobservable)• Then the type of price discrimination just discussed is

impossible• High-income buyer will pretend to be a low-income buyer

– to avoid the high entry price– to pay the smaller total charge

• Take a specific example

Ph = 16 – Qh & Pl = 12 – Ql

MC = 4

Page 16: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

16

• First-degree price discrimination requires:– High Income: entry fee $72 and $4 per drink or entry

plus 12 drinks for a total charge of $120– Low Income: entry fee $32 and $4 per drink or entry plus

8 drinks for total charge of $64• This will not work

– high income types get no consumer surplus from the package designed for them but get consumer surplus from the other package

– so they will pretend to be low income even if this limits the number of drinks they can buy

• Need to design a “menu” of offerings targeted at the two types

Page 17: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

17

The seller has to compromise• Design a pricing scheme that makes buyers

– reveal their true types– self-select the quantity/price package designed for them

• Essence of second-degree price discrimination• It is “like” first-degree price discrimination

– the seller knows that there are buyers of different types– but the seller is not able to identify the different types

• A two-part tariff is ineffective– allows deception by buyers

• Use quantity discounting

Page 18: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

18

Second degree price discrimination

High-income Low-Income

$

Quantity Quantity

16

16

12

12

4 MC 4 MC

12 88

$328

$16$32

$

$32

$32

$64

$32

$8$24

$8

$40 $32

Page 19: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

19

1, Offer the low-demand consumers a package of entry plus 8 drinks for $64

2, The low-demand consumers will be willing to buy this ($64, 8) package

3, So will the high-demand consumers:because the ($64, 8) package gives them $32 consumer surplus

4, So any other package offered to high-income consumers must offer at least $32 consumer surplus

5, This is the incentive compatibility constraint– Any offer made to high demand consumers must offer

them as much consumer surplus as they would get from an offer designed for low-demand consumers.

– This is a common phenomenon• performance bonuses must encourage effort• insurance policies need large deductibles to deter

cheating

Page 20: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

20

• piece rates in factories have to be accompanied by strict quality inspection

• encouragement to buy in bulk must offer a price discount

6, High demand consumers are willing to pay up to $120 for entry plus 12 drinks if no other package is available

7, So they can be offered a package of ($88, 12) (since $120 - 32 = 88) and they will buy this

8, Low demand consumers will not buy the ($88, 12) package since they are willing to pay only $72 for 12 drinks

9, Profit from each high-demand consumer is $40 ($88 - 12 x $4)10, And profit from each low-demand consumer is $32 ($64 - 8x$4) 11, These packages exhibit quantity discounting: high-

demand pay $7.33 per unit and low-demand pay $8

Page 21: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

21

• Can the club-owner do even better than this? Yes, reduce the number of units offered to each low income consumer

• See next slide first.

• The monopolist does better by reducing the number of units offered to low-income consumers since this allows him to increase the charge to high income consumers.

Page 22: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

22

High-Demand

Low-Demand

$

Quantity Quantity

16

16

12

12

4 MC 4 MC

12

$

Can the club-owner do even better than this? Yes

Can the club-owner do even better than this? Yes

8

Suppose each low-demand consumer is offered 7 drinks

7

Each consumer will pay up to $59.50 for entry and 7 drinks

$59.50

Profit from each ($59.50, 7) package is $31.50: a reduction

of $0.50 per consumer

$31.50

A high-demand consumer will pay up to $87.50 for entry and 7 drinks

7

$87.50

$28

So buying the ($59.50, 7) package gives him $28 consumer surplus

$28

So entry plus 12 drinks can be sold for $92 ($120 - 28 = $92)

$92

$28

Profit from each ($92, 12) package is $44: an increase of $4 per

consumer

$44

$48

Page 23: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

23

• Will the monopolist always want to supply both types of consumer?

• There are cases where it is better to supply only high-demand types– high-class restaurants– golf and country clubs

• Take our example again– suppose that there are Nl low-income consumers– and Nh high-income consumers

• Suppose both types of consumer are served– two packages are offered ($57.50, 7) aimed at low-

income and ($92, 12) aimed at high-income– profit is $31.50xNl + $44xNh

• Now suppose only high-income consumers are served– then a ($120, 12) package can be offered

Page 24: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

24

• Profit is $31.50xNl + $44xNh

• Now suppose only high-demand consumers are served– then a ($120, 12) package can be offered

– profit is $72xNh

• Is it profitable to serve both types?

– Only if $31.50xNl + $44xNh > $72xNh

31.50Nl > 28Nh

This requires thatNh

Nl

<31.50

28= 1.125

There should not be “too high” a proportion of high-demand consumers

Page 25: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

25

• Characteristics of second-degree price discrimination– extract all consumer surplus from the lowest-demand

group– leave some consumer surplus for other groups

• the incentive compatibility constraint– offer less than the socially efficient quantity to all

groups other than the highest-demand group– offer quantity-discounting

• Second-degree price discrimination converts consumer surplus into profit less effectively than first-degree

• Some consumer surplus is left “on the table” in order to induce high-demand groups to buy large quantities

Page 26: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

26

Non-linear pricing and welfare• Non-linear price discrimination

raises profit

• Does it increase social welfare?– suppose that inverse demand of

consumer group i is P = Pi(Q)

– marginal cost is constant at MC – c

– suppose quantity offered to consumer group i is Qi

– total surplus – consumer surplus plus profit –is the area between the inverse demand and marginal cost up to quantity Qi

Price

Quantity

Demand

c MC

Qi Qi(c)

TotalSurplus

Page 27: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

27

Non-linear pricing and welfare

• Pricing policy affects– distribution of surplus

– output of the firm

• First is welfare neutral

• Second affects welfare

• Does it increase social welfare?

• Price discrimination increases social welfare of group i if it increases quantity supplied to group i

Price

Quantity

Demand

c MC

Qi Qi(c)

TotalSurplus

Q’i

Page 28: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

28

Non-linear pricing and welfare

• First-degree price discrimination always increases social welfare– extracts all consumer surplus– but generates socially optimal

output– output to group i is Qi(c)– this exceeds output with

uniform (non-discriminatory) pricing

Price

Quantity

Demand

c MC

Qi Qi(c)

TotalSurplus

Page 29: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

29

Non-linear pricing and welfare • Menu pricing is less

straightforward– suppose that there are two markets

• low demand

• high demand

Price

QuantityPrice

Quantity

MC

MC

• Uniform price is PU

• Menu pricing gives quantities Q1s, Q2

s

PU

PU

QlU

QhU

• Welfare loss is greater than L

• Welfare gain is less than G

Qls

Qhs

L

G

High demand offered the

socially optimal quantity

Low demand offered less than

the socially optimal quantity

Page 30: Chapter 6 Price Discrimination and Monopoly: Nonlinear Pricing

30

Non-linear pricing and welfare

Price

QuantityPrice

Quantity

MC

MC

PU

PU

QlU

QhU

Qls

Qhs

L

G

= (PU – MC)ΔQ1 + (PU – MC)ΔQ2

= (PU – MC)(ΔQ1 + ΔQ2)

ΔW < G – L

• A necessary condition for second-degree price discrimination to increase social welfare is that it increases total output

• It follows that

• “Like” third-degree price discrimination

• But second-degree price discrimination is more likely to increase output