Top Banner

of 19

Bureaucratic Capacity

Apr 04, 2018

Download

Documents

Oana Dumitrescu
Welcome message from author
This document is posted to help you gain knowledge. Please leave a comment to let me know what you think about it! Share it to your friends and learn new things together.
Transcript
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    1/19

    http://apr.sagepub.com

    American Politics Research

    DOI: 10.1177/1532673X073016542007; 35; 790American Politics Research

    Jason A. MacDonald and William W. Franko, JRCongress Tie Policy Authority to Performance?

    Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion: Does

    http://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/35/6/790

    The online version of this article can be found at:

    Published by:

    http://www.sagepublications.com

    can be found at:American Politics ResearchAdditional services and information for

    http://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/alertsEmail Alerts:

    http://apr.sagepub.com/subscriptionsSubscriptions:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navReprints:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navPermissions:

    http://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/content/refs/35/6/790SAGE Journals Online and HighWire Press platforms):

    (this article cites 12 articles hosted on theCitations

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://apr.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://apr.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://apr.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/content/refs/35/6/790http://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/content/refs/35/6/790http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/content/refs/35/6/790http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://apr.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://apr.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    2/19

    790

    American Politics Research

    Volume 35 Number 6

    November 2007 790-807

    2007 Sage Publications

    10.1177/1532673X07301654

    http://apr.sagepub.comhosted at

    http://online.sagepub.com

    Authors Note: The authors would like to thank Steve Balla and anonymous reviewers for

    American Politics Research for comments that improved this manuscript. This research was

    supported in part by the University Research Council of Kent State University.

    Bureaucratic Capacity andBureaucratic Discretion

    Does Congress Tie Policy Authority

    to Performance?

    Jason A. MacDonaldWilliam W. Franko Jr.

    Kent State University

    This article assesses whether the managerial capacity of agencies influences

    the volume of policy authority that lawmakers delegate. Examining a sample

    of agencies whose managerial capacities were assessed along the same criteria,

    and allowing for the comparison of performance across agencies, we observe

    that poorly performing agencies are more likely to lose policy authority. Our

    findings suggest that lawmakers promote effective policymaking by giving

    agencies the incentive to perform well and that models of discretion that do notaccount for performance underestimate the effect of another factorpolicy

    conflict between the legislative and executive brancheson how much discretion

    agencies receive.

    Keywords: bureaucracy; Congress; public policy; bureaucratic discretion;

    agency capacity; delegation; policy authority

    Modern democracies confront complex problems, often employingpolicies that combine scientific knowledge across disciplines fromthe natural sciences and engineering to economics and policy analysis.Given this complexity, it is unlikely that modern lawmakerswith their

    backgrounds in law, business, and public servicewill ever be the most

    well-equipped individuals in government to design policy mechanisms to

    pursue favorable outcomes for these problems. Yet electoral status confers

    on lawmakers both the legitimacy to make policy decisions and the incen-

    tive to balance competing societal values and interests successfully. In part,

    lawmakers manage this responsibilitycapacity mismatch by delegating

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    3/19

    MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion 791

    authority to make policy decisions to the bureaucracy, as has been documented

    in diverse research traditions from the political economy of institutional

    design (e.g., McCubbins, Noll, & Weingast, 1987; Moe, 1989) to Americanpolitical development (e.g., Carpenter, 2001; James, 2000).

    A major area of research on delegation involves assessing why lawmak-

    ers vary the level of discretion provided to agencies, where discretion is

    defined as bureaucratic freedom to make policy decisions free from con-

    straints, such as rulemaking-requirements, and other tools used by law-

    makers to influence the substance of bureaucratic decisions (Epstein &

    OHalloran, 1999, chapter 5). A central finding of this research is that as

    policy disagreement between lawmakers and agencies increases lawmakersreduce the volume of discretion that agencies receive (Epstein & OHalloran,

    1999; Huber & Shipan, 2002; Huber, Shipan, & Pfahler, 2001; Lewis,

    2003; Potoski, 1999; Wood & Bohte, 2004). The theoretical basis for this

    finding is that policy disagreement prevents lawmakers from trusting agen-

    cies to render policy decisions consistent with lawmakers priorities. In the

    language of the transaction cost approach taken by these studies, such dis-

    agreement increases the costs of delegation to lawmakers to the point at

    which it becomes less costly for them to make policy themselves by writingdetailed laws (see especially Epstein & OHalloran, 1999 and Huber &

    Shipan, 2002).

    These studies constitute significant theoretical and empirical progress in

    understanding why agencies receive discretion to make policy. However,

    this literature does not address the question of whether lawmakers vary dis-

    cretion based on the capacity of agencies to make policies that are effective

    in meeting policy goals. This issue is central to understanding whether law-

    makers decisions in delegating policy authority contribute to the capacity

    of democratic governments to solve problems. Some agencies perform the

    tasks delegated to them effectively, solving problems that the architects of

    legislation place in their hands, whereas other agencies flounder (Ingraham,

    Joyce, & Donahue, 2003). To be sure, theories of delegation stress that law-

    makers provide greater discretion to agencies as policy complexity increases

    (Bawn, 1995; Epstein & OHalloran, 1999; Huber & Shipan, 2002). For

    any number of equally complex policy areas, though, the capacity of

    agencies to make effective policy can vary. Do agencies with greater/

    lesser capacities receive higher/lower levels of discretion? If the answeris in the affirmative, then there is reason to believe that democratic govern-

    ments can create effective solutions to important problems; however, if

    lawmakers do not tie bureaucratic authority, at least in part, to bureaucratic

    capacity, students of government should be more sanguine about the ability

    of democracies to solve many problems.

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    4/19

    792 American Politics Research

    Agency Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion

    Research on discretion, bureaucratic autonomy, and agency terminationprovides a basis for the hypothesis that agency capacity affects the latitude

    agencies receive to make policy decisions, though no empirical research

    employs a systematic indicator of capacity that varies across agencies to

    assess the relationship. With respect to discretion, formal models predict

    that lawmakers provide greater discretion to agencies as policy complexity

    increaseseven when lawmakers expect that agencies will make policy

    decisions that stray from lawmakers priorities (Bawn, 1995; Epstein &

    OHalloran, 1999; Huber & Shipan, 2002). The basis for this result is thatlawmakers need for policy solutions trumps the loss of utility they experi-

    ence from bureaucratic shirking. The implication of this research for the

    relationship between capacity and discretion is clear. If lawmakers did not

    care about effective policy solutions, there would be no reason to delegate

    when agencies are likely to make decisions that stray from lawmakers

    priorities. Of course, if agencies reputations for effective policymaking are

    poor, then lawmakers have reason to doubt that agencies will produce effec-

    tive solutions, undercutting the rationale for ceding discretion. This literature,therefore, suggests that agency capacity to perform the tasks delegated

    effectively is positively related to discretion.

    Research on bureaucratic autonomy suggests the same relationship,

    though the causal mechanism differs. Examining the histories of three agen-

    cies during the late 19th and early 20th centuries, Carpenter (2001) argues

    that elected institutions cede policy authority after agencies evidence the

    capacity to solve policy problems. Briefly, this capacity was created by

    middle-level managers, whose career longevities and institutional positions

    fostered policy learning and the ability to build support for policies they

    favored among diverse sets of interest groups. After securing interest group

    support for the policies they wanted to pursuein part because of sound

    reputations for the capacity to solve problems effectivelythese managers

    were able to place electoral pressure on members of Congress to give man-

    agers authority to create policies that they favored. Bureaucratic autonomy,

    then, was largely the result of sound policy performance engineered by man-

    agerial leadership.

    Research on agency termination also provides a basis for the hypothesisthat discretion is because of the capacity to make policies effectively.

    Carpenter (2000) and Carpenter and Lewis (2004) argue that failure by an

    agency, accompanied by media coverage of the negative consequences of

    its bungling of the tasks to which it was assigned, imposes political fallout

    on the legislators that delegated authority. Such costs might include the loss

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    5/19

    of electoral support from key constituencies, the provision of an election

    issue to an opponent who could trace the lawmaker to the failure (Arnold,

    1990) by credibly arguing that the lawmaker presided over the fiasco, andhaving to allocate scarce time on the legislative calendar in the future to

    revisit the policy. These costs increase the likelihood that legislators will

    exercise the ultimate act of political control (Carpenter & Lewis, 2004,

    p. 202), eliminating the agencyan act that, to understate the point,

    reduces discretion.

    In summary, various research traditions on the authority that agencies

    receive either suggest, or explicitly state, that discretion increases with

    agency capacity. The basis for this relationship is that lawmakers observethe capacity of agencies to perform the policymaking tasks delegated to

    them through a variety of means, including media reports (Carpenter &

    Lewis, 2004) and information from interest groups and constituents dissat-

    isfied with agencies (McCubbins & Schwartz, 1984) and react by manipu-

    lating discretion in the future. Yet empirical support for this hypothesis is

    wanting. Neither research on discretion nor agency termination incorpo-

    rates variables into empirical models of these phenomena to assess the

    influence of capacity on bureaucratic policy authority. Although Carpenter(2001) shows that the authority of the three agencies was due in large part

    to their reputation for effective policymaking, this finding has not been

    extended to contemporary politics.

    Data and Methods

    One reason why the relationship between capacity and discretion is

    not well understood empirically is because of the difficulty of calibrating

    capacity/performance in a valid manner and comparing it systematically

    across agencies. We take advantage of the availability of such a measure

    for a sample of 27 federal agencies. This sample was created by a joint

    effort of the Federal Performance Project (FPP), teamed by scholars in the

    Department of Public Administration at The George Washington University

    (GW) and correspondents for Government Executive, a biweekly periodical

    that provides specialized coverage of federal agencies. The project evaluated

    how well all agencies managed the tasks to which they were assigned, gradingagencies in 1999, 2000, and 2001. To be clear, the FPP did not assess how

    well agencies achieved the policy goals assigned to them by laws enacted

    in the past. Rather, the project assessed how well agency managers managed

    for results based on the criteria employed by the researchers.1 Managing

    MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion 793

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    6/19

    for Results refers to administrating agencies, so that they can realize the out-

    comes they are charged with achieving by law. The researchers employed

    surveys of agency managers and employees, external reports on agencyeffectiveness, and interviews with experts on the agencies inside and outside

    government to gauge performance.2 Researchers at George Washington

    University and correspondents for Government Executive then evaluated

    this information across agencies and assigned grades based on the performance

    of agencies in relation to one another. Hence, according to the collective

    judgment of the researchers, agencies receiving As performed better than

    agencies receiving Bs on these criteria and so on. As such, the grades

    constitute assessments of the managerial capacity of agencies. A presence/lack of capacity indicates the success/failure of managers to facilitate the

    realization of policy results desired by political principals.

    Although the sample of agencies is small, it represents the best data on

    agency capacity that are comparable across multiple agencies.3 Hence, in

    evaluating the connection between capacity and discretion, it makes sense

    to use this data as a starting point. Twenty-seven agencies were selected by

    FPP researchers because of their close interaction with the public. Therefore,

    the agencies do not represent a random sample of all federal agencies andour findings cannot be so generalized. Appendix A itemizes these agencies.

    The unit of analysis is the agency, that is, each agency has one observation

    and includes information on the grade received in the year that it was

    graded, as well as the other independent variables and the dependent

    variable described below.

    In evaluating the agencies management of their tasks, the FPP employed

    a grade range from F to A. However, no agency received F to D

    grades, limiting the range of the variables created to measure performance.

    Below, we assess the relationship between how much Congress limits the

    agencies discretion in the year after the grades were assigned and these

    grades. We do so by measuring capacity in three ways. First, we employ the

    plus/minus grades on a 1-13 scale with a grade of F coded as 1 and an

    A coded as 13 (in practice, the scale ranged between 4 and 13). Second,

    we employ a collapsed, traditional grade version of this variable ranging

    from F (1) to A (5) to guard against the possibility that there is little dif-

    ference between, for example, a B and B (in practice, this scale

    ranged between 2 and 5). Finally, to account for the possibility that perfor-mance affects discretion in a nonlinear manner, we create dummy variables

    for whether the agencies received grades of D, C, or B (1 if the agen-

    cies received these grades; 0 otherwise), with A as the reference category

    (because no agency received an F, no dummy variable for this grade was

    794 American Politics Research

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    7/19

    created). The basis for this variable is that Congress may not view the dif-

    ference between an A and B performance as it does a C and D per-

    formance. For example, Congress may take no action to limit the discretionof an agency when it receives a B instead of an A; although the

    agencys performance is not excellent, its mere good performance probably

    will not cause a political fallout. However, once an agencys performance

    becomes lackluster, for example, if the agencys performance is worthy of

    a D, political principals may limit discretion. Calibrating performance in

    this way allows us to observe such nonlinear effects. To be clear, we offer

    no theory that specifies precisely how poorly an agency must perform to

    lose discretion; rather, we note that it makes sense theoretically thatCongress will limit discretion after performance has become sufficiently

    poor. How low capacity must be to reach this tipping point will remain

    an empirical question.4

    To measure discretion, we create a variable that is the count of the

    number of limitation riders (LRs) attached to agencies appropriations in

    the year after their managerial capacities were assessed by the FPP. LRs

    forbid agencies from spending money for specific purposes. Importantly,

    agencies possess the authority to use funds for these purposes from pastlaws. However, when an LR is included in an appropriations bill that

    becomes law, agencies are prohibited from exercising that authority during

    the next fiscal year, limiting their discretion. For example, the fiscal year

    2001 Labor, Health and Human Services, and Education appropriations bill

    mandated that none of the funds . . . may be used by the Occupational

    Safety and Health Administration to promulgate, issue, implement, admin-

    ister, or enforce any proposed, temporary, or final standard on ergonomic

    protection. Congress includes hundreds of such LRs in appropriations bills

    annually (MacDonald, 2007), giving it an annual opportunity to reign in

    agency authority. As such, LRs constitute a tool that Congress employs to

    constrain agency authority regularly, making these tools of political control

    a valid indicator of the limitation of discretion.5

    To measure how much Congress impinged on discretion, we counted the

    number of LRs in Congresss annual appropriation acts that applied to each

    of the 27 agencies in the year after their performances were evaluated by the

    FPP.6 We examined LRs in the subsequent year because that was Congresss

    first opportunity to limit discretion after performance was assessed duringthe period for which grades were assigned.7 Therefore, for agencies whose

    performances were assessed in 1999/2000/2001, we counted LRs imposed

    on these agencies in the appropriations bills passed in 2000/2001/2002.

    If discretion is reduced because of low capacity, the relationship between this

    MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion 795

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    8/19

    dependent variable and the independent variables measuring capacity using

    the plus/minus and traditional grade scales should be negative and sig-

    nificant, whereas its relationship with the dummy variables indicating thepresence of low capacity (e.g., the dummy variable for agencies who received

    the grade of D) should be positive and significant.

    Because research demonstrates that Congress limits discretion when

    faced with a president of the opposite party (Epstein & OHalloran, 1999),

    a finding that holds for state governments (Huber & Shipan, 2002; Huber

    et al., 2001), we control for partisan conflict between the legislative and

    executive branches. To do so, we employ a dummy variable assuming the

    value of 1 when there is pure divided government, meaning that the pres-idency was controlled by one party and both chambers of Congress were

    controlled by its rival. Therefore, observations for agencies graded in 1999,

    for which we counted LRs applied in 2000 (under Democratic control of the

    presidency and Republican control of the House and Senate), were coded 1.

    Observations for agencies graded in 2000 and 2001, for which we counted

    LRs applied in 2001 and 2002, respectively (under Republican control of the

    presidency and House and Democratic control of the Senate), were coded as

    0. Although the Democratic Senate had the opportunity to influence the sub-stance of appropriations bills during these years, its capacity to do so was

    limited to a greater degree than was the case for the Republicans who con-

    trolled both chambers in 2000. We expect this variable to be positively and

    significantly related to the number of LRs imposed on agencies.

    We also account for congressional and presidential policy disagreement

    with agencies missions. Carpenter and Lewis (2004) show that agencies are

    more likely to be eliminated when the same party controls the U.S. House and

    the presidency but held minority status in the House and did not control the

    presidency when the agency was created. Agencies in this situation are in a

    precarious position because the current majority party is likely to object to the

    policy priorities embodied in the agencies missions. This conditiona uni-

    fied governments hostility toward agenciesmissionsmakes it more likely

    for such agencies to lose discretion. Therefore, following Carpenter and

    Lewis (2004), we create a variable assuming the value of 1 when this hos-

    tility condition holds, 0 otherwise, and expect this variable to be positively

    and significantly associated with the imposition of LRs.

    Additionally, because research shows that the public salience of policiesincreases the likelihood that members of Congress make, rather than dele-

    gate, policy (Epstein & OHalloran, 1999, chap. 8; Gormley, 1986, 1989) and

    that Congress tries to influence bureaucratic policy decisions to a greater

    extent in salient policy areas (Ringquist, Worsham, & Eisner, 2003), we control

    796 American Politics Research

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    9/19

    for the salience of the policy area over which agencies have jurisdiction. This

    variable is a count of the number of stories appearing in theNew York Times

    in which the agency was mentioned during the year before the agency wasgraded.8 In general, the Timess coverage is followed by other media outlets

    (Page, 1996). As such, this count approximates the degree to which the agen-

    cies missions are made salient to the public. We expect that it will be posi-

    tively and significantly related to the imposition of LRs.9

    Finally, we control for the size of the appropriation bill in which the agen-

    cies were funded, because bigger bills may contain a higher volume of LRs.

    Appendix B provides summary statistics for all variables employed in the

    analysis.10

    Because the dependent variable is a count, we employ the Poissonmaximum likelihood estimator to assess the effects of the independent vari-

    ables on the volume of LRs using the traditional grade-scale specification

    and the dummy variable grade specification. In using the plus/minus grade

    scale specification, likelihood ratio tests indicated that the variance of the

    dependent variable exceeded its mean; therefore, we employed the negative

    binomial maximum likelihood estimator for this model.

    Findings

    Models 1, 2, and 3 of Table 1 present estimates for the influence of the

    independent variables on the volume of LRs, employing the traditional

    grade scale variable (Model 1), the plus/minus grade scale variable

    (Model 2), and dummy variables for agency grades (Model 3). The hypoth-

    esis that Congress limits discretion as capacity declines is supported in all

    three models. Measuring capacity using the traditional and plus/minus

    grades assigned to the agencies yields a negative and significant association

    between the number of LRs imposed on agencies and the coefficient for

    agency grades. Additionally, in Model 3, the coefficients of the dummy vari-

    ables indicating that the agency received Cs and Ds are positively and

    significantly associated with the number of LRs with which agencies were

    burdened. This specification supports the interpretation that once agency per-

    formance drops below some adequate level at which Congress is willing to

    leave agencies alone, Congress will reduce discretion. Empirically, Model 3

    identifies this threshold level as the performance that merits a C based onthe FPPs criteria.

    Table 2 provides information on the magnitude of the influence of per-

    formance, as measured by the traditional grade scale, on LRs use, as

    estimated by Model 1. Setting the values of the independent variables to

    MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion 797

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    10/19

    798 American Politics Research

    the modal or mean values, the model predicts that about 20 LRs will beimposed on agencies receiving a B.11 However, when agencies receive an

    A, this prediction drops to approximately 17 LRs. Conversely, when

    agencies managerial capacities are graded at the C and D levels, the

    model predicts that agencies will be saddled with about 25 and 30 LRs,

    Table 1

    Poisson Regression Models of the Imposition of Limitation

    Riders on the FPP Sample of Agencies in the Year AfterAgency Performance Was Graded

    Independent Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

    Traditional grade scale .191***

    (.056)

    Plus/minus grade scale .060***

    (.024)

    B .127

    (.145)C .277*

    (.141)

    D .784***

    (.230)

    Divided government .188 .107 .193

    (.144) (.132) (.121)

    Unified and hostile government .298* .321* .358**

    (.141) (.179) (.152)

    No. ofNew York Times stories .0010* .0010 .0010*

    (.0005) (.0007) (.0005)No. of pages in bill .005* .006* .004*

    (.002) (.003) (.002)

    Constant 3.254 3.120 2.636

    (.270) (.320) (.188)

    Log likelihood 86.181 85.57 85.02

    Chi-square 31.30*** 14.49*** 33.63***

    N 27 27 27

    Note: Coefficients are unstandardized. Standard errors are in parentheses. The estimates for

    Models 1 and 3 are Poisson maximum likelihood estimates, because likelihood ratio tests didnot reject the null hypothesis that the mean and variance of LRs were equal. The estimates for

    Model 2 are negative binomial maximum likelihood estimates, because the null hypothesis

    that the mean and variance of LRs were equal could be rejected (p < .05) and the alpha statis-

    tic was positive. Models 1 and 3 were also analyzed using the negative binomial estimator; the

    only change in the significance of the coefficients was that, for both models, the no. ofNew

    York Times stories variable was significant at the .1, rather than at the .05, level.p < .10. *p < .05. **p < .01. ***p < .001 (one-tailed tests).

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    11/19

    MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion 799

    respectively. Hence, a decline in performance from the maximum to mini-

    mum grades assigned by the FPP leads to almost a 2 standard deviation

    increase in the number of LRs that Congress is expected to impose on agen-

    cies. Simulationsnot presentedbased on the coefficients from Model 2

    present a similar story. Simulations using the coefficients from Model 3

    paint a more nuanced picture of the relationship between managerial per-

    formance and discretion. Setting the independent variables to their mean

    and modal values with the dummy variable for a B grade equal to 1,

    Model 3 predicts that Congress will impose about 21 LRs on agencies, a

    prediction that decreases to 18 if agencies receive As, and increases to 24

    if agencies receive Cs. However, Model 3 predicts that Congress will

    attach about 41 LRs to appropriations language funding agenciesprograms

    during the next fiscal year if a D is assigned to their managerial perfor-mance. This finding suggests that there is a nonlinear relationship between

    performance and discretion. It is also consistent with a bounded ratio-

    nality explanation of political institutions (Jones & Baumgartner, 2005).

    Specifically, the finding suggests that Congress underreacts to information

    Table 2

    The Predicted Number of Limitation Riders by Agency

    Characteristics (Model 1 Estimates)

    Predicted Values for Model 1:

    Agency Characteristics Traditional Grade Scale

    Performance

    A 16.62

    B (baseline) 20.30

    C 24.65

    D 29.98

    Policy disagreement with agenciesAgency has support in at least one branch (baseline) 20.30

    Unified and hostile government 27.93

    No. ofNew York Times stories

    Mean (baseline) 20.30

    + 1 Standard deviation 21.61

    Note: Predicted values were calculated using Clarify (Tomz et al., 2003). The predicted values

    are compared with a hypothetical, or baseline model, where the variables are set to the

    modal or mean categories. The baseline was calculated using an agency operating under

    divided government that received a B, was created during a period when the presidency andthe House were not controlled by a unified and hostile party, and was covered by theNew York

    Times at the mean level for all agencies (58.63 stories). The bill in which the baseline agency

    was funded spanned 65.85 pages.

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    12/19

    stressing that the performance of agencies is merely average (C grades),

    limiting discretion slightly. However, when Congress learns that agency

    performance is poor (D grades), it decreases discretion greatly.The hypothesis that divided government reduces discretion receives

    some support for the models presented in Table 1. The coefficient for the

    divided government variable is positively and significantly related to the

    number of LRs imposed on agencies in Models 1 and 3, albeit at the .1

    level. Turning to the hypothesis that a unified and hostile government leads

    to less discretion, the coefficient for a hostile and unified government is

    positive and significant in all three models, providing support for the

    hypothesis. Table 2 provides information on the magnitude of this relation-ship, showing that Model 1 predicts about eight additional LRs (approxi-

    mately 1 standard deviation of the dependent variable) for an agency

    supervised by a U.S. House and a president controlled by the opposite party

    that created the agency.

    Additionally, the number of stories in theNew York Times mentioning

    agencies is positively and significantly related to the number of LRs

    imposed on agencies in all three models presented in Table 1. Table 2 shows

    that Model 1 predicts two additional LRs for agencies mentioned by theTimes at a standard deviation above the mean of that variable. This finding

    supports the hypothesis derived from the work of Gormley (1986, 1989) by

    Ringquist et al. (2003) that Congress will try to influence the bureaucracys

    policy decisions to a greater degree in policy areas that the public views as

    salient. Ringquist et al. (2003) find that Congress both introduces and

    passes a greater number of new bills to reverse agency decisions when

    agencies preside over policy areas of salience to the public. The positive

    and significant coefficients for this variable, though not the main focus of

    the research presented in this article, reinforce this finding.

    One objection to the analysis presented above involves the ability to

    draw conclusions based on this small sample of agencies. What if the few

    agencies receiving very low grades happened to be burdened with relatively

    high numbers of LRs for idiosyncratic reasons, and these reasons led to the

    significant relationships between performance and discretion observed in

    the models? If this is the case, a sample with more agencies, or an analysis

    including the entire population of federal agencies, would make it less

    likely that we would make a Type I error and reject the null hypothesis thatperformance does not influence discretion when it is in fact true. To

    respond to this very real concern, we reestimated Models 1 and 2 without

    the one observation for which an agency received a D. In Model 1, the

    coefficient for the Traditional Grade Scale variable remained positive and

    800 American Politics Research

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    13/19

    significant (p < .05). This finding held for Model 2, though the significance

    slipped to the .1 level.12 In other words, it is not simply one observation dri-

    ving the finding that Congress imposes a greater number of LRs on agenciesas the managerial performance of agencies decreases.13

    Conclusions

    The Federal Emergency Management Agencys (FEMA) bungling of the

    federal response to the devastation wrought by Hurricane Katrina and the

    scurrying by members of Congress and President Bush to avoid the politi-cal fallout (e.g., VandeHei, 2005; Weisman & Goldstein, 2005) demonstrate

    that poor performance on the part of agencies managers can create substantial

    trouble for elected officials.14 Additionally, formal theories of delegation

    stress that legislatures are willing to trade control over policy for the technical

    expertise agencies offer (Bawn, 1995; Epstein & OHalloran, 1999). It should

    be no surprise, then, that when agencies perform poorly elected officials

    respond by stripping agency authority.

    Yet to our knowledge, no prior research has examined the relationshipbetween agency capacity and discretion across a large sample of agencies.

    To be sure, research on agency termination emphasizes agency failure as a

    factor that increases the risk of termination (Carpenter, 2000; Carpenter &

    Lewis, 2004); however, this research does not show a relationship between

    these phenomena because of the lack of a measure of performance across

    the sample of agencies it examines. Using a unique data set, we observe that

    lower levels of performance are indeed associated with the loss of discre-

    tion, controlling for the political environment, the salience of the agency,

    and the size of appropriations legislation through which lawmakers scale

    back discretion.

    These findings suggest the need to account for performance for a more

    complete understanding of why lawmakers grant discretion. Importantly,

    this emphasis on performance implies that lawmakers give agencies the

    incentive to make effective policies. If agencies want freedom to design the

    programs under their direction, as research on bureaucratic policymaking

    emphasizes (Carpenter, 2001), then convincing lawmakers of their effec-

    tiveness is one way to obtain this freedom. Although prior studies of discre-tion improved the understanding of interbranch policymaking substantially,

    they provided no evidence as to whether lawmakers rewarded effective

    agencies by increasing their authority to make policy decisions (or punished

    ineffective agencies by reducing such authority). Our analysis, however,

    MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion 801

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    14/19

    implies that lawmakers promote effective policymaking, a hopeful finding

    in an era in which many problems are complex and require bureaucratic

    expertise. As such, it is consistent with recent research stressing thatCongress sometimes fosters effective policymaking by employing policy

    research (Esterling, 2004).

    An additional implication of this study is that models of discretion that do

    not control for performance risk underestimating the influence of legislative

    executive policy conflict on discretion. Consider one hypothetical case dur-

    ing unified government when legislativeexecutive conflict is low, and, all

    else equal, lawmakers are prone to grant discretion (Epstein & OHalloran,

    1999; Huber & Shipan, 2002). Nevertheless, the agency that would imple-ment a law under consideration has a poor record of performance, leading

    lawmakers to scale back the agencys discretion. In contrast, a second case

    occurs during divided government when lawmakers, all else equal, lean

    toward slashing discretion. In this case, however, the agency that would

    receive authority has a record of good performance, enticing lawmakers to

    take advantage of its technical capacity (Bawn, 1995) by providing more

    discretion than they would have if the agency had a mediocre reputation.

    Ignoring considerations about performance, theory would predict a rela-tively high level of discretion for the former observation and a relatively low

    level of discretion for the latter. However, considerations about performance

    attenuate this relationship. Any model using these observations to probe the

    relationship between legislativeexecutive conflict and discretion that did

    not control for performance, then, would underestimate the magnitude of the

    relationship between interbranch policy conflict and discretion. Therefore,

    the findings of this research suggest that prior studies of discretion that do

    not control for performance observe a weaker connection than exists.

    Of course, our findings are based on a relatively small number of agen-

    cies whose inclusion in the sample was based on their close interaction with

    the public. Do lawmakers limit discretion based on performance generally?

    Or is this relationship conditional on the nature of agencies interaction

    with the public? Future research on the link between capacity and discre-

    tion should focus on developing measures of performance across more, and

    different types of, agencies to answer these questions. This is especially the

    case given there is good reason to believe that many of the factors influ-

    encing the volume of discretion agencies receive are conditional. Forexample, Volden (2002) theorizes that interbranch policy disagreement

    influences how much discretion agencies receive conditional on the existence

    of an executive veto. Similarly, Huber and Shipan (2002) theorize that the

    professional capacity of legislatures to craft effective policies conditions

    802 American Politics Research

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    15/19

    MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion 803

    whether interbranch disagreement affects how much discretion agencies

    receive, and they provide empirical support for this perspective.

    Additionally, although our findings support the hypothesis that (a lackof) capacity (reduces) increases the policymaking authority that agencies

    receive, there are several causal mechanisms that can account for this rela-

    tionship. A goal of future research should be to explore the underlying

    cause. Do lawmakers cede (reduce) authority based on assessments of how

    likely the agencys actions are to lead to negative political fallout? Are law-

    makers concerned intrinsically about the quality of policies created by

    agencies when providing authority?

    Appendix A

    Federal Agencies Graded by the Federal Performance Project

    Agency Year of Grade Grade

    Coast Guard 2000 A

    National Weather Service 2001 A

    Social Security Administration 1999 A

    Postal service 2001 A

    Administration for Children and Families 2001 B

    Army Corps of Engineers 2000 B

    Federal Emergency Management Agency 1999 B

    Food and Drug Administration 1999 B

    Food and Nutrition Service 1999 B

    Food Safety and Inspection Service 1999 B

    NASA 2001 B

    Veterans Health Administration 1999 B

    Environmental Protection Agency 1999 BFederal Housing Administration 1999 B

    Occupational Safety and Health Administration 1999 B

    Patent and Trademark Office 1999 B

    Veterans Benefits Administration 2000 B

    Bureau of Consular Affairs 2001 C

    Customs service 1999 C

    Federal Aviation Administration 1999 C

    Forest service 2001 C

    Health Care Financing Administration 1999 C

    Internal Revenue Service 1999 CNational Park Service 2000 C

    Office of Student Financial Assistance 2000 C

    Immigration and Naturalization Service 1999 C

    Bureau of Indian Affairs 2001 D

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    16/19

    Appendix B

    Descriptive Statistics

    Variable Minimum Maximum Mean Standard Deviation

    Limitation riders 6 36 21.63 7.62

    Grade dummies

    B 0 1 0.48 0.51

    C 0 1 0.33 0.48

    D 0 1 0.04 0.19

    Traditional grade scale 2 5 3.74 0.76

    Plus/minus grade scale 4 13 8.96 2.24

    Divided government 0 1 0.56 0.51Unified and hostile government 0 1 0.11 0.32

    No. ofNew York Times stories 0 304 58.63 75.65

    No. of pages in bill 28 98 65.85 21.33

    Notes

    1. Briefly, the criteria included how well managers defined and measured success, man-

    aged agency resources, took measures to ensure that managers were held accountable for deci-

    sions and performance, communicated effectively and honestly with stakeholders and politicalprincipals, ensured that employees possessed information necessary to perform tasks to

    achieve results, staffed individuals with appropriate skills for the tasks they performed, pos-

    sessed the physical infrastructure necessary to achieve the results, and provided sound fiscal

    management.

    2. The FPP interviews included groups such as congressional oversight and appropria-

    tions committees, the GAO, the OMB, think tanks, the press, client and advocacy groups, aca-

    demic institutions, and government commissions (Laurent, 1999). More detailed information

    about the FPP can be found on the projects Web site: http://www.gwu.edu/~fpp/. Also see

    Ingraham et al. (2003).

    3. Another source on agency performance is the Performance Assessment Rating Tool

    (PART) through which the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) evaluates the performance

    of federal programs. Using PART data would increase the size of the sample of agencies.

    However, given that the OMB works directly for the president within the executive office of

    the president (EOP), and given that presidents politicize the work of the EOP (Lewis, 2005;

    Moe, 1985), we believe that PART ratings are likely to be endogenous to the political priori-

    ties of the president, making them an invalid measurement of agency performance.

    4. The grades assigned to agencies by the FPP can be found in Laurent (1999, 2000, 2001).

    5. Measuring the volume of authority stripped from agencies in this way has an advan-

    tage. It is possible that agencies that possess high levels of discretion develop greater capaci-

    ties than agencies that possess low levels of discretion. If this were the case, employing a

    dependent variable that measures the volume of discretion that agencies possess would pre-

    clude unbiased estimates of the influence of capacity on discretion because higher levels of

    discretion also cause high levels of capacity. However, our indicator measures the volume of

    authority taken away from an agency in year t+ 1. Authority taken away in the future cannot

    804 American Politics Research

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    17/19

    affect agency capacity in the present. Additionally, existing research on the link between

    agency capacity and authority emphasizes that capacity leads to authority (Carpenter, 2001)

    rather than the other way around, suggesting that, at any rate, managerial capacity is notendogenous to the volume of discretion agencies possess.

    6. All the agencies graded by the FPP receive funding from these bills. We examined the

    versions of bills that became public lawrather than House/Senate committee passed or

    House/Senate passed versions.

    7. To count LRs, we first identified the bill in which the agency was funded. Next, we

    counted the number of instances stating no funds or none of the funds could be spent for

    specific purposes that applied to the agency. LRs applied to the agency if they were located in

    the specific section funding the agency, or a general provisions section, or title that applied to

    the agency. Using counts of the number of LRs in the year during which, and the year before,

    performance was graded did not change the findings reported below.8. This count was obtained through a Lexis/Nexis search of agency names, as they

    appear in Appendix A, in the titles and lead paragraphs ofNew York Times stories in the year

    before the agencys managerial performance was graded.

    9. Ringquist et al. (2003) also examine the relationship between complexity and con-

    gressional efforts to direct the bureaucracy, finding no direct relationship between complexity

    and such efforts even though complexity does condition the relationship between salience and

    such efforts. We opt not to control for complexity in our analysis because of the following:

    The primary focus of our analysis does not involve the relationship between policy type

    and discretion.

    These authors found no direct relationship between complexity and such efforts.There is no readily available measure of complexity across agencies.

    The degrees of freedom in our analysis is small to begin with.

    10. Huber and Shipan (2002) identify factors, such as legislative capacity that vary across

    legislatures influencing the level of discretion agencies receive. In the analysis below, we

    focus on cases in which a single legislature delegates authority. Therefore, these factors are

    constant and cannot explain variance in our dependent variable.

    11. The note in Table 2 provides information on these baseline values. Predictions were

    calculated using Clarify 2.1 (Tomz, Wittenberg, & King, 2003).

    12. These results are available from the authors on request.

    13. The results of this estimation are available from the authors on request.14. The title of VandeHeis article in The Washington Post illustrates the alacrity with

    which members of Congress and the President sought to avoid the political costs of Federal

    Emergency Management Agencys (FEMA) failure: Officials Deal with Political Fallout by

    Pointing Fingers.

    References

    Arnold, R. D. (1990). The logic of congressional action. New Haven, CT:Yale University Press.Bawn, K. (1995, March). Political control versus expertise: Congressional choices about

    administrative procedures.American Political Science Review, 89, 62-73.

    Carpenter, D. P. (2000). Stochastic prediction and estimation of nonlinear political durations:

    An application to the lifetime of bureaus. In D. Richards (Ed.), Political complexity:

    Nonlinear models of politics (pp. 209-238). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion 805

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    18/19

    806 American Politics Research

    Carpenter, D. P. (2001). The forging of bureaucratic autonomy: Reputations, networks and

    policy innovation in executive agencies, 1862-1928. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Carpenter, D. P., & Lewis, D. E. (2004, Summer). Political learning from rare events: Poissoninference, fiscal constraints, and the lifetime of bureaus. Political Analysis, 12, 201-232.

    Epstein, D., & OHalloran, S. (1999).Delegating powers: A transaction cost politics approach

    to policy making under separate powers. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Esterling, K. M. (2004). The political economy of expertise: Information and efficiency in

    American national institutions. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Gormley, W. (1986). Regulatory issue networks in a federal system. Polity, 18(4), 595-620.

    Gormley, W. (1989). Taming the bureaucracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Huber, J. D., & Shipan, C. R. (2002).Deliberate discretion: The institutional foundations of

    bureaucratic autonomy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Huber, J. D., Shipan, C. R., & Pfahler, M. (2001, April). Legislatures and statutory control ofthe bureaucracy.American Journal of Political Science, 45, 330-345.

    Ingraham, P., Joyce, P. K., & Donahue, A. K. (2003). Government performance: Why manage-

    ment matters. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    James, S. C. (2000). Presidents, parties, and the state: A party system perspective on democ-

    ratic regulatory choice, 1884-1936. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Jones, B. D., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2005). The politics of attention: How governments prior-

    itize problems. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Laurent,A. (1999, February 1). Stacking up. Government Executive, 31(2). Retrieved April 30,

    2007, from http://www.govexec.com/gpp/0299over.htm

    Laurent, A. (2000, March 1). Measuring up. Government Executive, 32(3), 10-15. RetrievedApril 30, 2007, from http://www.govexec.com/gpp/0300ov.htm

    Laurent, A. (2001, April 1). Managing for results. Government Executive, 33(4). Retrieved

    April 30, 2007, from http://www.govexec.com/fpp/fpp01/s1.htm

    Lewis, D. E. (2003). Presidents and the politics of agency design: Political insulation in the

    United States government bureaucracy, 1946-1997. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Lewis, D. E. (2005, September). Staffing alone: Unilateral action and the politicization of the

    executive office of the president, 1988-2004. Presidential Studies Quarterly, 35, 496-514.

    MacDonald, J. A. (2007). Competing agents: Managing policy through competition in the U.S.

    House of Representatives. Typescript, Kent State University, OH.

    McCubbins, M. D., Noll, R. G., & Weingast, B. R. (1987). Administrative procedures asinstruments of political control.Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 3, 243-277.

    McCubbins, M. D., & Schwartz, T. (1984). Congressional oversight overlooked: Police patrols

    versus fire alarms.American Journal of Political Science, 2, 165-179.

    Moe, T. M. (1985). The politicized presidency. In J. E. Chubb & P. E. Peterson (Eds.),New

    directions in American politics (pp. 235-271). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Moe, T. M. (1989). The politics of bureaucratic structure. In J. E. Chubb & P. E. Peterson

    (Eds.), Can the government govern? (pp. 267-330). Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

    Page, B. I. (1996). Who deliberates? Mass media in modern democracy. Chicago: University

    of Chicago Press.

    Potoski, M. (1999, October). Managing uncertainty through bureaucratic design: Administrativeprocedures and state air pollution control agencies. Journal of Public Administration

    Research and Theory, 9, 623-639.

    Ringquist, E. J., Worsham, J., & Eisner, M. A. (2003). Salience, complexity, and the legislative

    direction of regulatory bureaucracies. Journal of Public Administration Research and

    Theory, 13, 141-164.

    distribution. 2007 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized

    by marta pohrib on November 27, 2007http://apr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/http://apr.sagepub.com/
  • 7/29/2019 Bureaucratic Capacity

    19/19

    Tomz, M., Wittenberg, J., & King, G. (2003, January 5). CLARIFY: Software for interpreting

    and presenting statistical results (version 2.1). Stanford University, University of Wisconsin,

    and Harvard University. Retrieved March 10, 2006, from http://gking.harvard.eduVandeHei, J. (2005, September 5). Officials deal with political fallout by pointing fingers. The

    Washington Post, p. A17.

    Volden, C. (2002, January). A formal model of the politics of delegation in a separation of

    powers system.American Journal of Political Science, 46, 111-133.

    Weisman, J., & Goldstein, A. (2005, September 8). Bush requests $51.8 billion more for relief;

    GOP leaders launch inquiry on Katrina preparation and response. The Washington Post,

    pp. A1+.

    Wood, B. D., & Bohte, J. (2004, February). Political transaction costs and the politics of

    administrative design.Journal of Politics, 66, 176-202.

    Jason A. MacDonald is an assistant professor in the Department of Political Science at Kent

    State University.

    William W. Franko Jr. is a PhD candidate in the Department of Political Science at Kent

    State University.

    MacDonald, Franko / Bureaucratic Capacity and Bureaucratic Discretion 807